Sachs 1995
Sachs 1995
Sachs 1995
Author(s): Jeffrey D. Sachs, Andrew Warner, Anders Åslund and Stanley Fischer
Source: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1995, No. 1, 25th Anniversary Issue
(1995), pp. 1-118
Published by: Brookings Institution Press
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2534573 .
Accessed: 24/09/2013 08:31
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Brookings Institution Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity.
http://www.jstor.org
1. Lucas (1988) and Young (1991) observe that standard trade theory predicts an effect
of openness on the level, not the long-run growth rate, of GDP. Of course, a level effect
can appear as a growth effect for long periods of time, since adjustments in real economies
may take place over decades. Some recent theory has introduced various forms of increas-
ing returns to scale with the result that openness can affect long-term growth as well as the
level of income. See Young (1991), Grossman and Helpman (1991), Eicher (1993), and Lee
(1993).
2. Some developing countries, such as Peru, Sri Lanka, and several Central American
countries, were rather open at the end of World War II, but then moved into a prolonged
phase of import substitution in the 1950s and 1960s.
3. See Sachs, Tornell, and Velasco (1995) and Warner (1994) regarding the Mexican
crisis.
One and one-half centuries ago, two close observers of the capitalist
revolution in Western Europe made a pithy prediction about the course
of global economic change. Marx and Engels correctly sensed the un-
precedented efficiency of the industrial capitalism that had emerged.
They predicted that as a result of superior economic efficiency, capital-
ism would eventually sweep through the entire world, compelling other
societies to restructure along the lines of Western Europe. In the pun-
gent rhetoric of the Communist Manifesto they expostulated that:
The bourgeoisie,by the rapidimprovementof all instrumentsof production,by
the immenselyfacilitatedmeans of communication,draws all, even the most
barbarian,nationsinto civilization.The cheap prices of its commoditiesare the
heavy artillerywithwhich it battersdown all Chinesewalls, with whichit forces
the barbarians'intenselyobstinatehatredof foreignersto capitulate.It compels
all nations, on pain of extinction,to adoptthe bourgeoismode of production;it
compels them to introducewhat it calls civilizationinto their midst, i.e., to be-
come bourgeoisthemselves. In one word, it createsa worldafterits own image.4
Marx and Engels got much disastrously wrong in their predictions,
but they correctly sensed the decisive global implications of capitalism.
As they foresaw, capitalism eventually spread to nearly the entire
world, in a complex and sometimes violent process that dramatically
raised worldwide living standards but also provoked social upheaval and
war. It is often forgotten today, in the flush of the communist collapse
after 1989, that global capitalism has emerged twice, at the end of the
nineteenth century as well as the end of the twentieth century. The ear-
lier global capitalist system peaked around 1910 but subsequently disin-
tegrated in the first half of the twentieth century, between the outbreak
of World War I and the end of World War II. The reemergence of a
global, capitalist market economy since 1950, and especially since the
mid-1980s, in an important sense reestablishes the global market econ-
omy that had existed one hundred years earlier.
The first episode of global capitalism, of course, came about as much
through the instruments of violent conquest and colonial rule as through
economic reform and the development of international institutions.
Starting around 1840, Western European powers wielded their superior
As in the late twentieth century, the emergence of the first global sys-
tem was based on the interaction of technology and economic institu-
tions. Long-distance transport and communications achieved break-
throughs similar to those in the present.7 The Suez Canal, completed in
1869, and the Panama Canal, completed in 1914, dramatically cut inter-
national shipping times, as did the progressive development of faster
and larger steamships from the 1840s. New railways in India, Russia, the
United States, and Latin America-often built with foreign finance-
opened vast, fertile territories for settlement and economic develop-
ment. The spread of telegraph lines and transoceanic cables from the
1850s linked the world at electronic speed. Military innovations, partic-
ularly the breech-loading rifle in the 1840s, combined with mass-produc-
tion made possible by industrialization, decisively shifted the military
advantage to Europe. Medical advances, particularly the use of quinine
as a preventative against malaria, played a pivotal role in the spread of
European settlements, domination, and investment, especially in Af-
rica. Without doubt, these technological breakthroughs were as revolu-
tionary in underpinning the emerging global system as those of our own
age.
