Jør gen Carl ing, Mat hias Czaika and Mart a Bivand Erdal
Transl at ing migrat ion t heory int o
empirical proposit ions
Del iverabl e 1. 2
QuantMig has received funding from the European Union’ s Horizon 2020 research and
innovation programme under grant agreement No. 870299.
i
History of changes
Version
Date
Changes
1.0
27 October 2020
Issued for Consortium Review
1.1
30 October 2020
First version submitted as official deliverable to the EC
Suggested citation
Carling J, M Czaika, and M.B. Erdal (2020) Translating migration theory into empirical
propositions. QuantMig Project Deliverable 1.2.
Dissemination level
PU Public
Acknowledgments
This document reflects the authors’ view and the Research Executive Agency of the European
Commission are not responsible for any use that may be made of the information it contains.
We are very grateful for useful comments and advice from Jakub Bijak, Michaela Potancokova,
and Jackie Wahba.
Cover photo: iStockphoto.com/Guenter Guni
Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
1
Table of Contents
Acknowledgments.................................................................................................................................. i
Table of Contents ................................................................................................................................... 1
1.
Introduction ......................................................................................................................................... 2
2.
What is migration theory? ................................................................................................................. 4
3.
Propositions ......................................................................................................................................... 7
3.1
Migration flows often reflect pre-existing connections between countries ....................... 7
3.2
Migration flows beyond a certain threshold become self-sustaining ................................ 8
3.3
Migrants are outnumbered by involuntary non-migrants .................................................. 9
3.4
Migrants with fewer resources make more fragmented, convoluted and unpredictable
journeys ................................................................................................................................................... 9
3.5
Environmental stress separates populations into trapped and mobilised groups......... 10
3.6
Violent conflict causes short-distance migration, often followed by geographically
dispersed secondary migration ......................................................................................................... 12
3.7
Emigration rises with economic development until a certain level and thereafter falls 13
3.8
Development aid can deter emigration from low- and middle-income countries......... 14
3.9
Migration policies are largely ineffective in producing desired outcomes ..................... 16
3.10
Migration restrictions affect migration flows in unintended ways .................................. 17
4.
Conclusion ......................................................................................................................................... 18
5.
References .......................................................................................................................................... 19
Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
2
1. Introduction
With the steady rise in absolute numbers of international migrants globally, especially since the turn
of the Millennium, scientific and policy interest in migration dynamics, both to understand (and
seek to manage) present developments, and to predict future trends, has only increased. Meanwhile,
the challenge of untangling the causes of migration, offering a clear-cut and context-independent
explanation of who migrates, why, when, where, and how, remains to be overcome (Arango 2000).
As recent contributions show, the lack of a grand theory of migration might be understood in the
light of the well-evidenced reality of composite sets of migration drivers (Czaika and Reinprecht
2020). Attempts at explaining migration processes, also for the purpose of enabling the development
of plausible scenarios of future migration, must build on approaches and models that recognise both
this complexity and the uncertainty which profoundly shapes migration (Bijak and Czaika 2020).
It seems self-evident that the connection between theorisation and empirical insight is crucial.
Meanwhile, it is pertinent to ask: What can we know? If the grand theory of migration does not exist,
is this because such a migration theory is (tentatively) unconceivable, due to epistemic uncertainty
of the very complex nature of migration? Or, is it because we lack appropriate tools, both
conceptually and methodologically perhaps, to allow for the collection of data that would yield
necessary empirical insight, and which could enable empirical validation of different hypotheses
and associated theorisation? Conversely, could reasons be linked to not posing the right questions,
in the first place, and not at the relevant scale?
This paper sets out to translate migration theory into empirically testable propositions. Drawing
actively on elements from different corners of the fragmented landscape of migration theory, we
formulate ten propositions, selected based on their relevance to current societal and academic
debates on international migration, its dynamics and patterns. We deliberately refer to ‘migration
theory’ rather than ‘theories’ because the relevant insights and assertions are packaged so diversely.
In fact, Everett Lee’s (1966) seminal article remains exceptional in unabashedly putting forth ‘a
theory’ of migration. Some of the more recent contributions have been composite bundles of
relationships and mechanisms that, in variable measure, concern the causes, effects and dynamics
of migration. Examples include the new economics of labour migration (Stark and Bloom 1985;
Taylor 1999), migration systems (Mabogunje 1970; Bakewell 2014) and the aspirations and
capabilities framework (de Haas 2014). Neither fits the label of ‘a theory’ but they encompass several
more focused proffers. For instance, the ‘migration hump’—an empirical relationship between
development and migration that we later discuss in detail (Martin and Taylor 1996)— fits within a
broader notion of migration systems. Similarly, the aspiration/ability model of migration (Carling
2002) is incorporated in the comprehensive aspirations and capabilities framework of migration and
development. In such a multi-layered landscape, ‘theories’ are hardly distinct and countable units.
Moreover, the disciplinary and methodological diversity of migration studies is reflected not only
in diverse elements of theory, but also in diverse ways of using and relating to theory in the research
process. The notion of testing a theory with empirical data is central to some approaches and alien
to others. But in formulating empirically testable propositions, it would be a misstep to exclude
theoretical insights from the latter approaches. For instance, the transnational turn in migration
studies grew out of anthropological and other ethnographic research before being adopted by
researchers that searched for empirical regularities with quantitative methods.
Before setting out our approach to the present the landscape of migration theory, and its relevance
and applicability for the development of empirical propositions and testable hypotheses, a view to
the past is justified. Looking back then, Ravenstein’s ‘laws of migration’ published in the 1880-1890s,
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
3
and more appropriately referred to as hypotheses emanating from empirical observation (Grigg
1977; Samers 2010), were developed in the context of understanding and explaining internal
migration within the UK, but arguably grappled with many of the same issues as contemporary
efforts (Rees and Lomax 2019). Ravenstein’s ideas about the roles of a ‘push-pull’ comparative
evaluation between contexts, has had a profound impact, and found support across empirical
contexts, at a generalised level. His basic, initial hypotheses about migration, first, underscore the
value of a context of reference for theorization efforts which is well-known and where empirical
patterns are readily available and intelligible. Second, Ravenstein’s acknowledgment of the value in
exploring women’s and men’s different, and not always predictably different migration experiences,
illustrates the necessity for differentiation (Samers 2010: 56-57). And, third, the above raises the
question of why today, nearly a century and a half later, the impasse on agreement even about basic
aspects of a migration theory at a grand scale appear to prevail, within the interdisciplinary field of
migration studies.
In the absence of a grand theory, migration scholars have mobilised a wide range of concepts in
efforts to demonstrate and to explain the mechanisms of migration. These mechanisms are
conceptualised in migration theorization which have been developed across social science
disciplines, as well as some humanities disciplines (Brettell and Hollifield 2014; Garip 2012).
Consequently, a fragmented body of migration theorizations has developed, in a sense perpetuating
a self-fulfilling prophecy that the complex, multi-faceted and multi-layered processes of migration
cannot be cast into a comprehensive “grand theory” of migration (Arango 2000).
The fragmentation apparent across this body of existing migration theories is demonstrated and
summarised by some comprehensive reviews (Brettell and Hollifield 2014; Ghatak et al. 1996;
Hagen-Zanker 2008; King 2012; Massey et al. 1993; Morawska 2007). Drawing on these reviews and
our own reading of existing work, we approach this body of work with a problem-oriented focus,
asking how these existing theoretical approaches may explain some forms of contemporary, and
potentially, future forms of migration.
Evidently, our ability as migration researchers to ask the right questions is key to the opportunities
and limitations, which lie in present theorisation efforts. The types of questions which we ask, and
the spatial, temporal, and aggregation scales at which these are anchored reflect our different
disciplines. In the context of an effort to translate migration theory into empirical propositions it is
therefore key to acknowledge that we must understand each theoretical contribution appropriate to
the inner logic of the scientific context it grows out of (Massey et al. 1993: 433). Inspired by previous
efforts to ‘talk across disciplines’ (Brettell and Hollifield 2014) this is also the approach taken in this
paper. Simultaneously, we recognise the opportunities and limitations in our ability to ask the right
questions as impacted not just by our disciplinary or methodological lenses, but also by where in
the world we are based (Portes and DeWind 2008).
In the next section, we further explore the state of migration theory and its conceptual limitations in
grasping the broader picture and propose ‘theoretical triangulation’ as a pragmatic approach for
understanding migration in its multifaceted spatial and temporal manifestations. We then elaborate
on a set of theoretically informed propositions for empirical tests, for use in the empirical evaluation
of theories, factors and drivers, with focus on new temporalities and geographies. This paper
extracts and formulates ten empirically testable propositions. These propositions are based on
empirical evidence and establish stylized facts, useful for further analysis and empirical validation.
A stylized fact must be true in general, but not necessarily in every case or context. For example, it
is a stylized fact that it is not the poorest migrating first, or the most. This is approximately true for
most countries, but it is not exactly true for any country or context. Empirical analyses typically
require operationalization and specifications of various elements in each proposition, and we engage
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
4
with those needs where they are substantively important. However, given the conceptual slant of
this paper, we stop short of practical issues of data availability and methodological considerations
such as research design and model specifications.
2.
What is migration theory?
Migration experts or policy makers refer to migration theory only reluctantly when making claims
or statements about contemporary and future migration. There are several possible reasons for this.
First, there is not one theory of migration but multiple pieces of theory that explain diverse forms or
aspects of migration. In this sense, migration theory can be perceived as fragmented and messy.
Alternative approaches are sometimes conflicting in their assumptions and claims, and they often
explain only specific forms or features of the observed phenomenon. Consequently, migration
theory is a toolbox where those interested in understanding migration as a complex social
phenomenon are referred to in order to choose the best fitting concept for explaining certain forms
or manifestations of migration. The untidiness of migration theory is not a flaw, but rather reflects
the nature of migration processes. It would be futile seek universal ‘laws’ of migration that can be
used for prediction in a nomological fashion (Bijak and Czaika 2020).
The meaning of ‘migration theory’ is not self-evident. In fact, both the ‘migration’ and the ‘theory’
parts of the term are open to different perspectives. In terms of thematic scope, we can differentiate
between migration theory in the narrow sense of explaining migration outcomes and in a broader sense
of also explaining the consequences of migration for societies of origin and destination, and for the
people who migrate (cf. White and Woods 1980, King 2020). The two sometimes overlap, as in the
case of neoclassical theory that sees migration as a response to wage differentials and therefore
predicts a convergence of wage levels as a result of migration (Lewis 1954). Our emphasis here,
however, is on migration theory in the narrow sense of explaining migration outcomes. Such theory
should offer answers to the following questions (paraphrased from White and Woods 1980, King
2020):
-
Why does migration occur?
-
Who migrates and who stays?
-
What are the spatial and temporal patterns of migration?
-
How does migration self-perpetuate?
