No. 347
July 1992
'I'D
BARTZN-GOIQC!Uf N:>DZL IN 'I'D AIDS l'RAMEWORlt
By
M. Luisa Ferreira and C. Federico Perali
University of Wisconsin-Madison
:1
Abstract
The Barten-Gorman model has been difficult to estimate due to the problems in
identifying all demographi c parameters and the highly nonlinear nature of the
specification. Restrictions on the demographic parameters that allow the
identification of the model and make it estimable are derived. An empirical
application shows that the Barten-Gorman model behaves well and preferred to
the nested Translating and Scaling specifications.
Key Words: Barten-Gorman Model, Identification , Concavity and Demographics.
*/
Both authors are graduate students , Department of Agricultural
Economics , University of Wisconsin-Madison. The authors would like to
thank, without implicating , Rueben C. Buse, and Thomas L. Cox for their
comments.
1 . Introduction
Incorporating demographic or other factors into a demand system is
gaining renewed interest due to the results derived by Lewbel (1985).
Using a
somewhat cryptic notation, Lewbel shows how to modify complete demand systems
with the introduction of demographic characteristics that interact with prices
and income in an almost unlimited variety of functional specifi cations .
Such
modifications include the popular Barten (1964) scaling and translating
specifications, first introduced by Pollak and Wales (1981), as special cases .
Lewbel describes the properties that the modifying functions must maintain to
ensure integrability of the modified demand system.
This guarantees that the
original preference structure is preserved and that the modified model is
still theoretically plausible.
These conditions are necessary to compute the
true equivalence scales and to derive correct measures of welfare.
This study concentrates on the Barten- Gorrnan modifying specification
which combines both translating and scaling.
Deaton and Muellbauer (1986)
shows that this model is metrically superior to competing specifications for
generating equivalence scales.
Similar to the Slutsky decomposition of income
and substitution effects, the Barten-Gorrnan specification translates the
budget line through the fixed cost element (translating) and rotates the
budget constraint by modifying the effective prices with the related
substitution effec ts via demographic characteristics (scaling ).
The Barten construction is motivated by German's (1976) observation that
"when you have a wife and a baby, a penny bun costs threepence."
However,
some characteristics may affect consumption only through income effects , or
may show both a translating and a scaling effect.
Only a model that nests
both could resolve this empiri cal question.
In the past, the Barten-Gorrnan model was not very popular because its
estimation is highly nonlinear and the model was thought to have serious
identification problems.
Moreover, Lewbel states that there is no guaranteee
that all parameters can be identified, just as there is no guarantee that all
t he parameters in any demand system can be identified (1985 : 5) . Deaton and
1
Muellbauer assert that in practical applications it will always be extremely
difficult to estimate the parameters of the Gorrnan- Barten model (1986 : 740) .
Chung (1987 ) circumvents the problem by arbitrarily introducing into the
translating function demographic variables different from the ones
incorporated into the scaling function. Davidson and McKinnon (1981) identify
the artificial par ameters used to compound alternative specification
hypotheses into a nesting model by estimating the artificial parameters
conditional on the knowledge of the
estimated parameters of the single
alternatives (Atkinson 197 0) .
In the present study we specify the Barten-Gorrnan model in a
theoretically plausible way . We use the property of homogeneity of degree one
in p of the cost function to derive the identifying restrictions that make the
model estimable.
We complete the description of the Barten-Gorrnan model by
providing the expres sion to analyze the concavity properties. We also derive
the expressions for the elasticities .
The paper first lays out the notation and definitions .
section specifies the model .
The third
The fourth section demonstrates how all the
demographic parameters can be identified .
The next section derives the
conditions to test concavity in the Barten-Gorrnan model .
The sixth section
applies the model to the estimation of the demand for food at home and food
away from home in the United States during the period 1953-1988.
The
conclusions complete the discussion .
2 . Notation and
D•~
i nit
i ons
Set the basic notation according to the following definitions:
h
(h 1 ,
..
