Optimal insider control of systems with delay
arXiv:1610.07311v1 [math.OC] 24 Oct 2016
Olfa Draouil1 and Bernt Øksendal2,3
11 October 2016
MSC(2010): 60H05; 60H07; 60H40; 60G57; 91B70; 93E20.
Keywords: Stochastic delay equation; optimal control; inside information; Donsker delta
functional; stochastic maximum principles; time-advanced BSDE; optimal insider portfolio
in a financial market with delay.
Abstract
We study the problem of optimal inside control of a stochastic delay equation
driven by a Brownian motion and a Poisson random measure. We prove a sufficient
and a necessary maximum principle for the optimal control when the trader from
the beginning has inside information about the future value of some random variable
related to the system.
The results are applied to the problem of finding the optimal insider portfolio in a
financial market where the risky asset price is given by a stochastic delay equation.
1
Introduction
In this paper we consider an insider’s optimal control problem for a stochastic process X(t) =
X(t, Z) = X u (t, Z) defined as the solution of a stochastic differential delay equation of the
form
= dX(t, Z) = b(t, X(t, Z), Y (t, Z), u(t, Z))dt + σ(t, X(t, Z), Y (t, Z), u(t, Z))dB(t)
dX(t)
R
+ R γ(t, X(t, Z), Y (t, Z), u(t, Z), ζ)Ñ(dt, dζ), 0 ≤ t ≤ T
X(t) = ξ(t), −δ ≤ t ≤ 0
1
Department of Mathematics, University of Tunis El Manar, Tunis, Tunisia.
Email:
[email protected]
2
Department of Mathematics, University of Oslo, P.O. Box 1053 Blindern, N–0316 Oslo, Norway.
Email:
[email protected]
3
This research was carried out with support of the Norwegian Research Council, within the research
project Challenges in Stochastic Control, Information and Applications (STOCONINF), project number
250768/F20.
1
where
Y (t, Z) = X(t − δ, Z),
(1.1)
δ > 0 being a fixed constant (the delay).
Here B(t) and Ñ (dt, dζ) is a Brownian motion and an independent compensated Poisson random measure, respectively, jointly defined on a filtered probability space (Ω, F = {Ft }t≥0 , P)
satisfying the usual conditions. T > 0 is a given constant.We refer to [ØS1] for more information about stochastic calculus for ItÙ-Lévy processes.
The process u(t, Z) = u(t, x, z)z=Z is our insider control process, where Z is a given FT0 measurable random variable for some T0 > 0 , representing the inside information available
to the controller.
We assume that the inside information is of initial enlargement type. Specifically, we
assume that the inside filtration H has the form
H = {Ht }0≤t≤T , where Ht = Ft ∨ σ(Z)
(1.2) {eq1.1}
for all t, where Z is a given FT0 -measurable random variable, for some T0 > 0 (constant).
Here
T and in the following we use the right-continuous version of H, i.e. we put Ht = Ht+ =
s>t Hs .
We also assume that the Donsker delta functional of Z exists (see below). This assumption implies that the Jacod condition holds, and hence that B(·) and N(·, ·) are semimartingales with respect to H. See e.g. [DØ2] for details. We assume that the value at time t of
our insider control process u(t) is allowed to depend on both Z and Ft . In other words, u(.)
is assumed to be H-adapted, such that u(., z) is F-adapted for each z ∈ R.
Let U denote the set of admissible control values.We assume that the functions
b(t, x, y, u, z) = b(t, x, y, u, z, ω) : [0, T ] × R × R × U × R × Ω 7→ R
σ(t, x, y, u, z) = σ(t, x, y, u, z, ω) : [0, T ] × R × R × U × R × Ω 7→ R
γ(t, x, y, u, z, ζ) = γ(t, x, y, u, z, ζ, ω) : [0, T ] × R × R × U × R × R × Ω 7→ R
(1.3)
are given bounded C 1 functions with respect to x, y and u and adapted processes in (t, ω)
for each given x, y, u, z, ζ. Let A be a given family of admissible H−adapted controls u. The
performance functional J(u) of a control process u ∈ A is defined by
Z
J(u) = E[
T
f (t, X(t, Z), u(t, Z), Z))dt + g(X(T, Z), Y (T, Z), Z)],
(1.4) {eq1.4}
0
where
f (t, x, u, z) : [0, T ] × R × U × R 7→ R
g(x, z) : R × R 7→ R
2
(1.5)
are given bounded functions, C 1 with respect to x and u. The functions f and g are called
the profit rate and terminal payoff, respectively. For completeness of the presentation we
allow these functions to depend explicitly on the future value Z also, although this would
not be the typical case in applications. But it could be that f and g are influenced by
the future value Z directly through the action of an insider, in addition to being influenced
indirectly through the control process u and the corresponding state process X.The problem
we consider is the following:
Problem 1.1 Find u⋆ ∈ A such that
sup J(u) = J(u⋆ ).
