Public Disclosure Authorized
WPS4081
Utilities reforms and corruption
in developing countries1
Public Disclosure Authorized
Public Disclosure Authorized
Antonio Estache
The World Bank and
ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles
Ana Goicoechea
The World Bank
Lourdes Trujillo
Universidad de Las Palmas de Gran Canaria and
Center for Regulation and Competition Policy, City University London
Abstract
This paper shows empirically that “privatization” in the energy, telecommunications, and water sectors, and
the introduction of independent regulators in those sectors, have not always had the expected effects on
access, affordability, or quality of services. It also shows that corruption leads to adjustments in the
quantity, quality, and price of services consistent with the profit-maximizing behavior that one would
expect from monopolies in the sector. Finally, our results suggest that privatization and the introduction of
independent regulators have, at best, only partial effects on the consequences of corruption for access,
affordability, and quality of utilities services.
Public Disclosure Authorized
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4081, December 2006
The Policy Research Working Paper Series disseminates the findings of work in progress to encourage the
exchange of ideas about development issues. An objective of the series is to get the findings out quickly,
even if the presentations are less than fully polished. The papers carry the names of the authors and should
be cited accordingly. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely
those of the authors. They do not necessarily represent the view of the World Bank, its Executive Directors,
or the countries they represent. Policy Research Working Papers are available online at
http://econ.worldbank.org.
1
The authors are grateful for the insights and suggestions of Daniel Benitez, Cecilia Briceno, Claude
Crampes, Mathias Dewatripont, Katharina Gassner, Jose-Luis Guasch, Paul Grout, Charles Kenny, Lazlo
Lovei, Marco Manacorda, Martin Rodriguez-Pardina, Stephane Saussier, and Stephane Straub, and of
participants in seminars at the University of Bristol, the Université Libre de Bruxelles, the Université des
Sciences Sociales de Toulouse, the French State Council, and the U.K. Department for International
Development.
2
1. Introduction
Utility reform has been a common feature of developing countries’ economic
adjustment programs since the early 1990s. While the reforms have covered a wide range
of policy areas, their most visible dimensions, and certainly the most debated, have been:
(i) the increased autonomy of regulators of the sector, (ii) an increased role for the private
sector in the delivery of infrastructure services, and (iii) the opening of infrastructure
markets to competition. The main motivation for reform was often the need to cut fiscal
deficits rather than a concern for performance. However, reformers also promised
improved efficiency and social benefits, such as wider access, more affordable services,
and better service quality.
A lower level of corruption in the sector was another expected benefit. That
expectation was supported by the theoretical modeling of corruption as the
“nonbenevolence of government” by authors such as Shapiro and Willig (1990), Shleifer
and Vishny (1993), and Boycko, Shleifer, and Vishny (1996). Their intuition was that
privatization could reduce the control of government over the rents offered by the direct
operation of public services.2 For utilities, the message from this research was simple.
Privatize as soon as possible and increase the independence of regulation of public and
private monopolistic operators to increase their transparency. Doing so would increase
the political accountability of the regulatory role and thereby reduce corruption.
Now, 15 years after the first large-scale utilities reforms were launched, the
pendulum is swinging back. The value of private sector participation and of regulation at
arms length no longer appears to be favored by newly elected governments, often with
the support of their electorate, in developing countries. Critics of the 1990s reforms
currently dominate the media with a plethora of anecdotes pointing to reform failures,
including a large number that suggest that corruption remains a problem in the sector.
At this turning point in political support for past reforms, it seems useful to try to
get a quantitative sense of what the reforms actually achieved in developing countries.
There is little quantitative, cross-country evidence in the literature. Most cross-country
studies deal with specific aspects of reform; studies that consider all dimensions of
reforms jointly, on the other hand, tend to focus on specific countries. A few crosscountry studies have focused on a single sector—generally telecommunications but
occasionally electricity or water.3 There is also a large literature on the effects of
privatization in general, but most studies do not distinguish between regulated and
unregulated industries and hence are of little relevance here.4 Moreover, assessments to
date generally have failed to systematically address the relevance of the many dimensions
2
These models imply two major assumptions. First, they assume that it is easier for corrupt politicians to
control public firms than private firms. Second, they assume that reforms make political interference
costlier or at least more visible.
3
For a recent review of the impact of reforms, see Kessides (2004).
4
See Chong and Lopez-de-Silanes (2004) or Bortolotti and Siniscalco (2004), for instance.
2
of performance.5 Finally, with a few exceptions discussed later, the literature has not
accounted for the relevance of corruption as a driver of success of reform.
This paper addresses some of the main gaps in the current literature and makes
four main contributions. First, we compare the impact of reforms across sectors, because
there is no reason to expect that all sectors should adjust in the same way to reforms. The
sectors we treat are electricity, fixed telecommunications, and water services delivery.
While our data do not reflect all forms of supply relevant to each sector, they cover a
representative share of the total population of the developing world and of the services
used.6
Second, we take into account the various dimensions of performance.7 Within
each sector, we examine the impact of reforms on access, affordability, and quality of
services. These dimensions correspond to the common trilogy found in textbook
discussions of the regulation of monopolies—quantity, price, and quality together
determine monopolistic profits and hence rents. Using all three dimensions allows us to
check whether reforms in electricity and telecommunications revealed trade-offs or winwin situations across performance dimensions. We were not able to do this for water
because we could not find good data on prices and quality in the water sector. Our crosssectoral, cross-dimensional assessment using a similar approach for each sector makes
possible a comparative assessment of operators’ preferences as revealed by the trade-offs
they make among quantity, quality, and prices across sectors. Again, this contribution is
limited to telecoms and electricity because of data gaps in the water sector.
Third, the largest dataset used for our analysis has the widest country coverage for
the three sectors and one of the longest time spans since reforms began to be
implemented (five years on average). We widened coverage on the policy side by
simplifying the modeling of the reforms. Basically the extent of reforms is modeled as a
binary variable: (i) either countries have managed to attract large-scale private providers
or they have not; (ii) either countries have created a separate regulatory agency to
supervise the sector or they have not. This simplicity has its drawbacks, as discussed
later. But the benefit of being able to cover 153 developing countries for the period 1990–
2002 should not be underestimated, even if the resulting data panels are unbalanced.
Last, but certainly not least, we provide a systematic assessment of the
interactions between reform and corruption in terms of the three dimensions of
performance (access, quality, and price). This may be one of the most interesting
contributions to the assessment of the impact of reform. Privatization and greater
autonomy of regulation are standard recommendations for fighting corruption in the
theoretical literature, but most of the empirical evidence behind those recommendations
is derived from the telecommunications sector and focuses on access.
5
Notable exceptions focusing on utilities include Andres, Foster, and Guasch (2006), Kirkpatrick et al.
(2006), Estache and Rossi (2005), Ros (1999) and Wallsten (2001, 2003), but these papers all focus either
on a specific sector, a specific region, or the interaction between competition and privatization.
6
In developing countries, there are alternatives to electricity as a source of energy, and mobile phones are a
very good substitute for fixed lines for a very large share of the population.
7
The forthcoming book by Andres, Foster, and Guasch (2006) works with eight performance criteria across
utilities. Their work is at the firm level, however, and focuses on Latin America exclusively.
3
Our analytical approach may be summarized as follows. We first analyze what the
basic data reveal. We do so to expose the shortcomings of the basic data analysis often
reported in popular publications in articles on performance changes associated with
changes in ownership, market structure, and regulation. Our basic correlation analysis
suggests that reform policies have improved infrastructure performance in terms of
access, affordability, and quality. We then test the robustness of these conclusions
econometrically, revealing several forms of misinformation to which the basic data
analysis can lead. For each output, we conduct generalized least squares estimations with
country fixed effects.
The paper is organized as follows: section 2 provides a brief overview of the
spread of reforms across sectors in the developing world. Section 3 explains the
analytical approach adopted to analyze the impact of those reforms. Sections 4 through 6
analyze the impact of reforms on access rates, affordability, and quality, respectively.
Section 7 discusses the consistency of the evidence across performance indicators for
each sector. Section 8 offers concluding comments based on a brief overview of the main
lessons offered by our cross-sectoral comparison.
2. Reforms in infrastructure utilities
For any reform, experts will argue that the devil is in the details. This is why,
ideally, we should have been able to report a detailed description of the reforms carried
out in each and what they were intended to achieve. Details are difficult to accommodate
in cross-country comparative studies, where some broader characterization is needed.
Over the last 15 years or so, the main experiments in utility reform have taken three
broad forms that together have brought major changes in the role of the public sector in
the delivery of infrastructure services around the world.
The first is the unbundling of the regulatory function. Institutionally, the reform
implies the establishment of “independent regulatory agencies” (IRAs).8 The major
outcome expected from this step is a switch from self-regulated or politically regulated
providers of services to providers, public or private, that are monitored and controlled by
agencies without interference from the elected government and without the conflicts of
interest that self-regulation implies.
