C
Capability and Multinational
Enterprises (MNEs)
David J. Teece
Berkeley Research Group, LLC, Emeryville, CA,
USA
Abstract
Academic approaches to the activities of the
MNE have been dominated by the internalization theories developed in the field of ▶ international business (IB), including the envelope
approach known as the ▶ eclectic paradigm.
These theories are helpful but have several
shortcomings, including an emphasis on the
cost of investment decisions rather than on
the opportunities they can create, a limited
focus on managerial decision-making, and no
model of the creation and maintenance of firmlevel advantage. These problems can be
addressed by a capability-based approach,
such as the dynamic capabilities framework.
Definition The activities of the multinational
enterprise (MNE) frequently involve the extension, leveraging, and creation of capabilities
across borders. However, the literature on crossborder investment is dominated by theories based
This chapter was originally published in The New Palgrave
Dictionary of Economics, Online edition, 2016. Edited by
Palgrave Macmillan
on concepts that ignore capabilities, such as transaction costs. Non-capabilities-based theories
reveal little about the use of strategy to build
competitive advantage. Capability-based explanations for MNE activities received relatively little
attention until the 2000s.
Since the 17th-century appearance of globespanning trading companies such as the Dutch
East India Company, the global economy has
been knit ever more tightly together by multinational enterprises (MNEs). The spread of crossborder trade and investment accelerated in the
latter half of the 20th century. Today, some startups are born as “international new ventures” and
establish an overseas presence from the very outset (Oviatt and McDougall 1994).
“Explanations” for the multinational form of
organization abound, particularly from an economic perspective. These include theories of
interest rate arbitrage (Aliber 1970), multiplant
economies (Caves 1980), the extension of monopoly power (Hymer 1976), and the minimization of
transaction costs (Hennart 1982). Researchers in
the field of ▶ international business (IB) developed theories that were somewhat better
grounded, such as internalization to offset possible market failures (Buckley and Casson 1976).
The ▶ “eclectic paradigm” (Dunning 1988) combined internalization with Hymer-esque ownership advantages and location-specific factors to
yield a richer and more robust model of the
# The Author(s) 2016
M. Augier, D.J. Teece (eds.), The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management,
DOI 10.1057/978-1-349-94848-2_25-1
2
determinants of ▶ foreign direct investment (FDI)
and multinational business activity.
Other theories of FDI have come to emphasize
knowledge transfer (Teece 1976; Kogut and Zander 1993) or, more generally, capability development and transfer (Teece 1986, 2014). Capabilitybased theories have the potential to “explain” not
only the existence of multinationals and their
investment patterns but also how they exploit
their internal and external networks to differentiate themselves from rivals in the effort to build
▶ sustainable competitive advantage (SCA).
Non-capabilities Approaches
Many of the non-capabilities theories about the
MNE and FDI have their own entries in this encyclopedia. The two leading theories, which will be
briefly described here, are known as “internalization” and “the eclectic paradigm.”
The internalization perspective has dominated
much of the literature on the MNE over the past
30 years (Dunning and Lundan 2008). It is primarily associated with the claim that FDI is a
response to transaction cost issues that cause
market-based contracting to be less attractive.
A less discussed variant claims that internalization
occurs because of the relative transaction efficiency of internal resource transfers and learning
(Teece 2014).
The transaction cost approach to the MNE,
which was advanced by Buckley and Casson
(1976), Rugman (1981), Teece (1981), and others,
focused on potential problems arising from asset
specificity and renegotiation risk that cause possible market failure. This potential “failure” of market contracting can be overcome by the
internalization of the affected cross-border activity. The MNE form of organization is also seen as
minimizing the transaction costs resulting from
the public goods aspects of certain intermediate,
mostly intangible, assets by adopting managerial
control of these assets rather than attempting to
contract with others for their use.
The learning and technology transfer approach
to the MNE has been less explored within the
internalization school of research than approaches
Capability and Multinational Enterprises (MNEs)
based on market failures and inefficiencies. The
technology transfer argument emphasizes the
value of a unifying organizational culture and
the ease of coordination inside the firm relative
to the market. Integration of activities within a
firm opens pathways to learning and to sharing
know-how and expertise through cross-border
transfers within the MNE that might be blocked
between legally separate entities concerned about
leaking valuable information. The introduction of
learning as a consideration moved internalization
closer to a capabilities-based approach, in which
learning is an important source of revitalization
(Teece 1981).