The second word in ‘migration theory’ is far more ambiguous. One seminal definition of theory in
the social sciences is Merton’s (1967:39) reference to ‘logically interconnected sets of propositions
from which empirical uniformities can be derived’. Some migration theory meets this expectation.
Ravenstein’s (1885:199) laws of migration were claims to empirical uniformity, such as ‘each main
current of migration produces a compensating counter-current’. Similarly, the more recent notion of
a ‘migration hump’ postulates a specific empirical pattern of migration in response to economic
development (proposition 7 below). Migration theory of this kind are testable; that is, the general
validity and or context-specific applicability can be empirically verified. New data and empirical
evidence should be compatible with the theory. If propositions of a theory are repeatedly refuted,
the theory must be refined or rejected altogether (Popper 1935, 2005).
But such theoretical claims are the exception rather than the rule in migration studies. Arango (2000)
argues that ‘rather than fulfilling the function of guiding empirical research and providing testable
hypotheses that can be contrasted with facts, existing migration theories are mainly useful for
providing explanations ex-post'. Indeed, migration theory has pursued diverse objectives since its
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
5
infancy. In contrast to Ravenstein’s (1885) laws of migration, Lee’s (1966) theory of migration was as
much a framework for interpreting empirical uniformities. In this sense, his theory resembles what
Rueschemeyer (2009:1) calls theory frames, which ‘guide hypothesis formation but do not themselves
contain or logically entail a body of testable hypotheses’.
More recent theoretical advances in migration studies have also enlightened without implying
particular empirical uniformities. Often, such advances are focused on a concept that opens a new
analytical perspective on a complex reality. Cases in point are ‘transnational social fields’ (Basch et
al. 1996), ‘social remittances’ (Levitt 1998), and ‘migration infrastructure’ (Xiang and Lindquist 2014).
Such elements of theory cannot be empirically ‘tested’ and refuted. However, their usefulness is tried
in the encounter with empirical data. At times, the result is a call for revision or rejection.
Migration theories claim to explain certain aspects of the observable phenomenon of people moving
in time and space, but migration theory - as any theory- shall also allow predictions of the future in
migration trends and outcomes if the theoretical account is true. However, the fact that not any of
the established migration theories is capable in explaining all forms of migration – they do not even
claim to do so - does not suggest that existing ‘partial’ migration theories are wrong and must be
rejected due to their limited explanatory scope. Rather, migration theories are to be contextualised,
and where possible, combined to bridge the gap between theoretical assumptions, conceptual
claims, and empirical observation.
Theoretical accounts are inherently limited in addressing the complex interplay of economic, social,
political, environmental, and technological factors configuring context-specific migration driveroutcome relationships. However, the existence of multiple causal configurations of migration
drivers and mechanisms does not imply that different theories are mutually exclusive. Quite the
opposite, neoclassical income-maximizing migration (Harris and Todaro 1970) may simultaneously
be a form of migration that seeks to diversify risks (cf. new economics of labour migration, Stark
1991) and relies on social network and cumulative causation theory along the way (Garip 2012,
Massey 1990). In this sense, different elements of migration theory can be combined to provide
composite explanations.
Several accounts of migration theory have also stressed the distinction in how a theory relates to the
theoretical landscape within which it is set, either in actively seeking integration with other theories,
or operating as a standalone entity (Samers 2010). The fragmented body of theories, which seek to
provide explanations and generalisable insight about the causes, dynamics and impact of migration,
are inherently interdisciplinary in nature. Thus, the weight given from the outset to economic, social,
cultural, religious, or political factors that might affect migration aspirations, decision-making and
actual migration journeys, is also different.
Migration studies is an interdisciplinary field, and migration theory reflects this diversity. However,
there is a risk of exaggerating the importance of disciplines as such. It is common for migration
scholars to draw upon literature from multiple disciplines and many works in interdisciplinary
teams or institutions. Moreover, much migration research is published in interdisciplinary journals,
including the more than 40 journals that specialize in migration studies (Pisarevskaya et al. 2019).
The leading textbook on migration theory (Brettell and Hollifield 2014) is nevertheless organized by
discipline. Its ambition to foster dialogue across disciplinary boundaries is unquestionably fruitful,
but the presentation of each discipline’s dominant approach can at times seem caricatured. An image
of researchers from various disciplines approaching migration with ‘their own theories’ about
migration is only partially true. But there is great disciplinary variation in how researchers engage
with theory in their work. The insistence on testable hypotheses, for instance, is extraneous to the
research of anthropologists and many other qualitatively oriented researchers in other social
sciences (Boyer et al. 2015).
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
6
Across disciplines, the appreciation both for the complexity of migration processes, and for the need
of multiple angles in order to make sense of them, is evident. How to marry the insights from across
the interdisciplinary field of migration studies concretely, and in empirically researchable ways,
remains less clear-cut.
However, one might, by contrast, start from categories of migrants, leaning on labelling actively
used by nation-states in the governance of migration, and by humanitarian actors concerned with
the protection of human life, thereby e.g. considering terms such as refugees, IDPs, persons subject
to modern slavery, those trafficked or exposed to human smuggling, and probably also students and
(temporary) labour migrants, whether high-or-low skilled. A further approach, proposed by Samers
and Collyer (2016: 8), appears more fruitful, in both recognizing that migrant lives rarely fit squarely
into the boxes which categories offer, but simultaneously, that categorisation is nonetheless
necessary, for the study of migration:
Migrants seem to fit both into and across different types or categories of migration that
imply a certain citizenship or residency status (e.g. internal or international, temporary
and permanent, legal and undocumented), and different modes of entry (e.g. as asylumseekers, refugees, low-income and highly skilled workers, students, and so on). Concerning
their mode of entry, they may also be classified by academics, policymakers, or
statisticians as ‘forced’ or ‘voluntary’. Given the apparent fluidity of migrant lives across
these different categories and modes of entry, it has now become common in migration
studies to reject the significance of categorizations in some cases (e.g. Faist 2008;
Richmond 2002).
The contextualization of migration theory suggests that the applicability of theoretical claims and
propositions is conditional to the time-, location-, and group-specific circumstances and
characteristics. Massey and Taylor (2004) have identified as a major step in advancing migration
research “the testing of various theoretical explanations comparatively to determine which ones
prevail under what circumstances and why” (p.384) as a major step in advancing migration research.
This suggests that any attempt to explain or predict migration must identify the most relevant and
best fitting theory or theories for accounting variations in the number, rate, forms and characteristics
of migration patterns over space and time. In this context, it becomes especially salient to pay
attention to the nature of migration flows at the individual level. For instance, we know that ‘the
feminization of labour migration’ is a core trait of contemporary migration dynamics (Castles et al.
2013), underscoring a need for attention to gender in empirical, and therefore also, theoretical terms.
Similarly, ethnic, religious, sexual or other minority status, as well as political dissident roles, are
other key traits that may at the individual (or group) level trump other key variables in
understanding migration dynamics and must therefore also be accounted for.
The ‘transnational turn’ in the 1990s, where transnational social spaces, constituted by the ties which
migrants forged and maintained between places of residence and of origin, played a central role in
migration studies (Pries 1996, Portes et al. 1999). The 2010s have similarly seen what is referred to as
a ‘temporal turn’ in migration studies, foregrounding the different ways in which time – as
chronological time, but also as experienced and narrated – profoundly impact migration processes
(Griffiths et al. 2013). Meanwhile, it may be argued that neither the spatial nor the temporal
dimensions of migration, which are being explored, have to date influenced migration theories in
ways that reflect their overall relevance and potentially also contribution to explanations of
migration. Given the proliferation of work, both referencing transnationalism and temporalities, this
might be a surprising claim. Nevertheless, plausibly because both these bodies of work encompass
the complexity of migration – across space and over time – meaningful incorporation into e.g.
economically framed theories foregrounding wage differentials, is not straightforward.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
7
3. Propositions
The following ten propositions state in a declarative form tentative and conjectural relationships
between established driver constructs and specific forms and features of migration – with migration
always as the phenomenon to be explained. The selection of themes for the ten propositions has been
informed by their relative prominence in policy debates as well as their salience in more recent
migration scholarship. We hereby consider these propositions and the underlying hypotheses
plausible but also contestable. This means that all propositions refer to a substantive but nonconclusive body of empirical work with an explicit need and potential for future research that may
bring a stronger evidence base on the subject. But these propositions have also been selected for their
analytical relevance in assessing future migration scenarios which at the same time ensures their
relevance for forward-looking policymaking.
3.1
Migration flows reflect pre-existing connections between countries
Whereas international migration is often approached both as an exception to otherwise sedentary
norms, and as separate from pre-existing connections between countries, in fact, migration flows to
a large extent reflect long-standing connections. Such pre-existing connections refer to ties of
different nature, such as trade, or ties connected to a different period in time, such as a colonial past,
or these pre-existing connections might take the form of linguistic or ethno-cultural commonalities,
but also quite simply of geographic proximity regionally between countries.
In part reflecting an enduring presentism in migration research (Schmidt 2017), much attention is
given to relatively recent transnational social fields, which are the result of international migration
flows and ensuing transnational connections (Lubbers et al. 2020). However, considering global
migration patterns, and despite diversification of migration destinations, which include increasing
South-South migration, it remains true that ‘the former colonial past continues to play a role’
(Hooghe et al. 2008: 502). Former colonial powers, such as Spain and Portugal, France and the UK,
continue to see migration patterns, which also reflect this history of former colonial connections.
While it might be tempting to equate such former connections between countries simply with past
human mobility, other kinds of pre-existing connections, whether or not part of colonial legacies,
also matter (Morawska 2007). More often than not, such pre-existing connections might include
migration, which is embedded within a larger tapestry of ties, where economic, as well as political
ties play mutually constitutive roles. Taking the example of the history of Chinese intra-Asian
migrations, Zhou and Benton (2017) place the history of Chinese diasporas not only in the context
of, but as inextricably tied to, the formations of economic and political connections between and,
significantly, on behalf of states over time.
Trade has historically been a crucial driver of connections across geographic distances, where the
migration of people has often been both instrumental to – and entirely framed by it. Meanwhile, also
political and geopolitical considerations have shaped ties between countries, which may be seen in
the roles they play as pre-existing connections reflected in current migration flows. Indeed, when
considering ‘human geopolitics’ (Gamlen 2019), it is hard to imagine the leverage which current
migration might have, without its firm anchoring in different forms and degrees of pre-existing
connections between countries, set within the context of global and regional power hierarchies.
Considering pre-exiting connections between countries, and how they shape current migration
flows, it is necessary to recognise that the movement of nation-state borders themselves, both
happens and has an impact on patterns of migration seen today (Gorodzeisky and Leykin 2020).