On the economic level, key institutions similarly spread on a global
scale. International gold and silver standards became nearly universal
after the 1870s, eventually embracing North and South America, Eu-
rope, Russia, Japan, China, as well as other European colonies and inde-
pendent countries. By 1908 roughly 89 percent of the world's population
lived in countries with convertible currencies under the gold or silver
standard.8 Basic legal institutions, such as business and commercial
imports stayed below 10 percent in France, Germany, and the United Kingdom; between
10 and 20 percent in Italy; between 20 and 30 percent in the United States; and between 20
and 40 percent in Russia.
7. See Headrick (1981).
8. See Eichengreen and Flandreau (1994, p. 9). The countries on the gold or silver stan-
dards in 1908 include, in Europe: United Kingdom, France, Belgium, Switzerland, Italy,
Germany, Netherlands, Portugal, and Romania; in North America: United States and
Canada; in Central America: Mexico, Nicaragua, Guatemala, Honduras, Salvador, and
Costa Rica; in South America: Peru, Chile, Brazil, Venezuela, and Argentina; in Asia and
the Pacific: India, China, Indonesia, Japan, Siam, Philippines, and Australia; and in the
Middle East: the Ottoman Empire, Egypt, and Persia. The national currencies were con-
vertible into gold in all cases except the following: Italy, Austria, Spain, Portugal, Nicara-
gua, Guatemala, Peru, Chile, Brazil, and Venezuela. The Italian and Austrian currencies
were stable though not convertible.
16. See Thorp (1984) for very insightful essays on the country-by-country experience.
17. Keynes (1933).
18. Keynes (1933, p. 236).
At the end of World War II, the international economic system was
in a shambles. International markets for trade in goods, services, and
financial assets were essentially nonexistent. International trade was de-
stroyed by currency inconvertibility and a web of protectionist mea-
sures stemming from the Great Depression and World War II. When the
IMF published its first comprehensive review of exchange rate arrange-
ments in 1950, only five countries had established freely convertible cur-
rencies under the standard of article VIII of the IMF Articles of
Agreement: the United States and four Latin American countries
pegged to the dollar, El Salvador, Guatemala, Mexico, and Panama.2'
Switzerland, not then a member of the IMF, also had a convertible cur-
rency. The IMF characterized another four countries as having effec-
19. Keynes (1933, p. 236).
20. Keynes (1933, p. 241).
21. IMF, Annual Report on Exchange Restrictions, 1950.
Livelyconvertible currencies, even though they had not yet formally ac-
cepted the obligations of article VIII: Cuba, Dominican Republic,
Honduras, and Venezuela. As late as 1957, only two more countries had
established convertibility subject to article VIII: Canada and Haiti. The
members of the European Community established convertibility in
1958. Most other developing and socialist countries postponed the move
for decades.
While market-based economic linkages were methodically restored
among the leading countries during the 1950s, most of the world's popu-
lation lived in countries that chose fundamentally nonmarket economic
strategies for development. Roughly one-third of the world's population
lived in socialist countries (as measured by Kornai for the year 1986);
another 50 percent or so lived in countries where governments pro-
claimed a kind of "third way" between capitalism and socialism, state-
led industrialization (SLI).2
In figure 1, we show the time profile of the opening of the world econ-
omy in the postwar era, using the specific criteria for openness discussed
below and in the appendix. The world economy was essentially closed
after World War II, and only around 20 percent of the world's population
lived in open economies by 1960. It was not until 1993 that more than
60 percent of the world's GDP, and more than 50 percent of the world's
population, was located in open economies.23 The figure extends up to
1994, so that by our criteria, neither Russia nor China is part of the open
system. If both of these countries cross the threshold to openness (and
trade reforms in 1995 might well lead them to qualify), the proportion of
openness by population would jump another 30 percent, to reach around
87 percent of the world's population; and the proportion of openness by
GDP would jump by another 15 percent, to reach around 83 percent of
the world's GDP (using 1975 weights in both cases).
The governments of almost all the developing countries adopted
either socialist or SLI policies after World War II. This was true of the
22. The population in socialist countries is measured by Kornai (1992, pp. 6-7) for
1986. The population under SLI is based on the authors' calculations using data from Sum-
mers and Heston (1991).
23. Let PO, be the proportion of the world economies that are open in year t, as shown
in figure 1. PO, is constructed as PO, = IVt'75Djt -1, where Dit -1 is a dummy variable set
equal to one if the country is open as of year t - 1, and zero otherwise. W(75is the weight
of country i in the world in 1975. The weights are constructed using 1975 population data
and 1975 real GDP data from version 5.6 of the data in Summers and Heston (1991).
