Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Donor Herding and Domestic Debt Crisis

2006, IMF working paper

This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate. This paper presents a new model based on the loan-pushing model by Basu (1991) to show how a domestic debt crisis can occur in a low-income country following donor herding. The model focuses on the rational herding behavior of donors due to payoff and information externalities. Although there are many theoretical models on herding behavior, these models have not formally considered the relationship between donor herding and domestic debt crisis in a low-income country. This paper is an attempt to fill this gap. The paper shows that due to donor herding behavior a domestic debt crisis can occur once the actual debt level is above the desirable one.

WP/06/109 Donor Herding and Domestic Debt Crisis Yohane Khamfula, Montfort Mlachila, and Ephraim Chirwa © 2006 International Monetary Fund WP/06/109 IMF Working Paper Western Hemisphere Department Donor Herding and Domestic Debt Crisis Prepared by Yohane Khamfula, Montfort Mlachila, and Ephraim Chirwa1 Authorized for distribution by David O. Robinson April 2006 Abstract This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the IMF. The views expressed in this Working Paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to further debate. This paper presents a new model based on the loan-pushing model by Basu (1991) to show how a domestic debt crisis can occur in a low-income country following donor herding. The model focuses on the rational herding behavior of donors due to payoff and information externalities. Although there are many theoretical models on herding behavior, these models have not formally considered the relationship between donor herding and domestic debt crisis in a low-income country. This paper is an attempt to fill this gap. The paper shows that due to donor herding behavior a domestic debt crisis can occur once the actual debt level is above the desirable one. JEL Classification Numbers: E6, F3 Keywords: Donor herding behavior; domestic debt crisis; loan-pushing model; domestic-debt repayment gap; fiscal expenditure Author(s) E-Mail Address: [email protected]; [email protected]; [email protected] 1 Yohane Khamfula is at Stellenbosch University, South Africa, and Ephraim Chirwa is at the University of Malawi. An earlier version of this paper is forthcoming in Applied Economics Letters. The authors would like to thank, without implication, Robert Flood and Paul Cashin for stimulating discussions and useful suggestions, as well as Peter Fallon, Carlos Leite, and David O. Robinson for comments and suggestions. -2Contents Page I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................3 II. The Model .............................................................................................................................3 A. Basic Model Details ..................................................................................................4 B. Generating a Domestic Debt Crisis...........................................................................5 III. Conclusion ...........................................................................................................................7 References..................................................................................................................................8 -3I. INTRODUCTION In this paper, we assume that aid donors follow herding behavior that determines aid flows in a low-income country (LIC). We modify a loan-pushing model by Basu (1991) to introduce the donor herding behavior that may trigger domestic debt crisis in a LIC. According to Devenow and Welch (1996), rational herding behavior is usually modeled for three reasons: payoff externalities, principal-agent problems, and information externalities. Our model focuses on rational herding behavior of donors due to payoff and information externalities. Although there are many theoretical models on herding behavior, these models have not formally considered the relationship between donor herding and domestic debt crisis in an LIC. This paper is an attempt to fill this gap. Vives (1993) defines “herding” as behavior where one person (or agent) observes the action(s) of their predecessor(s), updates their prior belief, and then has more incentive to imitate their predecessor(s) knowing that their choice may ex post not be optimal. Thus, agents often infer information out of the actions of other agents. The tendency to base decisions largely on the observed decisions of other agents has been modeled as information externalities. Banerjee (1992); and Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer, and Welch (1992) (henceforth BHW) introduced the first models that emphasized the inefficiencies of these information externalities in a context of social learning. Each one of these models considers a population of agents endowed with a private, costless and imperfect signal concerning the desirability of a course of action. Chamley and Gale (1994) consider a setup similar to the BHW models, except that all players have the possibility to wait, in order to observe how many players invest in the current period and to make their investment decision in the next period based on superior information. Their analysis shows how bad outcomes and inefficient waiting may occur in equilibrium. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section II presents our model. In Section III, we conclude by offering suggestions for empirical analysis. II. THE MODEL In our modified loan-pushing model, aid donors base their strategies on what they see other aid donors doing, and they, themselves, are also searching for extra information. As a result of searching for this extra information, there are costs ensuing to donors. The loan-pushing theory is further based on the assumption that aid donors or lenders are supplying more credit to the borrowing LIC than the latter would voluntarily take at the prevailing interest rate.2 In practice, the assumption that countries are persuaded to take more loans than they are willing to take might not be realistic, as loans are typically given with conditionality, which may be (politically) costly to the borrower. In certain cases, political economy considerations can be an important factor in contracting loans. For instance, when the number of (new) loan2 Basu (1991) observes that the interest rate is not the only factor involved; debt maturity and default provisions are also important. -4financed projects enters positively in the voting function, in the short term politicians could be inclined to borrow beyond what could be justified by economic return. This aspect is not explicitly modeled here. We also exclude cases of donors acting purely for humanitarian reasons, for example, due to a natural disaster. A. Basic Model Details In our model, the aid-recipient country announces (Lt, it), where Lt is the amount of loan that the LIC wants to borrow, and it the interest rate it is willing to pay in a given period, t. Thus, in the model, the borrowing LIC chooses and announces (Lt, it) so as to maximize utility. Assume further that each lender supplies either one unit of credit or nothing. Let EtS be the expected excess supply of credit, and rj the lowest rate at which the lender j is willing to lend to the borrower. It is assumed that rj is inversely related to expected excess supply, EtS : rj = rj( EtS ). (1) We assume that the total supply of loans in period t, St, to the LIC is determined as: St = St( EtS , it) (2) where ∂S t / ∂EtS ≥ 0 and ∂S t / ∂it ≥ 0 . Donors view an excess supply of loans as a positive sign. Thus, given the S-function in equation (2), aid donors regard the current-period excess supply of loans, EtS , as the sign of the LIC’s creditworthiness. The lenders (aid donors) then supply the amount of loans or credit on rational expectations, where e is the expectations superscript relative to the information set held in period t-1: St = St( Yt e – Lt, it) (3) where Yt e is the expected supply of funds in the current period; Lt the demand for credit in the current period; and it the interest rate the aid recipient or borrower is willing to pay in period t. Aid donors will end up supplying Y units of credit only if this amount satisfies equation (3). The lender’s expected return, ρ te , in period t is given as: ρ te = (it − π tθ − γ t λ) e (4) S is now a function of the expected supply of funds, Yt e , and the lender’s expected return, (it πtθ - γtλ)e. πt is the default parameter for the borrowing LIC and it lies between 0 and 1. Judging from past performance of a LIC in terms of loan repayment, the donor community is assumed to hold some prior knowledge of the lender’s propensity to default. The closer this -5parameter is to 0 for a given value of θ, the higher will be the lender’s expected return. θ is a given constant. Thus, πtθ is the value of the default costs of the debt to the lender or donor. The parameter γt in the lender’s expected return, (it - πtθ - γtλ)e, represents cost of acquisition of information to the lender and it also lies between 0 and 1. As mentioned above, apart from observing what their peers are doing, donors also seek information about the LIC on their own. There is, however, a cost attached to acquiring this extra information. It should be noted that a lower value of γt will imply a higher expected return to the lender. The symbol λ stands for some given constant. We rewrite the S-function, which assumes rational expectations, as follows: St = St( Yt e – Lt,(it - πtθ - γtλ)e) (5) In the loan-pushing model, the supply of loans in period t, St, depends positively on expected supply in period t, Yt e , and lender’s expected return in period t, ρ te = (it − π tθ − γ t λ ) e . The supply of new loans can be expressed as follows: ⎧⎪0, if (it +1 − π t +1θ − γ t +1λ ) e < ρ * or Yt e+1 < Y S t +1 = ⎨ ⎪⎩S t +1 (Yt e+1 − Lt +1 , (it +1 − π t +1θ − γ t +1λ ) e ) if (it +1 − π t +1θ − γ t +1λ ) e ≥ ρ * and Yt e+1 ≥ Y (6) In equation (6), Y is the threshold level of the supply of funds and ρ* is the threshold level of the lender’s return. If the expected supply in period t, Yt e , and the lender’s expected return in period t, (it - πtθ - γtλ)e, exceed their threshold levels, Y and ρ* respectively, the LIC receives foreign loans or aid. Otherwise, there is no supply of new loans. This means that the supply function becomes discontinuous at the threshold levels. However, the model presents an extreme case of herding behavior, since a small decrease in the lender’s return will cause a drop in the supply of loans to zero.3 The strength of the model is that the discontinuity and the reversal of aid flows are explained endogenously, even though the entire primitive behavioral functions—equations (1) and (2)—in the model are continuous. B. Generating a Domestic Debt Crisis We next show how a domestic debt crisis occurs in the event of n-successive-period simultaneous withdrawals