Whether considering post-colonial Africa, or the array of border movements in Europe in the past
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
8
century, it is evident that the ways in which pre-existing ties shape present migration, are tempered
by the location of countries’ borders over time. Unsurprisingly therefore, linguistic and ethnocultural ties, across borders, which spur ‘ethnic return’ for instance, are a significant component of
how pre-existing connections produce present-day migration flows, even before longer historical
lines are considered (Mylonas and Žilović 2019).
The impact of pre-existing connections between countries on migration flows and patterns,
necessitates a focus methodologically beyond the present, but also beyond a focus explicitly on
migrants in migration studies (Dahinden 2016).
3.2
Migration flows beyond a certain threshold become self-sustaining
While much migration theory focuses on individual-level migration decision-making, the salience
of the meso-level and collectives to which migrants belong, are well evidenced for both destinationchoices and migration decision-making (Banerjee 1983; Boyd 1989; Massey et al. 1993). The
phenomenon of ‘chain migration’ has been empirically observed over time across different contexts,
where kinship-based and location-specific social networks contribute to self-sustaining migration
flows, often in a specific migration corridor (Choldin 1973; Eurenius 2020; MacDonald and
MacDonald 1964; Shah and Menon 1999). The role of migration becoming self-perpetuating, has
been theorized in terms of cumulative causation (Massey et al. 1993; Fussell 2010).
The roles of social networks in migration processes usually emphasises the roles of family members,
extended family, kinship group or co-ethnics in the locations of both destination and of origin. The
roles of social networks in decision-making about migration have been hypothesized to manifest
through affinity, information, facilitation, conflict and encouragement (Haug 2008: 589). The strength and
nature of ties in places of destination, as well as in places of origin, temper the effects of social
networks for migration decision-making – for both initial and subsequent return or onward
movement (Massey et al. 1993; Ryan 2011).
The initial stage of migration, which might become chain migration, fuelled by social networks, is
often referred to as pioneer migration (Bakewell et al. 2012; Wessendorff 2019), and is sometimes
dominated by migrants from a more elite background, with more education or social capital, often
in the form of connections (Poros 2001; Friberg 2012). The different stages of migration that may
become a self-sustaining chain-migration flow, typically involve a sequence from pioneers, who by
virtue of remaining part of social networks with people in places of origin, and elsewhere,
subsequently play a role in the sustained migration from the same areas of origin to the same areas
of destination (Paasche 2020).
Given that the conditions for chain-migration in legal and structural ways are in place, such as e.g.
was the case for a long time from Mexico to the US, from Turkey to Germany, and from a number
of newly independent colonies to the UK and France, once such chain migration gains force – in
volume and speed of growth – its momentum is arguable self-sustaining, for a period of time.
Depending on the regulation of mobility, where free intra-EU mobility offers a very different
structural background, to that of international migration between most other states globally, chain
migration may be more or less encouraged, or constrained by nation-states (Massey and Espinosa
1997; Wolf 2016).
While the emphasis in the context of migration flows becoming self-sustaining is often on specific
migration corridors, such as from a region of country of origin x, to a region in country of destination
y, such migration corridors are often embedded within multi-sited transnational networks (Caarls
et al. 2020; Lubbers et al. 2020). The roles of migrants’ social networks in creating and sustaining
migration to particular destination locations, whether cities, regions or even countries, holds some
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
9
key similarities with mechanisms which enable migration, referred to as the ‘migration industry’,
facilitating, enabling or brokering migration (Fernandez 2013; Lindquist et al. 2012; Spaan and van
Naerssen 2018). Thus, the roles of migrant networks – as well as institutions (formal or informal) –
across contexts of origin, destination and beyond, play a part in contributing to make certain
migration flows self-sustaining (Massey et al. 1993; Fussell 2010).
3.3
Migrants are outnumbered by involuntary non-migrants
Fewer than 4 per cent of the global population are international migrants, living outside their
country of birth. However, a higher proportion of people would have migrated if they had the
opportunity. These individuals, who remain despite their preference to leave, are involuntary nonmigrants (Carling 2002). Data on migration aspirations, intentions and plans have proliferated over
the past decade or two. It is now possible to say with considerable certainty that the number of
involuntary non-migrants is at least twice the number of migrants worldwide (Esipova et al. 2015,
Laczko et al. 2017, Clemens and Mendola 2020).
The extent of involuntary immobility matter for the explanation, modelling and prediction of
migration. If actual migration is just the tip of the iceberg of migration desires, then the limiting
factor is the ability to migrate (Carling 2002). Consequently, the size of migration flows will be
determined primarily by changes in the obstacles to migration. Obstacles first and foremost take the
form of legal restrictions on migration; their effect depend on the regulations in their own right as
well as their implementation and the opportunities for circumventing them (cf Czaika and de Haas
2013). In some cases, these obstacles represent a credit constraint, as when large amounts of money
are needed to pay smugglers or other intermediaries.
Even if migrants are outnumbered by involuntary non-migrants worldwide, this does not hold true
for every country of origin and every population segment. For instance, the dynamics of migration
aspirations and actual migration are stratified by education levels (Docquier et al. 2014).
Identifying involuntary non-migrants requires survey data. The amount of data has swelled and
now include several multi-round multi-country surveys as well as specialized surveys from various
parts of the world. 1 However, conceptual and methodological challenges remain. The value of
existing data is often hampered by haphazard formulations in survey instruments (Carling and
Schewel 2018, Carling 2019). Future empirical work would benefit from a stronger conceptual and
methodological foundation. 2
3.4
Migrants with fewer resources make more fragmented, intricate and
unpredictable journeys
Key migration theories seek to explain why people migrate, foregrounding specific drivers or
composite sets of drivers (Czaika and Reinprecht 2020). Meanwhile, the question of how migration
can and does take place, has also received some attention, exploring question both of how migration
is financed and in practice realised, but also of where people migrate. In particular, research sought
to understand how migration destinations are chosen (Brunarska 2019; Neumayer 2004). Here, the
implications of permanent vs. temporary migration durations has been found to make a difference
See QuantMig deliverable 2.1 (in preparation, due 2021).
Developing such a foundation is central to the ongoing ERC-funded project Future Migration as Present
Fact (www.prio.org/fumi)
1
2
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
10
(Liu and Xu 2017). Interest in migration management and migration control, has also contributed to
an emphasis on how migration is realised, in addition to the question of why, using concepts such
as ‘migration infrastructures’ as vehicles for multifaceted engagements with how migration comes
about (Lindquist et al. 2012; Xiang and Lindquist 2014).
The relationship between resources available to migrants, and the distance and duration of
migration journeys, is well-captured by the title of a much-cited contribution to debates on how
class, capital and migration are interconnected: ‘I went as far as my money would take me’ (Van Hear
2006). These links are rather intuitive yet have only to a limited extent been central to empirical
investigations of migration. This is perhaps in part due to a pre-occupation with drivers at a massgeneralised scale, and perhaps in part due to challenges with access to baseline data which might
easily offer opportunities of analysing prospective and actual migrants’ capital endowments of
various kinds systematically.
Nevertheless, the basic insight that there is a relationship between resources, migration journeys and
destinations holds. This is reflected in labour migration patterns from South Asia to the Gulf states,
where the direction of migration to particular locations is based on specific resources, which in this
case grant the possibility of participating in highly regulated temporary labour migration schemes.
Conversely, it is probably even more strongly reflected in patterns of internal migration, such as
where female migrants travel to cities to find employment as domestic workers.
Meanwhile, qualitative research offers much insight into the fragmentation of migrant journeys,
indicative of how migration actually happens, often allowing for time and opportunity to
accumulate further needed resources along the way (Schapendonk et al. 2020). Migration journeys
come with a cost, and migrants with different types of human capital may therefore plan for
stepwise migration, toward their destination of preference (Paul 2011). Other research also
demonstrates the same dynamics at work, in the context of onward migration of third country
nationals upon naturalisation in one EU country, to another (Ahrens et al. 2016; Hoon et al. 2020;
Moret 2016). An important insight from these studies is that the distinction between migration which
may be associated with particular drivers including conflict, in relation to the degree of
fragmentation of migration journeys, becomes extremely elusive (Erdal and Oeppen 2018).
International student migration, which has tripled in volume since the year 2000 (King and
Raghuram 2013), further illustrates the connections between resources and complex migration
trajectories. Student migration both has the prerequisite of own or family resources to invest in
higher education, and the inherent possibility of becoming a long-term investment in mobility
capital if the student upon completion of the degree remains in the country of study, and is able to
naturalise and acquire a ‘stronger passport’ in mobility and residence-rights terms, e.g. such as a
European or US citizenship. The example of student migration combines migration where a driver
is the pursuit of education, with a reality where migration simultaneously may also be conceived of
as a stepwise strategy, of going as far as resources allow, in order to accrue further resources, in this
case in the form of human capital. As such, student migration illustrates how access to resources
affects the type and degree of fragmentation of migration journeys over time, but also how
fragmented migration journeys also reflect relationships between amount of resources and
accessible migration pathways.
3.5
Environmental stress separates populations into trapped and
mobilised groups
Climate change and environmental degradation has multiple implications on people’s livelihoods.
Environmental change in its multidimensional manifestations causes stressful situations for a
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
11
growing population around the globe affecting people’s necessity, willingness and ability to
migrate. Environmental change forms a predisposing factor that makes population movements
increasingly likely in the longer term, while more sudden events have the potential to trigger
immediate and large-scale internal displacements but may also force people to permanently move
abroad (Black et al. 2011; Shen and Binns 2012; Martin et al. 2014; Veronis and McLeman 2014; Islam
2018). Spatial disparities in the availability of natural resources such as fertile soil, woodland or
freshwater may establish a migration-conducive context. Detrimental effects of climate change as
well as sudden environmental shocks, such as earthquakes, droughts, or floods, destroy gradually
or rapidly livelihoods and may lead to food insecurity and scarcity. Environmental shocks may also
detrimentally affect public health systems due to flooding and power shortages (Kishore et al. 2018).
Climate change as a predisposing driver of both internal and international migration is extensively
studied (Migali et al. 2018). Studies find that slow-onset changes in temperatures and precipitation
are associated with emigration, particularly from more agricultural countries and rural areas
(Backhaus et al. 2015; Bohra-Mishra et al. 2014; Cai et al. 2016; Nawrotzki et al. 2015). However, if
climatic factors are evaluated alongside economic factors, the latter’s effects are often stronger
(Joseph and Wodon 2013), and several studies suggest that climate change does not directly
influence migration (Abu et al. 2014; Beinebe and Parsons 2015; Codjoe et al. 2017; Mortreux and
Barnett 2009). Climate change affects migration primarily by its impact on economic factors
including agricultural incomes, livelihood opportunities, or food security (Martin et al. 2014;
Khavarian-Garmsir et al. 2019), health-related risks (Marchiori et al. 2012), or resource scarcity and
conflict (Abel et al. 2019). At the same time, environmentally stressful situations often affect the
poorest and financially constrained most adversely, which often increases their inability to move
(Veronis and McLeman 2014). Migration as an adaptation strategy is often not available for a poorly
resourced population, with the effect of a rapidly growing global population trapped in deprived
and vulnerable situations (Black et al. 2011; Cattaneo et al. 2019).