,hH)El+H (I the real numbers, I+ the non negative reals ) is the
index vector for demographic profile s at year h=l, . . ,H: h=O designates
the reference profile , h=l designates the profile chosen for comparison;
Pj
P
the price of commodity i =l , .. ,n assumed constant across profiles;
(P11··1Pn ) El+n;
2
qih
the quantity of the ith commodity consumed by the h th demographic
profile;
q
= ( ql, . . , qn) EI+ n;
wih
= the
budget share of the i th cormnodity by the h th profile;
yh
the total expenditures of the h th demographic profile (income in short );
dr
the r th demographic characteristic;
d
(d1, .. ,dR) El+R;
ai r
the scaling demographic parameter for the ith cormnodity and the r th
characteristic;
Oi = (61 1
• •
,0R) EIR the R vector of scaling parameters for the ith cormnodity;
mi (d; Oi) : l +R- 1 =the scaling function specific to the i th commodity;
= the translating demographic parameter for the ith commodity and the r th
~ ir
characteristic;
~ i
= ( ~ 1 , .. , ~ R)
EI
R
the R vector of translating parameters for the ith
commodity;
t i(
d;
~ i):
R-1 I
=the translating function specific to the ith commodity;
C(u,p) = the minimum cost of attaining utility level u at prices p.
By
definition, yh=C(u , p) . This cost function is assumed to be twice
continuously differentiable and theoretically plausible .
V(y,p) = the indirect utility function at income y and prices p .
t (u) = the level o f utility of the reference demographic profile .
3.
Spec
i ~ ic
a ti
on o~
th• Bar t e n-Gorman Model
Following Lewbel (1985) , consider the relation:
y::: C ( u,p,d) ::: f{c•[u,h(p,d ) ] , z (p , d ) , d)
where c*( u , p*) is a well- behaved expenditure function, y* = c*[ u , h(p,d)J =
c*(u,p* ) is the minimum expenditure necessary to attain utility level u at
s ome scaled prices Pi*= hi( p,d) and translated prices PiT=zi(p ,d ) f or some
vector valued functions h and z.
3
(1)
Using the facts y=C=f and y*=c*, the Barten-Gorman specification 1 is
obtained from equation (1) using the following f (y,p, d) modifying function:
y
= C(u,p, d)
.a
f(y•,z (p,d),d) • y • p T
with
pT •
TI
(z1 (P 1 1 d)
)t1( d )
•
l
This expression corresponds to the Barten (1964) specification with the
addition of fixed overheads pT for "necessary" or "subsistence" quantities
(Gorman 1976) .
Several different demographic specifications can be derived by
making explicit assumptions about the functions h(p,d) and z (p,d).
The
specifications are:
(a) h(p ,d)=z(p ,d)=p
(b) h(p,d)=z(p,d)=pm=p *
(c) h(p,d)=p * and z(p,d)=l
(d) h(p,d)=p * and z(p,d )=p
-
budget share Translating
budget share Reverse Gorman
budget share Scaling
b•Jdget share Gorman.
These definitions comply with Pollak and Wales (1981) terminology.
empirical convenience 2 the translating demographic functions ti(d) are
specified as
~(dl=ri
a ir,
ti(d)=
For
and the scaling demographic functions mi (d ) as
E r ~ irln(d
for r=l, .. , n.
Assume quasi-homothetic preferences as described by the demographically
modified Gorman Polar cost function:
C(u , p , d) = (A(p,d)
( ~ (u)
(2)
)B(p,dl) pT.
The linear in logarithm analog is:
1
The Barten-Gorman demographic specification that we refer to in this
paper is the Reverse Gorman modifying structure.
2
It should be emphasized that the choice of the functi ona l form of the
demographic functions is not restricted to any particular form partly
because only the relative magnitudes of the estimated demographic
functions have a meaningful interpretation. The researcher, howeve r,
can specify a more complex form such as a translog if interested in
modelling economies of scale.
4
ln C( u,p, d) "' (ln
A(p ,
d)
+ B(p, d)
ln ~ ( u))
+
ln
pT
where:
ln A (p, d)
=
cxo
r
+ ~
i
ex · ln p •·
l
l
+ •
5 ~ r~ r
i j
•
yijln
p i•
ln P j•
n
B(p , d)
"'
Po II
(p ;) P1 •
i •l
The corresponding Barten-Gorrnan AIDS indirect utility function is given
by:
ln y• - («o
ln V•
~
+
~
l;:
l
«i ln
pj
+
.5
l;: l;:
l
~,-
Po II
J
Yi j ln
pj ln pjl
~
(3)
~-
(p;) P1
i
where Yi j=Yij*+Yji* , V=
~ (u)
and ln y*=ln y - t iti(d)ln p* from equation (2).
This extension pe rmits distinguishing between the intercept shifting function
and the transla ting function .
income elasticities .
Moreover, it allows deriving profile specific
Roy ' s identity yields the Barten- Gorman AIDS budget
shares: 3
(4)
Lewbel shows that a theoretically plausible specification of a modified
Marshallian share demand system can be obtained from equation (1) by applying
the following trans formation (1985 , Theorem 4):
where t iti (d)=O due to the homogeneity restrictions.