The theory has been easier to spell out than the practice. Depending on the sector,
the country, and the institutional context, the degree of independence and the extent of
the responsibilities of IRAs vary significantly.9 This diversity is difficult to capture
properly. We lack data on the characteristics of regulatory agencies around the world. On
the other hand, it is possible to collect data on which countries have created IRAs, and
8
Throughout the data collection process we worked with the definition of independence given by the
International Telecommunications Union (ITU) for telecoms and tried to apply it across sectors. ITU
considers that an IRA is independent if it is separate from the ministry and from the incumbent operator in
terms of its financing, structure, and decision making.
9
As pointed out by Wallsten (2003), subjectivity affects the methods used to collect and report data.
Wallsten states that regulators may have incentives to report that they are independent even if they are not.
He also argues that no matter the definition of independence, regulatory agencies always will be to some
degree connected to the government. Brown and others (2006) offer a checklist of the relevant
characteristics of regulation at a very detailed level, as well as a useful survey of the literature on the topic.
4
when, to regulate which sectors, at least nominally, and to make cross-country
comparisons using those data. The establishment of an IRA is often taken as a strong
signal of the government’s commitment to end self-regulation and to replace political
considerations by economic concerns.10 It is rarely that simple, however, as we shall see.
The second and third most common infrastructure reforms of the last 15 years—a
wider role for the private sector and the opening of infrastructure markets to
competition—are highly correlated. Technological progress and better management
know-how made the introduction or increase of competition in a sector and the associated
opening to the private sector serious options in sectors that had been dominated by
national public monopolies. As a result, many reform programs separated state-owned
giants into several smaller companies. These were then sold, bid out as concessions, or
licensed to private operators, which were expected to compete with the incumbents and
other entrants.
Because there is no reliable measure of the degree of competition in a large
sample of countries over a long period of time, the existence of private participation may
well be the best proxy for the commitment of a government to increase competition in a
given sector. The proxy requires very little information and yet gives a reasonable sense
of a government’s willingness to open the economy. Moreover, it does so for the largest
possible sample of countries and in a way that is comparable across sectors. Clearly it is
not a perfect indicator.11 Opening to the private sector is necessary but not sufficient to
increase effective competition. But for countries for which more detailed information is
available for both variables, the correlation between private participation and the more
detailed information is extremely high. The main apparent exception is the water sector,
where the presence of the private sector is associated with ex-ante competition (that is,
competition for the market) and very little ex-post competition (competition in the market
among several providers).12
As in the case of independent regulation, the definition of private participation is a
challenge. There are indeed many possible definitions.13 The definition of private
participation in infrastructure (PPI) used here varies according to the sector to reflect
differences in technology and market structure across sectors. In electricity, we focus on
10
Initially, most monopolistic state-owned utilities were self-regulated or government regulated. Thus,
regulation was not service-oriented, but rather related to fiscal or employment concerns. Tariffs were
designed to generate fiscal revenues rather than to reflect costs and cross-subsidy schemes.
11
In telecoms, PPI in fixed lines probably gives a lower bound of the extent to which competition prevails.
Indeed, in Africa, for instance, even if about 50% of the fixed lines are still operated publicly, all providers,
including the public ones, are subject to competition from mobile providers. In energy and in water, in
many countries, the large scale private sector picked up by our PPI variables is also subject to competition
from local small and medium scale providers around the world as discussed in Kariuki and Schwartz
(2005).
12
The data on competition raise other issues. For example, international databases on the existence of
competition often refer to the “legal” status but not to the “de facto” situation.
13
Budds and McGranahan (2003) present a very useful classification of private participation in terms of
the responsibilities of the private parties, which helps to make the definition less arbitrary. They argue that
different degrees of private participation can be identified by assessing the involvement of private parties in
asset ownership, capital investment, commercial risk, and/or operations and maintenance. Today, there is
no database on the market that reports this kind of detail for any country, for any sector.
5
distribution, because, in most countries, that is generally where rents are either captured
by the operator or shared with users. More specifically, we measured PPI in the sector by
the year private parties started to participate in asset ownership, capital investment,
commercial risk, and/or operation and maintenance in electricity distribution.
For telecoms, we rely on the definition used by the International
Telecommunications Union (ITU). According to ITU, PPI refers to full or partial private
ownership of the assets of fixed-line telephone companies. We focus on fixed-line
telephony because in most countries the private sector is active in mobile telephony. This
is equivalent to having PPI in all countries, which would be much less interesting as an
econometric variable. The degree of PPI in fixed telephone companies is an indication of
the extent to which the public sector has been willing or able to rely on private financing
for the expansion of fixed-line services. In Africa, for instance, PPI is found in fixed
telephony in just 50 percent of countries. In water, PPI refers to asset ownership or
capital investment. It ignores management contracts, which involve private management
rather than capital.
With these definitions and issues in mind, we began to collect data from various
sources, relying on a Web search and commercial databases to get a first impression of
the situation. For telecoms, the information was relatively easy to collect, thanks to the
ITU database. For water and for electricity, however, the information was partial and
sometimes inconsistent across sources. We then prepared a questionnaire which we sent
to colleagues in international organizations directly involved in the reforms of these
sectors across the developing world. Their responses helped us to reduce the
inconsistencies. When necessary, we contacted the relevant country authorities to settle
uncertainties or disagreements across sources. The data samples vary across sectors
because, in spite of our consultations with the key actors, we were not able to obtain for
electricity and water the same coverage that ITU has managed to generate for telecoms.
Our country coverage ranges from 120 to 153, depending on the indicator and the sector.
This is still quite a significant advance over prior publications in electricity and water.14
The information we collected on the spread of IRAs and PPI between 1990 and
2004 is summarized in Table 1. The baseline (1990) reveals a distinct preference around
the world for self-regulated public provision. Since then, the share of countries with an
IRA and PPI has swelled in all sectors. But some sectors have seen their ownership and
institutional structure change much more than others.
Table 1 also reports the information we collected on the timing of the reforms in
the three sectors covered. On average the reforms began at roughly the same for the three
sectors. The average start was around 1998, with the water sector lagging by a year.
Contrary to what is viewed today as best practice, most countries established their IRA
shortly after opening their telecoms and water sectors to private participation. Our data
panel covers, on average, about five years of experience with reform. For some countries,
of course, the coverage is much longer. Argentina, for example, commenced reforms in
all three sectors between 1991 and 1993.
14
For more details about the data-gathering process see Estache and Goicoechea (2005).
6
Table 1
Worldwide spread of infrastructure reforms, 1990–2004
Countries with IRA in 1990
Countries with IRA in 2004
Average year of establishment of IRA*
Countries with PPI in 1990
Countries with PPI in 2004
Average year of privatization*
Percentage of sample
(number of countries covered by the sample)
Electricity
Telecoms
Water
4
5
1
(141)
(153)
(115)
54
67
23
(134)
(153)
(120)
1998
1998
1999
4
(135)
37
(136)
1998
9
(129)
60
(144)
1997
3
(125)
36
(125)
1998
Source: Authors’ calculations.
* Average among countries that reformed between 1991 and 2004.
IRA = independent regulatory authority; PPI = private participation in infrastructure.
Note: Private participation in electricity refers to private participation in distribution.
The most reformed sector is telecoms. By 2004, 60 percent of developing
countries had opened fixed telephony to the private sector. The regulatory change in the
sector is even larger. The number of countries with an IRA had reached 67 percent by
2004. For electricity distribution and water, the share of countries with private
participation is roughly one in three (one in two for electricity generation). There is,
however, a significant difference in terms of the commitment to institutional reforms.
According to Estache and Goicoechea (2004), only two-thirds of the countries that had
private sector participation in their water sector had adopted an independent regulator, so
that just 23 percent of countries had both. In electricity, the number of countries that had
an IRA was only slightly greater than the number of those that had opened to the private
sector, with the result that about 54 percent of the countries had both. This suggests that a
country need not establish an IRA to get the private sector to enter the sector if other
characteristics of the market are positive enough; and that establishing an IRA is not a
sufficient reform to attract PPI if the market is not attractive.
3. Methodology
The analysis of the impact of reforms on access, affordability, and quality (the
three dimensions of performance) relies on the econometric estimation of a simple model
for each sector. The approach is also designed to allow a formal test of the impact on
performance of the interactions between reforms and corruption. It is based on the idea
that performance depends on the policies that were implemented by a particular country,
its governance structure, income level, population size, technological progress, and the
interaction among some of these factors. Formally, the model can be expressed as:
(1) Yit=β0+POLit’β1 + β2CORRit + (POLit’* CORRit)β3 + Xit'β4 + d(t) + di + uit
7
where i indexes a country, and t time. Y is a performance output reflecting access,
affordability, or quality. POL is a vector of reform policies, CORR a measure of
corruption, and X a vector of additional regressors. The term d(t) represents a linear time
trend, which takes into account technological advances, and di represents country fixed
effects. For each performance output, we estimate the model with generalized least
squares (GLS), using the average population of the country as analytical weights. The
model is estimated for the 1990–2002 period.15 Equation (1) is run for each performance
indicator and each country.