(1.6)
{eq1.5}
u∈A
2
The Donsker delta functional
To study this problem we adapt the technique of the paper [DØ1] to the SDE with delay
situation. For the convenience of the reader we first recall briefly the definition and basic
properties of the Donsker delta functional:
Definition 2.1 Let Z : Ω → R be a random variable which also belongs to (S)∗ . Then a
continuous functional
δZ (.) : R → (S)∗
(2.1)
is called a Donsker delta functional of Z if it has the property that
Z
g(z)δZ (z)dz = g(Z) a.s.
(2.2)
{donsker}
{donsker pr
R
for all (measurable) g : R → R such that the integral converges.
For example, consider the special case when Z is a first order chaos random variable of
the form
Z t
Z tZ
Z = Z(T0 ); where Z(t) =
β(s)dB(s) +
ψ(s, ζ)Ñ(ds, dζ), for t ∈ [0, T0 ] (2.3) {eq2.5}
0
0
R
for some deterministic functions β 6= 0, ψ such that
Z T0
Z
2
{β (t) + ψ 2 (t, ζ)ν(dζ)}dt < ∞ a.s.
0
R
and for every ǫ > 0 there exists ρ > 0 such that
Z
eρζ ν(dζ) < ∞.
R\(−ǫ,ǫ)
3
(2.4)
This condition implies that the polynomials are dense in L2 (µ), where dµ(ζ) = ζ 2 dν(ζ).
It also guarantees that the measure ν integrates all polynomials of degree ≥ 2.
In this case it is well known (see e.g. [MØP], [DiØ1], Theorem 3.5, and [DØP],[DiØ2]) that
the Donsker delta functional exists in (S)∗ and is given by
Z
Z Z
Z T0
T0
1
⋄
ixψ(s,ζ)
δZ (z) =
exp
(e
− 1)Ñ(ds, dζ) +
ixβ(s)dB(s)
2π R
0
R
0
Z T0 Z
1
+
{ (eixψ(s,ζ) − 1 − ixψ(s, ζ))ν(dζ) − x2 β 2 (s)}ds − ixz dx,
(2.5)
2
0
R
where exp⋄ denotes the Wick exponential. Moreover, we have for t < T0
E[δZ (z)|Ft ]
Z Z
Z
Z t
t
1
exp
ixψ(s, ζ)Ñ(ds, dζ) +
ixβ(s)dB(s)
=
2π R
0
R
0
Z T0 Z
Z T0
1 2 2
ixψ(s,ζ)
+
(e
− 1 − ixψ(s, ζ))ν(dζ)ds −
x β (s)ds − ixz dx.
2
t
R
t
(2.6)
(2.7)
If Dt and Dt,ζ denotes the Hida-Malliavin derivative at t and t, ζ with respect to B and
Ñ , respectively, we have
and
E[Dt δZ (z)|Ft ] =
Z Z
Z
Z t
t
1
exp
ixψ(s, ζ)Ñ(ds, dζ) +
ixβ(s)dB(s)
2π R
0
R
0
Z T0 Z
Z T0
1 2 2
ixψ(s,ζ)
x β (s)ds − ixz ixβ(t)dx
+
(e
− 1 − ixψ(s, ζ))ν(dζ)ds −
2
t
R
t
(2.8)
E[Dt,z δZ (z)|Ft ] =
Z Z
Z
Z t
t
1
exp
ixψ(s, ζ)Ñ(ds, dζ) +
ixβ(s)dB(s)
2π R
0
R
0
Z T0 Z
Z T0
1 2 2
ixψ(s,ζ)
x β (s)ds − ixz (eixψ(t,z) − 1)dx. (2.9)
+
(e
− 1 − ixψ(s, ζ))ν(dζ)ds −
2
t
R
t
For more information about the Donsker delta functional, Hida-Malliavin calculus and
their properties, see [DØ1].
From now on we assume that Z is a given random variable which also belongs to (S)∗ ,
with a Donsker delta functional δZ (z) ∈ (S)∗ satisfying
E[δZ (z)|FT ] ∈ L2 (FT , P )
and
E[
Z
(2.10)
T
(E[Dt δZ (z)|Ft ])2 dt] < ∞, for all z.
0
4
(2.11)
3
Transforming the insider control problem to a related parametrized non-insider problem
Since X(t) is H-adapted, we get by using the definition of the Donsker delta functional δZ (z)
of Z that
Z
X(t) = X(t, Z) = X(t, z)z=Z =
X(t, z)δZ (z)dz
(3.1) {eq1.6}
R
for some z-parametrized process X(t, z) which is F-adapted for each z.
Then, again by the definition of the Donsker delta functional we can write, for 0 ≤ t ≤ T
Z t
Z t
X(t) = ξ(0, Z) +
[b(s, X(s), Y (s), u(s, Z), Z)]ds +
σ(s, X(s), Y (s), u(s, Z), Z)dB(s)
0
0
Z tZ
+
γ(s, X(s), Y (s), u(s, Z), Z, ζ)Ñ(ds, dζ)
0
R
Z t
= ξ(0, z)z=Z +
[b(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z)]z=Z ds
0
Z t
+
σ(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z)z=Z dB(s)
0
Z tZ
+
γ(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z, ζ)z=Z Ñ(ds, dζ)
0
R
Z
Z tZ
=
ξ(x, z)δZ (z)dz +
[b(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z)]δZ (z)dzds
R
0
R
Z tZ
+
σ(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z)δZ (z)dzdB(s)
0
R
Z tZ Z
+
γ(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z, ζ)δZ (z)dz Ñ (ds, dζ)
0
R R
Z
Z t
Z t
= {ξ(0, z) +
[b(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z)]ds +
σ(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z)dB(s)
R
0
0
Z tZ
+
γ(s, X(s, z), Y (s, z), u(s, z), z, ζ)Ñ(ds, dζ)}δZ (z)dz.