0.9 _
0.8 -
0.7-
0.6 -
By 1975 r-ealGDP ~
0.5 -
0.4 -
0.2 -------------------
0.-I
0.1
countries had convertible currencies or low external tariff rates, the gov-
ernment of any individual developing country naturally viewed its trad-
ing prospects with considerable skepticism. This "export pessimism"
was shared by a wide range of postwar economic analysts. Moreover,
since the value of trade liberalization generally depends on the openness
of potential trading partners, the choice of closed trading policies can
be understood, in part, as a kind of low-level trading equilibrium.24This
explanation helps to account for the delay in liberalization in most devel-
oping countries after World War II. It is not as helpful, however, in ex-
plaining the behavior of about one dozen countries (mainly in Central
and South America, as noted later) that were relatively open in the late
1940s, but closed up during the 1950s and early 1960s.25Nor does the
closed nature of the world economy in the late 1940s explain the persis-
tence of closed policies in developing countries even after the United
States, Canada, the European Community, and Japan had adopted more
outward policies in the 1960s. A full explanation must therefore look to
other factors.
MACROECONOMIC POLICIES. The roots of postwar currency incon-
vertibility at the end of World War II lay as much in macroeconomics as
in trade policy. Although exchange controls were introduced in many
countries during the Great Depression, the pressures of wartime infla-
tionary finance were probably an even greater factor in the spread of in-
convertibility. In country after country, government wartime purchases
were financed through inflationary finance (that is, government bor-
rowing from the central bank), coupled with domestic price controls,
foreign exchange controls, and extensive rationing of goods. By the end
of the war, there was an enormous overhang of nominal money balances
in most countries. In the British Commonwealth, for example, the In-
dian government held large reserves of sterling which were restricted in
use according to imperial monetary policy.
24. Rodriguez (1974), using a two-country model in which each country uses trade
quotas to shift the terms of trade in its favor, shows that zero trade is typically the Nash
equilibrium, since each country optimally responds to a tightening of trade quotas by simi-
larly tightening its own quotas.
25. The "late protectionists" are shown in table 11: Bolivia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, El
Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Jamaica, Kenya, Morocco, Nicaragua, Peru, Sri Lanka,
Syria, Turkey, and Venezuela. Most of the Central American countries closed during the
formation of the Central American Common Market (CACM) in the early 1960s; the An-
dean countries (Bolivia, Ecuador, Peru, and Venezuela) closed partly as the result ofjoint
actions of the Andean Group, and partly as the result of internal political choices.
26. Friedman (1953) has typically been read as an argument for floating rather than
fixed exchange rates. More fundamentally, it is an argument for convertibility (which auto-
matically follows from floating rates) as compared to inconvertibility (which often accom-
panies a fixed exchange rate regime). Friedman reasoned that a commitment to a fixed
exchange rate would almost inevitably lead to balance-of- payments pressures and hence,
multiple exchange rates or other forms of inconvertibility. This was certainly the pattern
as of 1953.
27. See Tomlinson (1992).
Export pessimism combined with the idea of the big push to produce
the highly influential view that open trade would condemn developing
countries to long-term subservience in the international system as raw
materials exporters and manufactured goods importers. Comparative
advantage, it was argued by the Economic Commission of Latin
America (ECLA) and others, was driven by short-run considerations
that would prevent raw materials exporting nations from ever building
up an industrial base. The protection of infant industries was therefore
vital if the developing countries were to escape from their overdepen-
dence on raw materials production. These views spread within the
United Nations system (to regional offices of the United Nations Eco-
nomic Commission), and were adopted largely by the United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD). In 1964 they found
international legal sanction in a new part IV of the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which established that developing coun-
tries should enjoy the right to asymmetric trade policies. While the de-
veloped countries should open their markets, the developing countries
could continue to protect their own markets. Of course, this "right"was
the proverbial rope on which to hang one's own economy!
