REM WORKING PAPER SERIES
Public Debt and Economic Growth in Brazil
António Afonso, Sérgio Gadelha, Agatha Silva
REM Working Paper 0148-2020
December 2020
REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics
Rua Miguel Lúpi 20,
1249-078 Lisboa,
Portugal
ISSN 2184-108X
Any opinions expressed are those of the authors and not those of REM. Short, up to
two paragraphs can be cited provided that full credit is given to the authors.
REM – Research in Economics and Mathematics
Rua Miguel Lupi, 20
1249-078 LISBOA
Portugal
Telephone: +351 - 213 925 912
E-mail:
[email protected]
https://rem.rc.iseg.ulisboa.pt/
https://twitter.com/ResearchRem
https://www.linkedin.com/company/researchrem/
https://www.facebook.com/researchrem/
PUBLIC DEBT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN BRAZIL*
António Afonso $
Sérgio Gadelha#
Agatha Silva
December 2020
Abstract
This paper provides new insights on the relationship between public debt and economic
growth in Brazil. We used Granger causality tests, in multivariate and bivariate analyses
using respectively VEC and ARDL methodologies, and monthly data over the period
1998:1-2019:11. We find that: i) debt-to-GDP and GDP growth rate have a bi-directional
Granger causality relationship; ii) debt can improve growth in the short run and becomes
harmful in the long run; iii) GDP growth always reduces debt, both in the short and long
run; iv) the dynamic between debt and growth in the long run is influenced by the inflation
rate, exchange rate and the Emerging Markets Bond Index Plus (Embi+).
Keywords: Granger causality; Vector Autoregressive; Autoregressive Distributed Lag;
government debt; economic growth; Brazil.
JEL Codes: C32; C22; O40; H63; H69.
The authors acknowledge financial Support from FCT – Fundação para a Ciência e Tecnologia (Portugal),
national funding through research grant UIDB/05069/2020. The opinions expressed herein are those of the
authors and not necessarily those of their employers.
$
ISEG, Universidade de Lisboa; REM/UECE. Rua Miguel Lupi 20, 1249-078 Lisbon, Portugal. email:
[email protected].
#
Full Collaborating Researcher - University of Brasília. Professor of the Professional Master's in
Economics, Public Policy and Development at the Brasiliense Institute of Public Law. email:
[email protected]
ISEG/ULisbon – University of Lisbon, R. Miguel Lupi 20, 1249-078 Lisbon.
STN, Brazilian National Treasury - Esplanada dos Ministérios, Bloco P (Ministério da Economia), 2º
andar - Centro Cívico - Brasília - DF - CEP: 70048-900 Brasil. email:
[email protected].
*
1
1. INTRODUCTION
Increasing government indebtedness worldwide has become a problem since the
Global Financial Crisis (GFC) of 2008-2009, raising concerns related to the vulnerability
of countries. In order to address this problem many economists argue that governments
should enforce fiscal consolidations, to decrease public debt, explaining that this would
result in economic growth. On the other hand, there are economists who advocate that
fiscal consolidations could result in increasing debt-to-GDP ratios, moreover, this
reduction in government size would affect the growth rate of the GDP.
Brazil, as many other countries, faces an increasing government debt burden.
Between 1998 and 2020 Gross General Government Debt increased from 40% of GDP
to 89%. In addition, the economic recession worsened the problem, in 2019, real GDP
grew only 1.1% and in 2020 it is expected to have a significant decrease. During the
period under analysis (January 1998 until November 2019) the Brazilian government had
five different presidents and alternated between moments of fiscal expansions and
consolidations. Furthermore, Brazil faced hyperinflation in the past, which also makes
the Brazilian Central Bank strongly conservative in relation to the interest rate, indirectly
implying higher costs to government debt, by increasing its debt service.
Since 1998, after the Plano Real1, Brazil has followed an inflation targeting regime
that includes floating exchange rate and primary surplus targets in addition to inflation
targets. Therefore, macroeconomic variables such as interest rate, inflation rate, exchange
rate and primary surplus may be correlated with the pattern followed by the GDP growth
rate and the debt-to-GDP ratio.
In December 2016, the Brazilian Congress approved a Constitution Amendment that
created a ceiling for public spending2 and the government has tried to implement some
austerity measures, even during recession. However, the government has not succeeded
in reducing government debt, moreover it was not able to overcome the recession. The
lack of consensus about the implications of public debt makes it hard for the government
to make the best policy decisions.
1
The Plano Real was a set of economic reforms implemented in Brazil, with the main objective of
combating the hyperinflation.
2
Constitutional Amendment n. 95.
2
The actual situation raises the question: “What is the relationship between public debt
and economic growth in Brazil?” This paper aims to empirically investigate the dynamic
between economic growth and public debt in Brazil in the period after the Plano Real. It
will also include other variables that are related to both public debt and economic growth.
The assessment is conducted through the analysis of growth equations, followed by a
Vector Autoregressive (VAR) model and an Autoregressive Distributed Lag
(ARDL) model, applying Granger causality tests. The data frequency is monthly, over
the period of January 1998 and November 2019.
Since there are just a few empirical studies applied to Brazil, this paper contributes to
the literature providing empirical results using Brazilian data. Moreover, we are not aware
of any other study that has analysed the interaction between debt and growth considering
the interrelationships with the other variables used in this composition.
The most relevant findings of our study are summarized as follows: Debt-to-GDP
ratio and GDP growth rate have a bi-directional Granger causality relationship. Debt can
improve growth in the short run and become harmful the in long run. Also, GDP growth
rate always reduces debt ratio, both in the short and long run. The dynamic between debt
and growth in the long run is influenced by inflation rate, exchange rate and the Emerging
Markets Bond Index Plus (Embi+), these variables are positively Granger caused by
changes in debt-to-GDP ratio and negatively Granger cause GDP growth rate, while GDP
growth rate negatively Granger causes Embi+, that in turn positively Granger causes debt.
Therefore, the negative impact of debt on growth is also indirect by changes on inflation
rate, exchange rate and Embi+, while the reduction on debt ratio provoked by GDP
growth rate is also indirectly, by the reduction on Embi+.
This remaining of this paper is structured as follows: section two reviews the literature
related to the topic; section three presents the methodology; section four presents the data
and the empirical estimation results; and section five is the conclusion.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
The literature associated with the relation between public debt and economic growth
is well developed, despite the lack of empirical studies applied to Brazil, for the best of
our knowledge. In addition, one should consider that empirical results have mixed
conclusions, divided between those which concluded that debt improves growth,
3
therefore generates a reduction on debt-to-GDP ratio, or those which advocate that debt
hurts growth. Another strand of literature argues that government debt is useful until some
threshold, after that becoming harmful. These different conclusions strengthen the idea
that results are country and time specific.
Next, the empirical literature review will be divided into three different perspectives.
Firstly, international studies that use Granger causality. Secondly, international studies
that employed different methodologies. Lastly, studies applied to Brazil.
2.1. Literature using Granger Causality Tests
Afonso & Jalles (2014) studied the two-way causality between government spending,
revenues and growth. They constructed different models applying OLS and GMM
estimators and Granger causality test for one hundred fifty-five developed and developing
countries, for the period of 1970 to 2010. They found weak evidence of causality from
per capita GDP to expenditures. However, they have found stronger evidence supporting
the reverse causality, in the short and long run. Moreover, they applied the same
methodology only for OECD sub-sample countries and found stronger evidence for
Granger causality from government spending to GDP in the short-run, although no
significant long-run effect. The reverse relationship still holds for OECD sub-sample, in
the short and long-run.3
Additionally, Gómez-Puig & Sosvilla-Rivero (2015) also used Granger causality for
eleven EMU countries over 1980 and 2013, analysing the bi-directional relationship
between debt and growth. Their study considered cross-country heterogeneity by
including central and peripheral countries. Before allowing for endogenous breaks they
found evidence of a positive effect of the change in debt on growth and vice versa. After
allowing breaks, they found a “diabolic loop” between low growth and high debt for
Spain, Belgium, Greece, Italy and the Netherlands. However, they found a positive
relationship from debt to growth for Austria, Finland and France. Their results somehow
explain why empirical studies are not always clear and can show ambiguous conclusions,
depending on the period analysed and the country considered. According to the authors,
causality should be examined from a dynamic and country specific point of view.
3
See Afonso & Alves(2016) for a complementary analyses of the possibility of Wagner´s law.
4
Lai et al (2015) explored the casual relationship between government debt, GDP and
inflation in France, using annual data between 1980 and 2010. After performing unit root
tests, they concluded that there is no long run co-integration between these variables.
Therefore, they implemented VAR models and Granger causality test to check if there is
short run relationship. They found a unidirectional causality from debt to GDP and from
inflation to GDP, either a bidirectional relation between inflation and government debt.
Butts (2009) studied the relationship between economic growth and short-term
external debt of twenty-seven Latin American and Caribbean countries, using data from
1970 to 2003. He concluded by the existence of Granger causality from economic growth
to short term external debt in thirteen countries.
2.2. Literature using different methodologies
Afonso & Jalles (2013) investigated the effect of government debt ratio on economic
growth using a panel of one hundred fifty-five countries, over the period of 1970 and
2008. They concluded that government debt has a negative effect on growth. Moreover,
they concluded that the longer the average maturity of government debt the higher the
growth rate for OECD countries in the group. They also found a threshold of 59% of GDP
to European countries and 79% for emerging countries.