(3.2) {eq1.7}
0
R
Comparing (3.1) and (3.2) we see that (3.1) holds if we for each z choose X(t, z) as the
solution of the classical (but parametrized) SPDE
z) = [b(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), u(t, z), z)]dt + σ(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), u(t, z), z)dB(t)
dX(t,
R
+ R γ(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), u(t, z), z, ζ)Ñ(dt, dζ); t ∈ [0, T ]
X(t, z) = ξ(t); t ∈ [−δ, 0]
(3.3) {eq3.3}
As before let A be the given family of admissible H−adapted controls u. Then in terms
of X(t, z) the performance functional J(u) of a control process u ∈ A defined in (1.4) gets
the form
5
Z T
J(u) = E[
f (t, X(t, Z), u(t, Z), Z)dt + g(X(T, Z), Z)]
0
Z T Z
Z
= E[
( f (t, X(t, z), u(t, z), z)E[δZ (z)|Ft ]dz)dt + g(X(T, z), z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]dz]
R
R
Z 0
=
j(u)(z)dz,
(3.4) {eq0.13}
R
where
j(u)(z) := E[
Z
T
f (t, X(t, z), u(t, z), z)E[δZ (z)|Ft ]dt
0
+ g(X(T, z), z)E[δZ (z)|FT ].
(3.5) {eq1.5}
Thus we see that to maximize J(u) it suffices to maximize j(u)(z) for each value of the
parameter z ∈ R. Therefore Problem 1.1 is transformed into the problem
Problem 3.1 For each given z ∈ R find u⋆ = u⋆ (t, z) ∈ A such that
sup j(u)(z) = j(u⋆ )(z).
(3.6)
{problem2}
u∈A
4
A sufficient-type maximum principle
In this section we will establish a sufficient maximum principle for Problem 3.1.
Problem 3.1 is a stochastic control problem with a standard (albeit parametrized) stochastic partial differential equation (3.3) for the state process X(t, z), but with a non-standard
performance functional given by (3.5). We can solve this problem by a modified maximum
principle approach, as follows:
Define the Hamiltonian H : [0, T ] × R × R × U × R × R × R × R × Ω → R by
H(t, x, y, u, z, p, q, r) = H(t, x, y, u, z, p, q, r, ω)
= E[δZ (z)|Ft ]f (t, x, u, z) + b(t, x, y, u, z)p
Z
+ σ(t, x, y, u, z)q + γ(t, x, y, u, z, ζ)r(ζ)ν(dζ).
(4.1) {eq4.1}
R
R denotes the set of all functions r(·) : R → R such that the last integral above
converges. The quantities p, q, r(·) are called the adjoint variables. The adjoint processes
p(t, z), q(t, z), r(t, z, ζ) are defined as the solution of the z-parametrized advanced backward
stochastic differential equation (ABSDE)
6
dp(t, z) = E[µ(t, z)|Ft ]dt + q(t, z)dB(t) +
∂g
p(T, z) = ∂x
(X(T, z))E[δZ (z)|FT ]
R
R
r(t, z, ζ)Ñ(dt, dζ) t ∈ [0, T ]
where
∂H
(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), u(t, z), p(t, z), q(t, z))
∂x
∂H
(t + δ, X(t + δ, z), Y (t + δ, z), u(t + δ, z), p(t + δ, z), q(t + δ, z))1[0,T −δ] (t) (4.2)
−
∂y
µ(t, z) = −
We can now state the first maximum principle for our problem (3.6):
Theorem 4.1 [Sufficient-type maximum principle]
Let û ∈ A, and denote the associated solution of (3.3) and (4.2) by X̂(t, z) and
(p̂(t, z), q̂(t, z), r̂(t, z, ζ)), respectively. Assume that the following hold:
1. x → g(x, z) is concave for all z
2. (x, y, u) → H(t, x, y, u, z, pb(t, z), qb(t, z), r̂(t, z, ζ)) is concave for all t, z, ζ
3. supw∈U H t, X̂(t, z), Yb (t, z), w, pb(t, z), qb(t, z), r̂(t, z, ζ)
= H t, X̂(t, z), Yb (t, z), u
b(t, z), pb(t, z), qb(t, z), r̂(t, z, ζ) for all t, z, ζ.
Then u
b(·, z) is an optimal insider control for Problem 3.1.
Proof.
By considering an increasing sequence of stopping times τn converging to T , we
may assume that all local integrals appearing in the computations below are martingales
and hence have expectation 0. See [ØS2]. We omit the details.