For the reform policies vector, POL, we rely on the two reform variables
discussed earlier. The first, IRA, reflects whether country i at time t has established an
“independent” regulatory agency. The second, PRIV, reflects whether the country has
opened its doors to private participation. We also model the interactions between the two
variables: (POLit’= [IRAit PRIVit IRAit*PRIVit]).
Focusing on these two policies alone might lead one to ignore the fact that
reforms do not take place in a vacuum. That would be a mistake, because there are wide
differences in governance across countries that may influence the effects of reforms on
performance. Governance can be included in the analysis in several ways. For example,
in electricity, Zhang and others (2005) include an index of economic freedom as a
determinant of electricity performance; in telecoms, Wallsten (2001) includes
expropriation risk as a determinant of telecoms performance. Our sense is that among all
existent governance measures, corruption may be the most appropriate to relate to
infrastructure performance, even if it has been rarely used in empirical studies of sector
performance.16 In our context, the level of corruption may determine the scope of action
of an IRA. An IRA may perform certain functions in a highly corrupted country and very
different ones in a country with very little corruption. Similarly, the level of corruption
may determine the extent to which private participation is attracted to a country.
In the empirical academic literature, there are many studies about the effects of
corruption on economic growth17 and about the determinants of corruption.18 However,
the coverage of the impact of corruption on specific performance outputs is much more
limited. We found four working papers analyzing the effects of corruption on
infrastructure sectors. Estache and Kouassi (2002) show that corruption increases the cost
of providing water in Africa. That result is confirmed by Kirkpatrick and others (2006),
who use a larger and more recent database. Dal Bo and Rossi (2006) show that labor
productivity in electricity distribution companies is hurt by corruption. However, none of
these three studies explicitly accounts for the interaction between reform policies and
corruption as we propose to do. The fourth study, by Guasch and Straub (2005), includes
such an interaction, but the authors examine corruption’s effects on the renegotiation of
infrastructure concessions in Latin America, as opposed to its effects on infrastructure
15
We could not cover the entire period from 1990 to 2004, because most of the relevant performance
indicators are not yet available for the last two years of the period.
16
The exceptions are papers on investment flows to the sector, typically flows of foreign direct investment
(FDI). For a recent paper that includes all relevant references on corruption and FDI, see Ghosh Banerjee
and others (2006)
17
See for example Rock and Bonnett (2004), Pellegrini and Gerlagh (2004), and Méndez and Sepúlveda
(2006).
18
Examples are Clarke and Xu (2002) and Laffont and N’Guessan (1999).
8
outputs. They find that the stronger the level of corruption, the more important the effect
of having a regulator in place to oversee renegotiations.
Measuring the impact of corruption on performance and the interaction between
corruption and reform policies allows us to test the extent to which reform policies have
managed to reinforce or offset the impact of corruption and, vice versa, the extent to
which corruption reinforces or offsets the impact of the policies. This is the rationale for
introducing the interaction between the CORR and POL variables in the regression.
However, caution is needed when drawing conclusions from the coefficients associated
with these interactions. It is also important to account for other economic dimensions
likely to drive infrastructure performance which could influence our inference on
corruption if we failed to take them into account. Countries with poorer governance
generally have lower income, and poor governance cannot be simply attributed to the
effects of income. The two most obvious, as recognized in most of the literature, are
incomes levels and the degree of urbanization to capture the ability to pay and the size of
the market on the demand side. This is why we introduce in vector X, the GDP per capita
in 2000 constant U.S. dollars and the urbanization rate, which captures the size of the
market from the demand side.
The measure of corruption used here is a corruption index published by the
International Country Risk Guide. The index offers comparable figures for about 100
developing countries over a reasonably long period of time. Defined as an assessment of
corruption within the political system, the index includes financial corruption (such as
bribes connected with trade, taxes, or protection), but it concentrates on corruption in the
form of excessive patronage, nepotism, job reservations, “favor-for-favors,” secret party
funding, and suspiciously close ties between politics and business. According to the
ICRG measure, average corruption levels increased 29 percent in developing countries
between 1990 and 2005 (Table 2). Given the empirical evidence about the important role
of corruption for economic outcomes, the observed increase in the corruption index may
be an important determinant of outputs in infrastructure sectors.
Table 2
Evolution of average corruption between 1990 and 2004
Corruption index (0=low 1=high)
1990
1995
2000
2005
Average
Standard
deviation
Number of
observations
0.52
0.49
0.57
0.67
0.19
0.16
0.16
0.11
93
94
104
104
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from ICRG.
From a more technical viewpoint, it may be worth mentioning that our model
assumes that the adoption of a certain reform policy is conditionally exogenous to the
error term in the model. Because we control for country fixed effects, a linear trend, and
GDP per capita, we completely absorb differences in the outcome variables due to
intrinsic characteristics of each country that do not vary over time (their history, for
example), changes in economic performance, and the generalized trend in IRA and
9
privatization. Ultimately, we are arguing that, conditional on these covariates, policy
reforms are not correlated to the error term and that GLS estimates of the coefficients on
the policy variables are consistent. We based this hypothesis on the fact that in most
developing countries reforms were initially implemented to improve fiscal deficits and
not to improve performance. This may be seen as a limitation of the paper, but the
alternative was to depend on unreliable instruments. We chose to avoid such reliance,
because there is no theoretically convincing argument demonstrating that bad instruments
will yield better results than the assumption we are making here.
The coverage of our data is extensive, but there is a great deal of variability across
sectors and variables. For each dependent variable, we used the largest possible sample
and, to reduce sample selection biases, included countries that have reformed as well as
countries that have not reformed. We constructed one data panel for each sector. For
electricity and telecoms, the unbalanced panels each contain 1,989 observations,
including data for 153 developing countries during the period 1990–2002. For these
sectors we were able to assess performance in terms of access, affordability, and quality.
However, our water coverage is much more limited. We were able to collect data only for
access and for two time periods. Thus, the unbalanced water panel contains 306
observations, including data for 153 developing countries for 1990 and 2002. Because of
the size of the water panel, we did not include country fixed effects in these regressions.
A final comment deals with the way the econometric results need to be read. It is
essential not to take each coefficient at face value. Regression coefficients represent the
effects of policies under specific scenarios, and not the total average effect of policies
across countries. For example, in equation (1), the coefficient of the dummy variable that
reports whether or not a country has an IRA expresses the effect of an IRA on
performance only in those countries that do not have private participation and in which
the corruption index is equal to zero. The marginal effect, by contrast, considers all the
information jointly and provides the correct assessment of the average impact of reform
policies and corruption on performance across countries.
To compute the marginal effects of the IRA variable, the first-order derivative of
equation (1) with respect to IRA needs to be computed. Next, all the variables in the
derivative need to be set to their average value. This is done by taking the data sample
used for the regression and then computing the average (or the share of the sample,
according to what the derivative requires). Finally, the hypothesis that the derivative is
equal to zero needs to be tested with a t-test. We repeat this procedure to get the marginal
effects of privatization and of corruption.
Note that the need to calculate the marginal effect does not imply that the
econometric model itself is unimportant for drawing policy conclusions. Indeed, it
provides an opportunity to test the statistical significance of bilateral interactions, such as
independent regulation with privatization, corruption with privatization, and corruption
with independent regulation.
10
4. Impact of reforms on access rates
This section focuses on the impact of reform on the first measure of utility
performance: access. We first explain how and why we picked our specific performance
proxies. We then move to a basic data analysis in which we describe their evolution
between 1990 and 2002, distinguishing between groups of countries that have reformed
and those which have not. This serves as a benchmark for a discussion of the extent to
which the econometric analysis can provide additional insights.
4.1 Selection of access indicators
There is disagreement in the literature on how to define access. Should it be a
measure of the extent to which people have the right to obtain, use. or take advantage of
infrastructure services? Or, should it be a measure of the actual consumption by users?
There is no consistent approach across the three sectors.
In electricity, for now, the only information on access rates defined as an
entitlement and available for a large number of countries is a survey conducted in 2002
by the International Energy Agency (IEA) that reports access for the year 2000.
