This document summarizes Merton Miller's analysis of how taxes impact corporate capital structures and valuations. It argues that even when interest payments are fully tax deductible, a firm's value will still be independent of its capital structure in equilibrium. Bankruptcy costs are small relative to tax savings. Income bonds demonstrate how firms can achieve tax benefits without bankruptcy costs. Empirical evidence shows little change in capital structures despite rising tax rates. The tax advantages of debt are smaller than conventionally believed once personal taxes are considered. Market forces will restore equilibrium without firms needing to consider bankruptcy costs when setting capital structures.
This document summarizes Merton Miller's analysis of how taxes impact corporate capital structures and valuations. It argues that even when interest payments are fully tax deductible, a firm's value will still be independent of its capital structure in equilibrium. Bankruptcy costs are small relative to tax savings. Income bonds demonstrate how firms can achieve tax benefits without bankruptcy costs. Empirical evidence shows little change in capital structures despite rising tax rates. The tax advantages of debt are smaller than conventionally believed once personal taxes are considered. Market forces will restore equilibrium without firms needing to consider bankruptcy costs when setting capital structures.
This document summarizes Merton Miller's analysis of how taxes impact corporate capital structures and valuations. It argues that even when interest payments are fully tax deductible, a firm's value will still be independent of its capital structure in equilibrium. Bankruptcy costs are small relative to tax savings. Income bonds demonstrate how firms can achieve tax benefits without bankruptcy costs. Empirical evidence shows little change in capital structures despite rising tax rates. The tax advantages of debt are smaller than conventionally believed once personal taxes are considered. Market forces will restore equilibrium without firms needing to consider bankruptcy costs when setting capital structures.
This document summarizes Merton Miller's analysis of how taxes impact corporate capital structures and valuations. It argues that even when interest payments are fully tax deductible, a firm's value will still be independent of its capital structure in equilibrium. Bankruptcy costs are small relative to tax savings. Income bonds demonstrate how firms can achieve tax benefits without bankruptcy costs. Empirical evidence shows little change in capital structures despite rising tax rates. The tax advantages of debt are smaller than conventionally believed once personal taxes are considered. Market forces will restore equilibrium without firms needing to consider bankruptcy costs when setting capital structures.
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online from Scribd
Download as pptx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 21
DEBT AND TAXES Finanzas Corporativas
MERTON H. MILLER Carlos Arango
SCHEDULE 1. Objective 2. Bankruptcy costs in perspective 3. An important case: income bond 4. Taxes and capital structures: the empirical record 5. The tax advantages of debt financing reexamined 6. Special cases 7. Taxes and market equilibrium 8. Properties of market equilibrium 9. Conclussions OBJECTIVE Trying to establish the propositions about valuation implied by the economist's basic working assumptions of rational behavior and perfect markets.
He will argue that even in a world in which interest
payments are fully deductible in computing corporate income taxes, the value of the firm, in equilibrium will still be independent of its capital structure. BANKRUPTCY COSTS IN PERSPECTIVE Bankruptcy costs and agency costs do indeed exist as was dutifully noted at several points in the original 1958 article. It is just that these costs, by any sensible reckoning, seem disproportionately small relative to the tax savings they are supposedly balancing. The tax savings, after all, are conventionally taken as being on the order of 50 cents for each dollar of permanent debt issued.3 The figure one usually hears as an estimate of bankruptcy costs is 20 percent of the value of the estate. But when that figure is traced back to its source in the paper by Baxter it turns out to refer mainly to the bankruptcies of individuals, with a sprinkling of small businesses, mostly proprietorships and typically undergoing liquidation rather than reorganization. BANKRUPTCY COSTS IN PERSPECTIVE Warner tabulated the direct costs of bankruptcy and reorganization for a sample of 11 railroads that filed petitions in bankruptcy under Section 77 of the Bankruptcy Act between 1930 and 1955. He found that the eventual cumulated direct costs of bankruptcy-and keep in mind that most of these railroads were in bankruptcy and running up these expenses for over 10 years!