Choose arbitrary u(., z) ∈ A, and let the corresponding solution of (3.3) and (4.2) be X(t, z),
p(t, x, z), q(t, x, z), r(t, x, z, ζ). For simplicity of notation we write
b z), u
f (t) = f (t, X(t, z), u(t, z)), fb(t) = f (t, x, X(t,
b(t, z)) and similarly with b, bb, σ, σ
b and so
on.
Moreover put
b z), Yb (t, z), u
Ĥ(t) = H(t, X(t,
b(t, z), pb(t, z), qb(t, z), rb(t, z, .))
and
H(t) = H(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), u(t, z), pb(t, z), qb(t, z), rb(t, z, .))
e = X − X.
b
In the following we write fe = f − fb, eb = b − bb, X
Consider
j(u(., z)) − j(b
u(., z)) = I1 + I2 ,
where
I1 = E[
Z
T
0
{f (t) − fb(t)}E[δZ (z)|Ft ]dt],
(4.3)
(4.4)
I2 = E[(g(X(T, z), z) − g(X̂(T, z), z))E[δZ (z)|FT ]].
(4.5) {eq4.7}
7
By the definition of H and the concavity of H, we have
Z T
b z) − pb(t, z)eb(t, z) − qb(t, z)e
I1 = E[
{H(t, z) − H(t,
σ (t, z)
0
Z
− r̂(t, z, ζ)γ̃(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ)}dt]
R
h Z T ∂ Ĥ
∂ Ĥ
≤E
(t, z)X̃(t, z) +
(t, z)Ỹ (t, z)
(
∂x
∂y
0
∂ Ĥ
+
(t, z)ũ(t, z) − pb(t, z)eb(t, z) − qb(t, z)e
σ (t, z)
∂u
Z
i
− r̂(t, z, ζ)γ̃(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ))dt
(4.6) {eq4.8}
R
Since g is concave with respect to x we have
(g(X(T, z), z) − g(X̂(T, z), z))E[δZ (z)|FT ]
∂g
(X̂(T, z), z)E[δZ (z)|FT ](X(T, z) − X̂(T, z)),
≤
∂x
(4.7)
and hence
∂g b
e
I2 ≤ E[ (X(T,
z))E[δZ (z)|FT ]X̃(T, z)] = E[b
p(T, z)X(T,
z)]
∂x
Z T
Z T
Z T
e
e
= E[
pb(t, z)dX(t, z) +
X(t, z)db
p(t, z) +
d[p̂, X̃]t ]
0
0
0
Z T
e z)E[µ(t, z)|Ft ]
= E[
{b
p(t, z)eb(t, z) + X(t,
0
Z
+σ
e(t, z)b
q (t, z) + γ̃(t, z, ζ)r̂(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ)}dt].
(4.8) {eq4.11}
R
Combining (4.6) and (4.8) we obtain using the fact X(t) = X̂(t) = ξ(t) for all t ∈ [−δ, 0]
hZ
j(u(., z)) − j(b
u(., z)) ≤ E
where
T
∂ Ĥ
∂ Ĥ
(t, z)X̃(t, z) +
(t, z)Ỹ (t, z)
∂x
∂y
0
i
∂ Ĥ
+
(t, z)ũ(t, z) + µ(t, z)X̃(t, z))dt
∂u
h Z T +δ ∂ Ĥ
∂ Ĥ
=E
{
(t − δ, z) +
(t, z)1[0,T ] (t) + µ̂(t − δ, z)}Ỹ (t, z)dt
∂x
∂y
δ
Z T
i
∂ Ĥ
+
(t, z)ũ(t, z)dt
(4.9) {eq4.11a}
∂u
0
(
µ̂(t − δ, z) =
∂ Ĥ
∂ Ĥ
(t − δ, z) +
(t, z)1[0,T ] (t)
∂x
∂y
8
(4.10)
then
hZ
j(u(., z)) − j(b
u(., z)) ≤ E
hZ
E
T
0
hZ
E
T
0
≤0
i
∂ Ĥ
(t, z)ũ(t, z)dt
∂u
0
i
∂ Ĥ
(t, z)ũ(t, z)|Ft ]dt
E[
∂u
i
∂ Ĥ
E[
(t, z)|Ft ]ũ(t, z)dt
∂u
T
(4.11)
The last inequality holds because of the maximum condition of H. Hence j(u) ≤ j(û).
Since u ∈ A was arbitrary, this shows that û is optimal.
5
A necessary-type maximum principle
In some cases the concavity conditions of Theorem 4.1 do not hold. In such situations a
corresponding necessary-type maximum principle can be useful. For this, instead of the
concavity conditions we need the following assumptions about the set of admissible control
values:
• A1 . For all t0 ∈ [0, T ] and all bounded Ht0 -measurable random variables α(z, ω), the
control θ(t, z, ω) := 1[t0 ,T ] (t)α(z, ω) belongs to A.
• A2 . For all u; β0 ∈ A with β0 (t, z) ≤ K < ∞ for all t, z define
δ(t, z) =
1
dist((u(t, z), ∂U) ∧ 1 > 0
2K
(5.1) {delta}
and put
β(t, z) = δ(t, z)β0 (t, z).