More radical anti-capitalist views fueled Marxist-inspired revolu-
tions in nearly two dozen countries during the postwar period. Forrest
Colburn offers a masterful evocation of the underlying ideas and sym-
bols common to these revolutions.30 He puts great stress on the role of
ideas, rather than the political economy in motivating the revolutionary
leaders:
The trajectoryof contemporaryrevolutionaryregimesilluminateswhy, at least
in poor countries, the choices of politicalelites are so consequential.In many
such countries,politicalelites are not significantlyconstrainedby eitherthe in-
stitutionsandnormsof governmentor by civil society. Thus, the timefor experi-
mentationand implementationof ideas can be dangerouslycompressed.31
STATE BUILDING. In his classic analysis of European mercantilism,
Eli Heckscher argued that mercantilist trade and industrial policies were
a crucial mechanism by which new nation states consolidated their polit-
30. The list, as provided by Colburn (1994, p. 8) is as follows: Afghanistan (1978), Alge-
ria (1962), Angola (1975), Benin (1972), Bolivia (1952), Burkina Faso (1983), Burma (1962),
Cambodia (1975), China (1949), Cuba (1959), Egypt (1952), Ethiopia (1974), Grenada
(1979), Guinea-Bissau (1974), Laos (1975), North Korea (1948), South Yemen (1967), Viet-
nam (1945). The Iranian revolution (1979) was inspired by Islamic, not Marxist, principles.
31. Colburn (1994, p. 103).
36. Waterbury (1993, p. 10) writes that "for most of the period under scrutiny for each
of the cases, the state has enjoyed considerable autonomy from any constellation of class
actors."
37. Bauer (1954, p. 246).
40. One example is Peru, which maintained open trade during the Odria dictatorship,
between 1948 and 1956. Trade remained relatively free during the democratic presidency
of Manuel Prado (1956-63), but then turned gradually more protectionist under Fernando
Belaunde Terry (1963-68). Peru finally embarked on autarkic, socialist policies under a
left-wing military dictatorship led by Juan Velasco Alvarado (1968-75). Conversely, it was
the Pinochet dictatorship in Chile after 1973 which ended decades of protectionism. For
details, see Skidmore and Smith (1984).
41. See Lipton (1976) and Bates (1981).
we have found eight other developing countries that followed this pat-
tern (see table 1) and thirteen that had episodes of temporary liberaliza-
tion (these periods are identified in parentheses in tables 1-5).
A parallel process of liberalization was underway in the developed
economies, although integration was typically achieved in the 1950s and
1960s, rather than the 1980s and 1990s (see table 4). Note that for the
purposes of this paper, we define developed economies as all countries
with a real GDP of $5,000 or more in 1970, according to the purchasing-
power adjusted data in Summers and Heston.42 This criterion results in
a few classifications that are not standard, namely that Ireland, Greece,
and Portugal are classified as developing countries, while Trinidad and
Tobago and Venezuela are classified as developed. But these unusual
classifications have little impact on our main conclusions.
Our categorization and timing of trade liberalization are fundamental
to tables 1-5 and the subsequent empirical work. We judge a country to
have a closed trade policy if it has at least one of the following character-
istics:
1. Nontariff barriers (NTBs) covering 40 percent or more of trade.
2. Average tariff rates of 40 percent or more.
3. A black market exchange rate that is depreciated by 20 percent or
more relative to the official exchange rate, on average, during the 1970s
or 1980s.
4. A socialist economic system (as defined by Kornai).43
5. A state monopoly on major exports.
Exter-nal External
Year of payments debt High
Count3,y opening' arrears r-eschedulintg itiflationib Relnar ks
Source: External payments arrears, the variable EPA, are recorded in IMF, Annual Repo-t on? Exchange
Restrictions, various issues. External debt rescheduling, the variable DC, is recorded in World Bank (1994c). See
appendix for complete definitions of variables and sources.
a. Dates in parentheses identify temporary liberalizations.
b. High inflation, the variable Hi, indicates annual inflation exceeding 100 percent.
23
44. Our choice of dating is surely subject to further refinement. Our chosen criteria are
useful and objective indicators of trade policy, but we recognize that they are too simplis-
tic. The threshold levels (such as a 20 percent black market premium) are arbitrary, and
the measurements do not account for the general-equilibrium effects of an array of trade
policies. For example, we use nominal tariff rates rather than effective protection rates,
and we do not consider the role of export subsidies in offsetting import protection. The
quantification of nontariff barriers is also inherently difficult. Perhaps most difficult was
judging the year in which openness is first achieved. We relied on a wide array of second-
ary sources, which sometimes contradicted each other. Despite all of these difficulties,
we still believe that our measures of openness and the timing of liberalization convey a
substantial amount of information, though with inevitable error.