Besides gradually worsening environmental conditions, sudden environmental shocks such as
floods, storms, droughts, or earthquakes may also trigger large-scale displacements. Natural
disasters predominantly lead to internal, and to a lesser extent, to international migration (Beine and
Parsons 2015; Islam 2018; World Food Program 2017). Disaster-induced migration is often
temporary (Mallick and Vogt 2014), and sometimes indirectly driven by resource conflicts (Naudé
2010). Sudden onset disasters are often the underlying cause for the deterioration of more proximate
economic drivers, such as deprivation, loss of assets, and joblessness (Warner et al. 2010; Wodon et
al. 2014). In surveys, respondents often refer to economic factors, such as wages and market
inaccessibility, as reasons for migration; even though the underlying cause, however, may be a
gradual or sudden environmental deterioration (Afifi 2011).
Overall, the relationship between environmentally induced deprivation and migration is complex
but bifurcated. While some people have the capacity and are willing to move outside risk zones,
most others who are vulnerable and impoverished must stay put. Adversely affected people are
often involuntary immobile due to a lack of resources, but also aspirations, information, or other
factors that limit their ability to move (Carling 2002; Schewel 2019). Not all immobility in the context
of environmental stress is involuntary though but can be self-determined. Reasons mentioned are a
variety of factors, such as place attachment (Adams and Kay 2019; Nawrotzki and DeWaard 2018),
family responsibilities (Schewel and Fransen 2020), or care for assets.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
12
3.6
Violent conflict causes short-distance migration, often followed by
geographically dispersed secondary migration
Civil, ethnic, or religious conflicts and violations of human rights are known as key drivers of
involuntary and forced migration including displaced persons such as asylum seekers, refugees,
irregular migrants, unaccompanied migrant minors, and internally displaced persons (IDPs). Safety
and security concerns usually do not immediately trigger out-migration as it may be unsafe to
prepare for exit or individuals anticipate and hope for an improving security situation. But once
insecurity and life-threatening situations surpass a certain tolerance level, people consider
emigration or flight as the last available option for survival (Bohra-Mishra and Massey 2011).
Individuals often migrate (or flee) due to direct or indirect exposure to violence but also more
generic feelings of insecurity and danger for life (Lundquist and Massey 2005; van Wijk 2010). A
plethora of qualitative and quantitative studies implemented at the micro and more aggregated
levels have investigated the link between different measures of insecurity in sending countries and
out-migration (Castles et al. 2013; Correa-Velez et al. 2017; Davenport et al. 2003; Hagen-Zanker and
Mallett 2016; Hatton 2004; McAuliffe 2017; Migali et al. 2018; Moore and Shellman 2007, 2004;
Ruyssen and Rayp 2014). However, the complex nexus between conflict and migration is not fully
explored yet. Specifically, not all forms and contexts of violent conflicts trigger large-scale
emigration, the best contemporary example is the conflict and scale of refugee movements from
Syria compared to conflict situations in Yemen or Eritrea. While about a quarter of the Syrian
population (about 5.6 million people) has fled from Syria since 2011, only about 10 per cent in the
case of Eritrea and even a smaller fraction of Yemen’s population has been able to leave for seeking
refuge abroad (UNHCR 2020).
A majority of the forcefully displaced persons and refugees relocate - often only temporarily - within
their home country and only a minority and self-selected group of the primarily younger, male, and
better endowed and educated people (can) move abroad. Distance and costs of moving play an
important role in most forms of migration but, in particular, for refugees with limited choice
regarding domestic or international destinations. For most refugees, it is neighbouring countries that
are predominantly providing a first safe place which most (even though not all) people in need of
protection can or aspire to reach. It is therefore these geographically proximate first countries of
asylum that usually absorb between 80 and 90 percent of those who flee their home country often
with the intention to return as soon as the situation allows (Moore and Shellman 2007).
Contemporarily, most “new” forcibly displaced persons seeking protection have moved across the
border from their home country in conflict to a neighbouring country, such as Syrians to Turkey,
South Sudanese to Sudan, or Congolese to Uganda (UNHCR 2020). Only a small, albeit increasing
fraction of those who seek refuge outside their home country travel longer distances for claiming
asylum in Western destinations. A key characteristic of the global refugee distribution is its
concentration by origin and destination, respectively, that is the very limited number of countries
(or sometimes even regions within countries) where refugees are coming from, but also the relatively
small number of destinations where they are seeking protection.
War and conflict drive involuntary displacements also indirectly through their effects on the
functioning of the public infrastructure, availability of economic opportunities, and sustainability of
livelihoods (Khavarian-Garmsir et al. 2019). While conflict and violence may directly predispose and
trigger migration, conflict as such is often mediated or reinforced by its detrimental impact on
economic, environmental or political factors (Moore and Shellman 2004; Naudé 2010). Refugees and
other conflict-displaced persons often share similar motivations with other types of migrants. Like
economic migrants, refugees are concerned about economic opportunities and employment,
sustainable livelihoods, and prospects for their children. Migration decisions are decisions taken
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
13
under risk and uncertainty, but in conflict and life-threatening situations, insecurity creates
additional emotional stress that diminishes the role and relative importance of other socioeconomic
factors. In such situations, the decision whether and where to migrate to depends on people’s risk
and insecurity perceptions, emotional resilience, and attitudes towards uncertain outcomes (Czaika
2015).
3.7
Emigration rises with economic development until a certain level and
thereafter falls
It would seem logical that when incomes rise in poor countries, more people prefer to stay rather
than emigrate. However, there is compelling evidence of the opposite. Emigration appears to rise
with national income in low- and lower-middle-income countries, creating an inverted U-shaped
relationship between economic development and emigration. Based on census and register data on
migrant stocks 1960–2010, Clemens (2014) estimated that the turning point is a per capita purchasing
power that corresponds to around 7000–8000 USD.
The proposition of an inverted U-curve is an aspect of migration transitions and holds a central place
in migration theory (de Haas 2010; Hatton and Williamson 2005; Martin and Taylor 1996; Zelinsky
1971). The theoretical relationship has been buttressed by the image of middle-income countries
such as Mexico, Morocco and the Philippines as emigration countries par excellence. In the early
1990s, Philip Martin popularized the idea of a ‘migration hump’ in his predictions about the impacts
of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). He concluded that “NAFTA is likely to
produce a temporary migration hump, slightly raising already high migration levels in the 1990s,
but reducing the volume of Mexico-to-U.S. migration that would otherwise occur over subsequent
decades” (Martin 1993, p. 329). Still, the conviction that economic development will stem migration,
especially in poor societies, has been entrenched in policy circles (Collyer 2019).
There are several reasons for the counterintuitive upward-sloping curve at lower income levels
(Clemens 2014; de Haas 2010; Lucas 2005). Most are rooted in all the other societal changes that tend
to accompany economic growth. First, emigration may be spawned by the demographic transition,
which, in early stages, produces large cohorts of young adults. Second, even as average incomes
grow, traditional labour-intensive sectors, especially agriculture, may provide shrinking livelihoods
and free up large numbers of potential migrants. Third, economic development tends to produce
greater inequality, especially in early stages of growth. The result can be that, for much of the
population, the reference level of a decent income rises faster than their actual income. This
experience of relative deprivation could be a powerful driver of emigration (Czaika and de Haas
2012). In addition to rising local inequality, increasing exposure to media and social media can spur
awareness of differences and relative deprivation. In other words, the reference group against which
people assess their own lives could shift away from the local community.
Analyses of migration drivers call for a breakdown of effects on the aspiration and the ability to
migrate (Carling 2002; Carling and Schewel 2018). Experiences of relative deprivation increase only
the appeal of migration; they do not make migration more feasible. However, other aspects of
economic development do. Economists have stressed the easing of credit constraints, meaning that
with higher average incomes, more people can afford the initial investment in migrating. Moreover,
at higher levels of economic development, higher levels of education could increase opportunities
for employment abroad.
The proposition that emigration from low- and middle-income countries rises with economic
development could potentially be challenged in two ways. First, one could imagine crude empirical
results to the contrary. That is, analyses of income and emigration levels could show a pattern that
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
14
undermines the idea of a hump. In a recent paper, using long time series of global data, however,
Clemens and Mendola (2020) finds that the expected relationship is robust to a variation in
measures, samples, time periods and model specifications.
A second way of challenging the migration hump would be to undercut the appropriateness of
‘economic development’ as the independent variable. The problem with this measure, of course, is
that it is simultaneously a clear-cut individual variable and a proxy for complex societal changes.
With relevant additional data, it is possible to decompose the relationship and examine diverse
corollaries of rising income (Clemens and Mendola 2020). However, econometrics alone might not
resolve the epistemological and pedagogical challenges of explaining how migration evolves with
the societal transformations subsumed under the term ‘development’.
3.8
Development aid can deter emigration from low- and middle-income
countries
‘It has often been suggested that […] aid, trade and investment could be utilized to influence
migration pressures in major sending countries’ wrote Morrison (1982, p. 4) almost four decades
ago. The strategic deployment of aid to curb migration remains an appealing prospect to many
policy makers—with added emphasis and funding in the wake of the 2015 migration and refugee
crisis. The merits of aid as a migration policy tool has been continuously contested, with
disagreement revolving around two core issues: is such a strategy ethically and politically
justifiable? Moreover, can it ever work? Even if the strategy affects migration, it could be hard to
justify as a humanitarian one if it, for instance, means diverting aid from the countries where it is
needed the most or would have the greatest impact on development (Bakewell 2008; Carling and
Talleraas 2016; Collyer 2019). Here we address only the issue of effectiveness, captured in the
proposition that development aid can deter emigration from low- and middle-income countries.
However, assessing this claim with sufficient nuance is also a prerequisite for considering the ethical
and political implications.
The reasoning behind this proposition is that international aid can stimulate development, which in
turn reduces the incentives to emigrate. Since the 1980s, it has been rejected primarily on two
grounds. First, international aid is claimed to have limited effect on development (Marchal et al.
2020; Morrison 1982). That is, even if individual programs are deemed successful, they are unlikely
to sway the development trajectory of a country and thereby affect the drivers of migration. Second,
it is claimed that development in poor countries tends to raise rather than lower emigration
(Berthelemy et al. 2009; Clemens and Postel 2018a; Faini and Venturini 1993). Such an effect of
development on migration is exactly what proposition 7 above asserts. Yet, the two propositions are
independent of each other. Even if the migration hump hypothesis (proposition 7) holds true, certain
forms of aid might affect migration in other ways than via impacts on overall economic
development.