However, that information is not enough to estimate the panel data required by the
econometric model. An alternative is thus needed. Generation capacity is often used as a
proxy for access (Cubbin and Stern 2001; Zhang and others 2002 and 2005). We prefer to
use levels of energy use per capita (expressed in kg of oil equivalent), defined by the IEA
as “apparent consumption, which is equal to indigenous production plus imports and
stock changes, minus exports and fuels supplied to ships and aircraft engaged in
international transport.” The IEA measure yields a much larger dataset—but it has a cost.
In the energy sector, any change in consumption, in particular in higher-income
countries, may result from demand-management policies designed to reduce usage. In our
context, such a reduction would be interpreted as a reduction in access, which would
distort the real story.
In telecoms, there are multiple access indicators with time series available. The
number of mainlines (see definition, below) is one of the most popular choices,
sometimes accompanied by an indicator of mobile penetration.19 We chose the number of
telephone subscribers per 1,000 people, because it includes both fixed mainlines and
mobile subscribers, better representing the market options available today. ITU defines
this measure as the number of fixed lines plus the number of mobile subscribers per 1,000
people, where fixed lines are “telephone mainlines connecting a customer's equipment to
the public switched telephone network,” while “mobile phone subscribers refers to users
of portable telephones subscribing to an automatic public mobile telephone service using
cellular technology that provides access to the public switched telephone network.” This
indicator may over- or underestimate access because, as Wallsten (2001) explains, it is
not possible to differentiate if one person has multiple lines, or if one line is used by
multiple persons.
To measure access in the water sector, we use the percentage of population with
access to improved water sources published by the Joint Monitoring Program (JMP), the
19
Examples can be found in Ross (1999), Wallsten (2001 and 2003), Fink and others (2001 and 2002),
Gutiérrez (2003), and Li and Xu (2004).
11
only water access indicator available for a reasonably large sample of countries. JMP
defines access as follows:
“[t]he availability of at least 20 liters of improved water per person per
day from a source within one kilometer of the user's dwelling. Improved
water supply sources are: household connection, public standpipe,
borehole, protected dug well, protected spring, rainwater collection.
Unimproved sources include unprotected well, unprotected spring,
vendor-provided water, bottled water (based on concerns about the
quantity of supplied water, not concerns over the water quality), and
tanker truck-provided water.”
Our choice was based solely on data availability and not on the quality of the
indicator. Other indicators, although better, have serious coverage issues. For example,
Clarke, Kosec, and Wallsten (2004) were able to gather household data on the number of
connections to piped water, but only for some Latin American countries. They noted how
difficult it is to find cross-country data in the water sector. In theory, access to improved
water sources as defined by JMP is a good indicator of access, because it is based on
household data and is available for multiple countries, but it is available only for two
points in time. Furthermore, the JMP estimates access values by running a regression
with data from multiple household surveys and using the estimated coefficients to
calculate access in 1990 and 2002. The access figures for these two time periods are
constantly reestimated as more surveys are carried out. Thus, it is difficult to track the
marginal improvements in access to water over time.
4.2 Basic data analysis
On average, access has improved in all sectors between 1990 and 2002 (Table 3).
The greatest improvement is observed in the telecoms sector (an increase of 330 percent),
followed by electricity (22 percent), and water (7 percent). This difference reflects both
technological advances and changes in the sectors. The fact that there has been very little
technological progress in energy and water, however, suggests that the other factors may
be relatively more important—in particular, the potential contribution of reform policies.
Technology is no doubt the driving force in the telecoms sector.
Table 3
Evolution of average access between 1990 and 2002
Energy use (kg of oil equivalent per capita)
1990
2002
Telephone subscribers per 1,000 people
1990
2002
Access to improved water sources (percentage of
population)
1990
2002
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from WDI, JMP, WHO, and UNICEF.
Average
Standard
deviation
Number of
observations
1098
1335
1071
1255
76
95
57
245
70
269
150
151
72
77
21
19
102
138
12
To relate access indicators to reform policies, we calculated averages for different
groups of countries according to the status of their reform implementation. In all sectors,
countries that established an IRA and introduced private participation have higher
average access than countries that did not implement either of these policies (Table 4,
columns 1 and 4). We can also look at the average access of countries that decided to
implement only one of these policies (columns 2 and 3). In electricity, establishing an
IRA seems to be more important than introducing private participation when it comes to
access. The opposite is observed in telecoms; countries with an IRA have lower access
than those with private participation. In water, there seems to be no difference. Overall,
ignoring the fact that each group may reflect a selection bias, the story that emerges is
that reforms helped the access performance across sectors.
Table 4
Access vs. reform policies in 2002
1
Energy use (kg of oil
equivalent per capita)
Telephone
subscribers/1,000
people
Access to improved
water sources
(percent of population)
Average
(standard deviation; number of observations)
2
3
4
5
Without IRA
Without PPI
With IRA
Without PPI
Without IRA
With PPI
With IRA
With PPI
All
countries
1,249
(1,255; 36)
1,769
(1,511; 22)
632
(500; 3)
1,271
(1,116; 30)
1,362
(1,272; 91)
154
(206; 26)
161
(189; 40)
242
(201; 15)
363
(347; 47)
243
(276; 128)
71
(19; 63)
81
(13; 7)
81
(18; 22)
77
(22; 9)
77
(19; 138)
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from WDI, ITU, and WHO.
Note: For some indicators, coverage in 2002 is not as good as for previous years. Thus, for some groups samples are too small to draw
significant conclusions.
IRA refers to the existence of an independent regulatory agency, PPI refers to the existence of private participation.
4.3 Econometric analysis
The econometric results are provided in Table 5. The best model in terms of the
R–squared is the one for telecoms. The worst one is for water, even after accounting for
the fact that there is a strong demand for water for irrigation (proxied by the addition of
agricultural value added as an explanatory variable). The sample size for that sector is
also significantly lower than for the other sectors.
The econometric results nuance the “naïve” impressions that could be drawn from
Table 4. They show that the effectiveness of reforms depends on the sector and on the
reform. The marginal effects reported at the bottom of the table show that the effect of
corruption on access varies by sector. Of particular interest are the statistical significance
and the sign of the marginal effects.
Keeping in mind that these are average effects for a wide range of countries, the
initial story is sobering. Increasing PPI in telecoms had the expected effect of increasing
access. However, in electricity and in water, it did not have a statistically significant
effect during the period of analysis, contrary to the impression left by the basic data
analysis (Table 5, line 16).
13
The results for the introduction of IRAs are even more puzzling. For the period
covered by our sample the presence or absence of an IRA did affect the access rate in the
water sector. However, it was associated with a statistically significant reduction in
access rates in electricity and in telecoms (line 15).
Finally, whatever the impact of either reform, the coefficient on their interaction
(line 3) suggests that together they exert beneficial effects in electricity and telecoms but
do not interact in the water sector.
Table 5
(1)
IRA
(2)
Privatization
(3)
IRA * privatization
(4)
Corruption index
(0=low 1=high)
IRA * corruption
(5)
Econometric results for access, 1990–2002
(8)
Privatization *
Corruption
Ln GDP per capita
(2000 US$)
Ln Urbanization
(9)
Time trend
(10)
Ln agricultural value
added (percent of GDP)
(11)
Constant
(12)
(13)
Observations
R–squared within
(14)
No. of countries in sample
(6)
(7)
(1)
(2)
(3)
Ln energy use (kg of
oil equivalent per
capita)
0.016
[0.55]
-0.066**
[2.16]
0.031*
[1.66]
Ln telephone
subscribers/1,0
00 people
-0.063
[0.76]
0.055
[0.79]
0.214***
[5.57]
Ln access to improved
water sources (percent
of population)
-0.425
[1.16]
0.234**
[1.98]
-0.243
[1.28]
-0.092***
[6.23]
-0.111**
[2.16]
0.095*
[1.75]
0.195***
[11.58]
-0.123*
[1.92]
0.548***
[9.80]
-0.290**
[2.22]
0.023
[0.23]
1.884***
[33.24]
1.625***
[8.03]
-0.476***
[3.72]
1.156
[1.30]
-0.416
[1.01]
0.342***
[5.03]
-0.068
[0.75]
0.013***
[10.25]
0.102***
[24.64]
0.191**
-19.610***
[7.93]
929
0.64
-222.553***
[28.79]
1108
0.96
[2.50]
1.571**
[2.31]
122
0.54
80
92
72
-0.148***
[5.30]
0.149***
[5.53]
0.443***
[7.18]
0.061
[0.58]
-0.017
[0.29]
-0.181
[0.74]
Marginal effects
(15)
IRA
(16)
PRIV
(17)
CORRUPTION
-0.035***
[3.77]
-0.007
[0.58]
-0.107***
[6.58]
Absolute value of t statistics in brackets. * significant at 10 percent, ** significant at 5 percent, *** significant at 1 percent.
For water, we include the agricultural value added as percentage of GDP (Agri-VA) to capture the strong demands on water supply for
irrigation purposes, thus significantly improving the explanatory power of the regression.