Yearof
Countiy openinga
Australia 1964
Austria 1960
Belgium 1960
Canada 1952
Denmark 1960
Finland 1960
France 1959
Germany 1959
Israel 1985
Italy 1959
Japan 1962
Luxembourg 1959
Netherlands 1959
New Zealand 1986
Norway 1960
Spain 1960
Sweden 1960
Switzerland 1950 or earlier
Trinidad and Tobago closed
United Kingdom 1960
United States 1950 or earlier
Venezuela (1950-59) (1989-92)
Source: See appendix.
a. Dates in parentheses identify temporary liberalizations.
rn rn ? cn
oo rq - " \C rn ON t- 00 CD rn "t ob
tr tr q C- - : oo - " ')
r4 t oNo
,C "t CD :t rn C' C)
N~~~~~~~~~
L~~~~~~~~~
~~ OOni *ON0~~~~0N0
x - dcx d3__4< ,
to4 A >rq C, tf .\CN I?t C ,\ ON \C CD .n O:t C) 00 .00 rq
It CD ON n ', t 00 rq \C )
CN, C C ) It C l eclm C', ) Csl
rS CN,< C
X r5 o o o C o
rU*<rnOn r
.N<rO .0<~r QQoo;== N i-niUU UUU *'
~~~~~~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~
u u
~ uC uu
~~~2 uu u
._~~~2
Z" - \C t): CD C 0 0 C ) \C
(Z
r1 C C C
OOONr O O O O O O OO=OOO =O~ CrO O O OrO
Z 5,
?? N_, utio o t.oo
C..C .O o .. O *oo oCN
u to mmmm00Z 711;mmC
28 t~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
BXS=N.NOO==o<oooU
CCC0 s
C)SOOOOOOOO
28
? o N
o ~~~~CD
o~~~~~~~~0
I:o*t Co C? oon (= (=
rn
rq 00 (--uNo
b
0 0 t r< ON N C 00 ON 0n ro ON t ri ?C r? 0000 oo 0 oC 0o r
I-qoN oooouoNoo N b
o ~~~~~
00 rIO ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~00r
X X It 00 Iot
N o o oo^ o
CDo o
0 N 0 N
o ooooU
ooooo oooo^
.o Z Z Z
.~ 00 0 0
a) O l- m ) l - a) ,) a) l- .~*~ . -t 0 -t.?<
? ? NCt C O uN o U UtXo?e
? ?obt tot
U?29
29
no
-m X
n (OO C) N It C o0r no t N 1 0
toL
X .t~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.
(N4 *0 (N oo 0
0( *N O (O C) C0 C) o
CDc )C C~ oCv4
OD
30
o o o o
e' 'r ON
03
E
03
OO~~~~~~~4O t-0
0 o v
>. >>
03
t
0 Z -=
o 00
4)> > _
00 * - E
00 E E
000
? =? ?
a> 0 E E
?
U
0Z-
*L==CC0 4)
CZ
CZ
t9 cL Q Q Q Q
ct
~~>
>
E E
31
and Indonesia (1970). It has become fashionable to argue that East Asian
countries are not really open or market-oriented, and that, in fact, they
systematically "got the prices wrong" to spur industrial growth.46 It is
surely true that Korea, Taiwan and Indonesia are not laissez faire, but
they and their neighbors in Southeast Asia, Thailand and Malaysia, have
been more open to trade than other developing countries, based on ob-
jective indicators of trade policy, shown in table 7. All of the East Asian
economies have low or zero BMPs; all but Thailand have low tariff rates;
and all but Taiwan have low NTB coverage. Moreover, the Thai tariffs
and the Taiwanese NTBs are moderate, not extreme.
In a later paper we intend to specify a detailed model of the timing of
liberalization during the postwar period. Here we simply test a few of the
simplest propositions that arise from political economy considerations:
that timing should be related to the relative endowments of labor and
land, the size of the economy, the per capita income, and perhaps the
previous political history (for example, number of years since indepen-
dence). As described above, we would expect the transition to openness
to be faster in land-scarce and labor-abundant economies, since it is
plausible that governments will tend to be more responsive to the inter-
ests of labor over landowners. We would also expect the transition to
46. See Wade (1990) with regard to Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan,
and Amsden (1989) with regard to South Korea.
In this section we show that during the period 1970-89 open econo-
mies outperformed closed economies on three main dimensions of eco-
nomic performance: economic growth, avoidance of extreme macroec-
onomic crises, and structural change. In the process we demonstrate the
close relationship between economic integration and economic conver-
gence, that is, poor countries tend to grow faster than richer countries,
as long as the poor and rich countries are linked together by international
trade. Poor, closed economies have often performed significantly less
well than the richer countries.