-averaged 5.3% of the market value of the firm's securities as of the end of the month in which the railroad filed the petition. There was a strong inverse size effect, moreover. For the largest road, the costs were 1,7%. And remember that these are the ex post, upper-bound cost ratios, whereas, of course, the expected costs of bankruptcy are the relevant ones when the firm's capital structure decisions are being made. On that score, Warner finds, for example, that the direct costs of bankruptcy averaged only about 1 percent of the value of the firm 7 years before the petition was filed; and when he makes a reasonable allowance for the probability of bankruptcy actually occurring, he comes up with an estimate of the expected cost of bankruptcy that is, of course, much smaller yet. BANKRUPTCY COSTS IN PERSPECTIVE Warner's data cover only the direct costs of reorganization in bankruptcy. The deadweight costs of rescaling claims might perhaps loom larger if measures were available of the indirect costs. Why speculate about the size of these costs? AN IMPORTANT CASE: INCOME BOND Interest payments on such bonds need be paid in any year only if earned; and if earned and paid are fully deductible in computing corporate inconmetax. But if not earned and not paid in any year, the bondholders have no right to foreclose. The interest payments typically cumulate for a short period of time-usually two to three years-and then are added to the principal. Income bonds, in sum, are securities that appear to have all the supposed tax advantages of debt, without the bankruptcy cost disadvantages. In sum, the great emphasis on bankruptcy costs in recent discussions of optimal capital structure policy seems to me to have been misplaced. TAXES AND CAPITAL STRUCTURES: THE EMPIRICAL RECORD If the optimal capital structure were simply a matter of balancing tax advantages against bankruptcy costs, why have observed capital structures shown so little change over time? First observation in 1960 under the auspices of the Commission on Money and Credit: I found, among other things, that the debt/asset ratio of the typical nonfinancial corporation in the 1950's was little different from that of the 1920's despite the fact that tax rates had quintupled-from 10 and 11 percent in the 1920's to 52 percent in the 1950's TAXES AND CAPITAL STRUCTURES: THE EMPIRICAL RECORD Such rise as did occur, moreover, seemed to be mainly a substitution of debt for preferred stock, rather than of debt for common stock. The year-to-year variations in debt ratios reflected primarily the cyclical movements of the economy. During expansions debt ratios tended to fall, partly because the lag of dividends behind earnings built up internally generated equity; and partly because the ratio of equity to debt in new financings tended to rise when the stock market was booming. TAXES AND CAPITAL STRUCTURES: THE EMPIRICAL RECORD Some upward drift in debt ratios did appear to be taking place in the 1960's, at least in book-value terms Some substantial portion of this seeming rise, however, is a consequence of the liberalization of depreciation deductions in the early 1960’s An accounting change of that kind reduces reported taxable earnings and, barring an induced reduction in dividend policy, Will tend to push accumulated retained earnings (and total assets) below the levels that would otherwise have been recorded Thus, without considerable further adjustment, direct comparison of current and recent debt ratios to those of earlier eras is no longer possible. TAXES AND CAPITAL STRUCTURES: THE EMPIRICAL RECORD The increases in debt of such concern in 1974 can be seen to be a transitory response to a peculiar configuration of events rather than a permanent shift in corporate capital structures.
A surge in inventory accumulation was taking place as firms
sought to hedge against shortages occasioned by embargoes or price controls or crop failures. Much of this accumulation was financed by short-term borrowing-a combination that led to a sharp deterioration in such conventional measures of financial health as "quick ratios" and especially coverage ratios TAXES AND CAPITAL STRUCTURES: THE EMPIRICAL RECORD But this inventory bubble burst soon after the famous doomsday issue of Business Week hit the stands
And since failure to close the gap cannot convincingly be
attributed to the bankruptcy costs or agency costs of debt financing, there would seem to be only one way left to turn: the tax advantages of debt financing must be substantially less than the conventional wisdom suggests THE TAX ADVANTAGES OF DEBT FINANCING REEXAMINED
When the personal income tax is taken into account along with the corporation income tax, the gain from leverage, GL, for the stockholders in a firm holding real assets can be shown to be given by the following expression:
All the taxes are assumed to be proportional,
And to maintain continuity with the earlier MM papers, the expression is given in its "perpetuity"form SPECIAL CASES:
When all tax rates are set equal to zero, the expression does indeed reduce to the standard MM no-tax result of When the personal income tax rate on income from bonds is the same as that on income from shares-a special case of which, of course, is when there is assumed to be no personal income tax at all-then the gain from leverage is the familiar When the tax rate on income from shares is less than the tax on income from bonds, then the gain from leverage will be less than For a wide range of values for and the gain from leverage vanishes entirely or even turns negative! The gain evaporates or turns into a loss because investors hold securities for the "consumption possibilities" they generate and hence will evaluate them in terms of their yields net of all tax drains If, therefore, the personal tax on income from common stocks is less than that on income from bonds, then the before-tax return on taxable bonds has to be high enough, other things equal, to offswt this tax handicap. Otherwise, no taxable investor would want to hold bonds. Thus, while it is still true that the owners of a levered corporation have the advantage of deducting their interest payments to bondholders in computing their corporate income tax, these interest payments have already been "grossed up," so to speak, by any differential in the taxes that the bondholders will have to pay on their interest income.