The other leading non-capability approach to
the MNE is the eclectic paradigm, which was
developed by John Dunning (1995) and mentioned earlier in this article. The eclectic paradigm
combines internalization with “ownership advantages” and host-country location factors to provide a more complete picture of MNE choice sets.
The ownership factors are those that give a specific firm the competitive advantage that allows it
to incur the expense of investing abroad and still
earn a profit. Such advantages would certainly
include organizational capabilities, and Dunning
eventually incorporated the theory of dynamic
capabilities into the eclectic paradigm (Dunning
and Lundan 2010). However, the eclectic paradigm is generally used to explain only the geographic distribution of FDI and the cross-border
investment decisions of firms, which are the concerns of the field of IB. It does not yield an
understanding of the creation of ownership advantages or of their astute management to create firmlevel advantage, which is seen as the province of
international management studies.
Internalization and Dunning’s ownership and
location extensions in the eclectic paradigm have
a number of shortcomings with respect to understanding the range of activities of the MNE and
the advantages of specific firms. The most important of these is the limited attention to the role of
entrepreneurs and entrepreneurial managers
(Pitelis and Teece 2010; Teece 2014; Jones and
Pitelis 2015). The activities of entrepreneurial
managers, which, as will be discussed, make up
an important part of the dynamic capabilities of
Capability and Multinational Enterprises (MNEs)
the MNE, include the identification of opportunities, innovation with respect to the design of business models, and the creation and co-creation of
markets.
In
short,
internalization-based
approaches leave out most of what makes global
firms viable over the long term: the creation and
maintenance of a unique competitive advantage.
Virtually the only managerial activity
encompassed by internalization-based approaches
to the MNE is the coordination of technology and
other resources across borders.
Rather than squeezing capabilities concepts
into the eclectic paradigm, as Dunning and
Lundan (2010) have done, it can be argued that
internalization is more properly seen as a subset of
the development and deployment of capabilities
(Teece 2014). As capabilities have become more
globally dispersed and cross-border coordination
less onerous, global supply chains seem less
dependent than ever on internalization (i.e., on
owning offshore factories).
Consider Apple, which became one of the largest computer and communications hardware firms
in the world. It no longer owns its own
manufacturing plants. Instead, it tightly coordinates supply relations with many companies,
especially Foxconn, which is headquartered in
Taiwan with its largest factories in China. Apple
provides financing to some of its suppliers and
may obtain exclusive purchase arrangements from
them for periods up to several years. These
non-internalized yet not-quite-arm’s-length contractual arrangements appear to suffice for Apple
to achieve the necessary coordination to leverage
its considerable marketing and design capabilities
while retaining flexibility to respond to demand
changes.
Apple is just the most prominent example of an
electronics industry in which large firms such as
Hewlett-Packard have steadily sold off their offshore factories in favor of alliances with contractors, leaving the brand name firms responsible
primarily for marketing and network coordination. It was the forerunner of an outsourcing
trend that has spread in varying degrees to other
sectors such as autos and from manufacturing to
service activities.
3
Internalization perspectives do not provide a
complete understanding of how contemporary
outsourcing helps create firm-level advantages.
Internalization needs to be combined with, and
perhaps embedded into, a capability-based paradigm of the firm.
The Capabilities Approach
The capabilities approach to the MNE was built,
in part, on the resource-based view of the firm, as
well as extending the often-ignored learning and
technology transfer branch of the internalization
approach. Its leading expression is the dynamic
capabilities framework, which was developed in
the field of strategic management (Teece
et al. 1997; Teece 2014).
An organizational capability allows firms to
marshal resources to produce a desirable outcome
with some degree of predictability. Most capabilities are somewhat fungible and can be used to
support any of a variety of activities. Large organizations have many such capabilities and at any
point in time some of them will be underutilized.
Capabilities arise in part from learning, from combinations of organizational assets, and from
acquisitions.
The ordinary capabilities that the firm needs to
carry out a given programme of production can
often be replicated – and imitated – with relative
ease. Much know-how, which used to be proprietary by default as much as by intention, is now
effectively in the public domain – available from
consultants, schools of engineering, and the public literature. That’s not to say that getting to the
level of best practice is easy. It is not, but there is
usually a fairly clear path for getting there if the
cost of doing so is deemed worthwhile.