Then the control
u
e(t, z) = u(t, z) + aβ(t, z);
t ∈ [0, T ]
belongs to A for all a ∈ (−1, 1).
• A3. For all β as in (5.2) the derivative process
χ(t, z) :=
d u+aβ
X
(t, z)|a=0
da
9
(5.2) {beta(t,z)}
exists, and belongs to L2 (λ × P) and
∂b
∂b
∂b
(t, z)χ(t, z) + ∂y
(t, z)χ(t − δ, z) + ∂u
(t, z)β(t, z)]dt
dχ(t, z) = [ ∂x
+[ ∂σ (t, z)χ(t, z) + ∂σ (t, z)χ(t − δ, z) + ∂σ (t, z)β(t, z)]dB(t)
∂y
∂u
R∂x ∂γ
∂γ
(t,
z,
ζ)χ(t,
z)
+
(t,
z,
ζ)χ(t
−
δ,
z) + ∂γ
(t, z, ζ)β(t, z)]Ñ(dt, dζ)
+
[
∂y
∂u
R ∂x
χ(t, z) = 0 ∀t ∈ [−δ, 0].
(5.3) {d chi}
Theorem 5.1 [Necessary maximum principle]
Let û ∈ A. Then the following are equivalent:
1.
d
J((û
da
+ aβ)(., z))|a=0 = 0 for all bounded β ∈ A of the form (5.2).
(t, z)|Ft ]u=û = 0 for all t ∈ [0, T ].
2. E[ ∂H
∂u
Proof. For simplicity of notation we write u instead of û in the following.
By considering an increasing sequence of stopping times τn converging to T , we may assume
that all local integrals appearing in the computations below are martingales and have expectation 0. See [ØS2]. We omit the details.
We can write
d
J((u + aβ)(., z))|a=0 = I1 + I2
da
where
d
I1 = E[
da
Z
T
f (t, X u+aβ (t, z), u(t, z) + aβ(t, z), z)E[δZ (z)|Ft ]dt]|a=0
0
and
d
E[g(X u+aβ (T, z), z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]]|a=0 .
da
By our assumptions on f and g and by (4.1) we have
I2 =
Z T
∂f
∂f
∂f
(t, z)χ(t − δ, z) +
(t, z)β(t, z)}E[δZ (z)|Ft ]dt]
I1 = E[
{ (t, z)χ(t, z) +
∂x
∂y
∂u
0
Z T
Z
∂γ
∂H
∂b
∂σ
= E[
{
(t, z) −
(t, z)p(t, z) −
(t, z)q(t, z) −
(t, z, ζ)r(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ)}χ(t, z)dt
∂x
∂x
∂x
0
R ∂x
Z T
Z
∂H
∂b
∂σ
∂γ
+
{
(t, z) −
(t, z)p(t, z) −
(t, z)q(t, z) −
(t, z, ζ)r(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ)}χ(t − δ, z)dt
∂y
∂y
∂y
0
R ∂y
Z T
∂f
(t, z)β(t, z)E[δZ (z)|Ft ]dt]
(5.4) {iii1}
+
0 ∂u
I2 = E[g ′ (X(T, z), z)χ(T, z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]] = E[p(T, z)χ(T, z)]
10
(5.5) {iii2}
By the Itô formula
I2 =
=
−
+
+
Z T
Z T
Z T
E[p(T, z)χ(T, z)] = E[
p(t, z)dχ(t, z) +
χ(t, z)dp(t, z) +
d[χ, p](t, z)](5.6)
0
0
0
Z T
∂b
∂b
∂b
(t, z)χ(t − δ, z) +
(t, z)β(t, z)}dt
E[
p(t, z){ (t, z)χ(t, z) +
∂x
∂y
∂u
0
Z T
χ(t, z)E[µ(t, z)|Ft ]dt
0
Z T
∂σ
∂σ
∂σ
q(t, z){ (t, z)χ(t, z) +
(t, z)χ(t − δ, z) +
(t, z)β(t, z)}dt
∂x
∂y
∂u
0
Z TZ
∂γ
∂γ
∂γ
{ (t, z, ζ)χ(t, z) +
(t, z, ζ)χ(t, z) +
(t, z, ζ)β(t, z)}r(t, z, ζ)ν(ζ)dt]
∂y
∂u
0
R ∂x
Summing (5.4) and (5.6) we get
Z T
∂H
d
J((u + aβ)(., y))|a=0 = I1 + I2 = E[
(t, z) + µ(t, z)}dt
χ(t, z){
da
∂x
0
Z T
∂H
∂H
+
χ(t − δ, z)
(t, z) +
(t, z)β(t, z)dt]
∂y
∂u
0
Z T
∂H
∂H
∂H
(t, z) −
(t, z) −
(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)}dt
= E[
χ(t, z){
∂x
∂x
∂y
0
Z T
∂H
∂H
(t, z) +
(t, z)β(t, z)dt]
+
χ(t − δ, z)
∂y
∂u
0
Z T
∂H
= E[
(t, z)β(t, z)dt]
∂u
0
we conclude that
RT
if and only if E[ 0
(5.7)
d
J((u + aβ)(., z))|a=0 = 0
da
∂H
(t, z)β(t, z)dt]
∂u
= 0 for all bounded β ∈ A of the form (5.2).