It is important to note that the system represented in equation (4) is
not a unique specification of the Barten-Gorman.
Many other specifications
can be obtained by applying Lewbel ' s technique.
Consider, for example, the
3
The term ln A' (p,d ) is the same as ln A(p,d) with Yij in place of y · · ' .
Henceforth, to simplify notation ln A(p,d) will be used in lieu of 1:1n
A' (p,d ) .
5
af(y • ,p, d)
ay •
y• ~
-
'" (1 - l: t i (d))
i
~
y
Pi
•( • •
af(y* ,p, d l P i
wi y ,p 1 + - - - - - ap i
y
P j•
ah i (p, dl
J·
apl ·
wj (y*,p * )
'"'wj
+ t 1 ( d)
+ t i (d)
following exponential specification of the h (p , d) function hi (p , d)
*
exp(pimi(d) ) =exp(pi).
The derived Barten-Gorrnan shares are :
(5)
This specification is interesting because the translation term l ooks much like
the committed quantity term of the linear expenditure system. However, the
The supernumerary quantities increase as the ratio
overhead is not fixed.
.
.
p *1 y * a l so increases
Hence the degree to which a good is perceived as a
necessity is subjective and varies from individual to individual (Lewbel
1985).
The Barten-Gorrnan model in equation (4) nests the following demographic
specifications:
(a) Scali ng
w · ==
l
al ·
+
l:
j y l·]· ln P j•
+
A •
... 1
ln (
(
Y•
(6)
)
A p , d)
where h (p , d)=p*=pm, and ln y*=ln y ;
(b) Trans lating
w 1· == a 1· + t 1• ( d)
+
l: y · · ln p · +
j
lJ
J
A·
,..1
ln ( AY(p)
• )
(7)
where h (p , d) =p , and ln y*=ln y-ln P1 .
Integrability r equires that these specifications be estimated including
y * and without linearization of the deflating index A(. ) . This guarantees
6
recovering exactly the underlying modified cost and indirect utility function
which can then be used to derive equivalence scales and to make welfare
comparisons that are fully cardinal.
4.
Identi~
i cation
From the previous section , recall the Barten- Gorrnan specification of
f(y*,p*,d) where h(p,d)=z(p , d)=pm=p*:
(8 )
that nests both the scaling and translating specifications.
A straightforward
application of Lewbel's Theorem 1 (1985) leads to the following proposition .
Proposi t i o n 1.
Let c* (u,p*) be a cost function homogeneous of degree one in prices.
C(u,p,d) will maintain the same property if and only if (iff):
n
ohi (p, d)
since _____
ap j
E
j •l
n
1 -
:E
n
of(y• ,p, dl
Pj
opj
f(y* , p, d)
j •l
of(y• ,p, dl y •
ay •
y
• 1 -
n
1,
iff
E
t i ( d)
i •l
E
t 1 !dl
=0 V
j ,,.i ,
-
; 0 .I
i •l
Using Euler's law, the legitimate cost function C(u,p,d) can be
rewritten as:
7
Then
C( u,p, d)
oc• op;
·Ei
- - - Pi
Ei -opi
opi
(9)
Given the Barten-Gorman specification of C(u,p,d ) in equation (8), the Euler
relation in (9) becomes:
f(y
•,p, d)
~
oC
i opi
- LJ - - Pi .. p
T
~
oc• • c LJ
~
ti
i opl
i
LJ--Pi +
(d)
I
(10)
where:
of
Equation (10) gives the fundamental economic relationship that is used to
derive the econometric restrictions at the share demand level. The
homogeneity, or invariance, property implicit in the budget constraint
modified by the Barten-Gorman specification is a sufficient condition to
identify all demographic parameters. It makes the derived share demand models
econometrically tractable.
By applying Shephard's lemma to (10) and dividing both sides by
C(u,p,d)=c*( u,p*)pT, we obtain:
E
i
wi .. 1 .
Hence, homogeneity of degree one in prices of the cost function or of degree
zero in prices and income of the share demands require:
In the Barten-Gorman framework the number of "free" demographic
parameters doubles from r (n-1), as in scaling or translating, to 2xr(n-l).
The procedure of specifying the same demographic functions for scaling and
translating gives rise to problems of perfect correlation between the
8
translating and scaling set of parameters.
Moreover, this procedure would
imply the behavioral assumption that the translating effect is the same as the
scaling effect.
Thus, this approach would result in a loss of economic
information.