Ln stands for neperian logarithm
14
The story emerging on the impact of corruption is also complex (line 17). In
electricity, corruption is associated with a lower access rate, as expected—that is, an
increase in the corruption index was associated with a decline in energy use. In the water
sector, corruption does not seem to have had a statistically significant impact on access
rates. The results for telecoms were unexpected: greater corruption is linked to higher
access. As discussed later, these effects need to be assessed simultaneously with the two
other performance dimensions to check for possible trade-offs made by operators.
How reforms have affected the interaction of corruption and access rates may be
the most politically sensitive contribution of this paper (lines 5 and 6). Reforms were
expected, of course, to improve utility coverage among the population. Access was to
become an entitlement, no longer a “favor” bestowed by a corrupt bureaucrat. But our
results suggest that reforms do not necessarily have the expected impact on corruption.
The positive sign of the statistically significant interaction term between corruption and
PPI means two things. It means that PPI seems to influence the effects of corruption in
electricity but it also means that corruption influences the effects of PPI on access.20 The
lack of statistical significance of the effects in the other sectors implies that reforms are
not effective in addressing the impact of corruption on access in those sectors. More
positively, it also means that corruption does not interfere with the impact of reform on
access rates.
The negative sign of the statistically significant interaction term between
corruption and IRA means that the presence of an IRA seems to offset the effects of
corruption in electricity and in telecoms. It also means that corruption reduces the effects
of the IRA on access in those sectors. The lack of statistical significance of the effects in
the water sector implies that reforms have not been effective in addressing the impact of
corruption on access in that sector, and that corruption does not interfere with the impact
of reform on access rates.
Adding up the coefficients in rows 4 to 6 in the table yields an assessment of the
joint impact of the two reforms on the effects of corruption on access. This assessment is
relevant only in electricity, where all of the coefficients are statistically significant. In
that case, the negative effects of corruption on access are higher in countries that have
adopted the two reforms (sum of rows 4 to 6) than in countries that have not reformed
(row 4).
5. Impact of reforms on affordability
This section discusses the impact of reforms on user prices, which we use to
approximate the performance dimension of affordability. As in section 4, we first explain
how and why we picked our proxies. We then move to a basic data analysis before
discussing the econometric results.
20
Note that whether the desirability of a reinforcing or mitigating effect of reform depends the sign of the
direct effect of corruption on performance
15
5.1 Selection of affordability indicators
Affordability indicators should give a sense of the extent to which infrastructure
services are provided at a price consistent with the income levels of residential users—
ignoring for now the consistency of costs and prices. Ideally, affordability measures will
capture the extent to which the price of a standard consumption bundle is consistent with
users’ ability to pay. These measures should be collected from household surveys that
specify the percentage of household income or household expenditure allocated by
different income classes to a specific service.
The only practical information available for a large set of countries is the average
price and, occasionally, the tariff structure. This information is widely seen as
problematic, however, because it does not account for the informal alternatives available
to consumers in developing countries. But because it is the only information available for
a large sample of countries, it is used in the few econometric studies of reforms. For
example, Steiner (2001), Zhang and others (2002 and 2005), and Hattori and Tsutsui
(2004), use electricity end-user prices as an independent variable to study the impact of
reforms. For telecoms, three cross-country studies document the impact of reforms on
prices (Boylaud and Nicoletti 2000; Ross 2001 and 2003).
We chose electricity end-user prices for households and for industry as proxies for
affordability. End-user prices are defined as prices actually paid, net of rebates, including
nonrefundable taxes and transport costs that the consumer must pay as part of the
transaction, but excluding value-added tax. Data were collected from the following
sources: IEA, Energy Regulators Regional Association (ERRA), Energy-Economic
Information System of Latin America and the Caribbean (SIEE-OLADE), and South
African Development through Electricity (SAD-ELEC). The chief limitation of data on
electricity prices is coverage. We were able to get prices for just 56 of 153 developing
countries.
To proxy the affordability of telecom services, we relied on the price for a threeminute local phone call in U.S. cents and the monthly subscription fee in U.S. dollars (for
residents and for business). ITU defines the price of local calls as “the cost of a peak rate
3-minute fixed line call within the same exchange area using the subscriber's own
terminal.” The monthly residential (or business) phone subscription fee is defined as “the
recurring fixed charge for a residential (business) subscriber to the public switched
telephone network.” The charge covers the rental of the line but not the rental of the
telephone set where the equipment market is liberalized. In some cases, the rental charge
includes an allowance for free or reduced-rate call units. If there are different charges for
different exchange areas, the largest urban area is used. These indicators refer to prices in
the fixed-line market and do not include mobile-market prices.
We could not find reliable databases at the national level in the water sector. Most
data are collected at the company level, and most companies serve only a limited segment
of the population. This may be why no comparable data is available at the country level.
16
5.2 Basic data analysis
Average electricity prices for both households and industry increased between
1990 and 2002 (Table 6). The increase probably was driven by significant improvements
in cost-recovery efforts introduced in a wide range of countries during the 1990s, often as
a component of reforms aimed at reducing direct public subsidies. In contrast, the
average price of a local telephone call, as well as average monthly residential and
business subscription fees, decreased thanks to technology-driven cost reductions and
tariff rebalancing, which was a common features of reforms in the 1990s. The ratios of
local call costs in 2002 to the same costs in 1990, compared with the ratios of
subscription fees, illustrate the effect of tariff rebalancing. Indeed, average tariffs
decreased more than connection fees. The basic picture is that electricity seems to have
become less affordable, while telecomunications have become more affordable.
Table 6
Evolution of average prices, 1990–2002
Electricity price, households
(2000 U.S. cents per kWh/10,000 GDP per capita)
[[what is 10,000 GDP?]]
1990
2002
Electricity price, industry
(2000 U.S. cents per kWh/10,000 GDP per capita)
1990
2002
Price of local phone call
(2000 U.S. cents/10,000 GDP per capita)
1990
2002
Monthly residential subscription fee
(2000 U.S. dollars /10,000 GDP per capita)
1990
2002
Monthly business subscription fee
(2000 U.S. dollars /10,000 GDP per capita)
1990
2002
Average
Standard
deviation
Number of
observations
43
59
50
67
30
56
45
57
49
73
30
56
339
114
1335
201
83
121
128
51
235
61
80
125
189
71
326
69
76
123
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from EIA, ERRA, OLADE, and SAD-ELEC.
In order to relate affordability to out two reforms, Table 7 presents “affordability”
indicators for different country groups according to the extent to which they have adopted
reforms (samples for some groups are too small to permit any conclusions to be drawn).
This is the typical way in which anecdotal assessments of the impact of reforms on
affordability are done. It does not really tell a statistically robust story, but it is widely
popular among the partisans of anecdotal evidence on the impact of “privatization”.
17
Table 7 Affordability vs. reform policies in 2002
Average
(standard deviation; number of observations)
1
2
3
4
Without IRA
With IRA
Without IRA
With IRA
Without PPI
Without PPI
With PPI
With PPI
Electricity price for households (2000
U.S. cents/kWh/10,000 GDP per
capita)
Electricity price for industry (2000
U.S. cents per kWh/10,000 GDP per
capita)
Price of Local Phone Call (2000 U.S.
cents/10,000 GDP pc)
5
All
countries
132
(89; 7)
48
(78; 20)
..
..
44
(40; 24)
58
(70; 51)
159
(127; 7)
41
(61; 20)
..
..
40
(40; 24)
57
(76; 51)
84
(104; 16)
146
(172; 36)
69
(147; 10)
132
(283; 41)
123
(214; 103)
Monthly Residential Subscription Fee
46
65
(2000 U.S. dollars/10,000 GDP per
(68; 19)
(78; 37)
capita)
Monthly Industrial Subscription Fee
65
78
(2000 U.S. dollars/10,000) )GDP per
(65; 19)
(77; 37)
capita
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from EIA, ERRA, OLADE, and SAD-ELEC.
29
(36; 10)
51
(53; 41)
53
(64; 107)
65
(100; 9)
68
(59; 41)
71
(70; 106)
- For some indicators, coverage in 2002 is not as good as the one for previous years. Thus, for some groups samples are too small to draw significant
conclusions.
- IRA refers to the existence of an independent regulatory agency, and PPI refers to the existence of private participation.
This basic data analysis implies that electricity prices are lower in reformed
economies than in economies that have not adopted either of the reforms we are
examining. In telecoms, countries that have not reformed have average lower local prices
than countries that have reformed. This reflects improvements in cost recovery but also
tariff rebalancing, on which most telecoms reforms placed heavy emphasis. With
rebalancing, cross-subsidies from international calls to local calls, for example, tend to
disappear. Interestingly, the basic data analysis suggests that the lowest costs for local
calls are found in countries that have increased private sector participation without
adopting regulatory agencies. In other words, the basic data analysis suggests that the
presence of an IRA in the telecoms sector is associated with a worsening of affordability.