Additionally, Afonso & Alves (2015) also used panel data techniques to analyse the
effect of government debt on real per capita GDP for fourteen European countries, during
the period 1970-2012. They found that debt has a negative effect on growth both in the
short and in long run. Furthermore, debt service had a much more negative effect than
debt on economic performance, they also found a debt threshold around 75%.
Cherif & Hasanov (2018) using a VAR model with debt feedback, analysed the
impact of macroeconomic shocks on US public debt dynamics, with data from 1947 to
2015. They concluded that austerity shocks could make debt decline at a cost of lower
growth, moreover, debt converged to its pre-shock path, suggesting that austerity is selfdefeating. On the other hand, growth shocks could substantially reduce debt, with none
of the pain associated with austerity.
Focusing on the inverted U-shape relationship between debt and growth, Reinhart &
Rogoff (2010), used a data set of two hundred years for forty-four countries and found a
threshold for public debt of 90%, this value is the same for advanced and for emerging
5
markets. They also found that inflation is higher when public debt is higher, when they
used data only from emerging markets.
However, Égert (2015) analysed a variant of Reinhart & Rogoff (2010) dataset, he
employed nonlinear threshold models and concluded that this negative nonlinear
relationship is not ensured, moreover, it changes across samples and different model
specifications.
2.3. Studies Applied to Brazil
Gadelha (2011) investigated the relationship between GDP, public expenditure,
public revenues, and government debt. He applied Granger causality in a bivariate and
multivariate framework, using data over January 1997 and June 2009. Results indicated
a bidirectional causality between government revenues and expenditures, concluding that
there is fiscal synchronization in Brazil.
Rodrigues & Teixeira (2013) analysed the relationship between public spending and
debt using Granger causality, over the period of 1950 and 2000. They concluded that
public spending did not cause GDP growth, it is mostly a consequence of economic
growth, supporting Wagner´s Law.
Gadelha & Divino (2008) investigated whether there is monetary dominance or fiscal
dominance4 in Brazil. They applied models of multivariate and bivariate Granger
causality, with monthly data over January 1995 and December 2005. The variables
analysed were interest rate, debt to GDP ratio, primary surplus to GDP ratio, real
exchange rate and risk premium. They concluded that Brazil was under monetary
dominance and both interest rate and primary surplus unidirectionally Granger caused the
debt-to-GDP ratio.
The studies applied to Brazil did not focused on the relationship between public debt
and growth, most of them emphasised the relation between government expenditures and
revenues or government expenditures and growth5 .Therefore, this study differentiates
4
In a monetary dominance the fiscal authority generates primary surplus that is enough to keep the debtto-GDP ratio stable, therefore the monetary authority can exercise their role. On the other hand, when there
is a fiscal dominance, the monetary authority needs to allow prices adjust to ensure that the current value
of the outstanding government debt is equal to the actual real value of the future primary surplus. See, for
instance, Afonso (2008).
5
Reinhart & Rogoff (2010) included Brazil in his sample, however it did not focused specifically on
Brazilian data, but on a set of emerging and advanced countries.
6
from empirical literature applied to Brazil by analysing the relation between government
debt and GDP. Moreover, aiming to find a more complete relationship we included the
variables used by Gadelha & Divino (2008), that are interest rate, inflation rate, exchange
rate, primary surplus and Embi+6 , since these variables are also important for the changes
in public debt and economic growth.
3. METHODOLOGY
3.1. Data Description and Unit Root Tests
The dataset was collected from several sources: the Gross Domestic General
Government Debt (ratio of GDP), which is called debt for simplicity throughout the text,
is represented by D; Y represents the GDP (growth rate), called growth throughout the
text; Over Selic7 interest rate is noted by I; Nominal Exchange rate direct quotation
(R$/US$), is noted by E, all the variables listed above were sourced from the Brazilian
Central Bank. R represents the inflation rate8 (percentage change), which has Brazilian
Institute of Geography and Statistics as source. S represents the primary budget (ratio of
GDP), which is sourced from Brazilian National Treasure. Embi+9 is sourced from JP
Morgan. We use monthly data, starting in January 1998 and ending in November 2019.
The data processing was as follows: First, we treated the outlier presented in the series
of primary surplus in September 2010, by excluding values that represented atypical
revenues and expenditures10. Then series of GDP and debt, which showed some seasonal
component, were seasonally adjusted by the methodology Census X-13. The seasonal
adjusted series and the one of primary surplus were converted to real terms, deflated by
consumer index price, which considered January 1998 as the base value. Thereafter, the
series were converted to annual values, by adding up the twelve rolling window values,
thus they could be analysed in the same bases as public debt, which is a stock variable.
Lastly, the values were converted in ratios of GDP.
6
Emerging Markets Bond Index is a benchmark index for measuring the total return performance of some
emerging countries bonds compared to a similar American bond.
7
Interest rate set by Central Bank, used as a monetary policy instrument.
8
Consumer Index Price (IPCA).
9
Measures the spread between the Brazilian bond and US bond, used as a proxy for risk.
10
In this month primary surplus was affected by capitalization and onerous operations with the Brazilian
oil company, Petrobras, that was atypical. The treatment followed (Gadelha & Divino, 2013).
7
The Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) unit root tests are the
most widely applied, however they can present problems related to power and size in
finite samples. Moreover, Maddala & Kim (2004) explain that structural change does
affect inference on unit roots and on cointegration, being important to allow for possible
breaks at the estimation stage. Therefore, the study of stationarity is going to be conducted
by a new generation of tests that address these related problems. Firstly, it is applied the
modified Dickey-Fuller (ADFGLS) test, suggested by Elliot et al (1996), then the PhillipsPerron (𝑀𝑍𝛼𝐺𝐿𝑆 ) suggested by Ng and Perron (2001).
Elliot at al (1996) proposed the use of generalized least squares (GLS) estimators
instead of ordinary least squares (OLS), to purge deterministic terms presented in the
regression, since OLS estimators are inefficient in the presence of heteroscedasticity.
Moreover, Ng & Perron (2001) explained that distortions of size in the presence of
negative moving averages, related to outliers, implicate an incorrect selection of lags by
the Akaike (AIC) and Schwarz (SIC) criteria. They also proposed the use of GLS
estimators in place of OLS, for the traditional PP test. Therefore, this study applies both
tests, making use of the modified Akaike Criteria (MAIC) for lag selection.
However, considering economic changes during the period, we may account for
structural breaks. Furthermore, the modified ADFGLS and 𝑀𝑍𝛼𝐺𝐿𝑆 tests still have low
power in the presence of breaks. Therefore, we applied two tests with endogenous breaks.
The first one is the test proposed by Saikkonen & Lütkepohl (2002), hereinafter referred
to as SL. The SL test considers that the change can occur over some period, and using a
level change function (𝑓(𝜃)´ 𝛾 ) it is possible to have a smooth transition function, which
is added to the deterministic term. The general model is expressed in the following
equation:
𝑦𝑡, = 𝜇0, + 𝜇1 𝑡 + 𝑓(𝜃)´ 𝛾 + ν𝑡
(1)
where y𝑡 is the data series, 𝜇0 is the intercept, 𝜇1 is the deterministic trend coefficient; θ
and γ are unknown parameters, ν𝑡 are residuals generated by an autoregressive process,
which may have a unit root. There are three possible changing functions for 𝑓(𝜃)´ 𝛾: shift
dummy, exponential shift and rational shift. In this study it is going to be applied the last
one, rational shift, which represents a rational function in the lag operator applied to a
shift dummy. In this test, deterministic trends are estimated by GLS, then they are
8
subtracted from the original series, generating a new series. Then, an ADF test is applied
for the adjusted series. Critical values were tabulated by Lanne et al. (2002).
The second test implemented is the one proposed by Vogelsang & Perron (1998),
hereinafter referred to as VP, that also allows for endogenous breaks by innovation
outlier, VP similarly to SL assumes the breaks to occur gradually. Two models are used
to check the stationarity hypothesis: intercept break and, trend and intercept break, both
in level and in first difference. The general model is expressed in the following equation:
ϳ
y𝑡 = 𝜇0 + 𝜇1 y𝑡−1 + 𝜇2 t + 𝛽1 D𝑙 + 𝛽2 D𝑝 + 𝛽3 D𝑡 + ∑ 𝘱𝑡 𝛥y𝑡−𝑖 + 𝜀𝑡
(2)
𝑖=1
where y𝑡 is the data series, 𝜇0 is the intercept, 𝜇2 is the deterministic trend coefficient; 𝛽1 ,
𝛽2 and 𝛽3 are breaking parameters to be estimated; D𝑙 , D𝑝
and D𝑡 are dummy variables for
the intercept break, one time break, and trend break, respectively; 𝘱𝑡 and 𝜇1 are unknown
parameters, 𝛥 is the first lag operator, ϳ is the optimum lag length to be selected by the
Akaike criterion; and ɛ𝑡 are i.i.d. innovations.