It is necessary at the outset to disaggregate ‘aid’. Development assistance is extremely diverse in
objectives and implementation. For instance, Lanati and Thiele (2020) point out that 20–25% of
official development assistance is spent within the donor’s borders as ‘non-transferred aid’. By
excluding this category, they find a modest but significant negative effect of aid transfers on
emigration rates. The diversity of in-country targets and objectives suggest that different
programmes or funding mechanisms will have diverging consequences for migration. It could also
matter how the aid is organized in term of national origins. Inflows of development aid are partly
bilateral and partly multilateral, with potentially different impacts (Azam and Berlinschi 2009;
Marchal et al. 2020). In the case of bilateral aid, it is an open question whether aid from, say,
Germany, affects migration to Germany any differently from migration to other destinations
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
15
(Berthelemy et al. 2009; Lanati and Thiele 2018c).
The economics literature—which dominates research on the aid-migration relationship—has
identified several possible channels, or mechanisms, through which aid could have an effect on
migration (Lanati and Thiele 2018b; Marchal et al. 2020). However, they have often muddled or
overlooked relevant insights from migration theory. First, there needs to be a fundamental
distinction between effects on the aspiration to migrate and effects on the ability to migrate. Even if the
ultimate goal is to explain migration flows, the impact of a determinant such as aid can only be
understood by disaggregating the two types of effect (Carling 2002; Carling and Schewel 2018). In
fact, when aid has no observable effect on migration flows, the reasons might be that effects on
aspiration and ability are cancelling each other out. With this in mind, and drawing upon migration
theory more broadly, we can identify several mechanisms through which inflows of development
aid could affect migration either positively or negatively:
The destination appeal mechanism: Inflows of aid could boost the recognition and prestige of donor
countries—or high-income countries more generally—as migration destinations. Not only are
overseas contributions often acknowledged in the media, inauguration events and the like, but many
national development agencies have branding requirements that are reflected in signage such as
“UK aid - from the British people” on infrastructure, assets, and handouts. Such multi-channel
promotional messaging could plausibly have a positive effect on migration aspirations.
The migration resource mechanism: Development aid could potentially raise prospective migrants'
ability to migrate by adding to the resources that are required to overcome obstacles to migration.
A case in point is relaxing credit constraints, as development economists have pointed out (Clemens
and Postel 2018b; Faini and Venturini 1993; Marchal et al. 2020). But, depending on the context, the
bottlenecks are typically policy-driven rather than financial. Aid could provide significant resources
via human capital formation and employment that increases the prospect of obtaining a visa
(Gaibazzi 2014; Infantino and Rea 2012).
The bridgehead mechanism: When bilateral aid is accompanied by deepening social, economic, and
political ties, migration can become more feasible (Clemens and Postel 2018a; Morrison 1982).
Personal connections, short-term travelling, exchange programs, and the like can reduce the
obstacles to migration. The direct link from development cooperation to migration can be clear in
individual cases. However, if there is a broader deepening of bilateral ties, migration and aid could
both be implicated in ways that make it hard to disentangle causal effects.
The opportunity cost mechanism: The migration decision is always a comparative one, in the sense that
the expected outcome of migrating must be related to the expected outcome of staying. This is, at
least, the essence of proposition 3 above. If aid enhances the scenario of staying, the opportunity cost
of migration increases, and migration aspirations decline. Development might have such an effect
in specific ways. For instance, Angelucci (2004) shows that a programme of secondary-school
subsidies reduces the migration propensity of participants in the short term. Similarly, Gamso and
Yuldashev (2018) find that emigration can be reduced by investments in agricultural capacity
building. In terms of broader societal changes, improvement in public services could improve the
appeal of staying and lower migration outflows (Lanati and Thiele 2018a). Similar effects are
plausible if aid has a tangible impact on corruption levels.
Policy leverage mechanism: Aid transfers give donor countries bargaining power that can produce
policy concessions that make migration control more effective. A case in point is making aid
conditional upon readmission agreements, which facilitate the removal of unauthorized migrants
and possibly dissuade future migration attempts (Cassarino 2009; Lavenex 2006) This is perhaps the
mechanism that most persuasively links aid to a reduction in migration. Ironically, it is completely
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
16
independent of development dynamics.
Beyond these five specific mechanisms, there are residual and indirect ways in which aid could affect
migration through broader societal changes, such as increasing levels of inequality and an
accompanying rise in life aspirations. These are perhaps less pertinent because development aid will
at most be a contributing factor to such fundamental transformation.
The proposition that development aid can deter emigration from low- and middle-income countries
remains rightfully contested. Research to date makes it impossible to confirm or reject outright, and
only gives pointers as to when it might hold true. Future research should examine the diversity of
mechanisms by breaking down the overall proposition into specific hypotheses.
3.9
Migration policies on their own are ineffective in producing desired
outcomes
The effectiveness of migration policies is continuously contested even though most migrants travel
through legal channels and abide to immigration regulations. A growing number of quantitative
studies indicate that immigration restrictions have a statistically significant deterrence effect on
migrant inflows (Hatton 2004; Mayda 2010; Ortega and Peri 2013, Czaika and de Haas 2017).
Scholars do not disagree about the stylized fact that restrictive migration policies adversely affect
immigration flows, but to what extent, and under what circumstances, pre-and post-entry
restrictions shape the volume, dynamic, direction, and the degree of legality of cross-border
movements.
Empirical evaluation of this proposition requires that policy effects can be measured and adequately
assessed, and for this purpose, multiple methodological challenges including the definition,
specification, and operationalisation of migration policies must be resolved. Migration policy
analyses can have a range of reference points for evaluating migration outcomes. For instance,
whether we evaluate migration outcomes against non-binding rhetorical claims or goals of some
policymakers, or policy objectives as stated in legislative provisions and executive orders, or policies
as implemented on the ground, has fundamental implications on the assessment of their
effectiveness. Also, whether the object of investigation is a specific policy instrument targeting for
instance a particular form of migration, or some ad hoc (one-off) interventions, or broader regulatory
frameworks and reform packages can have major implications on actual magnitude (Czaika and de
Haas 2013). Also, the effect size of a particular migration policy instrument is conditional upon
mediating migration drivers including other policies of the broader policy mix.
A further challenge is the identification of the intertemporal dynamics of causal relationship
between migration policy outcomes and effects on migration outcomes, in particular, the
responsiveness and sustainability of certain policy effects. Policy effects may unfold anytime
between instantly (or even before implementation if policy changes are expected by potential
migrants) and long after the policy change took place. Therefore, before-after assessments of policy
effects should not only focus on the immediate effects on migration outcomes but consider also the
long-term implications including both some “knock-on” effects on other than the targeted migration
forms. Moreover, endogeneity of migration policies, that is the fact that (expected or actual)
migration outcomes influence the formation and adaptation of migration policy goals, designs, and
their implementation, are to be considered when assessing their effectiveness.
Besides migration policies that aim to deter unwanted immigration, policies for attracting and
selecting certain types of migrants such as skilled workers or students are increasingly implemented
in most Westerns and many non-Western economies (Czaika and Parsons 2017). Despite the
continuous rise in the number of skilled and highly skilled migrants worldwide and the proliferation
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
17
of skill-selective migration policies, the degree to which such policies are truly effective is still
contested (Bhagwati and Hanson 2009). Doomernik et al. (2009) argue that the potential of attracting
high-skilled migrants in large numbers rather depend upon broader economic and social factors
than on immigration policies per se. Migrants in general, but highly skilled in particular, value a
myriad of factors such as the standard of living, the quality of schools, health services, and
infrastructure, and the presence of a well-established professional network (Papademetriou et al.
2008). Skill-selective migration and other public policies are only forming part of a broader
‘immigration package’ (Papademetriou et al. 2008), which skilled migrants may evaluate in the
migration decision-making process.
Future research should further explore the evolution, impact, and implications of the broader mix
of migration and migration-related policies that are instrumental in attracting, selecting, deterring,
and retaining specific migrant groups in the context of other economic, social, and political factors
that directly and indirectly affect migration decisions of diverse migrant populations. Policy impact
analyses must address the interference of heterogenous region-, occupation-, and gender-specific
drivers, dynamics, and policies in the assessment of specific or generic policy interventions. For this
purpose, advanced methodological tools for policy impact evaluation are available (cf. Treasury
2020).
3.10
Migration restrictions affect migration flows in unintended ways
Most migration control policies have the potential to develop both politically and ethically
unwanted outcomes. Obviously, whether policy effects are wanted (i.e. intended), or not, depends
on who is evaluating policy outcomes, and how, i.e. by what standards. Certain policy-induced
migration outcomes can, for instance, be wanted by employers and unwanted by unions, or wanted
by nativist groups and unwanted by human rights groups. The most objective yardstick for policy
evaluation is the policy aims as stated by the legislative provision or the authority that is responsible
for implementing a migration policy intervention (see Provision 9). Many if not most migration
policy interventions result in some fundamental externalities or, side effects, which often trigger
unintended consequences for migrants and host countries alike, and therefore, limiting or obscuring
the realisation of migration policy goals (Castles 2004; Czaika and de Haas 2013).
For instance, policy restrictions may be spatially diverting migrants to alternative locations and
destinations, may be categorically deflecting migrants towards other legal entry channels or even to
illegal routes and status. Migrants may also be intertemporally affected in their decision-making by
pre- or postponing the timing of migration, or by procrastinating the realisation of return and
onward migration plans as a reaction tightening migration policies. All these externalities often
come in conjunction with an intended deterrence effect. The overall effect of a restrictive policy
intervention on the volume and composition of short- and long-term immigration is a combination
of a range of effects on the timing, direction and duration of individual migration events.
Disentangling these multiple and multidirectional effects establishes a methodological challenge but
would be a major step towards more realistic, unbiased, and comprehensive conclusions about the
combination of intended and unintended effects of migration policy restrictions.
Moreover, migration policies tend to produce asymmetric policy effects with different effect sizes,
that is policy changes towards more liberalisation do not exactly mirror policy changes towards
more restrictiveness. For instance, Czaika and de Haas (2017) find that the introduction of a travel
visa restriction reduces migrant inflows to a much smaller extent compared to the effect size of a
migration-inducing visa policy liberalisation (visa waiver). Migration flows respond usually more
rapidly and much stronger to liberal policy changes than policy changes towards more restrictive
regimes (e.g. entry conditions). We may hypothesize that such asymmetric policy effects are
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
18
produced by complex interactions with, for instance, the facilitating role of migrant networks. But
also behavioural scientific explanations such as prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky 1979) can
explain such asymmetric migration behaviour (Czaika 2015).
In general, the effectiveness and the existence of significant side effects of migration policy
interventions depends on the way and extent migration policy is mediated or reinforced by the
interaction with other policy and contextual factors conjointly forming complex migration driver
configurations. Addressing conceptual and methodological challenges in assessing the ways
migration policy interventions are affected by complex configurations of ‘third factors’ in producing
intended and unintended outcomes remains to be resolved by future research.