5.3 Econometric analysis
The marginal effects of reforms on affordability, computed from the econometric
results, are reported in the lower part of Table 8. They confirm some of the observations
from the basic data analysis. First IRAs are not equally effective across sectors or users
(Table 8, line 14). Establishing an IRA in electricity was significantly associated with
reduced prices for households, but not for industry. For telecoms, the presence of an IRA
was associated with an increase in the average cost of a local call but had no effect on
subscription fees.
PPI affected almost all of the prices we looked at (line 15). However, those effects
were different from the ones suggested by the basic data analysis. In electricity, private
participation was associated with an increase in end-user prices for households
(negatively affecting affordability) but had no effect on industrial prices. In telecoms
private participation was associated with higher residential and business monthly
subscription fees but lower prices for local calls, consistent with the rebalancing policies
discussed earlier.
18
Corruption proved to have fewer statistically significant effects on affordability
than on access during the period of analysis (line 16). One exception stands out. On
average, an increase in corruption was associated with an increase in the price of a local
phone call. Because it has no effects on the fixed connection cost, it is likely that the
impact is on variable costs and interconnection rates.
Table 8 Econometric results for affordability, 1990–2002
(1)
(1)
IRA
(2)
Privatization
(3)
IRA *
Privatization
(4)
(5)
Corruption index
(0=low 1=high)
IRA * corruption
(8)
Privatization *
corruption
Ln GDP per capita
(2000 U.S.$)
Ln urbanization
(9)
Time trend
(10)
Constant
(11)
(12)
Observations
R–squared within
No. of countries in
sample
(6)
(7)
(13)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Ln monthly
residential
subs. fee
(2000 U.S.$)
Ln monthly
business
subs. Fee
(2000 U.S.$)
0.479**
[2.54]
0.505***
[3.08]
–0.101
0.177
[0.95]
0.465***
[2.91]
–0.068
Ln
electricity
price for
households
(2000 U.S.
cents/kWh)
Ln
electricity
price for
industry
(2000 U.S.
cents/kWh)
–0.110
[0.85]
0.437***
[3.35]
–0.001
–0.138
[1.21]
0.310***
[2.68]
–0.147**
Ln price of
local
telephone
call (2000
U.S.
cents/3-min
call)
0.064
[0.38]
0.738***
[5.16]
–0.178**
[0.01]
[2.30]
[2.37]
[1.18]
[0.82]
–0.159
[0.69]
0.033
[0.13]
–0.103
[0.38]
0.636***
[2.68]
0.264
0.035
[0.17]
0.365*
[1.67]
–0.345
[1.45]
1.305***
[6.19]
4.303***
0.756***
[4.43]
0.341
[1.29]
–1.583***
[6.74]
–0.454**
[2.28]
0.154
0.356*
[1.81]
–0.644**
[2.12]
–0.358
[1.47]
–0.816***
[3.93]
–3.538***
0.217
[1.13]
–0.162
[0.54]
–0.402*
[1.68]
–0.441**
[2.17]
–1.071**
[0.27]
0.003
[0.32]
–7.348
[0.37]
380
0.33
[4.95]
–0.063***
[7.38]
128.654***
[7.24]
380
0.22
[0.36]
–0.058***
[6.16]
120.283***
[6.83]
943
0.34
[7.19]
0.027**
[2.46]
–36.570*
[1.82]
968
0.15
[2.18]
–0.019*
[1.73]
48.241**
[2.47]
957
0.09
47
47
91
91
91
0.183***
[3.45]
–0.153***
[2.89]
0.394***
[2.74]
0.112
[1.79]
0.276***
[4.52]
–0.022
[0.13]
0.071
[1.16]
0.228***
[3.83]
0.020
[0.13]
Marginal effects
(14)
IRA
(15)
PRIV
(16)
CORRUPTION
–0.094**
[1.98]
0.385***
[7.41]
–0.176
[1.04]
–0.007
[0.18]
0.055
[1.19]
0.125
[0.83]
Absolute value of t statistics in brackets. * significant at 10 percent, ** significant at 5 percent, *** significant at 1 percent.
The interaction dummies suggest that in general IRA and PPI do not
systematically interact to influence prices (line 3). This is quite surprising, because it is
19
widely argued that IRAs are needed to control the pricing behavior of monopolies. Two
notable exceptions to the noninteraction of the dummy variables are in the prices of local
calls and of industrial electricity. In both of these cases, the interaction is negative and
stronger than the direct impact of each policy. In other words, in these two cases, the
evidence suggests that the regulator indeed limits the opportunistic pricing behavior of
operators.
The interactions between corruption and the reform dummies are once more the
most interesting of the effects. The effect of reforms on the price consequences of
corruption is, in general, less significant than suggested by theory. The introduction of an
IRA influences only some of the prices of concern to the industrial consumers,
reinforcing the impact of corruption on average electricity prices. In telecoms, the
presence of an IRA reduces the adverse impact of corruption on household connection
charges (line 5). The introduction of PPI has no impact on the price effect of corruption
(line 6). It does, however, offset the impact of corruption on local call prices and on
industrial connection fees in telecoms. Lines 4 to 6, considered together, suggest that the
two policies never combined to affect prices significantly during the period of analysis.
6. Impact of reforms on quality
This section focuses quality. As in sections 4 and 5, we first explain how and why
we picked our proxies in each sector. We then move to a basic data analysis before
discussing the econometric results.
6.1 Selection of quality indicators
The measurement of quality proved to be the most challenging of the three
dimensions of performance. Quality may be assessed from the technical point of view or
from a service perspective. The first angle is generally based on quantitative measures,
often generated by engineers. The second tends to rely on qualitative measures, often
based on surveys of users. Quantitative measures are less subjective, even if they are
usually reported by the utilities or providers based on self-assessments. Examples include
electric outages and reported phone faults. Qualitative measures often capture the
perceptions of respondents. Regardless of the merits of the two types of measures, we
could not find qualitative datasets with large enough coverage for our purposes.
In electricity, we rely on power transmission and distribution losses as
percentages of total output as our measure of technical quality. These are defined by IEA
as “losses in transmission between sources of supply and points of distribution and in the
distribution to consumers, including pilferage. Shares may not sum to 100 percent
because other sources of generated electricity (such as geothermal, solar, and wind) are
not shown.”21 Theoretically, power transmission and distribution losses are a suitable
proxy for the quality of service because the higher the losses, the higher the probability
21
We found only one working paper, Vagliasindi (2004), on the effects of reform policies on technical
quality in electricity; it, too, used the IEA measure. The paucity of academic literature on electricity quality
is in part due to data limitations.
20
that firms have operational problems that affect the quality of service from the
consumer’s perspective. But coverage is again an issue. Power transmission and
distribution losses for the most recent years are available for about 90 of 153 developing
countries. For earlier periods coverage drops even more.
In telecoms, we rely on telephone faults as our proxy for technical quality.
Telephone faults are defined by ITU as “reported faults per one hundred telephone
mainlines.” Compared with ITU’s indicators of access and affordability, coverage of
telephone faults is rather low. We have data for about 60 of 153 developing countries. An
additional problem with phone faults is that they include only reported faults, which is
sometimes misleading (especially in countries with bad reporting systems).
Regarding water, no technical quality indicators are available at the country level.
The few available indicators from the consumer’s perspective (like hours of water
supply) have very low coverage. Unfortunately, due to the lack of data, we were not able
to analyze the impact of reform policies on water service quality.
6.2 Basic data analysis
The evolution of technical quality between 1990 and 2002 differs from electricity
to telecoms (Table 9). In electricity, average losses increased by 13 percent, while in
telecoms average faults dropped by 57 percent. However, it is important to keep in mind
that these two indicators are reported by firms. Improvements in reporting and auditing
systems may increase the reported figure, even if the quality of the service has not
deteriorated.
Table 9
Evolution of average technical quality, 1990–2002
Power transmission and distribution losses (percentage
of output)
1990
2002
Telephone faults per 100 mainlines
1990
2002
Average
Standard
deviation
Number of
observations
15
17
9
11
72
89
98
42
86
39
45
62
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from WDI.
Reform policies, such as IRAs and PPI, may have influenced the service quality
and/or the efficiency of reporting systems. Table 10 relates technical quality to reform
policies by presenting averages for different country groups according to whether or not
reforms were adopted. There seems to be no difference in power losses between countries
that committed fully to reforms and those that did not (columns 1 and 4). In contrast,
telephone faults are 50 percent lower in countries that have reformed than in those that
lack an IRA and in which the telephone company remains state-owned. Regarding
countries that have partially committed to reforms (columns 2 and 3), in both electricity
and telecoms, those that have an IRA but not PPI show poorer quality performance than
21
those that lack IRA but have PPI. The difference is more pronounced in electricity than in
telecoms.