3.2. Growth Equations
The first specification we used to understand the interaction between variables is an
estimation of the linear relationship between D and Y, which follow Afonso & Alves
𝑗
(2015) and Afonso & Jalles(2013), using different variables from them in the vector 𝑋𝑡 ,
as follows:
𝑗
𝑌𝑡 = 𝛼𝑡, + 𝛽1 𝑋𝑡 + 𝛽2 𝐷𝑡 + ɛ𝑡 , 𝑡 = 1, … , 𝑇
(3)
where 𝑌𝑡 represents the growth rate of GDP; 𝐷𝑡 is the debt-to-GDP ratio, and ɛ𝑡 is the error
𝑗
term. 𝛼, 𝛽1 and 𝛽2 are unknown parameters to be estimated. The vector 𝑋𝑡 includes
variables that may impact on the relation between public debt and economic growth that
were described in Section 3.1.
Next, with the inclusion of 𝐷𝑡2 in the equation (3), one can check if there is some non-
linear relationship. Thus, in equation (4), if 𝛽2 is positive and 𝛽3 is negative, we have
support for the inverted U-shape relationship, meaning that we can check if debt has a
positive effect on growth until some threshold:
𝑌𝑡 = 𝛼𝑡 + 𝛽1 𝑋𝑡 + 𝛽2 𝐷𝑡 + 𝛽3 𝐷𝑡2 + ɛ𝑡 , 𝑡 = 1, … , 𝑇.
9
(4)
where; 𝐷𝑡2 is the debt-to-GDP ratio squared, 𝛽3 is an unknown parameter to be estimated.
3.3. Multivariate Causality
The investigation of the causality among the variables begins by estimating a Vector
Autorregressive (VAR) model, following Gadelha (2011) and Gadelha & Divino (2008).
The VAR model considers all variables as endogenous, which is a common characteristic
in economic series, in the sense that each variable can influence and be influenced by the
behaviour of other variables. The VAR in its reduced form is represented as:
X𝑡 = 𝐴0 + 𝐴1 X𝑡−1 + 𝐴2 X𝑡−2 + … + 𝐴𝑝 X𝑡−𝑝 + 𝜉𝑡
(5)
where X𝑡 is a vector of stationary variables, 𝑝 is the number of lags, 𝐴0 is a vector of
intercepts, 𝐴𝑖 is a matrix of coefficients, and 𝜉𝑡 is a vector of residuals not autocorrelated
and homoscedastic. The lag selection is made by the usual lag length criteria tests,
selecting the one that is considered the best for most of the test criteria results.
If the series are not stationary it is necessary to perform cointegration tests to examine
if there is a long run equilibrium relation among the series. This study will perform co-
integration tests following the procedures suggested by Johansen & Juselius (1990),
Johansen (2002) and Johansen at al (2000). The test equation is defined as follow:
𝑝−1
ΔX𝑡 = 𝜇 + 𝜋 X𝑡−1 + ∑ 𝜋 𝑖 𝛥X𝑡−𝑖 + 𝜀𝑡
(6)
𝑖=1
where X𝑡 is a column vector, 𝜇 is a vector of constants, 𝜋 and 𝜋 𝑖 represent a matrix of
coefficients, 𝑝 is the lag order, and 𝜀𝑡 is the residual not autocorrelated and homoscedastic.
The matrix 𝜋 is the co-integrating matrix, which represents the long run information about
the relationship among the variables. The number of values of 𝜋 that are statistically
different from zero, provides the number of co-integration equations. Johansen proposed
the use of two statistics to test for co-integration:
𝑛
λ𝑡𝑟𝑎𝑐𝑒 (r) = −𝑇 ∑ (1 − 𝜆̂𝑖 )
𝑖=𝑟+1
λ𝑡𝑟𝑎𝑐𝑒 (r, r + 1) = −𝑇 𝑙𝑛(1 − 𝜆̂
𝑟+1 )
10
(7)
(8)
where 𝜆̂ are the values estimated for the matrix 𝜋 , and 𝑇 is the number of observations.
The test follows a recursive procedure, where the null hypothesis is that there are, at least,
r cointegrated vectors.
Engle, & Granger (1987) explain that if there is co-integration among the series, there
must exist a long run relationship between them. Co-integration implies that deviations
from equilibrium are stationary, with finite variance. If that is the case, one should
estimate a Vector Error Correction Model (VEC) using the linear combination of the
series corrected by their co-integrating vector. The VEC model is represented as follow:
𝛥𝑋𝑡 = μ + Γ1 𝛥𝑋𝑡−1 + ⋯ + Γ𝑝−1 𝛥𝑋𝑡−𝑝+1 + 𝛱𝑋𝑡−1 + 𝜀𝑡
(9)
where, 𝑝 is the number of lags already selected in the VAR model. Π = αβ’, where β is a
matrix (p x r), whose columns contain the cointegration vectors, α is a matrix (p x r) with
the adjustment coefficients. The linear combinations of β’Xt-1 represents the r number of
cointegration equations.
3.4. Bivariate Causality
The bivariate analysis is conducted by ARDL models, following Gadelha (2011) and
Gadelha & Divino (2008). In this model both the dependent variable and the independent
variables are related contemporaneously and in its lagged values. The advantages of the
ARDL technique is that it accepts different lags between the variables, which allows to
capture the dynamic of the system without omission of important lag lengths. However,
ARDL models in a bivariate system can be affected by the omission of important
variables, this problem is overcome in this study by the multivariate causality.
The Error Correction Model (ECM) in a bivariate relationship can be derived as
follows:
Y𝑡 = μ + 𝛽1 X𝑡 + 𝘦𝑡
(10)
where Y𝑡 and X𝑡 are vectors respectively of the dependent variable and the independent,
𝘦𝑡
is the error term.
Solving for 𝘦𝑡 we find the cointegration equation for 𝑋𝑡 and 𝑌𝑡 . The ECMs for both
variables are respectively:
11
𝑝
𝑞
𝑖=1
𝑖=1
𝑙
𝑚
𝑖=1
𝑖=1
ΔX𝑡 = μ𝑥 + 𝛼𝑥 𝘦𝑥,𝑡−1 + ∑ 𝛼11 𝛥X𝑡−𝑖 + ∑ 𝛼12 𝛥Y𝑡−𝑖 + 𝜀𝑥𝑡
ΔY𝑡 = μ𝑦 + 𝛼𝑦 𝘦𝑦,𝑡−1 + ∑ 𝛼21 𝛥𝑌𝑡−𝑖 + ∑ 𝛼22 𝛥𝑋𝑡−𝑖 + 𝜀𝑦𝑡
(11)
(12)
where 𝜀𝑥𝑡 and 𝜀𝑦𝑡 are uncorrelated residuals, 𝘦𝑥,𝑡−1 and 𝘦𝑦,𝑡−1 are estimated parameters for
the lagged residual, that came from the solution of equation (10), the parameters 𝛼𝑥 and
𝛼𝑦
from equations (11) and (12) measures the speed of adjustment of X𝑡 and Y𝑡
respectively in direction to the long-run equilibrium. p, q, l and m are the optimal lags.
The parameters 𝛼11 , 𝛼21 , 𝛼12 and 𝛼22 represents the short-run relationship.
𝛥Y𝑡
In equations (11) and (12), the null hypothesis 𝐻0 : 𝛼12 = 0 and 𝛼𝑥 = 0 means that
does not Granger cause 𝛥X𝑡 , on the other hand, the alternative hypothesis 𝐻1 : 𝛼12 ≠0
and 𝛼𝑥 ≠ 0 means that 𝛥Y𝑡 Granger cause 𝛥X𝑡 . Similarly, 𝐻0 : 𝛼22 = 0 and 𝛼𝑦 = 0 means
that 𝛥X𝑡 does not Granger cause 𝛥Y𝑡 , on the other hand, the alternative hypothesis 𝐻1 :
𝛼22 ≠0
and 𝛼𝑦 ≠ 0 means that 𝛥X𝑡 Granger cause 𝛥Y𝑡 .
4. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
4.1. Unit Root Tests and Data Analysis
Table I reports the results of ADFGLS and 𝑀𝑍𝛼𝐺𝐿𝑆 unit root tests applied to the series
in level and in first differences. Results show that the primary surplus, the debt, the
exchange rate and the Embi+ are stationary in first difference; the inflation rate is
stationary in level; the GDP growth rate and the interest rate are not stationary in neither
of these tests. These results were expected because of the presence of structural changes,
which are represented by breaks in the series, also graphically noticeable in Figure 1.
[Table I]
[Figure 1]
Therefore, the analysis was improved using unit root tests with structural endogenous
breaks, presented in Table II. Both SL and VP tests reached the same conclusions, in
which series of the GDP growth rate, the interest rate, the Embi+ and the inflation rate
12
are stationary in level. However, the debt, the primary surplus and the exchange rate are
stationary in first difference.
[Table II]
Most of the selected break dates occurred between September 1998 and April 1999.
During this period multiple changes occurred in the economic policy, the most relevant
one was the switch from foreign exchange anchor to inflation target policies, which came
out with sharp exchange rate devaluation and strong control of interest rates to achieve
the inflation target.
Another important break selected by the tests were from October and November 2002.
This period reflects a crisis of external confidence related to the election of president Lula,
from Worker´s Party, which is called Lula´s effect. The third important break is related
to the economic recession that hit Brazil in the second quarterly of 2014, which may
explain the breaks that appeared between April 2014 and December 2015.