Instead, the hypothesis that the translating demographic effects differ
statistically from the scaling effects is interesting and can be tested by
using the nested procedure suggested by Pollak and Wales (1981). In line with
previous work (Atkinson 1970; Davidson and McKinnon 1981; and Pesaran and
Deaton 1981), Pollak and Wales (1981) propose the following parsimonius
solution to estimate the compound Barten-Gorrnan model:
t1
a
(l-v1) ln mj
for
i=l , . . ,n
Since the m1 and ti functions include the same parameters and have the same
functional form, the approach generates only r(n-1) "free" demographic slopes
and n artificial parameters vi. An additional benefit of this structure is
that it nests the translating and scaling hypothesis as special cases. If vi =l, the model collapses to scaling; if vi =O, it collapses to translating.
These restrictions are amenable to standard null hypothesis tests against the
more general compound specifi cation.
To evaluate the implications of (10) on this specification, it is
insightful to reconsider the share equations of the Barten-Gorman AIDS model:
wi = « i +
(l-v1)ln mj
+ l:
j
Yij (ln
Pj +
Vj ln mjl
where:
9
+Pi
ln (
y• ) .
A(p,d)
(11)
ln y• • ln
- 1;: [ (1-vj )ln mj(ln
C(u,p,d)
Pj + Vj
ln mj l
.l
t1],.
Let us examine the necessary conditions for an AIDS Bar ten- Gorrnan system to
generate a cost function homogeneous of degree l in prices.
t his is obtained by ens uring that the shares add to one.
recognize the restrictions on the vi's and
A:3
seen before,
In order to
parameters when adding up is
~ j r's
applied to equation (11) , it is convenient to isol ate three elements GT ( . ) ,
GS (.) and GCI(.) as follows:
GT(d;v
,~ ) · 1;: [(1-vi )lnmi]-o,
.l
GS ( d ;y ,v, tl )
GCI(d,p; y ,v,
"'r[r
Yij
Vj
ln
mJ],. 0,
~ ) a l;: [Pi ln y•] .. ln y• ~
.l
l
Pi
..
o.
Each of these terms is examined sequentially.
(1)
The GT ( . )
term
E ( (1-vi) ln mi"'~
i
ln
l
mi - ~v
i ln
l
mi,. O,
hence, homogeneity of C(u,p,d) in p and adding up imply :
1;: ln
1
mi
"' EE ~ ir
i r
ln
dr
0
-
for each r,
-
ln
dr
E
i
for each r,
() i r
ln
O, and
d r l;:vi ~ ir
.l
which implies:
10
"'
0,
E
v1
i
t>ir = 0,
and
( 12)
(2) Th• GS( . ) term
l;: [l;:
l
J
Yij v 1
E
r
t>1r
ln dr] • O, hence, for each r :
where x is a finite constant.
Note that the restriction on the function
GT(d;v, t> ) requires x be equal to 0.
Hence, as before:
(13 )
(3) The GCI ( . ) term
It can be easily shown that the function GCI (d , p; y ,v, t> ) does not
generate further restrictions .
In matrix notation, the identifying restrictions of the Barten- Gorrnan
model can be written as A\ =O , and AT=O , where A is a rxn matrix of demogr aphic
parameters with n be ing the number of equations , \ is a nxl vector of ones , T
is a n column vector of vi parameters and 0 is a rxl vector of zeros .
It is important to note that, given this set of restrictions, the
artificial paramete r s vi of the Barten-Gorrnan model a r e overidentified.
To
clarify, note that the condition A\ =O is derived from the homogeneity
condition of degree one in prices of the cost function. This implies that A is
o f rank n-1.
Hence , the parameter v 0 can take infinitely many solutions and
11
there is not a unique way to reconcile the values of vn.
Remarkably, it is
neither necessary nor interesting to recover the value of vn uniquely from the
product vn6nr•
Due to the homogeneity of degree zero in prices of the demand
system only n-1 of the artificial parameters, vn, have to be uniquely
identified to fully compound the translating and scaling effects in the
Barten-Gorman framework.
The existence of at least one solution is ensured by the fact that the
rank of 4 is
Observe that the system would be otherwise consistent if all
~r.
the vi are equal .
This option is not satisfactory since v would act as a
normalization that could take any value. Finally, note that neither equation
(12) nor equation (13) imply linear or nonlinear restrictions on the
parameters vi's per se when the vi's are equal.
Equations (12) and (13) are the restrictions needed to identify and
estimate the Barten-Gorman AIDS model. They are normalizations derived from
the homogeneity requirement of the cost function.
Therefore, these
restrictions do not alter the economic content of the model.