Dynamic capabilities, on the other hand, allow
the organization and its management to integrate,
build, and reconfigure internal and external competencies (including its ordinary capabilities) to
address changing business environments (Teece
et al. 1997). At a practical level, this involves
sensing and evaluating threats and opportunities,
designing structures and business models to
respond to them, and adjusting and renewing the
4
organization and its resources as needed. Strong
dynamic capabilities will enable an MNE to constantly create new technologies, differentiated
processes, and better business models to stay
ahead of the competition, stay in tune with the
market, and even, at times, shape the market.
A capacity to transfer technology and knowhow (embedded in routines and resources, including the minds of employees) across distances and
borders is a key capability of the multinational
firm (Teece 1976). Successful transfers of even
ordinary capabilities to host-country subsidiaries
can provide the basis for advantage in the host
country. MNEs investing abroad “appear to adopt
good management practices in almost every country in which they operate,” and foreign subsidiaries are generally better managed than similar
host-country firms (Bloom et al. 2012: 14). In
other words, strong ordinary capabilities developed at home can (at least temporarily) be distinctive abroad. However, as competition increases in
the host country, the strength or weakness of the
MNE subsidiary’s dynamic capabilities to
respond to the changes becomes paramount.
As this suggests, subsidiaries must have their
own capacity to anticipate and respond to changes
in the local business environment and be given
encouragement and autonomy to do so. KFC
Japan, for example, became a success in the
1970s under the leadership of Loy Weston and
Shin Ohkawara, who developed the local branch
more as a fashion business than as fast food
(Bartlett and Rangan 1986). Headquarters management must vet key resource commitments, but,
in order to preserve agility, information must flow
and decisions must be taken rapidly.
Headquarters can enhance local capabilities
further by allowing and facilitating knowledge
transfers amongst regional divisions and by
encouraging and supporting the exploitation of
cross-border complementarities. This approach
requires top management to treat the organization
more like an interconnected network than a rigidly
vertical M-form hierarchy (Bartlett and Ghoshal
1989). Top management’s fundamental roles are
global ▶ asset orchestration (allocating financial
and other resources to develop the most promising
Capability and Multinational Enterprises (MNEs)
activities wherever they may appear) and the provision of company-wide strategic direction.
In this decentralized M-form model, subsidiaries generate know-how, capabilities, and products from their own history, circumstances, and
innovation activities that can potentially be transferred to other business units at home or abroad
(Birkinshaw and Hood 1998). Local knowledge
creation and discovery of opportunities is encouraged and coordinated by the orchestration activities of headquarters management.
Comparison of Capabilities with Other
Theories of the MNE
Countless studies have applied an internalization
approach to the MNE to research on the “entry
mode” of firms in overseas markets – that is,
whether the MNE chooses to operate in a host
country through an alliance or via some level of
equity investment. However, from a strategic
management perspective, the more urgent questions involve which markets to enter and when,
not just how. Answering these requires a recognition and assessment of opportunities in multiple
markets, the ability to transfer knowledge, an
analysis of any capabilities gaps the firm may
have in terms of the requirements to carry out its
strategy, and so on. Any capability gaps, in turn,
must be evaluated as make/buy/ally problems
based on the strategic value of the capability,
including its availability from other firms and the
time required to “make” it internally versus the
timing of the opportunity to be exploited.
A particular deficiency of internalization theories is their focus on the cost of entry while ignoring the opportunities (and risks) that entry affords.
Consider, for example, a case where assets owned
by the MNE are strongly complementary to (i.e.,
co-specialized with) assets in the host country.
Such cases are quite common in a world where
value is determined largely by ownership and
control of ▶ intangible assets. The question facing
the MNE is not so much whether a mode of
operation in the host country will cost less when
owned or contracted but whether integration of
the cross-border activity within the firm will allow
Capability and Multinational Enterprises (MNEs)
it to better capture value by exercising more control over the design of a value appropriation architecture (Pitelis and Teece 2010).
In other words, internalization analysis can
reveal only part of the story behind the choice of
the firm’s boundary when entering overseas markets. A capabilities perspective allows consideration of other critical factors, including the
feasibility of transferring the necessary knowledge either internally or externally, the host
country’s treatment of intellectual property, and
the attractiveness of potential host-country
partners.
Internalization approaches that are based primarily on transaction cost or contractual analysis
offer even less insight into the building of firmlevel advantage. In such theories, if a firm has
market power, it is taken as given and assumed
to persist. The role of managers is reduced to
determining the (global) boundaries of the firm
by outsourcing until the cost of outsourcing the
marginal activity is equal to the cost of performing
it internally. There is little recognition of the
importance of opportunity discovery, learning,
strategy adjustment, and other forms of capability
development and maintenance.