In particular, applying this to β(t, z) = α(z, ω)1[s, T ](t) where α(z, ω) is bounded and Ft0
measurable, s ≥ t0 we obtain
Z T
∂H
(t, z)dtαdt] = 0
(5.8)
E[
∂u
s
Differentiating with respect to s, we get
E[
∂H
(s, z)α] = 0.
∂u
Since this holds for all s ≥ t0 and for all α, we conclude that
11
E[
∂H
(s, z)|Ft0 ] = 0.
∂u
6
Optimal insider portfolio in a financial market with
delay
As an application of the results above, consider a financial market with the following two
investment possibilities:
(i) A risk free asset, with unit price S0 (t) = 1 for all times t ≥ 0.
(ii) A risky asset, in which the investments have a delayed effect, in the following sense:
If we at time t invest in this asset the fraction π(t, Z) of the current wealth X(t, Z), then
we assume that the dynamics of the wealth X(t, Z) = X π (t, Z) is described by a stochastic
delay equation of the form
(
dX(t, Z) = π(t, Z)[α0 (t)X(t − δ, Z)dt + β0 (t)X(t, Z)dB(t)],
X(t, Z) = ξ(t), −δ ≤ t ≤ 0
0≤t≤T
(6.1) {eq6.1}
Here α0 (t) and β0 (t) are given bounded adapted processes and ξ is a given bounded deterministic function. The performance functional is defined by
Z
Z
J(π) = E[log X(T, Z)] = E[ log X(T, z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]dz] =
j(u)dz,
(6.2)
R
R
where
j(u) = j(u, z) = E[log X(T, z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]].
(6.3) {eq8.2}
Let AH be the set of H-adapted controls π(t) = π(t, Z) such that there is a unique solution
X(t) = X(t, Z) of (6.1) with X(T, Z) > 0 a.s. Note that equation (6.1) can be solved
inductively step by step in each interval [kδ, (k + 1)δ] for k = 0, 1, 2, .... We study the
following problem:
Problem 6.1 Find π ∗ ∈ AH (called an optimal control) such that:
sup J(π) = J(π ∗ )
(6.4)
π∈AH
This is a problem of the type investigated in the previous sections, in the special case
with no jumps and with controls π(t, z), and we can apply the results in Theorem 5.1 to
study it.
12
For studies of financial markets modelled by stochastic delay equations we refer to [AHMP1],
[AHMP2] and [KMT].
The Hamiltonian (4.1) gets the form, with u = π,
H(t, x, y, π, p, q) = πα0 yp + πβ0 xq
(6.5)
while the BSDE (4.2) for the adjoint processes becomes,
dp(t, z) = −{π(t, z)β0 (t)q(t, z) + E[α0 (t + δ)π(t + δ)p(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ]}dt
+q(t)dB(t)
1
p(T, z) = X(T,z)
E[δZ (z)|FT ]
The equation
∂
H(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), π, p(t, z), q(t, z)) = 0
∂π
(6.6)
α0 (t)X(t − δ, z)p(t, z) + β0 (t)X(t, z)q(t, z) = 0,
(6.7)
q(t, z) = −ψ(t, z)p(t, z),
(6.8)
is equivalent to
or
where
ψ(t, z) =
α0 (t)X(t − δ, z)
.
β0 (t)X(t, z)
(6.9)
Combining this with (6.1) we get
d(p(t, z)X(t, z)) = p(t, z)π(t, z)[α0 (t)X(t − δ, z)dt + β0 (t)X(t, z)dB(t)]
h
i
+ X(t, z) − {π(t, z)β0 (t)q(t, z) + E[α0 (t + δ)π(t + δ)p(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ]}dt + q(t)dB(t)
+ π(t, z)β0 (t)X(t, z)q(t, z)dt
(6.10)
Define
V (t, z) = p(t, z)X(t, z)
(6.11) {eq5.11}
W (t, z) = V (t, z)[π(t, z)β0 (t) − ψ(t, z)]
(6.12) {eq5.12}
and
then
2
2
dV (t, z) = {ψ(t, z)W (t, z) + ψ (t, z) − E[(ψ(t + δ, z)W (t + δ) + ψ (t + δ, z))1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ]}dt
+W (t, z)dB(t), 0 ≤ t ≤ T
V (T )
= E[δZ (z)|FT ].
For given ψ(t, z) this is a time-advanced BSDE in the unknown processes V (t, z) =
Vψ (t, z) and W (t, z) = Wψ (t, z) . It can be solved by backward induction, as in [ØSZ].
Then, solving (6.12) for π(t, z) and evaluating at z=Z, we get the following result:
13
Theorem 6.2 Suppose an optimal insider portfolio π ∗ (t, Z) of Problem 5.1 exists. Then it
is given in feedback form by
π ∗ (t, Z) =
Wψ (t, Z)
α0 (t) X(t − δ, Z)
.
+
,
2
β0 (t) X(t, Z)
β0 (t)Vψ (t, Z)
(6.13) {eq5.13}
where (V, W ) is the solution of the BSDE below (6.12).