5 . Concavity
Following Lewbel's proof of Theorem 3, let c * (u,h(p , d))=C*(u , p*)=y* be a
modified cost function and let C(u,p , d)=f(C* (u,h(p , d)),p*,d)]. For all
arbitrary n vectors v, C(u,p,d) is concave in p if and only if 4
V
/
a2
c(_
u,p,
d) v
__
_ __
~
0,
apap'
where:
As in Lewbel (1985), all gradient vectors, Jacobian and Hessian are
represented as derivatives or by vectors.
12
v' o 2c(u,p,d) v
opop 1
o 2 f(y*,p,dl v]
______
op op 1
+
[ of v , oh
o2c•
oh ] )
oy•
op op• op•'
v
o/
Assume that f[C*(u ,h (p,d)) ,p*,d] describe 8arten-Gorrnan preferences as:
Note that 8 1=0 since
and 8 2=0 because t i ti=l.
In fact ,
Thus, C(u ,p,d ) is concave in p if B 3 ~o
and c* in 8 4 is also concave
given that y* is only differentiable once and oh/opi>O because p lies in the
positive orthant and m>O is an exponential function. 5 Thus, in a BartenGorman context a sufficient test for concavity reduces to testing the
concavity in p of both f and c*.
5
Observe that for more general forms of f(y*,p* , d) where, for example , y*
is twice differentiable due to the introduction of a function of
demographics that also shifts the parameters , then the conditions for
C(u , p,d ) to be concave in p are more restrictive (See Lewbel Theorem 3) .
13
Assume again a Gorman Polar form for the cost function whose
el~nts
are specified by the AIDS model. Straightforward differentiation shows that
a 1n f(y •, p,d)
a1n P i
gives the Barten-Gorman specification of the AIDS model presented in equation
( 11) and that
a1n f 2 (y •,p, d)
aln P i aln
pj
gives the compensated component s ij of the Slutsky equation.
As suggested by Deaton and Muellbauer (1980), it is possible to obtain a
simpler algebraic expression to test for concavity by adopting the following
transformation :
and,
where Eij is the compensated price elasticity and Aij =l for i=j and 0
otherwise is the Kr onecker operator. The concavity of c* implies the concavity
of f since f is continuous, monotonic and separable in c* and pT as shown
above.
This complete s the proof.
6 . App1ication to Food at Som. and Food Away from Hom. in th• USA During th•
P•riod 1954-1990
6 . 1 Estimation
The application is carried out estimating a complete demand system over
the period 1953-1988 whose separable components are food- at-home, food-away-
14
from-home, and non-food.
In recent years the empirical examinati on of the
food-at-home/food-away-from-home issue has received increasing attention. From
the point of view of welfare measurement, the decomposition between food and
non-food is interesting because it is ethically in line with the Engel way of
associating utilities with well-being.
In the data set, personal consumption expenditure represents income.
Expenditure information was obtained from the National Income and Product
Accounts of the United States as published by the United States Department of
Commerce.
Price indices were derived from the annual city averages of
consumer price indices from the regular urban National Statistical Accounts
with base years 1983-84.
The demographic variables included in the model are
the percentage of the U. S . population falling in the 0-15 age (01)
category
and the percentage of U.S . population enrolled in schools in each year (02).
Demographic information was drawn from Current Population Reports o f the U.S .
Bureau of the Census. Descr.iptive statistics of the data used in the analysis
are presented in the Data Appendix.
The stochastic Barten-Gorman model is given by:
E(wi)
= «i
+ t i( d) +
J:lYi j lnpj
J
+Pi
ln (
y•
A (p,d)
(14)
) .
We assume that the errors across equations (Ei) are no rmally distributed, with
a constant covariance matrix C. They are uncorrel ated over time, but
correlated in each period:
E( Efr Ejsl •
l
Oi j
for
r = s
0
f or
r,,.
s
Moreover, all variables affecting demand are ass umed as exogenous.
The system of equations (14) formed by food-at-home (FH) , food-awayfrom-home (FAH) and non-food (NF) was estimated jointly using maximum
likelihood (ML) estimation.
Because the adding up restrictions were i mposed
to identify the parameters in the model, \ 'wi =l and \ 1 Ei =O,
15
the cova riance
matrix is singula r and the system is estimated by invariantly dropping the
non-food equation.
Following
Atkinson (1970), Pollak and Wales (198 1 ) , and Davidson and
McKinnon (1981) , the Barten Gorman model can be compounded in a parsimonious
fashion that allows testing the specification of both the nested and nonnested models.