Therefore, we used three dummies variables, considering the breaking dates that
appeared in the unit root tests and the information presented in Pastore et al (2020)11,
which reinforces the breaks pointed in the unit root tests. These dummies take the values
“1” for the specific period when some event occurred, and “0” otherwise. The dummies
used were: dexchangerate, dlula and dcrisis. The first one selected the period of January
1998 until March 1999, and it is related to changes in economic policy due to exchange
rate depreciation; the second one selected the period between June 2002 and April 2003,
which is related to Lula´s effect; the last is referred to the period between April 2014 and
December 2016, a period of a strong economic recession.
4.2. Growth Equation
We estimated five different static models: where model 1, model 2, model 3 and
model 4 are applications of equation (3) and model 5 checks the possibility of non-linear
relationship, as presented in the equation (4). We also used the dummies exchangerate,
dlula, and dcrisis which appeared to be statically significant at 10% level in all the
models. Results are presented in Table III.
11
Report presented by the Business Cycle Dating Committee (CODACE), which presents the most relevant
changes in economic cycles of Brazilian economy.
13
[Table III]
In model 1 we found significantly positive coefficients for debt and primary surplus,
significantly negative coefficient for interest rate, exchange rate and Emib+. Results
shows that debt has a positive impact on the GDP growth rate.
In model 2 we checked if the Brazilian Constitution amendment, which imposed a
ceiling for government expenditure, representing a fiscal consolidation, had some impact
on the debt and growth relationship. For this analysis we used a dummy represented as
dconsolidation, which receives the value “1” if in the period considered there was a
government consolidation, and “0” otherwise. However, dconsolidation showed not to be
significant at the 10% level. Moreover, the results for the coefficients are very similar to
those found on Model 1.
In model 3 and 4 we analysed if the relationship between debt and growth changes
when the debt ratio is “high” or “low”. In model 3, we used a dummy which received the
value “1” if in the period government debt was placed in between 30% and 60% of GDP,
and “0” otherwise, represented by d3060. In model 4 we used a dummy which received
the value “1” if in the period government debt was placed in between 60% and 90%, and
“0” otherwise, represented by d6090. These values followed those applied by Reinhart
and Rogoff (2010). The dummies used presented significant coefficients. Although the
results of the debt coefficient were almost the same in both models, our results also
suggest that growth intensifies when debt is in between 60% and 90%, since d6090 has a
positive coefficient and d3060 has a negative coefficient. These results are in line with
the findings of Reinhart and Rogoff (2010), they showed that growth rates in Brazil are
larger when debt ratio is between 60% and 90%, and smaller when it is above 90% or in
between 30% and 60%. They also found a threshold of 90% for debt-to-GDP ratio for
advanced and emerging countries.
Previous results lead us to estimate Model 5, where we followed equation (4), to check
for the possibility of an inverted U-shape relationship between debt and growth.
Although, 𝛽2 and 𝛽3 presented signals as expected, indicating the U-shape relationship,
𝛽3 was not statistically significant at 10% level. Therefore, we could not confirm the
threshold pointed by Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) for emerging countries.
14
In every model the results of the coefficients were very similar, all of them showed
debt presenting positive impacts on growth; interest rate, exchange rate and Embi+
presented negative impact; and primary surplus presented positive coefficients. In none
of the models inflation presented significant coefficients. The results of this section do
not consider the possibility of lagged effects, as well as the possible interaction between
the dependent and independent variables, which are going to be analysed in sections 4.3
and 4.4.
4.3. Multivariate Causality
Since half of the series became stationary only after the first difference, the next step
was testing for cointegration. However, before testing for the cointegration one needs to
select the correct lag length to be used. We applied the lag length criteria to the VAR of
the series and the decision was to select the lag pointed by most of the criteria’s results,
which was seven. This value was selected by Final Prediction Error (FPE) and Akaike
Information Criteria (AIC).
Firstly, we applied the Johansen Trace and Max-Eigenvalues tests, and results are
reported in Table IV. They suggest a long run relationship between the variables, as we
do not reject the null hypothesis for the presence of co-integration vector after the fourth
rank. Since it is known that the series have breaks, we selected the breaks that appeared
the most on the unit root test, then applied Johansen cointegration tests using these breaks.
Three pairs of dates were selected for the application of the test with breaks, they are:
January 1999 and November 2002, results are presented in Table V; January 1999 and
December 2015; and November 2002 and December 201512. All of them came to the
same conclusion: the existence of a long run relationship between the variables with five
co-integrating vectors. The presence of co-integration denotes that the multivariate
analysis should be conducted using a VEC. Thus, we estimated the VEC with five cointegration vectors, we used only exchangerate, dlula and dcrisis, we did not use
dconsolidation, d3060 and d6090 since they were not significant for most of the vectors.
[Table IV]
[Table V]
12
Results of the last two tests are not presented for reasons of parsimony.
15
In addition, we also tested the significance of the coefficients of the co-integration
equations in the VEC by employing a 𝜒 2 Wald Test. If the null hypothesis is rejected, we
can validate the results of Granger causality, moreover we can follow the strategy of
analysing all the variables as endogenous in the system. We rejected the null hypothesis
for all the coefficients 1% of significance, results are presented in Table VI.
[Table VI]
The VEC model satisfies the stability condition, since none of the roots of the model
lies outside the unit circle. Results of the Roots of AR Characteristic Polynomial are
presented in Figure 2. The autocorrelation LM test was applied to check for the presence
of serial correlation in the error terms. Results conclude for no autocorrelation after lag
seven, since we cannot reject the null hypothesis of no serial correlation at a significance
level of 5%. Results of the LM test are presented in Table VII.
[Figure 2]
[Table VII]
The results of the Granger causality are presented in Table VIII, tests conclude that
the GDP growth rate has a bidirectional relation with the debt ratio. Also, it is Granger
caused by the exchange rate and by the primary surplus. Moreover, the debt ratio has a
bidirectional relation with the interest rate, inflation rate and Embi+. Therefore, it is
possible to say that the interest rate, inflation rate and Embi+ can influence the relation
between debt and growth, since they affect the behaviour of the debt ratio. Moreover,
these results are in accordance with the finds of Gadelha & Divino (2008), that also
concluded that interest rate and Embi + Granger causes debt.
[Table VIII]
In order to understand the whole scenario of the interactions between the variables in
the system, we complemented the analyses of the causality by impulse response functions
and variance decomposition. By the impulse response function, we can see the response
of one variable, over a future period of time, to a shock of another variable in the VEC.
Therefore, we analysed the response of GDP growth rate and debt ratio to innovations of
the rest of the endogenous variables in the system over the period of 18 months.
16
Figure 3, in the appendix, presents the response of the GDP growth rate to one
standard innovation in the other endogenous variables of the VEC over time. Results
suggest that a shock in debt ratio has negative effects on GDP growth rate, there are only
a few positive effects during the third and fifth months. This behaviour is in accordance
with the theory that government debt has a negative impact on growth. Moreover, the
results of the first six months after a positive shock in primary surplus generates a positive
impact on economic growth, validating the theory of expansionary fiscal consolidations13.
Further, Matheson & Pereira (2016) concluded that fiscal multipliers related to spending
and credit have dropped to near zero in Brazil between the global financial crisis and
2014, thus non-Keynesian effects are more likely to prevail.
[Figure 3]
The GDP growth rate shows a positive response to a shock in interest rates, and it is
possible that an increase in short term interest rate14 could lead to an increase in savings,
which may have a positive impact on the GDP growth rate. The response to a shock in
the exchange rate is negative, meaning that a depreciation of the currency provokes a
negative impact on the GDP, and this negative impact intensifies until the eighth month,
then it starts to decrease and erodes after eighteen months, which may be related to capital
imports. Inflation causes a negative impact on GDP growth rate during the first ten
months, then it vanishes. Embi+ is negative for GDP growth rate during the first sixteen
months, then it vanishes. Both, inflation and Embi+ negative effects on growth may be
related to bad expectations.
We also tested the response of debt to a shock on the system variables. Results are
presented in Figure 4, in the appendix, they show that the debt ratio decreases when the
GDP growth rate increases. A shock on interest rate made debt increase over the first nine
months. This behaviour is explained by part of the public debt being indexed to the
interest rate. The exchange rate also makes debt increase over the first seven months, then
it vanishes. This behaviour is explained by the external debt, which may increase when
there is a currency depreciation. Innovations in the inflation rate provokes a decrease in
the debt ratio, in this case, although the monetary authority sets the interest rate
13
14
See Afonso & Martins (2016) for a better understanding of expansionary fiscal consolidations.
We used the Selic interest rate, that is the interbanking day interest rate.
17
independently of the fiscal authority, the debt ratio is somehow benefited by the
seignioriage. Embi+ increases debt ratio over all the period, meaning that when Embi+
increases, expectations of the country get worse; therefore, investors demand more risk
premium, which increases the debt.
The result validated the theory of expansionary fiscal consolidations for Brazil, since
a decreasing debt ratio has positive impacts on economic growth. Moreover, as it is
presented in Figure 5, debt shocks generate increases on inflation rate most of the time,
corroborating the fiscal theory of the price level (FTPL)15. Debt shocks also generate
interest rate increases, meaning that the monetary authority may try to control inflation.