When the rates happen to satisfy the equation the offset is one-for-one and the owners of the corporation reap no gain whatever from their use of tax-deductible debt rather than equity capital. Any situation in which the owners of corpora- tions could increase their wealth by substituting debt for equity (or vice versa) would be incompatible with market equilibrium. Their attempts to exploit these opportunities would lead, in a world with progressive income taxes, to changes in the yields on stocks and bonds and in their ownership patterns. These changes, in turn, restore the equilibrium and remove the incentives to issue more debt, even without invoking bankruptcy costs or lending costs as a deus ex machina. TAXES AND MARKET EQUILIBRIUM Suppose, for simplicity that the personal tax rate on income from stock were zero Suppose that all bonds are riskless and that there are no transaction costs, flotation costs or surveillance costs involved in their issuance : TAXES AND MARKET EQUILIBRIUM
To entice these taxable investors into the market for corporate bonds, the rate of interest on such bonds has to be high enough to compensate for the taxes on interest income under the personal income tax. The intersection of this demand curve with the horizontal straight line through the point , i.e., the tax-exempt rate grossed up by the corporate tax rate, determines the market equilibrium. If corporations were to offer a quantity of bonds greater than B*, interest rates would be driven above and some levered firms would find leverage to be a losing proposition. If the volume were below B*, interest rates would be lower than and some unlevered firms would find it advantageous PROPERTIES OF MARKET EQUILIBRIUM There will be an equilibrium level of aggregate corporate debt, B*, and hence an equilbrium debt-equity ratio for the corporate sector as a whole. But there would be no optimum debt ratio for any individual firm. Companies following a no-leverage or low leverage strategy (like I.B.M. or Kodak) would find a market among investors in the high tax brackets; those opting for a high leverage strategy (like the electric utilities) would find the natural clientele for their securities at the other end of the scale. And in this important sense it would still be true that the value of any firm, in equilibrium, would be independent of its capital structure, despite the deductibility of interest payments in computing corporate income taxes. IF THE STOCKHOLDERS OF LEVERED CORPORA- TIONS DON'T REAP THE BENEFITS OF THE TAX GAINS FROM LEVERAGE, WHO DOES?
Universities and other tax exempt organizations, as well as
individuals in low tax brackets benefit from what might be called a "bondholders' surplus." Market interest rates have to be grossed up to pay the taxes of the marginal bondholder, whose tax rate in equilibrium will be equal to the corporate rate. Low bracket individuals (and corporations) have to pay the corporate tax, in effect, when they want to borrow. An equilibrium of the kind pictured in Figure 1 does not require, of course, that the effective personal tax rate on income from shares of the marginal holder be literally zero, but only that it be substantially less than his or her rate on income from bonds. MARKET EQUILIBRIUM AND THE BEHAVIOR OF FIRMS AND INDIVIDUALS CONCLUSSIONS: To say that many, perhaps even most, financial heuristics are neutral is not to suggest, however, that financial decision making is just a pointless charade or treat the resources devoted to financial innoviations are wasted. Neutral mutations that serve no function, but do no harm, can persist indefinitely. A mutation or a heuristic that is neutral in one environment may suddenly acquire (or lose) survival value if the environment changes.