This is accomodated by defining the demographic functions as
follows:
ti
(d)
a
(1 -
vi) ~
~ ir
ln
dr • ~
.l
~ ir
ln
dr
for
~ ir
• (1 - vi) ~ ir
,
and
.l
for s ome constant vi.
The models were estimated with the maintained hypothesis of homogeneity
and symmetry.
Adding up was explicitly imposed since the model is non- linear.
As shown in section 3, the artificial parameters vi of the Barten-Gorman model
are overidentified , but all demographic parameters can be uniquely identified.
The derivation of the income , price and demographic elasticities is presented
in Appendix A.
6 . 2 Resu1ts
Three demographic specifications were estimated .
The parameter
estimates for the Translating (T), Scaling (S) , and Barten-Gorman (BG)
specification can be found in Appendix B.
To test for the econometric
superiority of one demographic specification over the other we rely upon the
Likelihood Ratio .
The statistical difference of the v terms from either 1 or
0 is non-informative since the v 's are not exactly identified.
The likelihood ratio tests of translating against Barten-Gorman, and
Barten-Scaling against Barten-Gorman, are shown in Table 1 .
The values of the
test fail to reject the null hypothesis that scaling and translating are as
good as the Barten- Gorman.
Nevertheless, according to the likelihood
16
dominance criterion introduced by Pollak and Wales (1991), the Barten- Gorrnan
model is econometrica lly superior to both .
The values of the likelihood
functions are presented in Appendix B, Table B. l.
Tabl• l. Likelihood Ratio Test for demographic specification
D.moqraphic Sp9ci:fi cati on
LR-2 (L•-L)
x2 (.0 l;d.f.l
x2 ( . 05; d. fl
BG vs BS
d . f. - 2
1.12
9 . 21
5.99
BG vs T
d . f. - 2
1.23
9 . 21
5.99
Note:
L• is the unrestricted log- likelihood value . x 2 (s;d .f. ) wheres- significance level and
d .f. -number o f restrict ions.
If the model is to be used for estimating equivalence scales and money
metrics for u tility, Blackerby and Donaldson (1988) and Lewbel (1989) point
out that the money metric representations should be concave at all price
levels.
This requires that the Slutsky matrix must be negative definite at
all prices.
Concavity ensures that social judgements do not contradict
distributional judgments derived from a social welfare function which is
quasi-concave when each of its arguments is concave.
We test for "single-peaked" preferences, by computing the eigenvalues of
the Slutsky matrix incorporating demographic factors . 6
In all the three
demographic specifications the test for the violation of the second order
conditions was performed at all data points and at the data means following
the procedure explained in section 5.
No violations in sign were encountered.
All eigenvalues were negative.
The elasticities for the Scaling, Translating and Barten-Gorrnan models
are presented in Table 2. Comparing the results provides some
in~ghts
into
whether or not the estimated elasticities are sensitive to the demographic
specification.
6
Note that non- positive compensated elasticities is a necessary (minimal )
but not sufficient condition for negative semi - definiteness of the
Slutsky matrix.
17
Table 2 . Elasticities Estima t es for the Translating, Scaling and Barten- Gorman Models
Almost Ideal Model
Food at Home
(fh)
Food \ Home
(fah)
Others
(othl
T
s
BG
T
s
BG
T
s
BG
pfh
- .556
( . 095)
- .558
( . 095)
-. 569
( . 106)
-. 035
( . 197)
- .032
( .199)
-. 019
( .196)
.116
( .021)
. 116
(. 021)
. 119
( . 022)
pf ah
-. 012
( . 069)
-. 011
( . 069)
-. 007
( . 067)
- .088
(. 450)
- . 0 91
( . 45 6 )
-. 113
(. 009)
. 009
(. 019)
. 009
( . 019)
. 009
( . 018)
poth
. 569
( .10 1 )
. 56 9
( .1 03)
.575
( .108)
. 123
( . 273)
.123
( .277)
. 132
( .258)
- . 125
( . 014)
-. 125
(. 014)
-. 128
( . 015)
x
. 381
(. 078)
. 380
( . 078)
.396
( . 083)
.864
( . 092)
• 967
( . 094)
. 87 9
( . 101)
1.14
( . 012)
1.14
( . 012)
1.133
(. 013)
Dl
-. 330
( . 126)
-. 332
( . 125)
- .378
( .226)
.102
( . 222)
. 106
(. 019)
.105
( . 0 41 )
. 061
( .020)
. 060
( .230)
. 07
( . 219)
02
. 364
( . 123)
.371
( .226)
.333
( .227)
-.4 5 1
(. 226)
-.4 53
( . 129)
- . 464
( .308)
-. 043
(.019)
- . 04 4
(.019)
- . 036
( . 059)
Note: Asymptotic standa r d e r rors are i n paren t heses .