Additionally, it improves profitability of government bonds, which may be required by
investors in response to the increase in debt ratio; Embi+ increases, since investors
demand more risk premium and currency depreciates. Inflation rate, exchange rate and
Embi+ will provoke a negative impact on GDP growth rate. Therefore, debt may directly
provoke a negative impact on the GDP growth rate and indirectly have negative impact
by changes in inflation rate, exchange rate and Embi+.
[Figure 5]
Furthermore, a shock on GDP growth rate provokes an increase on interest rate, mixed
effects on inflation, appreciation of currency, decreases Embi+ and increases primary
surplus. The effect of the last three will result in a further debt reduction. Results are
presented in Figure 6. Thus, the increase in the GDP growth rate may also indirectly
decrease the debt ratio by the effect of exchange rate, Embi+ and primary surplus.
[Figure 6]
The variance decomposition quantifies the contribution of innovations in one variable
to changes in another variable. Therefore, we aim to quantify the proportion of the
variation in GDP growth rate and debt ratio that is related to each other and to the other
endogenous variables in the VEC. Results are presented in Table IX and Table X, values
are presented as percentage.
[Table IX]
15
The FTPL posits that the increase in government debt increases demand and leads to price pressures.
18
Table IX provides information about the variance decomposition of GDP growth rate.
Most of the change is related to its past values, however one important part seems to be
related to exchange rate, followed by primary surplus and debt ratio. These results also
reinforces the conclusion of the Granger causality, since these three variables appeared
Granger causing GDP growth rate.
Table X provides information about the variance decomposition of debt ratio. GDP
growth rate, Embi + and inflation contributes the most to changes in debt ratio. That
validates results for Granger causality, since these variables appeared Granger causing
debt ratio.
[Table X]
4.4. Bivariate Causality
The ARDL model in a bivariate causality allows us to have an embracing analysis of
the relationship between both variables included. Since it does not demand the same
number of lags for both variables, we do not run the risk of omitting important lags.
However, in a bivariate causality we run the risk of omission of important variables.
Therefore, both methodologies, VEC and ARDL, are going to be used as complementary
to each other.
The first step in the analysis was to perform the Engle-Granger cointegration test, in
which we used the AIC and the SIC criteria for the lag selection. Results are presented in
Table XI. All the pairs presented cointegration for at least one side of the selection criteria
used, which means we may find long run equilibrium for these pairs of variables.
[Table XI]
Therefore, we performed the ARDL model for all the pair of variables. The model
was carried out using restricted constant in the trend specification, we also included the
same dummies used in the VEC model as fixed regressor. After the results, we tested if
the dummies and the constant were significant and excluded those that did not show to
be significant in at least 10% of significance level.
Hereafter, the Error Correction was included, when it presented to be statistically
significant. Thus, we estimated the long run model of the error correction, otherwise we
estimated the short run model, which is the ARDL with the differenced lagged variables
19
without the error correction term. Results are presented in Table XII. The causality test
was checked by the joint significance in the Wald test.
[Table XII]
Results show that in most of the cases, when GDP growth rate is the dependent
variable, variables exhibited long run relationship, meaning that in the long run there is a
univariate relationship from the variables selected to GDP growth rate, except for debt,
which exhibited only short run relation with GDP growth rate. On the other hand, GDP
growth rate also Granger causes the pattern of most of the variables, although in the short
run. The opposite relation occurred for the debt, which appeared to have a long run
relationship with most of the variables, only when it was the independent variable,
however, in the short run debt is Granger caused by the pattern of most of the variables.
Primary surplus is not Granger caused neither by GDP growth rate nor by debt. The
same was found in the VEC Granger causality.
4.5. Results
In the first exercise we estimated the static relationship between the group of
variables. In this part we did not allow for lagged variables impacting in the dependent
variable, since the primordial objective was to understand if the relation would change
after the Constitutional ceiling amendment and after changing in debt ratios. Results
showed the same signals and almost small changes in the coefficients. In all the models
employed we find debt impacting positively in GDP growth rate.
Hereafter, we studied the causality between the variables, using VEC in a multivariate
analysis, and ARDL the bivariate one. The bivariate analysis allowed the impact of lagged
variables and showed a similar result as the static model. In this methodology debt
Granger causes GDP growth rate in a positive way in the short run. Moreover, GDP
growth rate is Granger caused by the rest of the system of variables, but in a negative
way. On the other hand, the multivariate analysis presented a different result, where debt
also Granger causes GDP growth rate, but in a negative way and in the long run.
Furthermore, the rest of the result of the bivariate analysis confirmed the results of the
multivariate when debt or GDP growth rate are the dependent variable, except for the
impact of primary surplus on the GDP growth rate.
20
Table XIII presents a comparison of both methodologies for the cases that we find
Granger causality. In the VEC, the signal is a result of the cumulative values of the
impulse response function. In the ARDL are the values of the summation of the
coefficients of the lagged values of the dependent variables. Overwritten letters “S” and
“L” represent that we find Granger causality respectively in short and long run models.
[Table XIII]
This result brings us the question: Why could debt impact positively on the GDP
growth rate in the short run and negatively in the long run? The answer to this question
takes in consideration the difference between ARDL and VEC methodologies. Since
ARDL runs the risk of omission of important variables and VEC runs the risk of the
omission of important lags, both analyses should be used in a complementary way.
Results of the VEC consider the impact that debt may generate in other variables, that
will also impact on GDP growth rate, such as inflation rate, exchange rate and Embi+,
that are positively Granger caused by debt and negatively Granger causes GDP growth
rate. That is, when debt increases, inflation rate, exchange rate and Embi+ also increases,
however all of them will work to decrease growth. Moreover, the impulse response of the
VEC showed positive impacts of debt on growth during the third and fifth periods, which
is in accordance with ARDL results.
Therefore, it is possible to say that the short run causality from debt to growth is
positive, however this relationship changes in the long run, when the causality becomes
negative, and part of it is related to the impact of inflation rate, exchange rate and Embi+.
On the other hand, the causality from growth to debt is also negative, meaning that
increasing in GDP growth rate causes reduction in debt-to-GDP ratio. Moreover, part of
it is related to the impact of growth on Embi+, since growth negatively Granger causes
Embi+ in the long run, that in turns, positively Granger causes debt; that is, when the
GDP growth rate increases, it decreases Embi+ in the long run, therefore the following
reduction on debt is related to growth directly and indirectly.
Primary surplus showed to be completely exogenous in the VEC, in the sense that it
was not Granger caused by none of the variables. In ARDL it appeared to be statistically
significant when it was dependent only by its lagged value. This may be explained by the
findings of Gadelha (2011) who concluded by a synchronization between government
21
revenues and expenditures, that makes primary surplus much more dependent on both
variables than in those used in this study. When primary surplus is the independent
variable, it decreases debt in the short run; however, it presents opposite results for its
relation with the GDP growth rate, which does not allow us to make a reliable statement
about this relationship.
Interest rate presented negative long run Granger causality with GDP growth rate
only in the ARDL and positive long run Granger causality with debt only in the VEC, the
last proposition is in accordance with the findings of Gadelha & Divino (2008). When
interest rate is the dependent variable, it showed to be positively Granger caused by GDP
growth rate both in the short and long run. However, it is not possible to make any
statement about its dependence of debt, since it has presented opposite signals in the VEC
and in the ARDL.
Another approach that one could takes to explain the difference in the relationship
from debt to growth in short and in long run is that fiscal multipliers are not long lasting,
therefore they are more likely to prevail in short run than in long run, while in long run
crowding-out effects are more likely to prevail. Results of Matheson & Pereira (2016)
shows that fiscal multipliers in Brazil are short lived. Moreover, they came to the same
conclusion of Gadelha (2011) about the fiscal synchronization, explaining that a
surprising increases in government spending in a given quarterly is likely to generate a
consolidation in the later on. Therefore, in long run, crowding-out effects are more
expected than Keynesian multipliers.
5. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The objective of this paper was to understand the relationship between public debt
and economic growth in Brazil. Moreover, we aimed to understand the interaction
between debt and growth with other variables such as: interest rate, inflation rate,
exchange rate and Embi+. To achieve that objective we have estimated growth equations,
and performed multivariate and bivariate Granger causality tests, by applying VEC and
ARDL methodologies.
We concluded that government debt and growth have a bi-directional relationship,
meaning that one variable causes and is caused by each other. Although the presence of
causality in both directions, the behaviour is not the same in the short and in the long run.
22
Debt may improve growth in the short run, however, it can be harmful to growth in the
long run, not only by its direct relation to the GDP growth rate, but by its indirect impact
over inflation rate, exchange rate and Embi+. On the other hand, economic growth
reduces debt, both in the short and long run, and there is also an indirect impact of growth
in debt by the reduction that growth causes in Embi+.
The important policy implication of this result is that if we can better understand the
relation between debt and inflation rate, exchange rate and Embi+, we may also be able
to soften the negative impact of debt on growth, by the use of other policies that can
impact on this variable.
Another issue that came up is why studies applied to other countries could find a
positive long run relationship between debt and growth, as the findings of Gómez-Puig
& Sosvilla-Rivero (2015). What is the difference between Brazil and other countries that
found this positive relation? Maybe the answer is related to what this debt is used for, or
else, the negative impact of other variables such as Embi+ is not that strong as it is in
Brazil. These questions can be evaluated more deeply by other studies and should be
taken into consideration by the policy makers.