4. Conclusion
Migration studies is still a fragmented and largely under-theorised research field. Arango (2000: 283)
states that “migration is too diverse and multifaceted to be explained by a single theory”, yet through
triangulation of various theoretical accounts and concepts, we may state propositions that address
even diverse and multifaceted migration patterns and regularities.
This paper outlines a limited set of ten propositions that can be empirically approached from very
different angles. It is beyond the scope of this paper to propose explicitly how these propositions
may be empirically approached. This was a deliberate decision since a comprehensive evaluation of
the validity of each proposition does require an ‘empirical triangulation’ including a mix of
hypotheses, data, methods, and contexts. Proposition 7, for instance, which claims that emigration
is non-linearly associated with economic development, can be assessed through multiple analyses
across analytical levels, geographic locations, scales of analyses, longitudinal coverage,
methodological tools, definitions and operationalisations of the underlying concepts “migration”
and “development”, and of course, the exact specification of testable hypotheses. For instance,
proposition 7 can be turned into hypotheses stating that “middle-income countries have higher
emigration rates than low-income countries”, or “semi-rural regions are more migratory than
metropolitan areas”, or hypotheses claiming that “better educated segments of society are more
mobile than the less educated”. And, as always, the specification of the research question in terms
of the hypotheses informs the choice of data. Again, based on proposition 7, data and analyses can
range from global assessments of emigration rates across many developing and developed countries
e.g. using the World Bank bilateral stocks database (Özden et al. 2011), to large-scale cross-national
surveys of migration intentions and events e.g. based on Gallup World Poll data (Migali and Scipioni
2019), to assessments of internal migration between locations within countries, e.g. based on
nationally representative surveys such as the Indian National Sample Survey (NSS) or the
Indonesian Family and Life Survey (IFLS), to the analysis of individual life courses of smaller, via
not necessarily nationally representative surveys (e.g. MAFE project).
However, even if a proposition is approached by a wide range of empirical angles and strategies,
providing a solid amount of supportive evidence, the validity of the proposition remains
inconclusive. We know that a proposition and its underlying theory is only tentatively true –
basically until a new and better concept has been formulated which may be more convincing and
powerful in explaining observable aspects of migration as a multifaceted social process and
phenomenon. However, despite this tentative validity, is migration theory nevertheless useful for
prediction of future migration?
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
19
A long-standing debate in the theory of science dwells upon the question whether explanation of a
phenomenon and its prediction is one or distinct (Hempel and Oppenheim 1948, Shmueli 2010). As
far as migration theory is concerned, the predictive power of most theories and concepts is limited
due to their partial nature and context-specific validity. Propositions of most migration theories are
conditional upon the influence of ‘third factors’ that may interfere with the underlying theoretical
relationship. The omnipresence of intervening factors in broader migration driver complexes,
however, should not hinder attempts to use theory to inform predictions or projections of future
migration trends. These predictions are likely to be even more accurate if contextualised to specific
groups, geographical locations, scales of analyses, forms of migration, and temporal frames.
Established but still contested ‘stylized facts’ about migration regularities have informed the
selection and specification of the propositions put forward in this article. This means that these
propositions already have a solid evidence base, but are nevertheless contentious – either for
theoretical, empirical, or ideological reasons. More theoretical and empirical work therefore must
consolidate and further substantiate our understanding of the regularities synthesized in these
propositions (and the many more that we should have discussed). Theoretically and empirically
triangulated and consolidated propositions are not only useful for ex post evaluations of historical
migration patterns and dynamics but are also instrumental for ex ante projections of uncertain
migration futures.
5. References
Abel, G. J., Brottrager, M., Crespo Cuaresma, J., & Muttarak, R. (2019). Climate, conflict and forced
migration. Global Environmental Change, 54(December 2018), 239–249
Abu, M., Codjoe, S. N. A., & Sward, J. (2014). Climate change and internal migration intentions in
the forest-savanna transition zone of Ghana. Population and Environment, 35(4), 341–364
Adams, H., & Kay, S. (2019). Migration as a human affair: Integrating individual stress thresholds
into quantitative models of climate migration. Environmental Science & Policy, 93, 129-138.
Afifi, T. (2011). Economic or Environmental Migration? The Push Factors in Niger. International
Migration, 49(SUPPL.1).
Ahrens, J., Kelly, M., & Van Liempt, I. (2016). Free movement? The onward migration of EU
citizens born in Somalia, Iran, and Nigeria. Population, Space and Place, 22(1), 84-98
Angelucci, M. (2004). Aid and Migration : An Analysis of the Impact of Progresa on the Timing and Size
of Labour Migration (1187). Retrieved from Bonn:
Arango, J. (2000). Explaining migration: a critical view. International social science journal, 52(165),
283-296.
Azam, J.-P., & Berlinschi, R. (2009). L'aide contre l'immigration. Revue d'économie du développement,
17(4), 81-108.
Backhaus, A., Martinez-Zarzoso, I., & Muris, C. (2015). Do climate variations explain bilateral
migration? A gravity model analysis. IZA Journal of Migration, 4(1), 3.
Bakewell, O. (2008). 'Keeping them in their place': The ambivalent relationship between migration
and development in Africa. Third World Quarterly, 29(7), 1341-1358.
Bakewell, O. (2014). Relaunching migration systems. Migration Studies, 2(3), 300-318.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
20
Bakewell, O., De Haas, H., & Kubal, A. (2012). Migration systems, pioneer migrants and the role of
agency. Journal of critical realism, 11(4), 413-437.
Banerjee, B. (1983) ‘Social networks in the migration process: empirical evidence on chain
migration in India’, The Journal of Developing Areas, 17(2): 185-196.
Basch, L., Glick-Schiller, N. and Szanton Blanc, C. (1994) Nations Unbound: Transnational Projects,
Postcolonial Predicaments, and Deterritorialized Nation-States. Amsterdam: Gordon & Breach Science
Publishers.
Beine, M., & Parsons, C. R. (2015). Climatic factors as determinants of international migration.
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 117(2), 723–767
Berthelemy, J.-C., Beuran, M., & Maurel, M. (2009). Aid and Migration: Substitutes or
Complements? World Development, 37(10), 1589-1599.
Bhagwati, J. N., & Hanson, G. H. (Eds.). (2009). Skilled immigration today: Prospects, problems, and
policies (Vol. 17). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bijak, J., & Czaika, M. (2020). Assessing Uncertain Migration Futures: A Typology of the
Unknown. QuantMig background paper D1.1, University of Southampton, UK
Black, R., Adger, W. N., Arnell, N. W., Dercon, S., Geddes, A., & Thomas, D. (2011). The effect of
environmental change on human migration. Global Environmental Change, 21(SUPPL. 1), S3–S11
Bohra-Mishra, P., & Massey, D. S. (2011). Individual decisions to migrate during civil conflict.
Demography, 48(2), 401-424.
Bohra-Mishra, P., Oppenheimer, M., & Hsiang, S. M. (2014). Nonlinear permanent migration
response to climatic variations but minimal response to disasters. Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences, 111(27), 9780-9785.
Boyd, M. (1989) ‘Family and personal networks in international migration: recent developments
and new agendas’, International Migration Review, 23(3): 638-670.
Boyer, D., Faubion, J.D. and Marcus, G.E., eds (2015) Theory Can Be More than It Used to Be: Learning
Anthropology's Method in a Time of Transition. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Brettell, C. B., & Hollifield, J. F. (Eds.). (2014). Migration theory: Talking across disciplines. Routledge.
Brunarska, Z. (2019). A “Good Enough” Choice: Bounded Rationality in Migration Destination
Choice. Studia Migracyjne-Przegląd Polonijny, 45(2 (172)).
Caarls, K., Bilgili, Ö., & Fransen, S. (2020). Evolution of migration trajectories and transnational
social networks over time: a study among sub-Saharan African migrants in Europe. Journal of
Ethnic and Migration Studies, 1-19.
Cai, R., Feng, S., Oppenheimer, M., & Pytlikova, M. (2016). Climate variability and international
migration: The importance of the agricultural linkage. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management, 79, 135–151.
Carling, J. (2002). Migration in the age of involuntary immobility: theoretical reflections and Cape
Verdean experiences. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 28(1), 5-42.
Carling, J. and Talleraas, C. (2016) Root causes and drivers of migration. Implications for humanitarian
efforts and development cooperation. PRIO Paper. Oslo: Peace Research Institute Oslo.
Carling, J., & Schewel, K. (2018). Revisiting aspiration and ability in international migration.
Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 44(6), 945-963.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
21
Cassarino, J. P. (2009). The Co-operation on Readmission and Enforced Return in the AfricanEuropean Context. In M. Trémolières (Ed.), Regional Challenges of West African Migration: African
and European Perspectives, (pp. 49-72). Paris: OECD.
Castles, S. (2004). Why migration policies fail. Ethnic and racial studies, 27(2), 205-227.
Castles, S., de Haas, H., & Miller, M. J. 2013. The Age of Migration: International Population
Movements in the Modern World (5th edition), Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan
Cattaneo, C., Beine, M., Fröhlich, C. J., Kniveton, D., Martinez-Zarzoso, I., Mastrorillo, M.,
Schraven, B. (2019). Human Migration in the Era of Climate Change. Review of Environmental
Economics and Policy, 1–19. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/rez002
Choldin, H. M. (1973). Kinship networks in the migration process. International Migration Review,
7(2), 163-176.
Clemens, M. A. (2014). Does development reduce migration? In R. E. B. Lucas (Ed.), International
Handbook on Migration and Economic Development (pp. 152-185). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar
Publishing.
Clemens, M. A., & Mendola, M. (2020). Migration from Developing Countries: Selection, Income
Elasticity, and Simpson's Paradox. IZA Discussion Paper no. 13612
Clemens, M. A., & Postel, H. M. (2018a). Can Development Assistance Deter Emigration? Retrieved
from Washington:
Clemens, M. A., & Postel, H. M. (2018b). Deterring Emigration with Foreign Aid: An Overview of
Evidence from Low-Income Countries. Population and Development Review, 44(4), 667-693.
doi:10.1111/padr.12184
Codjoe, S. N. A., Nyamedor, F. H., Sward, J., & Dovie, D. B. (2017). Environmental hazard and
migration intentions in a coastal area in Ghana: a case of sea flooding. Population and Environment,
39(2), 39–146.
Collyer, M. (2019). From preventive to repressive: the changing use of development and
humanitarianism to control migration. In K. Mitchell, R. Jones, & J. L. Fluri (Eds.), Handbook on
Critical Geographies of Migration (pp. 170-181). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Correa-Velez, I., Nardone, M., & Knoetze, K. (2017). Leaving family behind: Understanding the
irregular migration of unaccompanied asylum-seeking minors. In M. McAuliffe & K. Koser (Eds.),
A long way to go: Irregular Migration Patterns, Processes, Drivers and Decision-Making (pp. 141–165).