For the purposes of this section, we define a country as open if it satis-
fies the five policy criteria for the duration of the 1970s and 1980s. Coun-
tries that were closed during part of this period but subsequently liberal-
ized are treated as closed economies. In the following section, we pick
up the trail of those economies by examining the effects of relatively late
trade liberalization on economic performance.
48. Four developed economies were closed for part of the period: Israel, New
Zealand, Trinidad and Tobago, and Venezuela. While three of these countries are not nor-
mally classified as developed, on a purchasing power parity basis, their per capita GDP
exceeded $5,000 in 1970, and thus they qualify as developed by the standard used in this
paper.
Figure 2. Average Growth of Eight Always Open and Forty Always Closed Economies,
1966-90
Growthratea
0.15
0.14
0.13 -
0.12 -
0.11 _
0.10 _
0.09 /Open
0.08 -
0.07 -
0.06 -
0.05 -
0.04 -
0.03 - loe
0.02 -----Closed-
0.01 -%00
0.00 %
-0.01
-0.02'
-0.03-
-0.04-
-0.05 I l l I
1965 1970 1975 1980 1985
Source: Authors' calculations using version 5.6 of the data in Summers and Heston (1991).
a. Figure shows three-year moving averages.
Botswanae * Korea,R. of
* Taiwan
6 Singapore* * Hong Kong
Yemen * China
Indonesiae
* Mauritius
4 - Thailand* 0 Malaysia
0 Cyprus
%Hungary * Japan
Sri Lanka D Brazi 0 Ireland Norwa4 Finland *Canada
Burundie0 I a Gec 0*Iay o Austria 0 Luxembourg
2 2- _ CamerA
Camer~A k2lg4ia *Greece0 Israel
rItaly
4 * 0 DemBaelgium
BegUm Lxmor
'e tts
Jm Congo *lexico DenmaOFranct
Bur1na Faso Costaicga Trinidad* Netherlands S'Sfwl zerland.
& Tobago
JH5iti 9PanaAa
Guinead Gambia * South Africa
Ethiopia 00 * GJaa
NigetP * Nicaragua
Angola *.Madagascar
*Mozambique
-2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
1970 GDP per capita (thousandsof 1985 dollars)
Source: Version 5.5 of the data in Summers and Heston (1991) and World Bank (1994d).
the economy, then the aggregate economy may be freed from the dimin-
ishing marginal productivity of capital that is characteristic of standard
production processes. In this case, the rich countries could continue to
stay ahead of the poor countries, since their higher income would reflect
higher levels of learning or human skills, which in turn would raise the
future productivity of capital.
Romer's hypothesis, while intriguing, seems to be contradicted by
other data, which show convergence within more restricted subsamples
of economies. For example, Steve Dowrick and Duc-Tho Nguyen show
that the advanced economies of the Organisation for Economic Co-op-
eration and Development (OECD) displayed strong tendencies of con-
vergence in the postwar period, with the relatively poor OECD econo-
mies tending to grow more rapidly than the richer economies, thereby
closing the proportionate income gap. Similarly, Williamson and associ-
ates in several studies find evidence for convergence among the leading
economies during the period of internationalization at the end of the
nineteenth century. Robert Barro and Xavier Sala-i-Martin find strong
evidence of convergence in living standards among U.S. states and Jap-
anese prefectures. Dan Ben-David shows strong convergence among
the members of the European Community and the European Free Trade
Area, with the dispersion of income falling as trade liberalization pro-
ceeded.51
The contrasting evidence has given rise to two related hypotheses.
William Baumol and others have suggested that there may be a conver-
gence club, meaning a subset of countries for which convergence ap-
plies, while countries outside of the club would not necessarily experi-
ence convergence relative to those within it: "It also seems clear that
convergence does not apply to the poorest of the world economies,
though the line separating those eligible for membership in the conver-
gence club and those foreclosed from membership has not been deter-
mined definitively."52 Baumol suggests that only countries with an ade-
quate initial level of human capital endowments can take advantage of
modern technology to enjoy convergent growth. He therefore speaks of
the "advantages of moderate backwardness," arguing that while middle-
income developing countries can take advantage of their lag in technol-
51. See Dowrick and Nguyen (1989), Williamson (1992), Barro and Sala-i-Martin
(1991), and Ben-David (1993).
