Solow S Model and Growth Accounting
Solow S Model and Growth Accounting
Solow S Model and Growth Accounting
1. The models inner force (the diminishing returns to scale of capital, in particular) takes the economy smoothly to its Steady State. This is the state where output and capital grow at the same rate as population (labour). This means that per-capita income and capital-labour ratio (K/L = k) are constant at the steady state. Once the steady state is reached, the growth of per-capita income can come only from technical progress which is exogenous and un-explainable by the model.
2.
3.
An increase in saving rate (or any policy change to stimulate income) increases per-capita income but do not leave lasting effect on growth rate. The economy moves to a new steady state (with higher per-capita income, higher k and lower marginal productivity of capital). Once the economy reaches the new steady state, per-capita growth would be nil again (i.e total income will increase at the rate of population growth.)
An increase in population growth leads to lower per-capita income and lower k. But the economy settles back again at a new steady state whereby K and Y will be growing at the same new rate of population.
4.
6.
7.
Growth Accounting
Start with a Cobb-Douglas production function: Y =A K . L1- Where Y is output, K is capital , L is labour, A is a constant (to secures homogeneity of measuring units) and is a parameter. Cobb-Douglas function is a standard neoclassical function which exhibits: A considerable substitution possibility between the two inputs K and L. The elasticity of substitution is constant and equal one. Constant returns to scale with respect to all production inputs: + (1 - ) = 1. Diminishing returns to scale with respect to each input: < 1 and 1- < 1. This means that successive increases in K (or in L) lead to smaller and smaller increases in Y. Technically, the same can be expressed by saying that the first partial derivative of Y (with respect to L or to K) is positive, while the second is negative.
Growth Accounting
Y =A K . L 1-
The first partial derivative of Y, with respects to K, measures the increase in output due from deploying an extra unit of capital. This is the marginal productivity of capital (MPC): Y/ K = ( K-1 ) . A L 1- = . A K . L1- / K = . (Y/K) On the other hand, MPC = real rental cost of capital (the real interest rate) in equilibrium: (Y/K) = r / p (1) The partial derivative of Y with respect to labour gives the marginal productivity of labour (MPL): Y/L = (1- ) L1- -1 . A K = (1- ) . A K . L1- / L = (1 - ) . (Y/L). On the other hand, MPL matches the real wage rate in equilibrium. Thus: (1- ) Y/L = w/p (2)
Growth Accounting
Competitive equilibrium ensures that production factors receive their fair shares
of income, i.e. rewards to labour and capital equal their contributions in the production. I.e. the factors of production are paid according to their marginal productivities. The share of labour in total income is (MPL) . L/Y or (w/p) . (L /Y) Substituting the value of w/p from (2), the share of labour in Y (in the GDP) would equal (1- ) .
This is an interesting result. It affirms that the parameters of the Cobb-Douglas production function, 1- and , are non other than the shares of labour and capital in total GDP. Empirically, the actual share of labour in the GDP was found to be about 2/3 in the US. This means that (1- ) = 2/3, and therefore the share of capital in the GDP is = 1/3.
The production function becomes then Y = AK1/3 . L2/3 , and this can be
approximated by the following expression: gy = 1/3 gk + 2/3 gl where gy, gk and gl are growth rates of income, capital and labour. Thus, income growth during a certain period should match the growth in capital and labour weighted by their shares of the GDP. If the left-hand side turned to be larger than the right-hand side, the difference (the residual) is thought to be due to improved efficiency, a result of productivity growth.
Growth Accounting
Therefore, once we know the extra amounts of K and L deployed, the production function Y = A K1/3 . L2/3 gives the increase in Y (or GDP) due from these extra inputs. However, when this is compared with the actual growth rate in Y, the exercise can help to test the accuracy of the equation, and to determine the effects of other variables which are not taken into account in the production function.
When actual historic growth rates of capital, labour and GDP in the US, for the period 1890-1995, were inserted in the production function, it appeared that some 55% of the actual growth in the GDP was not explained by the function, i.e. was neither due from deployment of more capital or more labour. This unexplained growth is called Solows Residual: the portion of actual growth in GDP which is not explained by the use of more inputs. Solow referred to it as a measure of our ignorance. Economists argue that this unexplained growth results from improvements in total factor productivity (TFP). The increases in TFP refer to improvements in efficiency, in inputs productivities. The efficiency gains allow for producing more output from the use of the same amounts of inputs.
Growth Accounting
Several empirical studies have been conducted (on basis of the above explained methodology) to figure out the sources of actual growth in various parts of the world. For example, average annual growth rate in Latin America during 1944-85 was 5.3%. The sources of this growth were as follow:
2.5% (or 47% of total) came from more capital use 1.3% (or 25% of the total) came from more labour
1.5% (or only 28% of the total growth) resulted from better TFP Needless to say that the TFP is the most critical factor in determining long term growth, since all societies will confront ultimate limits on the amounts of labour and capital they can deploy. One study (Klenow et al, 1997) shows that 60% of income per capita differences among countries in 1985 cannot be explained by differences in physical or human capital. For an overview of
growth accounting in the LDCs see Agnor et. al. (1996) chapter 15.
Convergence
One of the most important implications of the neoclassical growth model is the convergence hypothesis:
Absolute convergence: poorer countries (i.e. countries or regions with lower k, thus with lower per-capita income) will grow faster than richer countries. This means that per-capita income in all countries will smoothly converge (and will be the same everywhere if full capital mobility prevails.) Conditional convergence: when a pair of countries are reasonably close to their steady states, the country which is further away from its steady state will grow faster than the one which is closer. This is a weaker proposition than the above, since it permits rich countries to grow faster than the poor. Numerous empirical studies are devoted to test these hypothesis. The results are mixed: convergence is well documented among regions in a single country. Also conditional convergence is more or less accepted among the rich countries, although it happens at a much slower rate than predicted by the model. As to the LDCs, the difficulties of identifying the steady state (and the corresponding per-capita income) in each country lead to widely contradicting results. (see, for example, Mankiew, Romer & Weil, 1992)
The AK models. Allowing for increasing returns while maintaining the norms of competitive equilibrium is done in a somewhat tricky manner. The approach assumes that capital has two different effects on output: a direct (private) effect which is rewarded by the usual marginal productivity, and an indirect social effect. The social effect is a by-product, accidental and unintended by those who make investment decisions. This by-product effect leads to higher capital productivity for the economy as a whole and eliminate the diminishing returns. The indirect effect works either via improving the efficiency of capital (Phelpss embodied technical progress), or via improving the effectiveness of labour (Arrows learning by doing) or via cultivating the human capital (Lucas model)..
The AK models then attempt to resolve the dilemma between allowing for nondiminishing returns and securing competitive equilibrium by suggesting that private investment brings about certain externalities (spill-over like technical progress, education, etc) which benefits the society as a whole. The private returns on investment are still the (diminishing) marginal product but the total benefits for the economy as a whole are much higher: capital exhibits constant returns for the society as a whole. This approach is known as AK, because it suggests an aggregate (social) production functions of the type Y = AK , with no diminishing marginal product (and thus no necessary slow down or convergence.)