Acton: Australian National University Press
Czaika, M. (2015). Migration and Economic Prospects. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 41(1),
58–82.
Czaika, M., & de Haas, H. (2012). The Role of Internal and International Relative Deprivation in
Global Migration. Oxford Development Studies, 40(4), 423-442
Czaika, M., & de Haas, H. (2013). The effectiveness of immigration policies. Population and
Development Review, 39(3), 487-508.
Czaika, M., & de Haas, H. (2017). The Effect of Visas on Migration Processes. International
Migration Review, 51(4), 893–926
Czaika, M., & Parsons, C. R. (2017). The gravity of high-skilled migration policies. Demography,
54(2), 603-630.
Czaika, M., & Reinprecht, C. (2020). Drivers of migration. A synthesis of knowledge (Vol. 163). IMI
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
22
Working Paper.
Dahinden, J. 2016. A Plea for the 'Demigranticization' of Research on Migration and Integration.
Ethnic and Racial Studies, 39 (13), 207-225.
Davenport, C. A., Moore, W. H., & Poe, S. C. (2003). Sometimes you just have to leave: Domestic
threats and forced migration, 1964-1989. International Interactions, 29(1), 27–55
De Haas, H. (2010). Migration transitions: a theoretical and empirical inquiry into the developmental
drivers of international migration, Working Paper 24, Oxford: International Migration Institute,
University of Oxford.
De Haas, H. (2014). Migration Theory: Quo Vadis? Working Paper, 100. Oxford: International
Migration Institute, University of Oxford.
Docquier, F., Peri, G. and Ruyssen, I. (2014) 'The Cross-country Determinants of Potential and
Actual Migration.' International Migration Review, 48(S1):37-99.
Doomernik, J., Koslowski, R., & Thränhardt, D. (2009). The battle for the brains. Why Policy is not
enough to Attract the Highly Skilled, Washington DC: Transatlantic Academy.
Erdal, M. B., & Oeppen, C. (2018). Forced to leave? The discursive and analytical significance of
describing migration as forced and voluntary. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 44(6), 981-998.
Esipova, N., Srinivasan, R. and Ray, J. (2015) 'Global Desires to Migrate.' in Besharov, D.J. and
Lopez, M.H. (eds) Adjusting to a World in Motion: Trends in Global Migration and Migration Policy.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 21-57.
Eurenius, A. M. (2020). A family affair: Evidence of chain migration during the mass emigration
from the county of Halland in Sweden to the United States in the 1890s. Population Studies, 74(1),
103-118.
Faini, R., & Venturini, A. (1993). Trade, Aid and Migrations: Some Basic Policy Issues. European
Economic Review, 37(2-3), 435-442. doi:Doi 10.1016/0014-2921(93)90032-6
Fernandez, B. (2013). Traffickers, brokers, employment agents, and social networks: The regulation
of intermediaries in the migration of Ethiopian domestic workers to the Middle East. International
Migration Review, 47(4), 814-843.
Friberg, J. H. (2012). The stages of migration. From going abroad to settling down: Post-accession
Polish migrant workers in Norway. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 38(10), 1589-1605.
Fussell, E. (2010). The Cumulative Causation of International Migration in Latin America. The
Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 630(1), 162-177.
Gaibazzi, P. (2014). Visa problem: Certification, kinship, and the production of 'ineligibility' in the
Gambia. Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 20(1), 38-55.
Gamlen, A. (2019). Human geopolitics: States, emigrants, and the rise of diaspora institutions. Oxford
University Press.
Gamso, J., & Yuldashev, F. (2018). Does rural development aid reduce international migration?
World Development, 110, 268-282.
Garip, F. (2012). Discovering diverse mechanisms of migration: The Mexico–US Stream 1970–2000.
Population and Development Review, 38(3), 393-433.
Ghatak, S., Levine, P., & Price, S. W. (1996). Migration theories and evidence: an assessment.
Journal of Economic Surveys, 10(2), 159-198.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
23
Gorodzeisky, A., & Leykin, I. (2020). When borders migrate: Reconstructing the category of
‘international migrant’. Sociology, 54(1), 142-158.
Griffiths, M., Rogers, A., & Anderson, B. (2013). Migration, time and temporalities: Review and
prospect. COMPAS Research Resources Paper, 199-217.
Grigg, D. B. (1977). E. G. Ravenstein and the “laws of migration”. Journal of Historical
Geography,3(1), 41-54
Hagen-Zanker, J. (2008). Why do people migrate? A review of the theoretical literature. A Review of
the Theoretical Literature (January 2008). Maastricht Graduate School of Governance Working Paper No. 2
Hagen-Zanker, J., & Mallett, R. (2016). Journeys to Europe: The role of policy in migrant decisionmaking. ODI Insights. ODI
Harris, J. R., & Todaro, M. P. (1970). Migration, unemployment and development: a two-sector
analysis. The American economic review, 60(1), 126-142.
Hatton, T. J. (2004). Seeking asylum in Europe. Economic Policy, 19(38), 6–62.
Hatton, T. J., & Williamson, J. G. (2005a). What Fundamentals Drive World Migration? In G. J.
Borjas & J. Crisp (Eds.), Poverty, International Migration and Asylum (pp. 15-38). London: Palgrave
Macmillan UK
Haug, S. (2008). Migration networks and migration decision-making. Journal of Ethnic and Migration
Studies, 34(4), 585-605
Hempel, C. G., & Oppenheim, P. (1948). Studies in the Logic of Explanation. Philosophy of science,
15(2), 135-175.
Hooghe, M., Trappers, A., Meuleman, B., & Reeskens, T. (2008). Migration to European countries:
A structural explanation of patterns, 1980–2004. International Migration Review, 42(2), 476-504.
Hoon, M. D., Vink, M., & Schmeets, H. (2020). A ticket to mobility? Naturalisation and subsequent
migration of refugees after obtaining asylum in the Netherlands. Journal of Ethnic and Migration
Studies, 46(7), 1185-1204.
Infantino, F., & Rea, A. (2012). La mobilisation d'un savoir pratique local: attribution des visas
Schengen au Consulat général de Belgique à Casablanca. Sociologies pratiques, 1(24), 67-78.
Islam, M. R. (2018). Climate change, natural disasters and socioeconomic livelihood vulnerabilities:
migration decision among the Char land people in Bangladesh. Social Indicators Research, 136(2),
575-593.
Joseph, G., & Wodon, Q. (2013). Is internal migration in Yemen driven by climate or socioeconomic factors? Review of International Economics, 21(2), 295–310.
Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk.
Econometrica, 47(2), 263-291.
Khavarian-Garmsir, A. R., Pourahmad, A., Hataminejad, H., & Farhoodi, R. (2019). Climate change
and environmental degradation and the drivers of migration in the context of shrinking cities: A
case study of Khuzestan province, Iran. Sustainable Cities and Society, 47, 101480
King, R. (2012). Theories and typologies of migration: An overview and a primer. Malmö
University
King, R. (2020). On migration, geography, and epistemic communities. Comparative Migration
Studies, 8(1), 1-10.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
24
King, R., & Raghuram, P. (2013). International student migration: Mapping the field and new
research agendas. Population, Space and Place, 19(2), 127-137.
Kishore, N., Marqués, D., Mahmud, A., Kiang, M. V., Rodriguez, I., Fuller, A., ... & Maas, L. (2018).
Mortality in puerto rico after hurricane maria. New England journal of medicine, 379(2), 162-170.
Khavarian-Garmsir, A. R., Pourahmad, A., Hataminejad, H., Farhoodi, R. (2019). Climate change
and environmental degradation and the drivers of migration in the context of shrinking cities: A
case study of Khuzestan province, Iran. Sustainable Cities and Society, 47.
Laczko, F., Tjaden, J. and Auer, D. (2017) Measuring Global Migration Potential, 2010–2015, Data
Briefing Series, 9. Berlin: IOM Global Migration Data Analysis Centre.
Lanati, M., & Thiele, R. (2018a). Foreign aid can dampen migration if it improves public services (2).
Retrieved from
Lanati, M., & Thiele, R. (2018b). Foreign assistance and migration choices: Disentangling the
channels. Economics Letters, 172, 148-151
Lanati, M., & Thiele, R. (2018c). The impact of foreign aid on migration revisited. World
Development, 111, 59-74. doi:10.1016/j.worlddev.2018.06.021
Lanati, M., & Thiele, R. (2020). Foreign assistance and emigration: Accounting for the role of nontransferred aid. The World Economy, 43(7), 1951-1976. doi:10.1111/twec.12914
Lavenex, S. (2006). Shifting up and out: The foreign policy of European immigration control. West
European Politics, 29(2), 329-350.
Lee, E. (1966). A Theory of Migration. Demography, 3(1), 47-57.
Levitt, P. (1998) 'Social remittances: Migration driven local-level forms of cultural diffusion.'
International Migration Review, 32(4):926-948.
Lewis, W. A. (1954) ‘Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour’. Manchester
School of Economic and Social Studies, 22: 139–91.
Lindquist, J., Xiang, B., & Yeoh, B. S. (2012). Opening the black box of migration: Brokers, the
organization of transnational mobility and the changing political economy in Asia. Pacific Affairs,
85(1), 7-19.
Liu, Y., & Xu, W. (2017). Destination choices of permanent and temporary migrants in China, 1985–
2005. Population, Space and Place, 23(1), e1963.
Lubbers, M. J., Verdery, A. M., & Molina, J. L. (2020). Social networks and transnational social
fields: A review of quantitative and mixed methods approaches. International Migration Review,
54(1), 177-204.
Lucas, R. E. B. (2005). International Migration and Economic Development: Lessons from Low-Income
Countries. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Lundquist, J. H., & Massey, D. S. (2005). Politics or economics? International migration during the
Nicaraguan Contra War. Journal of Latin American Studies, 37(1), 29.
Mabogunje A L. (1970) ‘Systems Approach to a Theory of Rural−Urban Migration’, Geographical
Analysis, 2(1), 1-18.
MacDonald, J. S., & MacDonald, L. D. (1964). Chain migration ethnic neighbourhood formation
and social networks. The Milbank Memorial Fund Quarterly, 42(1), 82-97.
Mallick, B., & Vogt, J. (2014). Population displacement after cyclone and its consequences:
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
25
Empirical evidence from coastal Bangladesh. Natural hazards, 73(2), 191-212.
Marchal, L., Naiditch, C., & Simsek, B. (2020). How Aid Impacts Migration Flows Once Again (202001). Retrieved from Lille:
Marchiori, L., Maystadt, J.-F., & Schumacher, I. (2012). The impact of weather anomalies on
migration in sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 63(3), 355–374
Martin, M., Billah, M., Siddiqui, T., Abrar, C., Black, R., & Kniveton, D. (2014). Climate-related
migration in rural Bangladesh: a behavioural model. Population and Environment, 36(1), 85-110.