52. Baumol, Nelson, and Wolff (1994, p. 82).
ogy to borrow from abroad, the poorest countries are unable to bridge
the gap in technology and knowledge.53
Barro and Sala-i-Martin have introduced the related notion of condi-
tional convergence, in which countries differ in their long-run per capita
income levels, with each country tending to grow more rapidly the
greater is the gap between its initial per capita income level and its own
long-run per capita income level.54 Formally, country i is assumed to
have the long-run per capita income level yi*, and initial per capita in-
come level yi. The rate of growth, ji, is assumed to be an increasing func-
tion of the gap between yi* and yi:
the literature for the absence of convergence shown in figure 3. The first
holds that productive technology is intrinsically kind to the technologi-
cal leader: the rich tend to grow richer as a result of increasing returns
to scale in one form or another.58The second holds that convergence is
a fact of life, but only among countries with a sound human capital base
for using modern technology. The third holds that currently poor coun-
tries have a low long-term potential income level (yi*), though countries
do tend to grow faster the greater is the gap between their current in-
come and their own long-run potential.
The first two interpretations, and possibly the third, would be pro-
foundly pessimistic for the poorer countries today, since they suggest
that the poorer countries will be unable to close the gap with the richer
countries. The conditional convergence hypothesis is ambiguous on this
fundamental point. If the low long-term potential income of the poor
countries that it posits is due to preferences and initial skill levels, then
it too is profoundly pessimistic. In this case the hypothesis is akin to
Baumol's convergence club. On the other hand, if the low long-term po-
tential income is due to bad policies, then convergence could still be
achieved by policy changes.
We suggest that the most parsimonious reading of the evidence is that
convergence can be achieved by all countries, even those with low ini-
tial levels of skills, as long as they are open and integrated in the world
economy. In this interpretation, the convergence club is the club of
economies linked together by international trade: thus the OECD, the
European Community, the late-nineteenth-century economies, the U.S.
states, and the Japanese prefectures all tend to show convergence. In
terms of the conditional convergence hypothesis, we argue that the ap-
parent differences in long-term income levels are not differences due to
fundamental tastes and technologies, but rather to policies regarding
economic integration.
The role of policy choices in convergence is dramatically evident in
figures 4 and 5, where we divide the sample in figure 3 into groups of
open and closed economies. Figure 4 shows that the open countries dis-
play a strong tendency toward economic convergence, and that the
countries with initially low per capita income levels grow more rapidly
58. Increasing returns to scale is shorthand for a wide variety of technological possibil-
ities, such as learning by doing, spillovers in knowledge accumulation, agglomeration
economies among suppliers of specialized inputs to production, etc.
-2
A I I
-2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
1970 GDP per capita (thousandsof 1985 dollars)
Source: Authors' calculations using version 5.5 of the data in Summers and Heston (1991).
than the richer countries.59 The closed economies in figure 5 do not dis-
play any tendency toward convergence. In fact, they are clearly the
source of the failure of convergence noted in figure 3. Even more strik-
ing, there is not a single country in our sample (which covers 111 coun-
tries and approximately 98 percent of the non-communist world in 1970)
which pursued open trade policies during the entire period 1970-89 and
yet had per capita growth of less than 1.2 percent per year (Switzerland
had the lowest growth, at 1.24 percent). And not a single open devel-
oping country grew at less than 2 percent per year (Greece, at 2.38 per-
cent, and Jordan, at 2.58 percent, are the lowest)!
59. The open economies also exhibit convergence in the sense of having a declining
dispersion of GDP over time (sigma-convergence in Barro and Sala-i-Martin's terminol-
ogy). For the open economies the standard deviation of the log of GDP was 0.83 in 1970
and 0.75 in 1989.
Annualgrowth
per capita (percent)
8
Botswana e
6-
* China
4 -
Tunisia* *Hungary
SriLanka Braz~
Burundi a Y D#
2 Camer(Ab lgejia * Israel
* to
as0 *Mexico
Congo Costa
BurkinaFaso Rica *Trinidad * New Zealand
O
Rwanda Chile
**tiPanat*a ~ & Tobago
&Tbg
Guine aGambia Southon
Africa
_O
Ethiopia@ e * *
Jamaica-Iraq
Benin
S
Sierra @etha *Argentina
Leone *Ocentral Afrcan RR.*retn
Iran * Venezuela
-2 - Chad*
Nige1% * * Nicaragua
Angola *eMadagascar
* Mozambique
A l l l l l l I
-2 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14
1970 GDP per capita (thousandsof 1985 dollars)
Source: Authors' calculations using version 5.5 of the data in Summers and Heston (1991) and World Bank (1994d).
