Papers by Fabio Castiglionesi
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking
We study the efficiency properties of the formation of an interbank network. Banks face a trade-o... more We study the efficiency properties of the formation of an interbank network. Banks face a trade-off by establishing connections in the interbank market. On the one hand, banks improve the diversification of their liquidity risk and therefore can obtain a higher expected payoff. On the other hand, banks not sufficiently capitalized have risk-shifting incentives that expose them to the risk of bankruptcy. Connecting to such risky banks negatively affects expected payoff. We show that both the optimal and the decentralized networks are characterized by a core-periphery structure. The core is made of the safe banks, whereas the periphery is populated by the risky banks. Nevertheless, the two network structures coincide only if counterparty risk is sufficiently low. Otherwise, the decentralized network is underconnected as compared to the optimal one. Finally, we analyze mechanisms that can avoid the formation of inefficient interbank networks.
This paper first reviews the basic theory of financial intermediation. In particular, the paper p... more This paper first reviews the basic theory of financial intermediation. In particular, the paper presents the main modeling device that rationalizes financial intermediaries as liquidity providers. In the second part of the paper we build on the basic model to analyze recent developments in the theory of financial intermediation. Especially motivated by the 2007/2008 financial crisis, we show how this literature could help to explain phenomena like financial contagion and systemic liquidity crises. Finally, we deal with the possible welfare benefit of liquidity regulation.
In this paper we model interbank liquidity networks as ‡ow networks. The aim is to compare the ab... more In this paper we model interbank liquidity networks as ‡ow networks. The aim is to compare the ability of di¤erent network structures to cope with the liquidity risk faced by the banks. In particular, we analyze the e¢ ciency of three network structures-star-shaped, complete and incomplete-in transferring liquidity among banks. It turns out that the star-shaped interbank networks achieve the full coverage of liquidity risk with the smallest amount of interbank deposits held by each bank. This implies that star-shaped networks generate the minimum counterparty risk for the banks. Moreover, the star-shaped network is more resilient to systemic risk: the default of one or more banks is less likely to cause the default of the entire system in a star-shaped network than in a complete network. These results provides a rationale of the consistent empirical evidence that interbank network are sparse networks.
We study the propagation of financial crises between regions characterized by moral hazard proble... more We study the propagation of financial crises between regions characterized by moral hazard problems. The source of the problem is that banks are protected by limited liability and may engage in excessive risk taking. The regions are affected by negatively correlated liquidity shocks, so that liquidity coinsurance is Pareto improving. The moral hazard problem can be solved if banks are sufficiently capitalized. Under autarky, a limited investment is needed to achieve optimality, so that a limited amount of capital is sufficient to prevent risk-taking. With interbank deposits the optimal investment increases, and capital becomes insufficient to prevent excessive risk-taking. Thus bankruptcy occurs with positive probability and the crises spread to other regions via the financial linkages. Opening the financial markets is nevertheless Pareto improving; consumers benefit from liquidity coinsurance, although they pay the cost of excessive risk-taking. Finally, we show that in this framew...
Macroeconomic Dynamics, 2013
This paper explores the main determinants of productivity growth. The analysis is performed using... more This paper explores the main determinants of productivity growth. The analysis is performed using Spanish firm-level data. We define a framework where the relative magnitudes of alternative, but not exclusive, sources of technical change are simultaneously estimated. Our main finding is that the average total factor productivity (TFP) growth is fully explained by embodied technical progress (i.e., either new capital goods or human capital). Our results contradict the existence of a positive contribution of economywide neutral technological progress in determining average TFP growth. They also leave little room for large, unpriced effects external to the firm, both at the aggregate and at the industry level. We find evidence of firm-specific learning by doing, short-lived and due to adoption of new processes.
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2014
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 2014
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch ge... more Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. Terms of use: Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your personal and scholarly purposes. You are not to copy documents for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. If the documents have been made available under an Open Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2013
This paper studies banks' incentives to engage in liquidity crossinsurance. In contrast to previo... more This paper studies banks' incentives to engage in liquidity crossinsurance. In contrast to previous literature we view interbank insurance as the outcome of bilateral (and non-exclusive) contracting between pairs of banks and ask whether this outcome is socially efficient. Using a simple model of interbank insurance we find that this is indeed the case when insurance takes place through pure transfers. This is even though liquidity support among banks sometimes breaks down, as observed in the crisis of 2007-2008. However, when insurance is provided against some form of repayment (such as is the case, for example, with credit lines), banks have a tendency to insure each other less than the socially efficient amount. We show that efficiency can be restored by introducing seniority clauses for interbank claims or through subsidies that resemble government interbank lending guarantees.
Journal of Banking & Finance, 2007
We investigate the role of a central bank (CB) in preventing and avoiding financial contagion. Th... more We investigate the role of a central bank (CB) in preventing and avoiding financial contagion. The CB, by imposing reserve requirements on the banking system, trades off the cost of reducing the resources available for long-term investment with the benefit of raising liquidity to face an adverse shock that could cause contagious crises. We argue that contagion is not due
Manuscript, Tilburg …, 2010
This paper analyzes the e¤ects of …nancial integration on the banking system. Financial integrati... more This paper analyzes the e¤ects of …nancial integration on the banking system. Financial integration allows banks in di¤erent countries to smooth local liquidity shocks by borrowing on the international interbank market. We show that, under realistic conditions, …nancial integration induces banks to reduce their liquidity holdings and to shift their portfolios towards more pro…table but less liquid long-term investments. Integration helps to reallocate liquidity when di¤erent countries are hit by uncorrelated shocks. However, when an aggregate liquidity shock hits, the aggregate liquid resources in the banking system are lower than in autarky. Therefore, …nancial integration leads to larger spikes in interest rates on the interbank market in crisis episodes. For some parameter values, …nancial integration can lead to higher overall volatility of interbank rates. Furthermore, the distribution of consumption under integration can display both negative skewness and higher volatility than under autarky. The model is consistent with recent trends in external positions and liquidity holdings of banks in the US and in Europe. JEL Classi…cation: G21.
In this paper we model interbank liquidity networks as ‡ow networks. The aim is to compare the ab... more In this paper we model interbank liquidity networks as ‡ow networks. The aim is to compare the ability of di¤erent network structures to cope with the liquidity risk faced by the banks. In particular, we analyze the e¢ ciency of three network structures-star-shaped, complete and incomplete-in transferring liquidity among banks. It turns out that the star-shaped interbank networks achieve the full coverage of liquidity risk with the smallest amount of interbank deposits held by each bank. This implies that star-shaped networks generate the minimum counterparty risk for the banks. Moreover, the star-shaped network is more resilient to systemic risk: the default of one or more banks is less likely to cause the default of the entire system in a star-shaped network than in a complete network. These results provides a rationale of the consistent empirical evidence that interbank network are sparse networks.
Ever since Bagehot's (1873) pioneering work, it is a widely accepted wisdom that in order to alle... more Ever since Bagehot's (1873) pioneering work, it is a widely accepted wisdom that in order to alleviate (ex ante) bank moral hazard, a lender of last resort should lend at penalty rates only. In a model in which banks are subject to shocks but can exert effort to affect the likelihood of these shocks, we show that the validity of this argument crucially relies on banks always remaining solvent. The reason is that when banks become insolvent, Bagehot's prescription dictates to let them fail. Penalty rates charged when banks are illiquid (but solvent) then reduce banks' incentives to avoid insolvency ex ante and thus increase bank moral hazard. We derive a condition which shows precisely when this effect on ex ante incentives outweighs the traditional one and show that it is fulfilled under plausible scenarios.
Uploads
Papers by Fabio Castiglionesi