Martin, P. L. (1993). Trade and Migration: The Case of NAFTA. Asian and Pacific Migration Journal,
2(3), 329-367
Martin, P., & Taylor, J. E. (1996). The anatomy of a migration hump. In J. E. Taylor (Ed.),
Development strategy, employment and migration: Insight from models, Development Centre (pp. 43-62).
Paris: OECD
Martin, P., & Taylor, J. E. (1996). The anatomy of a migration hump. In J. E. Taylor (Ed.),
Development strategy, employment and migration: Insight from models, Development Centre (pp. 43-62).
Paris: OECD.
Massey, D. (1990). 1990: Social structure, household strategies, and the cumulative causation of
migration. Population Index 56, 3-26
Massey, D. S., & Espinosa, K. E. (1997). What's driving Mexico-US migration? A theoretical,
empirical, and policy analysis. American journal of sociology, 102(4), 939-999.
Massey, D. S., & Taylor, J. E. (Eds.). (2004). International migration: Prospects and policies in a global
market. OUP Oxford.
Massey, D.S., Arango, J., Hugo, G., Kouaouci, A., Pellegrino, A. and Taylor, J.E. (1993) ‘Theories of
international migration: a review and appraisal’, Population and Development Review, 19(3): 431-466.
Mayda, A. M. (2010). International migration: A panel data analysis of the determinants of bilateral
flows. Journal of Population Economics, 23(4), 1249–1274.
McAuliffe, M. (2017). Seeking the views of irregular migrants: Decision-making, drivers and
migration journeys. In M. McAuliffe & K. Koser (Eds.), A Long Way to Go: Irregular Migration
Patterns, Processes, Drivers and Decision-making (pp. 103–139). Acton: Australian National University
Press.
Merton, R. K. (1967) On Theoretical Sociology, New York: Free Press.
Migali, S., & Scipioni, M. (2019). Who’s About to Leave? A Global Survey of Aspirations and
Intentions to Migrate. International Migration, 57(5), 181-200.
Migali, S., Natale, F., Tintori, G., Kalantaryan, S., Grubanov-Boskovic, S., Scipioni, M., Farinosi, F.,
Cattaneo, C., Benandi, B., Follador, M., & Bidoglio, G. (2018). International Migration Drivers, JRC
No. 112622, Publications Office of the European Union
Moore, W. H., & Shellman, S. M. (2004). Fear of Persecution: Forced migration 1952-1995. Journal of
Conflict Resolution, 48(5), 723–745.
Moore, W. H., & Shellman, S. M. (2007). Whither Will They Go. A Global Study of Refugees’
Destinations, 1965–1995. International Studies Quarterly, 51, 811–834
Morawska, E. (2007). International migration: Its various mechanisms and different theories that
try to explain it. Willy Brandt Series of Working Papers in International Migration and Ethnic
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
26
Relations; 1/07.
Moret, J. (2016). Cross-border mobility, transnationality and ethnicity as resources: european
Somalis’ post-migration mobility practices. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 42(9), 1455-1472.
Morrison, T. K. (1982). The Relationship of U.S. Aid, Trade and Investment to Migration Pressures
in Major Sending Countries. International Migration Review, 16(1), 4-26.
Mortreux, C., & Barnett, J. (2009). Climate change, migration and adaptation in Funafuti, Tuvalu.
Global Environmental Change, 19(1), 105–112.
Mylonas, H., & Žilović, M. (2019). Foreign policy priorities and ethnic return migration policies:
group-level variation in Greece and Serbia. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 45(4), 613-635.
Naudé, W. (2010). The determinants of migration from Sub-Saharan African countries. Journal of
African Economies, 19(3), 330–356.
Nawrotzki, R. J., & DeWaard, J. (2018). Putting trapped populations into place: Climate change and
inter-district migration flows in Zambia. Regional environmental change, 18(2), 533-546.
Nawrotzki, R. J., Hunter, L. M., Runfola, D. M., & Riosmena, F. (2015). Climate change as a
migration driver from rural and urban Mexico. Environmental Research Letters, 10(11), 114023
Neumayer, E. (2004). Asylum destination choice: what makes some West European countries more
attractive than others? European Union Politics, 5(2), 155-180.
Ortega, F., & Peri, G. (2013). The effect of income and immigration policies on international
migration. Migration Studies, 1(1), 47-74.
Özden, Ç., Parsons, C. R., Schiff, M., & Walmsley, T. L. (2011). Where on earth is everybody? The
evolution of global bilateral migration 1960–2000. The World Bank Economic Review, 25(1), 12-56.
Paasche, E. (2020). Elites and emulators: The evolution of Iraqi Kurdish asylum migration to
Europe. Migration Studies, 8(2), 189-208.
Papademetriou, D. G., Somerville, W., & Tanaka, H. (2008). Talent in the 21st century economy.
Migration Policy Institute.
Paul, A. M. (2011). Stepwise international migration: A multistage migration pattern for the
aspiring migrant. American Journal of Sociology, 116(6), 1842-86.
Pisarevskaya, A., Levy, N., Scholten, P., & Jansen, J. (2019). Mapping migration studies: An
empirical analysis of the coming of age of a research field. Migration Studies, 8(3), 455-481
Popper, K. (2005, 1935). The logic of scientific discovery. Routledge (reprint).
Poros, M. V. (2001). The role of migrant networks in linking local labour markets: the case of Asian
Indian migration to New York and London. Global networks, 1(3), 243-260.
Portes, A., & DeWind, J. (2008). Rethinking Migration: New Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives.
Berghahn Books.
Portes, A., Guarnizo, L. E., & Landolt, P. (1999). The study of transnationalism: pitfalls and
promise of an emergent research field. Ethnic and racial studies, 22(2), 217-237.
Pries, L. (1996). Transnationale Soziale Räume: Theoretisch-empirische Skizze am Beispiel der
Arbeitswanderungen Mexico–USA. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 25(6), 456-472.
Ravenstein, E. G. (1885). The laws of migration. London: Royal Statistical Society.
Rees, P., & Lomax, N. (2019). Ravenstein Revisited: The Analysis of Migration, Then and Now.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
27
Comparative Population Studies, 44.
Rueschemeyer, D. (2009) Usable theory. Analytic tools for social and political research. Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Ruyssen, I., & Rayp, G. (2014). Determinants of Intraregional Migration in Sub-Saharan Africa
1980-2000. Journal of Development Studies, 50(3), 426–443
Ryan, L. (2011). Migrants' social networks and weak ties: accessing resources and constructing
relationships post-migration. The Sociological Review, 59(4), 707-724.
Samers, M. (2010). Migration. Routledge.
Samers, M., & Collyer, M. (2016). Migration. Routledge.
Schapendonk , J., Bolay, M. and Dahinden, J. (2020): The conceptual limits of the ‘migration
journey’. De-exceptionalising mobility in the context of West African trajectories, Journal of Ethnic
and Migration Studies, DOI: 10.1080/1369183X.2020.1804191
Schewel, K. (2019) ‘Understanding Immobility: Moving Beyond the Mobility Bias in Migration
Studies’, International Migration Review, pp. 1–28.
Schewel, K. and Fransen, S. (2020) ‘Who aspires to stay? Immobility aspirations among youth in
Ethiopia, India, Peru, and Vietnam’. IMI Working Paper No 161.
Schmidt, G. (2017). Going beyond methodological presentism: examples from a Copenhagen
neighbourhood 1885–2010. Immigrants & Minorities, 35(1), 40-58.
Shah, N. M., & Menon, I. (1999). Chain migration through the social network: experience of labour
migrants in Kuwait. International migration, 37(2), 361-382.
Shen, S., & Binns, T. (2012). Pathways, motivations and challenges: contemporary Tuvaluan
migration to New Zealand. GeoJournal, 77(1), 63-82.
Shmueli, G. (2010). To explain or to predict? Statistical science, 25(3), 289-310.
Spaan, E., & van Naerssen, T. (2018). Migration decision-making and migration industry in the
Indonesia–Malaysia corridor. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies, 44(4), 680-695.
Stark, O. (1991). The migration of labour. Blackwell.
Stark, O., & Bloom, D. E. (1985). The new economics of labor migration. American Economic Review,
75(2), 173-178.
Taylor, J. E. (1999). The new economics of labour migration and the role of remittances in the
migration process. International Migration, 37(1), 63-86.
Treasury, H. M. (2020). Magenta Book: Central Government guidance on evaluation, UK
Government, https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/the-magenta-book
UNHCR (2020) Global Trends: Forced Displacement in 2019, UNHCR: Geneva
Van Hear, N. (2006) ”I went as far as my money would take me”: conflict, forced migration and
class. Forced migration and global processes: A view from forced migration studies, pp. 125-158.
Van Wijk, J. (2010). Luanda – Holanda: Irregular Migration from Angola to the Netherlands.
International Migration, 48(2), 1–30
Veronis, L., & McLeman, R. (2014). Environmental influences on African migration to Canada:
Focus group findings from Ottawa-Gatineau. Population and environment, 36(2), 234-251.
Warner, K., Hamza, M., Oliver-Smith, A., Renaud, F., & Julca, A. (2010). Climate change,
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions
28
environmental degradation and migration. Natural Hazards, 55(3), 689–715
Wessendorf, S. (2019). Pioneer migrants and their social relations in super-diverse London. Ethnic
and racial studies, 42(1), 17-34.
White, P. E., & Woods, R. I. (1980). The foundations of migration study. In P. White, & R. Woods
(Eds.), The geographical impact of migration (pp. 1–20). London: Longman.
Wodon, Q., Liverani, A., Joseph, G., & Bougnoux, N. (2014). Climate Change and Migration: Evidence
from the Middle East and North Africa. (Q. Wodon, A. Liverani, G. Joseph, & N. Bougnoux, Eds.).
Washington, DC: World Bank
Wolf, K. (2016). Marriage migration versus family reunification: How does the marriage and
migration history affect the timing of first and second childbirth among Turkish immigrants in
Germany? European Journal of Population, 32(5), 731-759.
World Food Program. (2017). AT THE ROOT OF EXODUS: Food security, conflict and international
migration
Xiang, B., & Lindquist, J. (2014). Migration infrastructure. International Migration Review, 48(1s),
122-148.
Zelinsky, W. (1971). The Hypothesis of the Mobility Transition. Geographical Review, 61(2), 219-249
Zhou, M., & Benton, G. (2017). Intra-Asian Chinese migrations: A historical overview. In
Contemporary Chinese Diasporas (pp. 1-25). Palgrave, Singapore.
QuantMig Translating Migration Theory into Empirical Propositions