of aid by aid-donors from the borrowing LIC. Suppose that, as a result of either bad governance and corruption or poor macroeconomic management, in 3 This is a corner solution. In practice, there may be a minimum level of donor inflows, for example, in the form of humanitarian aid. However, the results obtained in this case would not be qualitatively different from what follows in the rest of the paper. -6period t, aid donors announce their intention to withdraw financial assistance to the LIC with effect from period t+1 until favorable conditions prevail in the country. If this situation leads the government to borrow from domestic creditors (other than adjusting its expenditures, for example, in the expectation of a reversal of donors’ decision), we can envisage a rise in real interest rates in every period after t+1. We can formalize this scenario as follows. Consider a sequence of T-zero aid flows to the LIC, where T is the number of periods for which the LIC does not have aid inflows following donor herding. Thus, from period t+1 up to period T, there is no supply of new loans, namely St+1, St+2,…, St+T. From equation (6) above, we can see that starting from period t+1 the condition that (it − π tθ − γ t λ ) e < ρ * or Yt e < Y must hold to satisfy the outcome. As a result of ensuing high real interest rates on the domestic financial market, the government will start to default on domestic debt as long as accumulated debt in each period is above some threshold level. In each period, we have three likely outcomes: ψ t + k − ϖ t*+ k ⎧0, if ψ t + k equals ϖ t*+ k ⎪ = ⎨ Negative value, if ψ t + k is belowϖ t*+ k ⎪ * ⎩ Positive value, if ψ t + k is above ϖ t + k (7) where ψ t + k is the actual domestic debt accumulated in period t+k (k = 1, 2,…,T) and ϖ t*+ k is the level of accumulated domestic debt that the government is able to repay in every period. It is assumed that the actual domestic debt accumulated (ψ t + k ) is determined as follows: ψ t + k = f( ritd+ k , (DSt+k x ritd+ k )2) (8) where ritd+ k is the real interest rate prevailing on the domestic financial market; DSt+k is the dummy variable which takes the value of 1 if there is no supply of foreign aid in period t+k and 0 otherwise; and (DSt+k x ritd+ k )2 is the square of the interaction variable between DSt+k and ritd+ k . In equation (7), the actual domestic debt accumulated in period t+k, ψ t + k , is a strictly increasing function of the square of the interaction variable, (DSt+k x ritd+ k )2; that is, ∂ψ t + k / ∂ ( DS t + k xritd+ k ) > 0 , given that DSt+k = 1. On the other hand, if DSt+k = 0, ψ t + k is a decreasing function of ritd+ k ; that is, ∂ψ t + k / ∂ritd+ k ≤ 0 . From equation (7), we can see that as long as ψ t + k is equal to or less thanϖ t*+ k , a debt crisis does not occur in the LIC. A debt crisis occurs once ψ t + k is greater than ϖ t*+ k . The first two outcomes will obtain if the government of the LIC responds to donor herding by simultaneously reducing its expenditures and borrowing a well-calculated sum of loans from the home financial market. If no reduction to fiscal expenditures is made, then the third outcome (domestic debt crisis) is likely to be faced by the LIC. -7III. CONCLUSION Based on the analysis presented above, the main empirical research question that arises, therefore, is whether the changes in domestic debt stocks are linked to sudden shifts in external aid inflows, exacerbated by donor herding. Subsequent empirical work will need to establish whether there has been donor herding; that is, whether changes in the flows of assistance by one donor have been heavily influenced by one or more other donors. Concretely, this could be done, for example, by determining whether the growth rate of domestic debt beyond a certain threshold is explained by a decline in donor aid below a certain threshold, after controlling for a number of macroeconomic environment variables. Empirical work would also need to determine why, when faced with imminent or actual cuts in donor assistance, the government did not cut expenditure or raise revenues.4 Finally, the empirical analysis could also usefully assess the consequences of the behavior of the government for domestic economic outcomes. A major challenge of the empirical work will be to gather the data on individual donor financing commitments and disbursements with sufficient frequency (monthly or quarterly), and over a sufficiently long period. Finding adequate domestic debt data on stocks and flows by type and holder, while easier, is not a trivial exercise as most LICs do not have good domestic debt data beyond banking system credit, and on treasury bills and bonds. 4 A possible reason could be that the LIC government believes that donors will be faced with the “Good Samaritan’s” dilemma, and not walk away for a prolonged period. -8- REFERENCES Banerjee, A., 1992, “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp. 797–817. Basu, K., 1991, Analytical Development Economics (Cambridge: MIT Press). Bikhchandani, S., D. Hirshleifer, and I. Welch, 1992, “A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No. 5, pp. 992–1026. Chamley, C. and D. Gale, 1994, “Information Revelation and Strategic Delay in a Model of Investment,” Econometrica, Vol. 62, No. 5, pp. 1065–85. Devenow, A. and I. Welch, 1996, “Rational Herding in Financial Economics,” European Economic Review, Vol. 40. Vives, X., 1993, “How Fast do Rational Agents Learn?” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 60, No. 2, pp. 329–47.