Remark 6.3 (The no-delay case) Note that the above theorem also applies to the special case
when there is no delay, i.e. δ = 0. In this case we see that V (t, z) = E[δZ (z)|Ft ] and
W (t, z) = Dt V (t, z) = E[Dt δZ (z)|Ft ], and (6.13)reduces to
π ∗ (t, Z) =
α0 (t)
E[Dt δZ (z)|Ft ]z=Z
.
+
2
β0 (t) β0 (t)E[δZ (z)|Ft ]z=Z
(6.14)
This result has been proved in [ØR] and [DØ1] by different methods.
7
Optimal insider portfolio in a financial market with
delay (with jumps)
In this section we add jumps to the model discussed in Section 6. Thus we consider the
following controlled stochastic delay equation:
(
R
dX(t, z) = π(t, z)[α0 (t)X(t − δ, z)dt + β0 (t)X(t, z)dB(t) + R X(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)Ñ(dt, dζ)], 0 ≤ t ≤ T
X(t, z) = ξ(t), −δ ≤ t ≤ 0
(7.1) {eq1}
with performance functional given by
Z
Z
J(π) = E[log X(T, Z)] = E[ log X(T, z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]dz] =
j(u)dz,
(7.2)
R
R
where
j(u) = j(u, z) = E[log X(T, z)E[δZ (z)|FT ]],
(7.3) {eq8.2}
Let AH be the set of H-adapted controls π(t). We study the following problem:
Problem 7.1 Find π ∗ ∈ AH such that:
sup J(π) = J(π ∗ )
π∈AH
14
(7.4)
In this case the Hamiltonian (4.1) gets the form, with u = π,
Z
H(t, x, y, π, p, q) = πα0 (t)yp + πβ0 (t)xq + πx γ0 (t, ζ)r(ζ)ν(dζ)
(7.5)
R
while the BSDE (4.2) for the adjoint processes becomes,
R
dp(t, z) = −{π(t, z)[β0 (t)q(t, z) + R γ0 (t, ζ)r(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ)]
+E[α0 (t + δ)π(t + δ)p(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ]}dt
+q(t)dB(t)
p(T, z) = 1 E[δZ (z)|FT ]
X(T,z)
The equation
∂
H(t, X(t, z), Y (t, z), π, p(t, z), q(t, z), r(t, z, .)) = 0
∂π
(7.6)
is equivalent to
α0 (t)X(t − δ, z)p(t, z) + β0 (t)X(t, z)q(t, z) + X(t, z)
Z
γ0 (t, ζ)r(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ) = 0.
(7.7) {eq7.7}
R
Define
u(t, z) = p(t, z)X(t, z).
(7.8) {eq0.7}
Then by the Itô formula we get
du(t, z) = p(t, z)π(t, z)α0 (t)Y (t, z)dt − X(t, z)π(t, z)β0 (t, z)q(t, z)dt
Z
− X(t, z)π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)ν(dζ)dt
R
− X(t, z)E[α0 (t + δ)π(t + δ, z)p(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ]dt
+ p(t, z)π(t, z)β0 (t)X(t, z)dB(t) + X(t, z)q(t, z)dB(t)
+ q(t, z)X(t, z)π(t, z)β0 (t)dt
Z
+ {(X(t, z) + π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)X(t, z))(p(t, z) + r(t, z, ζ))
R
− p(t, z)X(t, z) − p(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)π(t, z)X(t, z) − X(t, z)r(t, z, ζ)}ν(dζ)dt
Z
+ {(X(t, z) + π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)X(t, z))(p(t, z) + r(t, z, ζ)) − p(t, z)X(t, z)}Ñ (dt, dζ)
R
= p(t, z)π(t, z)α0 (t)X(t − δ, z)dt − X(t, z)E[α0 (t + δ)π(t + δ, z)p(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ] dt
+ u(t, z)β0 (t)π(t, z) + X(t, z)q(t, z) dB(t)
Z
+
u(t, z)π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ) + X(t, z)r(t, z, ζ)(1 + π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)) Ñ(dt, dζ),
(7.9) {eq0.8}
R
15
Put
φ(t) := φ(t, z) := α0 (t)
X(t − δ)
,
X(t)
(7.10) {eq0.9}
and define
v(t, z) := u(t, z)β0 (t)π(t, z) + X(t, z)q(t, z)
(7.11) {eq7.10}
and
w(t, z, ζ) := u(t, z)π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ) + X(t, z)r(t, z, ζ)(1 + π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)).
(7.12) {eq7.11}
Then (7.9) can be written
du(t, z) = φ(t)π(t, z)u(t, z) − E[φ(t + δ)π(t + δ, z)u(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ] dt
Z
+ v(t, z)dB(t) + w(t, z, ζ)Ñ(dt, dζ),
(7.13) {eq7.12}
R
and the first order condition (7.7) gets the form
φ(t)u(t, z) + β0 (t)X(t, z)q(t, z) + X(t, z)
Z
γ0 (t, ζ)r(t, z, ζ)ν(dζ) = 0.