The dynamic capabilities framework, by contrast, models managers as exercising entrepreneurial and leadership functions that are vital to
building and maintaining firm-level advantages in
home and host-country markets. Global asset
orchestration, business model design, and entrepreneurial cross-border market creation and
co-creation are at the core of a capabilities-based
approach to the MNE.
See Also
▶ Asset Orchestration
▶ Co-specialization
▶ Eclectic Paradigm
▶ Evolutionary Theory of the Multinational
Corporation
▶ Federative Multinational Enterprise (MNE)
▶ Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)
▶ Hymer, Stephen Herbert
▶ Intangible Assets
5
▶ Internalization Theory
▶ International Business
▶ Make-or-Buy Decisions: Applications to Strategy Research
▶ Market Entry Strategies
▶ Market Failures and Multinational Enterprises
(mnes)
▶ M-Form Firms
▶ Multinational Corporations
▶ Multi-plant Economies
▶ Strategy and Structure of the Multinational
Enterprise (MNE)
▶ Sustainable Competitive Advantage
▶ Transaction Cost Theory of the Multinational
Enterprise (MNE)
References
Aliber, R.Z. 1970. A theory of direct foreign investment. In
The international corporation, ed. C.P. Kindleberger.
Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Bartlett, C.A., and S. Ghoshal. 1989. Managing across
borders: The transnational solution. Boston: Harvard
Business School Press.
Bartlett, C.A., and U.S. Rangan. 1986. Kentucky Fried
Chicken (Japan) Limited (case no. 9-387-043). Boston:
Harvard Business School.
Birkinshaw, J., and N. Hood. 1998. Multinational subsidiary evolution: Capability and charter change in
foreign-owned subsidiary companies. Academy of
Management Review 23: 773–795.
Bloom, N., C. Genakos, R. Sadun, and J. Van Reenen.
2012. Management practices across firms and countries. Academy of Management Perspectives 20: 12–33.
Buckley, P.J., and M.C. Casson. 1976. The future of multinational enterprise. London: Macmillan.
Caves, R.E. 1980. Investment and location policies of
multinational companies. Swiss Journal of Economics
and Statistics 116: 321–338.
Dunning, J.H. 1988. The eclectic paradigm of international
production: A restatement and some possible extensions. Journal of International Business Studies 19:
1–31.
Dunning, J.H. 1995. Reappraising the eclectic paradigm in
the age of alliance capitalism. Journal of International
Business Studies 26: 461–493.
Dunning, J.H., and S.M. Lundan. 2008. Multinational
enterprises and the global economy. Cheltenham:
Edward Elgar.
Dunning, J.H., and S.M. Lundan. 2010. The institutional
origins of dynamic capabilities in multinational enterprise. Industrial and Corporate Change 19:
1225–1246.
6
Hennart, J.-F. 1982. A theory of multinational enterprise.
Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Hymer, S. 1976. The international operations of national
firms. Boston: The MIT Press.
Jones, G., and C.N. Pitelis. 2015. Entrepreneurial imagination and a demand and supply-side perspective on the
MNE and cross-border organisation. Journal of International Management 21: 309–321.
Kogut, B., and U. Zander. 1993. Knowledge of the firm and
the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies 24:
625–645.
Oviatt, B.M., and P.P. McDougall. 1994. Toward a theory
of international new ventures. Journal of International
Business Studies 25: 45–64.
Pitelis, C.N., and D.J. Teece. 2010. Cross-border market
co-creation, dynamic capabilities and the entrepreneurial theory of the multinational enterprise. Industrial and
Corporate Change 19: 1247–1270.
Capability and Multinational Enterprises (MNEs)
Rugman, A.M. 1981. Inside the multinationals: The economics of internal markets. New York: Columbia University Press.
Teece, D.J. 1976. The multinational corporation and the
resource cost of international technology transfer.
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing.
Teece, D.J. 1981. The multinational enterprise: Market
failure and market power considerations. Sloan Management Review 22: 3–17.
Teece, D.J. 1986. Transaction cost economics and the
multinational enterprise: An assessment. Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization 7: 21–45.
Teece, D.J. 2014. A dynamic capabilities-based entrepreneurial theory of the multinational enterprise. Journal
of International Business Studies 45: 8–37.
Teece, D.J., G. Pisano, and A. Shuen. 1997. Dynamic
capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal 18: 509–533.