The price elasticities are compensa ted .
The results indicate that the statistical and economic differences
between the estimated elasti ci ties across demographic specifications are not
significant.
The estimates are consistent with the theory and conform with
estimates from other time-series studies.
Though the elasticity estimates do
not vary statistically and economically across demographic specifications , it
is worth noti ng that the estimated elasti cities are similar for the
Translating and Scaling but differ somewhat from the Barten-Gorman results.
This is an i ndication t hat the Barten-Gorman model signifi cantly captures the
economic information conveyed by either Translating or Scaling.
7 . Conclusions
This study provides a theo retical cons i s t ent specifcation of the BartenGorma n mod el , illustrates how i t can be ide ntified a nd estimates it in the
AIDS framework.
We use the homogeneity property of the modified Gorman cost
function t o derive conditi ons that allow identifying all demographic
parameters .
We also show how to test for concavity in the Barten-Go rman
context .
18
With the present data set the Likelihood ratio test did not indicate the
Barten-Gorman model as statistically superior.
Neverthless , the Barten-Gorman
specification can still be deemed as more interesting.
In fact, the v's
artefact permits singling out the price and income component of the
demographic effect and
distinguishing whether a variable affects consumption
through an income or a price effect . This knowledge is usually not available a
priori . On this ground , the Barten-Gorman model is preferred to a less
theoretically rich specification such as Translating and Scaling.
19
Appendix A . Derivation of the Income, Price and Demographic Elasticities for
the Barten- Gorman model
.
Recall from equation (11) the estimated version of the Barten-Gorman
model:
+
Pi
ln (
)
y•
A(p,d)
• « i + ( 1-vi ) l n mi +°1?-Yij (lnpj +lnmi) +Pi( (lny-1;: (1-vi) lnmi (lnpi +lnmi) ) -lnA (p,
1
J
d))
(A .1)
where:
ln A(p*)
=
ln A(p, d)
=Cl()
+ ~ « i ln pj + .5 EE y ~ ·ln p~
i j
l
l]
l
ln p~
J
and,
for i=l, .. , n, n being the number of equations and r=l , . . ,R, R being the number
of demographic variables.
Let:
A
nxl vector of
parameters ,
parameters,
of
demographic parametrs ,
of p parameters,
of ~ v parameters, 7
of the means of the natural log of the price variables,
of the means of the natural log of the demographic variables,
denoting the mean of the natural log of income, and
of shares,
of the natural log of quantities,
of 1.
r = nxn matrix of
A = nxR matrix
nxl
nxR
p = nxl
D Rxl
y
lxl
w nxl
Q = nxl
\ = nxl
B
A
Define:
M = A*D
S = A*D
T = M-S
P*= P+S
8
vector
matrix
vector
vector
scalar
vector
vector
vector
Cl
x
= nxl
vecto r valued demographic function ,
nxl vector valued scaling component of M,
nxl vector valued translating component of M, and
nxl vec tor valued fun c tion of demographically modified pri ces.
Given the overidentification of the Barten- Gorman model, t he e l ements o f
the row of the A matrix corresponding to the omitted equation are not
uniquely separable into its ~ and v components .
20
In matrix notation, equation (A.l) can be rewritten as:
where .* is the element-wise multiplication operator.
Using the definition of a share as wi=piqi/y, specify the following
relationship in matrix notation:
Q"'
ln w + Y - P.
Then, use the rule of vector differentiation to derive expenditure, price and
demographic elasticity.
Expenditure Elasticity 'l
'l ..
w "'
aY""
oln
oQ
oY
\ +
oln w aw
aw TY
UncOD1p9nsated Price Elastici t y Eu
oQ
CJP
oln w aw .. 1
aw oP
(r - a (A +
(M-sl
+
1\7
where I is an nxn identity matrix.
Compensated Pri ce Elasti city
E • Eu +
E
'l W1
using the Slutsky relationship.
Demoqraphi c Elasticity
oQ
aD
a1n
w aw
-aw- aD
= 1 . • (('1-Al + (r•Al
1\7
21
1r•P *l )'] - r
Appendix B .