(7.14) {eq7.13}
R
With φ(t), u(t, z), v(t, z), w(t, z, ζ) (and the coefficients α0 (t), β0 (t), γ0 (t, ζ) ) given, the
equations (7.11),(7.12) and (7.14) constitutes a coupled system of 3 equations in the 3 unknowns π(t, z), X(t, z)q(t, z), X(t, z)r(t, z, ζ).
To investigate this system further, we proceed as follows:
From (7.11) we get:
X(t, z)q(t, z) = v(t, z) − u(t, z)β0 (t)π(t, z),
(7.15) {eq7.16}
and from (7.12) we get
X(t, z)r(t, z, ζ) =
w(t, z, ζ) − u(t, z)π(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)
1 + γ0 (t, ζ)π(t, z)
(7.16) {eq7.17}
Substituting (7.15) and (7.17) into (7.14) we obtain the following equation for the optimal
portfolio π(t, z) = π̂(t, z) = π̂(u,v,w) (t, z):
Z
w(t, z, ζ) − u(t, z)π̂(t, z)γ0 (t, ζ)
2
β0 (t)u(t, z)π̂(t, z)− γ0 (t, ζ)
ν(dζ) = φ(t, z)u(t, z)+β0 (t)v(t, z).
1 + γ0 (t, ζ)π̂(t, z)
R
(7.17) {eq7.17}
Substituting this into (7.13) we can conclude as follows:
Theorem 7.2 Suppose an optimal portfolio for Problem 7.1 exists and there exists a unique
solution π̂(t, z), (u(t, z), v(t, z), w(t, z, ζ)) of the coupled system consisting of (7.17) and the
BSDE
du(t, z) = φ(t)π̂(u,v,w) (t, z)u(t, z) − E[φ(t + δ)π̂(u,v,w) (t + δ, z)u(t + δ, z)1[0,T −δ] (t)|Ft ] dt
Z
+ v(t, z)dB(t) + w(t, z, ζ)Ñ(dt, dζ),
(7.18) {eq7.18}
R
u(T, z) = E[δZ (z)|FT ]
(7.19) {eq7.19}
16
Then the optimal insider portfolio π̂(t) is given by (7.17).
Remark 7.3 Equations (7.18)-(7.19) constitute a time-advanced BSDE which can (in principle) be solved backwards by proceeding as in [ØSZ].
References
[AHMP1] M. Arriojas, Y. Hu, S.-E. Mohammed and G.Pap: A delayed Black and Scholes
formula. Stochastic Analysis and Applications 25 (2007), 471-492.
[AHMP2] M. Arriojas, Y. Hu, S.-E. Mohammed and G.Pap: A delayed Black and Scholes
formula II. arxiv: 0604641v1,28 April 2006
[DØ1] O. Draouil and B. Øksendal: A Donsker delta functional approach to optimal insider
control and application to finance. Comm. Math. Stat. (CIMS) 3 (2015), 365-421;
DOI 10.1007/s40304-015-0065-y.
[DØ2] O. Draouil and B. Øksendal: Optimal insider control and semimartingale decompositions under enlargement of filtration. arXiv: 1512.01759v1 (6 Dec.2015). To appear
in Stochastic Analysis and Applications.
[DiØ1] G. Di Nunno and B. Øksendal: The Donsker delta function, a representation formula
for functionals of a Lévy process and application to hedging in incomplete markets.
Séminaires et Congrèes, Societé Mathématique de France, Vol. 16 (2007), 71-82.
[DiØ2] G. Di Nunno and B. Øksendal: A representation theorem and a sensitivity result
for functionals of jump diffusions. In A.B. Cruzeiro, H. Ouerdiane and N. Obata
(editors): Mathematical Analysis and Random Phenomena. World Scientific 2007,
pp. 177 - 190.
[DØP] G. Di Nunno, B. Øksendal and F. Proske: Malliavin Calculus for Lévy Processes
with Applications to Finance. Universitext, Springer 2009.
[KMT] E. Kemajou, S.-E. Mohammed and A. Tambue: A stochastic delay model for pricing
debt and loan guarantees: Theoretical results. arxiv: 1210.0570v2, 30 October 2012.
[MØP] S. Mataramvura, B. Øksendal and F. Proske: The Donsker delta function of a Lévy
process with application to chaos expansion of local time. Ann. Inst H. Poincaré Prob.
Statist. 40 (2004), 553-567.
[ØR] B. Øksendal and E. Røse:
A white noise approach to insider trading.
http://arxiv.org.abs/1508.06376 (August 2015). To appear in T. Hida and L. Streit
(editors): Applications of hite Noise Analysis. World Scientific, Singapore.
[ØS1] B. Øksendal and A. Sulem: Applied Stochastic Control of Jump Diffusions. Second
Edition. Springer 2007
17
[ØS2] B. Øksendal and A. Sulem: Risk minimization in financial markets modeled by ItôLévy processes. Afrika Matematika (2014), DOI: 10.1007/s13370-014-02489-9.
[ØSZ] B. Øksendal, A. Sulem and T. Zhang: Optimal contril of stochastic delay equations
and time-advanced backward stochastic differential equations. Adv. Appl. Probab. 42
(2011), 572-596.
18