In addition, the fact that debt may improve growth in the short run and harm it in the
long run also emphasizes the trade-off faced by governments to correctly evaluate if it is
time to promote aggregate demand or to implement austerity measures. The actual
situation of high debts and economic recession also made the decision harder, since some
austerity measures can deteriorate growth in the short run. Therefore, evaluating the
quality of public expenditures, namely its efficiency and effectiveness could be the better
way to help the decision about in what policy or program to adopt austerity or
expansionary measures.
Further, bills such as the PEC 187/2019 that propose the use of resources of public
funds to pay down debts seems to be a more efficient way to use this feature, since part
of it has not been used and at the same time government pays interest on its debt.
Similarly, the use of part of Dollar reserves of the Central Bank to pay down public debt
may be a good solution, since the current exchange rate depreciation increased a lot the
Central Bank´s profit on its reserves for much more than what is necessary to face possible
future losses. Furthermore, measures such as the use of part of the amount saved by
23
austerity measures in infrastructure projects, presented in the PEC 188/2019 may also be
growth inducing and reduce public debt.
Finally, we have not included external public debt in our analysis because since
October 2006 the Brazilian net external public debt is negative. This occurs because of
the effort made by the government to increase dollars reserves, which decreases the
vulnerability related to exchange rate depreciations. However, we think that further work
could evaluate the interaction between external debt, dollar reserves, exchange rate and
Embi+. Moreover, we think that the impact from Embi+ in external debt may be much
stronger than in total debt.
REFERENCES
Afonso, A. (2008). “Ricardian Fiscal Regimes in the European Union”, Empirica, 35 (3),
313–334.
Afonso, A., & Alves, J. (2015). The role of government debt in economic growth.
Hacienda Publica Espanola / Review of Public Economics, 215 (4), 9–26.
Afonso, A., & Alves, J. (2016). Reconsidering Wagner’s Law: Evidence from the
Functions of the Government. Applied Economics Letters, 24 (5), 346–350.
Afonso, A., & Jalles, J. T. (2013). Growth and Productivity: The Role of Government
Debt. International Review of Economics and Finance, 25, 384–407.
Afonso, A., & Jalles, J. T. (2014). Causality for the Government Budget and Economic
Growth. Applied Economics Letters, 21 (17), 1198-1201.
Afonso, António, & Martins, L. (2016). Monetary Developments and Expansionary
Fiscal Consolidations: Evidence from the EMU. International Journal of Finance
and Economics, 21 (3), 247-265.
Butts, H. C. (2009). Short term external debt and economic growth - Granger causality:
Evidence from Latin America and the Caribbean. Review of Black Political
Economy, 36 (2), 93–111.
Cherif, R., & Hasanov, F. (2018). Public debt dynamics: the effects of austerity, inflation,
and growth shocks. Empirical Economics, 54 (3), 1087–1105.
Égert, B. (2015). Public debt, economic growth and nonlinear effects: Myth or reality?
Journal of Macroeconomics, 43, 226–238.
24
Elliot, G., Rothenberg, T. J., & Stock, J. H. (1996). Efficient Tests for an Autoregressive
Unit Root. Econometrica, 64 (4), 813–836.
Engle, R. F., & Granger, C. W. J. (1987). Co-Integration and Error Correction :
Representation , Estimation , and Testing, 55 (2), 251-276.
Gadelha, S. R. de B. (2011). Causalidade Temporal entre Receita e Despesa
Governamentais. Análise Econômica, Porto Alegre, 26 (56), 109–130.
Gadelha, S. R. de B., & Divino, J. A. (2008). Dominância Fiscal Ou Dominância
Monetária No Brasil? Uma análise de causalidade. Economia Aplicada, São Paulo,
12 (4), 659–675.
Gadelha, S. R. de B., & Divino, J. A. (2013). Uma análise da ciclicidade da política fiscal
Brasileira. Estudos Economicos, 43 (4), 711–743.
Gómez-Puig, M., & Sosvilla-Rivero, S. (2015). The causal relationship between debt and
growth in EMU countries. Journal of Policy Modeling, 37 (6), 974–989.
Johansen, S. (2002). A small sample correction for the test of cointegrating rank in the
vector autoregressive model. Econometrica, 70 (5), 1929–1961.
Johansen, S., & Juselius, K. (1990). Maximum Likelihood Estimation and Inference on
Cointegration — With Applications To the Demand for Money. Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 52 (2), 169–210.
Johansen, S., Mosconi, R., & Nielsen, B. (2000). Cointegration analysis in the presence
of structural breaks in the deterministic trend. The Econometrics Journal, 3 (2), 216–
249.
Lai, S.-L., Trang, L.-H., & Kuo, K.-C. (2015). Causal Relationship among Debt, GDP
and Inflation in France. International Journal of Intelligent Technologies and
Applied Statistics, 8 (3), 205–224.
Lanne, M., Lütkepohl, H., & Saikkonen, P. (2002). Comparison of unit root tests for time
series with level shifts. Journal of Time Series Analysis, 23 (6), 667–685.
Maddala, G. S., & Kim, I. (2004). Unit Roots, Cointegration, and Structural Change.
Cambridge University Press.
Matheson, T., & Pereira, J. (2016). Fiscal Multipliers for Brazil. IMF Working Papers
16/79.
Ng, S., & Perron, P. (2001). Lag length selection and the construction of unit root tests
with good size and power. Econometrica, 69 (6), 1519–1554.
25
Pastore, A. C., Bacha, E., Issler, J. V., Chauvet, M., Bonomo, M., Picchetti, P., Ardeo, V.
(2020). Economic Cycle Dating Committee - June 2020.
Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2010). Growth in a time of Debt. American Economic
Review, 100 (2), 573-578
Rodrigues, R. V., & Teixeira, E. C. (2013). Gastos Públicos e Crescimento Econômico
no Brasil da segunda metade do século XX: uma abordagem do Teste de Causalidade
de Granger. Revista Políticas Públicas, São Luís, 17 (1), 115–125.
Saikkonen, P., & Lütkepohl, H. (2002). Testing for a Unit Root in a Time Series With a
Level Shift at unknown time. Econometric Theory, 18 (2), 313–348.
Vogelsang, T., & Perron, P. (1998). Additional Tests for a Unit Root Allowing for a Break
in the Trend Function at an Unknown Time. International Economic Review, 39 (4),
1073–1100.
26
GDP Growth Rate (% change)
Debt (GDP ratio - %)
1.2
90
0.8
80
Primary Surplus (GDP ratio - %)
4
2
70
0.4
60
0.0
-2
-0.4
-0.8
0
50
40
98
00
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
16
18
30
98
00
02
04
Inflation Rate (%)
06
08
10
12
14
16
18
-4
98
00
02
04
06
Interest Rate (%)
4
10
12
14
16
18
12
14
16
18
Embi+
3.5
2,500
3.0
3
08
2,000
2.5
2
2.0
1,500
1
1.5
1,000
1.0
0
-1
500
0.5
98
00
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
16
18
16
18
0.0
98
00
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
16
18
0
98
00
Exchange Rate (R$/US$)
5
4
3
2
1
98
00
02
04
06
08
10
12
14
FIGURE 1 – Treated Series.
FIGURE 2 – ROOTS OF CHARACTERISTIC POLYNOMIAL.
27
02
04
06
08
10
Response to Generalized One S.D. Innovations
Response of GDP growth rate to debt ratio
Response of GDP growth rate to interest rate
.02
.02
.00
.00
-.02
-.02
-.04
-.04
-.06
-.06
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2
Response of GDP growth rate to inflation rate
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Response of GDP growth rate to exchange rate
.02
.02
.00
.00
-.02
-.02
-.04
-.04
-.06
-.06
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2
Response of GDP growth rate to Embi+
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Response of GDP growth rate to primary surplus
.02
.02
.00
.00
-.02
-.02
-.04
-.04
-.06
-.06
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
FIGURE 3 – Response of GDP growth rate to innovations on debt ratio, interest rate,
exchange rate, Embi+ and primary surplus.
28
Response to Generalized One S.D. Innovations
Response of debt ratio to GDP growth rate
Response of debt ratio to interest rate
.4
.4
.2
.2
.0
.0
-.2
-.2
-.4
-.4
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
2
18
4
Response of debt ratio to inflation rate
.4
.2
.2
.0
.0
-.2
-.2
-.4
-.4
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
2
18
Response of debt ratio to Embi+
.4
.2
.2
.0
.0
-.2
-.2
-.4
-.4
4
6
8
10
12
14
10
12
14
16
18
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Response of debt ratio to primary surplus
.4
2
8
Response of debt ratio to exchange rate
.4
2
6
16
18
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
FIGURE 4 – Response of debt ratio to innovations on GDP growth rate, interest rate,
inflation rate, exchange rate, Embi+ and primary surplus.
29
18
Response to Generalized One S.D. Innovations
Response of interest rate to debt ratio
Response of inflation rate to debt ratio
.020
.03
.016
.02
.012
.01
.008
.00
.004
-.01
.000
-.02
-.004
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
2
18
Response of exchange rate to debt ratio
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
16
18
Response of embi+ to debt ratio
.050
25
.045
20
.040
15
.035
10
.030
5
.025
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
Response of primary surplus to debt ratio
.00
-.01
-.02
-.03
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
FIGURE 5 – Response of interest rate, inflation rate, exchange rate, Embi+ and primary
surplus to innovations on Debt.
