Chap 016
Chap 016
Chap 016
McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2010 by the McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.
Key Concepts and Skills
Understand the effect of financial leverage
(i.e., capital structure) on firm earnings
Understand homemade leverage
Understand capital structure theories with and
without taxes
Be able to compute the value of the unlevered
and levered firm
16-1
Chapter Outline
16.1 The Capital Structure Question and The Pie Theory
16.2 Maximizing Firm Value versus Maximizing
Stockholder Interests
16.3 Financial Leverage and Firm Value: An Example
16.4 Modigliani and Miller: Proposition II (No Taxes)
16.5 Taxes
16-2
16.1 Capital Structure and the Pie
The value of a firm is defined to be the sum of the
value of the firm’s debt and the firm’s equity.
V=B+S
10.00 Debt
8.00 No Debt
point to debt
4.00
2.00
0.00
1,000 2,000 3,000
(2.00) Disadvantage EBIT in dollars, no taxes
to debt 16-8
Assumptions of the M&M Model
Homogeneous Expectations
Homogeneous Business Risk Classes
Perpetual Cash Flows
Perfect Capital Markets:
Perfect competition
Firms and investors can borrow/lend at the same rate
Equal access to all relevant information
No transaction costs
No taxes
16-9
Homemade Leverage: An Example
Recession Expected Expansion
EPS of Unlevered Firm $2.50 $5.00 $7.50
Earnings for 40 shares $100 $200 $300
Less interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64
Net Profits $36 $136 $236
ROE (Net Profits / $1,200) 3.0% 11.3% 19.7%
We are buying 40 shares of a $50 stock, using $800 in margin.
We get the same ROE as if we bought into a levered firm.
B $800 2
Our personal debt-equity ratio is:
S $1,200 3 16-10
Homemade (Un)Leverage: An Example
Recession Expected Expansion
EPS of Levered Firm $1.50 $5.67 $9.83
Earnings for 24 shares $36 $136 $236
Plus interest on $800 (8%) $64 $64 $64
Net Profits $100 $200 $300
ROE (Net Profits / $2,000) 5% 10% 15%
Buying 24 shares of an otherwise identical levered firm along
with some of the firm’s debt gets us to the ROE of the unlevered
firm.
This is the fundamental insight of M&M
16-11
MM Proposition I (No Taxes)
We can create a levered or unlevered position
by adjusting the trading in our own account.
This homemade leverage suggests that capital
structure is irrelevant in determining the value
of the firm:
VL = VU
16-12
16.4 MM Proposition II (No Taxes)
Proposition II
Leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders
Rs = R0 + (B / SL) (R0 - RB)
RB is the interest rate (cost of debt)
Rs is the return on (levered) equity (cost of equity)
R0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital)
B is the value of debt
SL is the value of levered equity
16-13
MM Proposition II (No Taxes)
The derivation is straightforward:
B S
RW ACC RB RS Then set RWACC R0
BS BS
B S BS
RB RS R0 multiply both sides by
BS BS S
BS B BS S BS
RB RS R0
S BS S BS S
B BS
RB RS R0
S S
B B B
RB RS R0 R0 RS R0 ( R0 RB )
S S S
16-14
MM Proposition II (No Taxes)
Cost of capital: R (%)
B
RS R0 ( R0 RB )
SL
B S
R0 RW ACC RB RS
BS BS
RB RB
Debt-to-equity Ratio B
S
16-15
16.5 MM Propositions I & II (With Taxes)
Proposition I (with Corporate Taxes)
Firm value increases with leverage
VL = VU + TC B
Proposition II (with Corporate Taxes)
Some of the increase in equity risk and return is
offset by the interest tax shield
RS = R0 + (B/S)×(1-TC)×(R0 - RB)
RB is the interest rate (cost of debt)
RS is the return on equity (cost of equity)
R0 is the return on unlevered equity (cost of capital)
B is the value of debt
S is the value of levered equity 16-16
MM Proposition I (With Taxes)
The total cash flow to all stakeholde rs is
( EBIT RB B) (1 TC ) RB B
The present value of this stream of cash flows is VL
Clearly ( EBIT RB B) (1 TC ) RB B
EBIT (1 TC ) RB B (1 TC ) RB B
EBIT (1 TC ) RB B RB BTC RB B
The present value of the first term is VU
The present value of the second term is TCB
VL VU TC B 16-17
MM Proposition II (With Taxes)
Start with M&M Proposition I with taxes: VL VU TC B
Since VL S B S B VU TC B
VU S B(1 TC )
The cash flows from each side of the balance sheet must equal:
SRS BRB VU R0 TC BRB
SRS BRB [S B(1 TC )]R0 TC RB B
Divide both sides by S
B B B
RS RB [1 (1 TC )]R0 TC RB
S S S
B
Which quickly reduces to RS R0 (1 TC ) ( R0 RB )
S 16-18
The Effect of Financial Leverage
Cost of capital: R B
(%) RS R0 ( R0 RB )
SL
B
RS R0 (1 TC ) ( R0 RB )
SL
R0
B SL
RW ACC RB (1 TC ) RS
BSL B SL
RB
Debt-to-equity
ratio (B/S) 16-19
Total Cash Flow to Investors
Recession Expected Expansion
EBIT $1,000 $2,000 $3,000
Interest 0 0 0
All Equity
S G S G
The levered firm pays less in taxes than does the all-equity firm.
Thus, the sum of the debt plus the equity of the levered firm is
greater than the equity of the unlevered firm.
This is how cutting the pie differently can make the pie “larger.”
-the government takes a smaller slice of the pie!
16-21
Summary: No Taxes
In a world of no taxes, the value of the firm is unaffected by
capital structure.
This is M&M Proposition I:
VL = VU
Proposition I holds because shareholders can achieve any
pattern of payouts they desire with homemade leverage.
In a world of no taxes, M&M Proposition II states that
leverage increases the risk and return to stockholders.
B
RS R0 ( R0 RB )
SL
16-22
Summary: Taxes
In a world of taxes, but no bankruptcy costs, the value of the
firm increases with leverage.
This is M&M Proposition I:
VL = VU + TC B
Proposition I holds because shareholders can achieve any
pattern of payouts they desire with homemade leverage.
In a world of taxes, M&M Proposition II states that leverage
increases the risk and return to stockholders.
B
RS R0 (1 TC ) ( R0 RB )
SL
16-23
Quick Quiz
Why should stockholders care about
maximizing firm value rather than just the
value of the equity?
How does financial leverage affect firm value
without taxes? With taxes?
What is homemade leverage?
16-24