Table 10
1
No IRA
No PPI
Quality vs. reform policies in 2002
Average
(standard deviation, number of observations)
2
3
4
With IRA
Without IRA
With IRA
Without PPI
With PPI
With PPI
5
All countries
Power transmission
and distribution losses
(percent of output)
18
(13,33)
16
(10,21)
12
(8,2)
18
(10,29)
18
(11,85)
Telephone faults
(reported faults/100
mainlines)
63
(55,7)
41
(40,20)
39
(26,3)
32
(29,25)
40
(37,55)
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from WDI.
Note: For some indicators, coverage in 2002 is not as good as coverage for previous years. Thus, for some groups samples are too small
to draw significant conclusions. IRA refers to the existence of an independent regulatory agency; PPI refers to the presence of private
participation.
Overall, the basic data analysis implies that quality is improving over time in
telecoms but not in electricity. Technology is probably a relevant factor. More surprising,
perhaps, is the sense that reform policies do not seem to be related to quality
improvements in electricity, whereas they do appear to be related to quality
improvements in telecoms.
6.3 Econometric analysis
The econometric work reported in Table 11 casts doubt on the conclusions
reached from the basic data analysis. However, the diagnostics provided by the
econometric analysis are not as reliable for quality as they were for access and
affordability. For one thing, the coefficients for the regressions are much less robust—a
consequence of the much weaker data coverage, in particular for electricity. Overall, the
regressions yield poor results, and our model has a much lower explanatory power for
quality than for the other two dimensions of performance. Only the income and the trend
variables are significant for both sectors and for a few of the policy variables.
The marginal effects suggest that the creation of an IRA is associated with a
statistically significant deterioration in the quality indicators for both electricity and
telecoms, and that PPI is not associated with any statistically significant effect on quality
in either sector. These are two quite unexpected results. As mentioned earlier, two
explanations are possible: (i) performance got worse or (ii) the measurement of actual
performance improved with the creation of an independent auditor. In the second case,
the apparent deterioration simply reflects better statistics; actual performance may even
have improved.
22
Table 11
(1)
IRA
(2)
Privatization
(3)
IRA * privatization
(4)
Corruption index
(0=low 1=high)
IRA * corruption
(5)
(8)
Privatization *
Corruption
Ln GDP per capita
(2000 U.S.$)
Ln urbanization
(9)
Time trend
(10)
Constant
(11)
(12)
Observations
R–squared within
No. of countries in
sample
(6)
(7)
(13)
Econometric results for quality, 1990–2002
(1)
Ln power T&D losses
(percent of output)
0.121
[1.32]
–0.043
[0.43]
0.032
(2)
Ln phone faults
(reported faults/100 mainlines)
0.767***
[3.67]
0.201
[1.14]
–0.072
[0.53]
[0.76]
0.073
[1.57]
0.023
[0.14]
0.196
[1.13]
–0.115**
[2.18]
–0.284
0.027
[0.12]
–1.188***
[3.43]
–0.262
[0.92]
0.605**
[2.54]
–2.906***
[1.43]
0.009**
[2.26]
–14.244*
[1.83]
880
0.23
[5.04]
–0.055***
[4.76]
119.837***
[5.59]
652
0.39
76
85
Marginal effects
(14)
IRA
(15)
PRIV
(16)
CORRUPTION
0.140***
[4.82]
0.070
[1.84]
0.125**
[2.42]
0.136**
[2.02]
0.037
[0.58]
–0.550***
[3.04]
Absolute value of t statistics in brackets. * significant at 10 percent, ** significant at 5 percent, *** significant at 1 percent.
The third marginal calculation suggests that corruption does not have the same
impact in the two sectors, even though we find in both cases a statistically significant
impact on quality. An increase in corruption was associated with an increase in power
losses but with a decrease in telephone faults. Thus, corruption is on average harmful to
quality in electricity but beneficial, at least in terms of quality, in telecoms.
The interaction dummies suggest that the reforms have no role in producing the
effects of corruption in the electricity sector. In the case of telecoms, the advent of PPI
has no effect on the impact of corruption on quality; by contrast, the creation of an IRA
does have the expected effect. That is, corruption leads to a deterioration of quality, but
the regulator mitigates that negative effect. The dummy for the interaction between IRA
and PPI reveals no statistically significant effect.
23
7. Does corruption reveal performance trade-offs for providers?
Up to now, we have looked at performance indicators one by one. This section offers a
perspective on the various indicators in combination, and on how corruption may
influence the sectors in the presence of both reforms (IRA and PPI), one reform, or
neither reform. Looking at the indicators in combination allows us to examine how
operators make trade-offs among the performance dimensions (access, affordability, and
quality). Our assessment is limited to the electricity and the telecoms sector, because for
the water sector we were able to analyze only one performance dimension (access).
Our chief purpose is to test the extent to which, on average, operators in the two
sectors behave as monopolies are expected to behave, that is, whether they try to
influence prices, quantity, and quality to increase profits, defined as revenue (i.e.
quantities multiplied by prices) minus costs. If reforms restrict one of the performance
dimensions—if regulation mandates output or caps prices, for example—operators would
be expected to try adjusting the other two dimensions to maintain their profit. For
quantity and prices we focus on residential users. The proxy for quality is valid for all
users.
The degree to which operators have used corruption to influence any of the three
performance dimensions is summarized in Table 12. The table reports the information for
countries grouped according to their extent of reform (IRA, PPI, both, or neither). The
table is best read down the columns—that is, within a country group and across
performance indicators. It can be used to compare, from one sector to the other, how
corruption produces higher profit through trade-offs. For example, the effects of lower
prices on profits may be offset by lower quality.
In electricity, an increase in corruption in countries with state-owned companies
(column 1) is associated with lower residential prices, but also with deterioration in
access (quantity) and quality. Countries that have both an IRA and PPI (the reformers in
column 4) behave similarly; however, their adjustments to corruption are much larger.
Corruption appears to reduce residential prices in reformed countries more than in
unreformed ones, but the deterioration quantity and quality is larger as well. One possible
interpretation of that result is that IRAs and PPI, when they co-exist in the electricity
sector, do not provide better protection against the effects of corruption than no reform at
all. The evidence suggests that, from the viewpoint of users chiefly concerned with
access, as in most developing countries, adopting only one of the two reforms achieves
better results in minimizing the impact of corruption. Indeed, comparing column 1 with
column 2, or column 1 with column 3, countries that have an IRA or PPI do not suffer
quantity reductions even if they enjoy lower prices. Quality is still adjusted, however—
and much more so when the sole reform is PPI.
24
Table 12
Net effects of corruption on utility performance in groups of countries,
by extent of reform undertaken
Countries without
IRA and without
PPI (1)
Countries with
IRA but without
PPI (2)
Countries without
IRA but with PPI
(3)
Countries with
both IRA and PPI
(4)
–0.092
0.203
0.003
–1.108
Electricity
Quantity
Residential prices
–0.159
–0.126
–0.262
–0.229
Quality *
–0.073
–0.096
–0.269
–0.292
Quantity
0.548
0.258
0.571
0.281
Residential prices
0.756
1.097
–0.827
–0.486
Quality *
–0.027
1.161
0.235
1.423
Telecoms
Note: The figures are generated by adding the coefficients of corruption (rows 4 to 6) for different reform scenarios. To calculate these
net effects all coefficients were included, regardless of their significance. All dependent variables are in logs.
* A positive sign means an improvement in quality (a decline in power losses or phone faults).
In telecoms, reforms deal with corruption differently—and apparently more
effectively. When corruption increases in countries with state-owned companies, those
companies are able to offer higher access but at higher prices and with lower quality
(column 1). In contrast, when corruption increases in countries with both an IRA and PPI,
companies are able to offer higher access, lower prices, and better quality (column 4).
When only IRA is introduced (column 2) there is improvement in terms of quality;
whereas when only PPI is introduced (column 3), there is improvement on all three
dimensions. It appears, therefore, that in telecoms PPI is more effective than an IRA in
dealing with corruption.
This section has demonstrated the usefulness of an integrated perspective when
diagnosing the interactions between corruption and reforms. The conclusions reached
using the integrated perspective are much more robust than those reached by focusing on
the sign and significance of the interaction dummies in the basic model. We have shown
that during the period of the study operators dealt rationally with corruption by making
simultaneous adjustments in all areas of performance to maximize their profits. The
assessment also shows that the most publicized reforms did not work with equal
effectiveness in the two sectors. To date, reforms have handled corruption better in
telecoms than in the electricity sector.
