Chap 009
Chap 009
Chap 009
Risk aversion ==> prefer certain outcome to an uncertain outcome with the same expected value
Examine risk aversion in more detail
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.2
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.3
$80,000
$100,000
$100,000
T9.4
Important Point:
Insurance reduces wealth if a loss does not occur Insurance increases wealth if a loss does occur
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.5
Risk Aversion
A risk averse person prefers a certain amount of wealth to a risky situation with the same expected wealth
Example:
Would you accept a 50-50 chance of winning $1,000 or losing $1,000? The gamble does not change a persons expected wealth, but it makes the persons wealth uncertain A risk-averse person therefore would choose not to accept the gamble
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.6
Risk Aversion
By not accepting the gamble, you are saying that the possible loss of $1,000 hurts more than the possible gain of $1,000 benefits you This is the essence of risk aversion:
A loss of $X hurts more than a gain of $X benefits you The loss hurts more than the gain benefits you because money means more to you when you have less of it
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.7
Risk Aversion
A risk averse person would require compensation (called a risk premium) before accepting the gamble in this example
change the odds (e.g., 60% chance of winning) change the payoffs (e.g., win $1,400, lose $1,000) The additional expected wealth ($200) needed to induce a risk averse person to accept the gamble is the premium required to compensate the person for the risk
A risk neutral person would not require a risk premium to accept this gamble; a risk neutral person only cares about expected wealth
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.8
Risk Aversion
A risk averse person would be willing to pay more than the expected loss to reduce risk Example:
2% chance of losing $10,000 Expected loss = $200 A risk averse person would pay more than $200 to eliminate the risk
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.9
Risk Aversion
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.10
H&N, Ch. 9
Information
Individuals perception of loading Underestimate the true risk ==> buy less insurance Overestimate the true risk ==> buy more insurance
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.12
Nonmonetary Losses
Examples:
pain and suffering loss of heirloom loss of consortium
Demand for insurance against nonmonetary losses differs from demand for insurance against monetary losses
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.13
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.14
Thus, many people would not demand insurance against nonmonetary losses even if there were no premium loading
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.15
Main Points:
Shareholder diversification reduces risk Shareholder diversification potentially substitutes for corporate risk management
Why should corporations reduce risk when shareholders are diversified?
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.16
Insurers provide services at lower costs than they can be purchased elsewhere
loss control claims processing
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.17
Insurance might be the lowest cost method of financing losses Alternative methods of paying losses
insurance internal funds raise new funds For firms without sufficient internal funds, insurance premium loading can be lower than the expected cost of raising new funds following a loss
T9.18
H&N, Ch. 9
Insurance might reduce expected financing costs for new investment projects Paying losses from internal funds increases the likelihood that new funds will have to be raised to finance new investment projects Cost of raising new funds
lowers value of new projects may pass up some good projects
T9.19
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.20
Reduce the likelihood of financial distress Bankruptcy is costly to other claimants (e.g., employees, lenders, suppliers, customers) These claimants require compensation for this risk (e.g., higher wages, higher lending rates) Shareholders can reduce costs by lowering likelihood of bankruptcy
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.21
H&N, Ch. 9
T9.22