The cross-price elasticity of demand measures how the demand for one good responds to changes in the price of another good. It is defined as the percentage change in demand for one good divided by the percentage change in price of the other. Cross-price elasticity can be positive, negative, or zero depending on whether the goods are substitutes, complements, or unrelated. If goods are substitutes, their cross-price elasticity is positive. If goods are complements, their cross-price elasticity is negative. Firms need to understand cross-price elasticity to know how changing the price of one product will affect sales of other products.
The cross-price elasticity of demand measures how the demand for one good responds to changes in the price of another good. It is defined as the percentage change in demand for one good divided by the percentage change in price of the other. Cross-price elasticity can be positive, negative, or zero depending on whether the goods are substitutes, complements, or unrelated. If goods are substitutes, their cross-price elasticity is positive. If goods are complements, their cross-price elasticity is negative. Firms need to understand cross-price elasticity to know how changing the price of one product will affect sales of other products.
The cross-price elasticity of demand measures how the demand for one good responds to changes in the price of another good. It is defined as the percentage change in demand for one good divided by the percentage change in price of the other. Cross-price elasticity can be positive, negative, or zero depending on whether the goods are substitutes, complements, or unrelated. If goods are substitutes, their cross-price elasticity is positive. If goods are complements, their cross-price elasticity is negative. Firms need to understand cross-price elasticity to know how changing the price of one product will affect sales of other products.
The cross-price elasticity of demand measures how the demand for one good responds to changes in the price of another good. It is defined as the percentage change in demand for one good divided by the percentage change in price of the other. Cross-price elasticity can be positive, negative, or zero depending on whether the goods are substitutes, complements, or unrelated. If goods are substitutes, their cross-price elasticity is positive. If goods are complements, their cross-price elasticity is negative. Firms need to understand cross-price elasticity to know how changing the price of one product will affect sales of other products.
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 11
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
A firm that produces an entire line of products has a
special interest in how a change in the price of one item affects the demand for another. For example, the Coca-Cola Company needs to know how changing the price of Cherry Coke affects sales of Classic Coke. The company also needs to know the relationship between the price of Coke and the demand for Pepsi and vice versa. Likewise, Apple needs to know how changing the price of one iPhone model affects the demand for the other iPhone models. The responsiveness of the demand for one good to changes in the price of another good is called the cross- price elasticity of demand.
This is defined as the percentage change in the demand
of one good divided by the percentage change in the price of another good.
Its numerical value can be positive, negative, or zero,
depending on whether the two goods in question are substitutes, complements, or unrelated, respectively. Substitutes If an increase in the price of one good leads to an increase in the demand for another good, their cross- price elasticity is positive and the two goods are substitutes. For example, an increase in the price of Coke, other things constant, shifts the demand for Pepsi rightward, so the two are substitutes. The cross-price elasticity between Coke and Pepsi has been estimated at about 0.7, indicating that a 10 percent increase in the price of one increases the demand for the other by 7 percent. Complements
If an increase in the price of one good leads to a decrease
in the demand for another, their cross-price elasticity is negative and the goods are complements.
For example, an increase in the price of gasoline, other
things constant, shifts the demand for tires leftward because people drive less and replace their tires less frequently.
Gasoline and tires have negative cross-price elasticity and
are complements. To Review: The cross-price elasticity of demand is positive for substitutes and negative for complements.
Most pairs of goods selected at random are unrelated, so
their cross-price elasticity is zero, such as socks and sushi. What Causes a Demand Curve to Shift? (1) Changes in the Prices of Related Goods • Substitutes: Two goods are substitutes if a fall in the price of one of the goods makes consumers less willing to buy the other good. Substitutes are goods that in some way serve a similar function: concert and opera, muffins and doughnuts. • Complements: Two goods are complements if a fall in the price of one good makes people more willing to buy the other good. Complements are goods that in some sense are consumed together: cars and gasoline, computer and software. (2) Changes in Income
• Normal Goods: When a rise in income increases the
demand for a good - the normal case - we say that the good is a normal good. Preferred, more expensive.
• Inferior Goods: When a rise in income decreases the
demand for a good, it is an inferior good. Less desirable alternative.
• When a good is inferior, a rise in income shifts the
demand curve to the left; when a good is normal, a rise in income shifts the demand curve to the right. (a)Why is it that when two commodities are substitutes for each other, the cross elasticity of demand between them is positive while when they are complements it is negative?
(Answer) For two commodities which are substitutes, a
change in the price of one, ceteris paribus (with other conditions remaining the same), causes a change in the same direction in the quantity purchased of the other.
For example, an increase in the price of coffee increases
tea consumption and a decrease in the price of coffee decreases tea consumption. Thus the cross elasticity between them is positive. On the other hand, ceteris paribus, a change in the price of a commodity causes the quantity purchased of its complement to move in the opposite direction.
Thus the cross elasticity between them will be
negative. It should be noted that commodities may be substitutes over some range of prices and complements over others. (b) How can we define an industry by using cross elasticities? What difficulties does this lead to?
(Answer) High positive cross elasticities (indicating a high
degree of substitutability) among a group of commodities can be (and frequently is) used to define the boundaries of an industry.
This, however, may sometimes lead to difficulties. For
example, how high should cross elasticities be among a group of commodities in order for us to include them in the same industry? In addition, if the cross elasticity of demand between cars and station wagons and between station wagons and small trucks is positive and very high but the cross elasticity between cars and small trucks is positive but low, are cars and small trucks in the same industry?
In these and other cases, the definition of the industry
adopted usually depends on the problem to be studied.