30
Response to Generalized One S.D. Innovations
Response of interest rate to GDP growth rate
Response of inflation rate to GDP growth rate
.025
.02
.020
.00
.015
.010
-.02
.005
-.04
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
2
18
Response of exchange rate to GDP growth rate
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
Response of embi+ to GDP growth rate
10
-.01
-.02
0
-.03
-.04
-10
-.05
-20
-.06
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
Response of primary surplus to GDP growth rate
.10
.08
.06
.04
.02
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
FIGURE 6 – Response of interest rate, inflation rate, exchange rate, Embi+ and primary
surplus to innovations on GDP growth rate.
31
18
TABLE I
UNIT ROOT TESTS WITHOUT STRUCTURAL BREAK
Variable
Test Equation
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
GDP growth rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Debt
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Primary Surplus
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Exchange Rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Interest Rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Embi+
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Inflation rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
ADF GLS
Lags
MZ αGLS
Lags
-1.290721
-1.753942
-0.801839
-2.115286
1.328672
-0.952966
-3.598385***
-3.593600***
-0.746254
-0.779822
-3.265969***
-3.501313***
0.267376
-1.475775
-6.005510***
-5.987699***
0.786271
-1.185095
-0.329988
-1.688773
-1.766380*
-2.393650*
-2.698043***
-4.847106***
-3.256705***
-4.319382***
-0.811405
-2.126006
12
12
11
11
2
2
12
9
12
12
10
10
3
2
4
4
12
12
11
11
7
7
11
11
8
8
11
12
-1.34344
-1.85005
-0.11943
-0.84698
1.37089
-0.96881
-1.70343*
-2.32025
-0.78408
-0.84424
-2.18834**
-2.42425
0.23421
-1.50945
-6.16886***
-6.11966***
0.87691
-1.16717
0.07366
-0.23832
-1.65462*
-2.33533
-1.36413
-3.01152**
-2.68997***
-3.89828***
0.53147
-0.60669
12
12
11
11
2
2
12
9
12
12
10
10
3
2
4
4
12
12
11
11
7
7
11
11
8
8
11
12
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *, ** and *** denotes significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels; D() denotes tests in first difference.
32
TABLE II
UNIT ROOT TESTS WITH STRUCTURAL BREAK
Variable
Test Equation
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
GDP growth rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Debt
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Primary Surplus
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Exchange Rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Interest Rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Embi+
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
Intercept
Trend and Intercept
Inflation rate
D(Intercept)
D(Trend and Intercept)
SL - Rational Shift
Date
2001 M6
2001 M6
2001 M6
2001 M6
1999 M1
1999 M1
1999 M1
1999 M1
2015 M12
2015 M12
2015 M12
2015 M12
2002 M10
2002 M10
2002 M10
2002 M10
1998 M9
1998 M9
1998 M9
1998 M9
2002 M11
2002 M11
2002 M11
2002 M11
2002 M11
2002 M11
2002 M11
2002 M11
t- statistic
-3.0334**
-2.4919
-6.0331***
-4.7778***
-0.6209
-0.9221
-7.3233***
-4.2197***
-0.6352
-1.3882
-8.4324***
-9.0591***
-0.8667
-1.1440
-3.5849***
-4.8238***
-3.1055**
-0.8898**
-10.1937***
-5.1881***
-3.0340**
-2.2273
-3.8811***
-4.8686***
-4.2899***
-4.7562***
-4.9046***
-5.4818***
Lags
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
VP- Innovational Outilier
Date
1998 M10
1999 M01
1999 M03
1998 M06
2015 M06
2012 M07
1999 M01
1999 M01
2014 M04
2015 M10
1998 M 06
1998 M08
2005 M03
2008 M12
2002 M10
2003 M04
1999 M03
1999 M03
1999 M03
1998 M11
2002 M10
2002 M10
1998 M09
1998 M09
1998 M11
1998 M11
1998 M08
1999 M04
t- statistic
-5.672562***
-5.715973***
-21.14956***
-21.55431***
-4.317432
-4.445778
-19.23603***
-19.51033***
-4.450804
-3.372438
-15.33422***
-15.30660***
-3.381711
-3.554331
-13.11930***
-12.38337***
-7.773424***
-8.281520***
-23.45007***
-23.66599***
-6.100274***
-6.285755***
-11.87812***
-12.23370***
-8.149452***
-8.074853***
-18.22486***
-18.34451***
lags
0
0
0
0
5
4
0
0
12
12
0
0
1
4
0
0
0
0
0
0
3
3
0
0
0
0
0
0
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *, ** and *** denotes significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels; D() denotes tests in first difference.
33
TABLE III
GROWTH EQUATIONS
Dependent Variable:
Model 1
GDP growth rate
D
0.024870***
(0.002983)
I
-0.132585**
(0.0277)
R
0.042858
(0.047159)
E
-0.361561***
(0.046593)
Embi+
-0.000225***
(8.17E-05)
S
0.094739***
(0.017846)
2
D
dconsolidation
Model 2
Model 3#
Model 4#
Model 5
0.024935***
(0.003012)
-0.133311**
(0.060150)
0.041920
(0.047558)
-0.359584***
(0.048054)
-0.000226***
(8.23E-05)
0.091282***
(0.026777)
0.015705***
(0.005455)
-0.186561***
(0.065033)
0.044768
(0.047371)
-0.330204***
(0.056359)
-0.000196**
(8.14E-05)
0.083513***
(0.018371)
0.015705***
(0.005455)
-0.186561***
(0.065033)
0.044768
(0.047371)
-0.330204***
(0.056359)
-0.000196**
(8.14E-05)
0.083513***
(0.018371)
0.026825***
(0.004447)
-0.147985**
(0.065337)
0.036706
(0.048343)
-0.340081***
(0.059040)
-0.000223***
(8.19E-05)
0.091210***
(0.018832)
-3.30E-05
(5.56E-05)
-0.019213
(0.110776)
-0.132068***
(0.045517)
d3060
d6090
dexchangerate
dlula
dcrisis
R-squared
0.132068***
(0.045517)
-0.318553** -0.317802** -0.310161** -0.310161**
(0.126371)
(0.126687)
(0.124783)
(0.124783)
0.349224*** 0.348969*** 0.341118*** 0.341118***
(0.111081)
(0.111303)
(0.110715)
(0.110715)
-0.124405* -0.129998* -0.183423** -0.183423**
(0.069517)
(0.076753)
(0.078511)
(0.078511)
0.559782
0.559834
0.574379
0.574379
-0.331970**
(0.128535)
0.359455***
(0.112550)
-0.150904*
(0.082689)
0.560394
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: Models are estimated by OLS*, ** and *** denotes significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels; std.
error in between (), # represents models estimated with constant.
34
TABLE IV
JOHANSEN COINTEGRATION TESTE WITHOUT STRUCTURAL BREAK
Rank
r=0
r≤1
r≤2
r≤3
r≤4
r≤5
r≤6
250.11***
169.29***
112.58***
61.316***
24.62
10.24
0.05
P-value
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.18
0.26
0.82
P-value
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.00
0.33
0.20
0.82
80.82***
56.71***
51.26***
36.69***
14.38
10.18
0.05
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *** denotes the rejection of the null hypo paper at 1% level of significance.
TABLE V
JOHANSEN COINTEGRATION TESTE WITH STRUCTURAL BREAK
Rank LR
P-Value
r = 0 325.12*** 0.0000
r ≤ 1 218.79*** 0.0000
r ≤ 2 135.43*** 0.0000
r≤3
86.33*** 0.0009
r≤4
55.08*** 0.0064
r≤5
24.68
0.1426
r≤6
6.35
0.5306
90%
155.31
121.52
91.65
65.79
43.98
26.11
12.24
95%
160.86
126.47
96.00
69.55
47.15
28.68
14.25
99%
171.61
136.11
104.53
76.97
53.48
33.93
18.57
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *** denotes the rejection of the null hypo paper at 1% level of significance.
Breaks date used: January 1999 and December 2002.
TABLE VI
SIGNIFICANCE OF COINTEGRATION EQUATION
Dependent Varialbe
GDP growth rate
Debt ratio
Interest Rate
Inflation Rate
Exchange Rate
Embi+
Primary Surplus
Chi-Square
23.14593***
56.99717***
69.72704***
55.38739***
16.03341***
23.499***
26.70278***
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *** denotes significance at 1% level
35
P-Value
0.000317
0
0
0
0.006749
0.000271
0.000065
TABLE VII
VEC RESIDUAL SERIAL CORRELATION LM TESTS
Lag
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
F-statistic
1.882022
2.000301
1.738961
1.377469
1.807478
1.813465
1.334598
1.245115
0.942524
0.636017
P-Value
0.0003
0.0001
0.0015
0.046
0.0007
0.0007
0.0646
0.1239
0.5873
0.9761
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: Null hypo paper : no serial correlation at lag h.