8. Concluding remarks
We have offered three broad new insights in this paper. First, our econometric
estimations cast doubt on many of the optimistic impressions, obtained from basic data
analysis, of the impact of reforms and corruption on utility performance. In fact, reforms
have not always delivered on their promises. While they helped improve some
dimensions of performance, they hurt or had no impact on others. Ignoring corruption for
the moment, the marginal effects show that establishing an IRA essentially influences all
the dimensions of performance relevant to users in electricity and telecoms, but it shows
no significant effect in our limited sample of water sector data. The introduction of PPI,
25
by contrast, does not have a similar systematic effect across performance dimensions. In
electricity it affects only affordability, while in telecoms it affects access and
affordability. It has no effect on the quality indicators used here.
Second, to get a better sense of the effectiveness of reform on corruption, it is
important to: (i) distinguish countries that have adopted just one of the two reforms from
countries that have adopted both, and (ii) to account for all performance indicators
simultaneously. When doing so, the results suggest that in telecoms, reforms influence
the impact of corruption on all performance dimensions. In electricity, however, they
influence the impact of corruption on access and quality. In water, there were no
statistically conclusive results—once more, possibly because of the poor quality of the
data available.
Third, a look at performance across indicators suggests that the monopolies that
deliver utility services behave as theory predicts and “play” with quantity, price, and
quality, the three instruments they control to increase their profit margins. On some of
these dimensions, corruption also tends to work their way. This may be why the standard
reforms have only limited or partial success in offsetting the consequences of corruption
in some sectors.
Much work remains to be done to get a clear sense of the impact of reforms and
of corruption in the electricity, telecoms, and water sectors. Most important may be the
need to generate much better data than the proxies we have used here. However, based on
the cross-country information available today, our sense is that increasing PPI or
introducing IRAs, while they may help improve access, quality, or affordability in some
cases, are not sure bets to make everyone better off overall, contrary to what was hoped
for based on theoretical papers about 15 years ago.
26
References
Andres, L., V. Foster and J. L. Guasch. 2006. “The Impact of Privatization on Firms in
the Infrastructure Sector in Latin American Countries.” Unpublished paper, World
Bank and University of Chicago.
Bortolotti, B., and D. Siniscalco. 2004. The Challenges of Privatization: An International
Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.
Boycko, M., A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny. 1996. “A Theory of Privatisation.” The
Economic Journal 106 (March), 309-319.
Boylaud, O., and G. Nicoletti. 2000. Regulation, Market Structure and Performance in
Telecommunications. OECD Economics Department Working Papers 237. Paris.
Brown, A., J. Stern, and B. Tennebaum. 2006. A Handbook for Evaluating Infrastructure
Regulatory Systems. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Budds, J., and G. McGranahan. 2003. “Privatization and the Provision of Urban Water
and Sanitation in Africa, Asia, and Latin America.” IIED Human Settlements
Discussion Paper Series (Water 1). London.
Chong, A., and F. Lopez-de-Silanes. 2004. Privatization in Latin America: What Does
the Evidence Say?" Economía 4 (2, Spring): 37–111.
Clarke, G., and L. Colin Xu. 2002. “Ownership, Competition, and Corruption: Bribe
Takers versus Bribe Payers.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series
2783. Washington, DC.
Clarke, G., K. Kosec, and S. Wallsten. 2004. “Has Private Participation in Water and
Sewerage Improved Coverage? Empirical Evidence from Latin America.” World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series 3445. Washington, DC.
Cubbin, J., and J. Stern. 2001. “Regulatory Effectiveness: The Impact of Good
Regulatory Governance on Electricity Industry Capacity and Efficiency in
Developing Countries.” Department of Economics Discussion Paper Series 04/04.
City University, London.
Dal Bó, E., and M. Rossi. 2006. “Corruption and Inefficiency: Theory and Evidence from
Electric Utilities.” Unpublished paper. Universidad de San Andres, Argentina
Estache, A., and A. Goicoechea. 2005. “How Widespread Were Private Investment and
Regulatory Reform in Infrastructure Utilities during the 1990s?” World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper Series 3595. Washington, DC.
27
Estache, A., and M. Rossi. 2005. “Do Regulation and Ownership Drive the Efficiency of
Electricity Distribution? Evidence from Latin America.” Economics Letters 86 (2):
253–257.
Estache, A., and E. Kouassi. 2002. “Sector Organization, Governance, and the
Inefficiency of African Water Utilities.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
3374. Washington, DC.
Fink, C., A. Mattoo, and R. Rathindran. 2001. “Liberalizing Basic Telecommunications:
The Asian Experience. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series 2718.
Washington, DC.
Fink, C., A. Mattoo, and R. Rathindran. 2002. “An Assessment of Telecommunications
Reform in Developing Countries.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
Series 2909. Washington, DC.
Ghosh Banerjee, S., J. M. Oetzerl, and R. Ranganathan. 2006. “Private Provision of
Infrastructure in Emerging Markets: Do Institutions Matter?” Development Policy
Review 2: 175–202
Guasch, J. L., and S. Straub. 2005. “Infrastructure Concessions in Latin America:
Government-led Renegotiations.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series
3749. Washington, DC.
Gutiérrez, L. H. 2003. “The Effect of Endogenous Regulation on Telecommunications
Expansion and Efficiency in Latin America.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 23
(3): 257–286.
Hattori, T., and M. Tsutsui. 2004. “Economic Impact of Regulatory Reforms in the
Electricity Supply Industry: A Panel Data Analysis for OECD Countries.” Energy
Policy 32: 823–832.
Kariuki, M. & J. Schwartz. 2005. "Small-scale private service providers of water supply
and electricity : a review of incidence, structure, pricing, and operating
characteristics," Policy Research Working Paper Series 3727, The World Bank.
Kessides, I. 2004. “Reforming Infrastructure: Privatization, Regulation,
Competition.” World Bank Policy Research Report 28985. Washington, DC.
and
Kirkpatrick, C., D. Parker, and Y. Zhang. 2006. “An Empirical Analysis of the State and
Private-Sector Provision of Water Services in Africa.” World Bank Economic Review,
Laffont, J., and T. N’Guessan. 1999. “Competition and Corruption in an Agency
Relationship.” Journal of Development Economics 60: 271–295.
28
Li, W., and C. Xu. 2004. “The Impact of Privatization and Competition in the
Telecommunications Sector around the World.” Journal of Law and Economics 47:
395–430.
Méndez F., and F. Sepúlveda. 2006. “Corruption, Growth and Political Regimes: Crosscountry Evidence.” European Journal of Political Economy 22(1): 82–98.
Pellegrini, L., and R. Gerlagh. 2004. “Corruption’s Effect on Growth and Its
Transmission Channels.” Kyklos 57(3): 429–456.
Rock, M., and H. Bonnett. 2004. “The Comparative Politics of Corruption: Accounting
for the East Asian Paradox in Empirical Studies of Corruption, Growth, and
Investment.” World Development 32(6): 999–1017.
Ross, A. 1999. “Does Ownership or Competition Matter? The Effects of
Telecommunications Reform on Network Expansion and Efficiency.” Journal of
Regulatory Economics 15: 65–92.
Ross, A. 2003. “The Impact of the Regulatory Process and Price Cap Regulation in Latin
American Telecommunications Markets.” Review of Network Economics 2 (3): 270–
286.
Shapiro, C., and R. Willig. 1990. “Economic Rationales for the Scope of Privatization. In
The Political Economy of Public Sector Reform and Privatization, ed. E. Suleiman
Ezra and J. Waterbury (pp. 56–57). London: Westview Press.
Shleifer, A., and R. Vishny. 1993. “Corruption.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108
(3): 599–617.
Steiner, F. 2001. “Regulation, Industry Structure, and Performance in the Electricity
Supply Industry.” OECD Economic Studies 32(1): 143–182.
Vagliasindi, M. 2004. The Role of Investment and Regulatory Reforms in the
Development of Infrastructure across Transition Economies. Utilities Policy, 12, pp. 303314
Wallsten, S. 2001. “An Econometric Analysis of Telecom Competition, Privatization,
and Regulation in Africa and Latin America.” Journal of Industrial Economics 49
(1): 1–19.
Wallsten, S. 2003. “Of Carts and Horses: Regulation and Privatization in
Telecommunications Reforms.” Journal of Policy Reform 6 (4): 217–231.
Zhang, Y., D. Parker, and C. Kirkpatrick. 2002. “Electricity Sector Reform in Developing
Countries: An Econometric Assessment of the Effects of Privatisation, Competition,
29
and Regulation.” Aston Business School Research Papers RP0216. Birmingham,
England.
Zhang, Y., D. Parker, and C. Kirkpatrick. 2005. “Competition, Regulation, and
Privatisation of Electricity Generation in Developing Countries: Does the Sequencing
of the Reforms Matter?” Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 45 (2–3): 358–
379.