Tab1• B . 1 . Values of the Likelihood Functions
Demographic Specit'ication
Barten-Gorman
356.83
(BG)
Barten Scaling (BS)
356.27
Translating (T)
356.21
Table B. 2. Parameter Estimates
pa ram
T
s
BG
a1
0 .44 82
(0.038 4)
0 .4456
(0.0373)
0 . 3883
(0 . 0695)
a2
0 . 01645
(0.0212)
0 . 0 1816
(0 . 0213)
0 . 02271
(0 . 02 42)
1'11
- 0 . 01280
(0.0119)
- 0 . 0 1291
(0 . 0118)
- 0 . 011 4 6
(0.0121)
I' 12
- 0 . 09936
(0.0124)
- 0.09921
(0 . 0 125)
- 0.09737
(0 . 0135)
1'22
0 . 05143
(0 . 0140)
0 . 05170
(0 . 0 136)
0 . 04603
(0. 0139)
~l
o. 04717
(0 . 0251)
0 . 0 4733
(0.02 48)
0 . 0 4 607
(0 . 0235)
~2
- 0 . 00739
(0.0052)
- 0 . 00756
(0.0051)
- 0 . 00673
(0 . 0056)
5u
- 1. 605
(1. 76 4 )
- 0 . 052 44
(0 . 0198)
-0.9252
(11.57)
512
1. 422
( 1. 4 97)
0 . 05772
(0 . 0195)
- 0.7986
(3 . 653)
521
o. 5119
(0 . 6813)
0 . 005695
(0 . 0 123)
3.085
(3 . 698)
522
- 0 . 7067
(0 . 5806
- 0 . 02506
(0 . 0125)
- 0.9219
(2. 721)
Vl
1. 042
V2
1.076
(0 . 0765)
(0 . 0 911)
Note : Standard deviations are in parentheses
22
Appendix c.
Swmnary Statistics
- Years 1953 to 1988
Unit
Minimum
Maximum
Mean
Std Dev
Sbil
232 . 6
3235.1
1070 . 61
904 . 2203
sha re(food at home)
%
0.1151
0.2056
0 . 1604
0.02 64
share(food away from
home)
%
0.0529
0 . 0606
0 . 0554
0 .0019
s hare( non food)
%
o. 7347
0 . 8302
0 . 78 43
0 . 0274
p(food at home)
$
29 . 5
116. 6
50.2916
1. 6450
p(food away from home)
$
21.5
121. 8
44.6150
1.8094
p(non food)
$
23.3238
124 .688
45 . 1786
l. 7558
population 0- 15 of age
%
0.2285
0.3306
0.2827
1.1421
pop enrolled in school
%
0.2047
0 . 2943
0 . 2584
1. 0905
Variable
total PC Expenditur e
23
Atkinson, A. 1970. "A Method for Discriminating between Models." Journal of
the Royal Statistical Society . 32 : 323-53 .
Barten, A.P. 1964. "Family Composition , Prices and Expenditure Patterns ." In
Econometric Analysis for National Economic Planning: 16th Symposium of
the Colston Society, ed. by P. Hart, G. Mills, and J.K. Whitaker.
London: Butterworth .
•
Blackorby, c . and D. Donaldson. 1988. "Money Metric Utility: A Harmless
Normalization?" Journal of Economic Theory. Vol. 46: 120-1 29.
Chung, C. 1987. "Modelling Demand Systems with Demographic Effects."
McKethan-Matherly Discussion Paper MM25, University of Florida,
Gainesville.
Davidson, R. and J. MacKinnon . 1981. "Several Tests for Model Specification in
the Presence of Alternative Hypothesis." Econometrica. Vol. 49: 781 -794.
Deaton, A. and J. Muellbauer. 1986. "On Measuring Child Costs: With
Application to Poor Countries". Journal of Political Economy.
Vol. 94 : 720-744.
Deaton , A. and Muellbauer, J. 1980 . "An Almost Ideal Demand System", American
Economic Review, 70:312-326.
Gorman, W. 1976. "Tricks with Utility Functions." In Essays in Economic
Analysis:Proceedings of the 1975 AUTE Conference, Sheffeld, ed. by
M.J . Artis and A.R.Nobay. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lewbel, A. 1985. "A Unified Approach to Incorporating Demographic or other
Effects into Demand Systems. " Review of Economic Studies. Vol.52:1-18 .
-~Journal
. 1989 . "Household Equivalence Scales and Welfare Comparisons. "
of Public Economics. Vol 39:377-391.
Pe.saran, M. and A. Deaton. "Testing Non-Nested Nonlinear Regression Models."
Econometrica. Vol 46:677-694
Pollak , R. and T. Wales . 1981. "Demographic Variables in Demand Analysis ."
Econometrica. 49(6 ) :1533-1559 .
. 1991. "The Likelihood Dominance Criterion. A New Approach to Model
----=s-e.....
lection." Journal of Econometrics. 47:227-242.
24