TABLE VIII
GRANGER CAUSALITY TEST
Independent
Variable
Y
D
I
R
E
Embi+
S
Dependent Variable
D
I
R
E
18.97380*** 14.53546** 10.96128*
9.820979
( 0.0042)
( 0.0242)
( 0.0896)
( 0.1324)
11.92609*
26.46606*** 21.87011*** 11.40607*
( 0.0636)
( 0.0002)
( 0.0013)
( 0.0766)
6.819487
27.62727*** 27.06110*** 8.311279
( 0.3379)
( 0.0001)
( 0.0001)
( 0.2162)
6.532053
30.84374*** 16.02811** 19.41075***
( 0.3663)
( 0.0000)
( 0.0136)
( 0.0035)
12.36035* 9.346753
33.94641*** 10.94679*
( 0.0544)
( 0.1550)
( 0.0000)
( 0.0900)
2.133336
41.60621*** 43.68729*** 25.21548*** 15.43095**
( 0.9070)
( 0.0000)
( 0.0000)
( 0.0003)
( 0.0172)
15.53278** 3.176217
6.516320
7.688136
2.334217
( 0.0165)
( 0.7864)
( 0.3679)
( 0.2619)
( 0.8865)
Y
Embi+
16.47853**
( 0.0114)
13.32261**
( 0.0382)
23.70176***
( 0.0006)
14.47299**
( 0.0248)
12.50652*
( 0.0516)
4.296242
( 0.6367)
S
3.821981
( 0.7008)
5.725819
( 0.4546)
6.525338
( 0.3670)
6.533845
( 0.3661)
8.922092
( 0.1780)
3.891478
0.6914
-
Direction of causality
Y ⟶ D; Y ⟶ I;
Y ⟶ R; Y ⟶ Embi+
D ⟶ Y; D ⟶ I; D ⟶ R
D ⟶ E; D ⟶ Embi+
I ⟶ D; I ⟶ R;
I ⟶ Embi+
R ⟶ D; R ⟶ I;
R ⟶ E; R ⟶ Embi+
E ⟶ Y; E ⟶ I;
E ⟶ R; E ⟶ Embi+
Embi+ ⟶ D; Embi+ ⟶ I;
Embi+ ⟶ R; Embi+ ⟶ E
S⟶Y
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *, ** and *** denotes significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels; variables between () are the p-values;
all the other values are the Chi-square of the Granger Causality.
36
TABLE IX
VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF GDP GROWTH RATE
Period
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
S.E.
0.183151
0.209598
0.222245
0.239047
0.247459
0.253935
0.269995
0.279718
0.286298
0.292677
Variance Decomposition of GDP growth rate:
GDP
Debt
Interest Inflation Exchange
growth
ratio
Rate
Rate
Rate
rate
100
0
0
0
0
96.00433 0.023999 1.064935 0.098707 0.01221
94.32781 0.111989 1.051877 0.202231 0.63681
87.45872 0.426099 0.92354 0.188218 6.492936
82.31036 0.410572 1.093467 0.17614 11.71551
79.74094 0.591579 1.328337 0.480751 13.35328
72.74237 2.157544 1.175015 2.05934 16.42001
67.90714 3.08716 1.158759 2.448218 19.97127
65.10216 3.333176 1.227076 2.368261 22.62983
62.43653 3.376321 1.206154 2.295998 25.04519
Embi+
Primary
Surplus
0
0.001204
0.272632
0.317128
0.29907
0.530367
0.78228
0.826217
0.802372
0.77863
0
2.794612
3.39665
4.193356
3.994875
3.974745
4.663444
4.60124
4.537124
4.861186
Embi+
Primary
Surplus
0
7.448036
8.258937
12.06869
14.23904
17.41046
16.73237
15.47039
13.99266
12.87357
0
0.615844
1.576718
1.991818
2.172995
2.858131
3.498234
4.531138
5.221348
5.931436
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: Factorization by Cholesky Decomposition.
TABLE X
VARIANCE DECOMPOSITION OF DEBT RATIO
Variance Decomposition of debt ratio:
Period
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
S.E.
0.89585
1.153488
1.395012
1.602214
1.771675
1.975189
2.103162
2.248552
2.401642
2.550495
GDP
growth
rate
0.767807
0.696747
3.187934
3.736209
4.983667
4.916541
6.123217
7.974579
9.818936
11.17809
Debt
ratio
99.23219
88.87458
83.56808
76.55858
67.26677
58.76718
55.67954
53.11785
52.86607
52.80089
Interest Inflation Exchange
Rate
Rate
Rate
0
0.399082
0.622883
1.738067
2.751705
2.786985
3.101031
2.953769
2.695913
2.419296
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: Factorization by Cholesky Decomposition.
37
0
1.941236
2.398688
3.248148
7.880829
12.69285
14.20159
14.97471
14.03063
12.97311
0
0.024476
0.38676
0.658492
0.704996
0.567856
0.664024
0.977567
1.374447
1.823604
TABLE XI
ENGLE-GRANGER COINTEGRATION TEST
Dependent
Variable
Independent
Variable
y
d
y
i
y
r
y
e
y
Embi+
y
s
d
i
d
r
d
e
d
Embi+
d
s
d
y
i
y
r
y
e
y
Embi+
y
s
y
i
d
r
d
e
d
Embi+
d
s
d
AIC
Lags
-2.236107
-1.562334
-2.101870
-2.796474
-2.099894
-4.007762***
-2.350242
-0.637093
-2.046844
-1.947773
-3.158550*
-1.466781
-0.307425
-3.498478**
-0.122924***
-4.017607
-2.924036
-3.256299*
-2.924036
-3.256299*
-1.369190
-2.070137
15
4
15
15
15
8
15
15
15
7
15
15
14
14
14
8
2
4
2
4
14
13
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: *, ** and *** denotes significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels.
38
SIC
-4.322247***
-2.010215
-4.096740***
-2.194599
-4.143831***
-7.566273***
-5.110468***
-3.402884*
-4.146842***
-2.695038
-4.938623***
-1.466781
-1.290000
-2.235684
-1.270687
-7.621434***
-4.500774***
-4.535044***
-2.946314
-2.472982
-3.487583
-3.032596**
Lags
1
0
1
12
1
0
1
0
1
1
1
15
1
12
2
0
2
2
2
0
0
0
TABLE XII
ENGLE-GRANGER CAUSALITY TEST
Null Hypotesis
Model
OBS
F-statistic
P-value
Causality
ADL
ΔD does not Granger causes ΔY
ΔY does not Granger causes ΔD
ΔI does not Granger causes ΔY
ΔY does not Granger causes ΔI
ΔR does not Granger causes ΔY
ΔY does not Granger causes ΔR
ΔE does not Granger causes ΔY
ΔY does not Granger causes ΔE
ΔEmbi+ does not Granger causes ΔY
ΔY does not Granger causes ΔEmbi+
ΔS does not Granger causes ΔY
ΔY does not Granger causes ΔS
ΔI does not Granger causes ΔD
ΔD does not Granger causes ΔI
ΔR does not Granger causes ΔD
ΔD does not Granger causes ΔR
ΔE does not Granger causes ΔD
ΔD does not Granger causes ΔE
ΔEmbi+ does not Granger causes ΔD
ΔD does not Granger causes ΔEmbi+
ΔS does not Granger causes ΔD
ΔD does not Granger causes ΔS
Short run
Short run
Long run
Short run
Long run
Long run
Long run
No relationship
Long run
Short run
Long run
No relationship
No relationship
Long run
Short run
Long run
Short run
Long run
Short run
Long run
Short run
No relationship
258
260
250
250
250
254
250
250
256
250
250
254
254
260
261
253
254
261
-
3.780155
6.927241
15.86195
12.58429
5.883427
14.71783
15.90652
5.195388
2.857744
17.01869
7.955811
4.443769
22.15795
12.82875
15.00638
12.14643
3.863187
3.441240
-
0.0241
0.009
0.0000
0
0.0032
0
0.0000
0.0005
0.0593
0.0000
0
0.0000
0
0.0004
0
0.0000
0.0022
0.0647
-
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
No
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
No
(4,2)
(2,2)
(12,12)
(12,12)
(12,6)
(4,2)
(12,7)
(12,11)
(6,6)
(12,6)
(12,10)
(12,7)
(8,7)
(2,0)
(1,1)
(9,6)
(1,8)
(0,1)
-
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: F-statistic is the result of the application of the Wald test for the joint coefficients of the dependent
variable.
TABLE XIII
COMPARISON OF RESULTS OF GRANGER CAUSALITY: VEC AND ARDL
Causality
VEC
ARDL
L
s
D⟶Y
Negative Positive
E⟶Y
NegativeL NegativeL
I⟶Y
R⟶Y
Embi+ ⟶ Y
S⟶Y
I⟶D
L
Negative
NegativeL
L
Positive
PositiveL
Negative
L
Negative
L
L
R⟶D
Negative Negative
S⟶D
Negative
E⟶D
Embi+ ⟶ D PositiveL
s
s
Positive
Positives
s
Causality
Y⟶D
Y⟶I
Y⟶R
VEC
ARDL
Negative
L
Y ⟶ Embi+ Negative
D⟶R
PositiveL
Positive
L
Positive
s
NegativeL
Positive
L
Positive
PositiveL
Source: Authors Elaboration.
Note: S represents Granger causality only in the short run and L in the long run.
39
s
s
L
D⟶E
Positive
D ⟶ Embi+ PositiveL
D⟶S
Negative
Positive
Positive
L
Negative PositiveL
Y⟶E
Y⟶S
D⟶I
L
L
L