So far we have analyzed growth per capita rather than growth per
worker. The reason is that per capita growth rates are available for a
longer time span than the per worker growth rates, which often rely on
less frequent census data. However, since some theories (the Solow
model in particular) predict convergence more precisely in terms of
growth per worker, it is worth examining the available data on such
growth. Figure 6 presents figure 4 redrawn with growth per worker on
the y axis (covering the period 1970-85 rather than 1970-89). The nega-
tive relation between growth and initial income is more clearly evident
in this figure than in figure 4.60 Based on this evidence, if growth per
worker were available for the full time period, we would expect it to
strengthen our conclusions regarding convergence, but the minimum
60. This result, that per worker growth exhibits stronger evidence for convergence
than per capita growth, is also observed by Wolf (1994).
Figure 6. Growth Per Worker and Initial GDP Per Worker, Open Economies, 1970-85
Annualgrowth
per worker(percent)
8
6 Yemen, N. Arab.
Indonesia * Korea, R. of o
0 Jordan Taiwan
4 Singapore* * Hong Kong
*Malaysia *Japan
Thailand* * YrVuspIreland*Norway
2 Mauritius
*~~~~~~~~~~ *SFinl1pdn
Portugale Asai S Canada
Spain e
~~Uniteftta?es
0 *Barbados
-2
-4
-6 X l lI l l l l
7 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5
Log of 1970 GDP per worker(thousandsof 1985 dollars)
Source: Authors' calculations using versions 5 and 5.5 of the data in Summers and Heston (1991).
growth rate of the open group would be about 0 percent rather than 1.2
percent. We plan to examine this phenomenon further when data from
the 1990 census rounds become available.
In summary, we find no cases to support the frequent worry that a
country might open and yet fail to grow. Of course, economic reforms
take time to work, so that some countries that adopted outward-oriented
market reforms in the late 1980s or early 1990s might not yet be enjoying
high growth rates as a result. We return to the growth effects of recent
reforms in the next major section of the paper.
We also find little support for the idea that our results might come
from reverse causality or from sample selection bias. We simply find
very few examples of developing countries that started open, performed
poorly, and closed as a result. The far more common case is that devel-
oping countries started closed, performed poorly, and then opened. As
61. Of course, our indicators of openness are associated with other market-based re-
form policies, which makes it difficult to identify the precise contribution of trade as com-
pared to other policies. A more precise statement is that open policies together with other
correlated policies were sufficient for growth in excess of 2 percent during 1970-89.
62. To quote his conclusions: "I have found some clear evidence that during 1980-90
more exports are positively associated with higher growth rates across Chinese cities. In
the late 1980s, the contribution to growth comes mainly from foreign investment. Further-
more, the contribution of foreign investment comes in the form of technological or mana-
gerial spillovers across firms as opposed to an infusion of new capital. Finally, the superb
growth rates of coastal areas relative to the national average can be entirely explained by
their effective use of exports and foreign investment." (Wei, 1995, p. 74.) Also, see Lardy
(1994) for further discussion of China's recent experience with international trade.
63. See Sachs and Woo (1994) for further details of the two-track approach in China
and the current macroeconomic problems.
Ii I I
II_I I I
en ) C NO
I O O en O O-,
en I 00 m cq q 0 W)O
I I
. 0 000 .-
00 o 00
.) ^ ? 00 eO
CqO0O ^00
00 0' en
- e0 0ekna-
-00-
C0 o o
u
48
elf) kf Ce400OO ~
C~ . n
aN~~~
Ci
- . 0
C cqN O C:3
O , 'ICe100 00 0
cq C n O en It be
0 o ?N oo
. U n
i- .- O
C)
O bi
_4 _ <O N 0
N N o t0^ t 3 0Q ? o
o N o o^-00 C: ;>.
0 0
- ~~~~
re 0 ~~~0J
oo.2 ?
- a C, r- o
~ ~
o~~~~~~~~'
O :U SO- C: ;> t
> 0
0 C3 M.-0 *
0 3
0 o
U U, > > 0
4) >~ ~~~4
S 0. U t- D
cq 0 0~~~~~~~4
of our data, such as the tariff and black market premium data, have been
used in previous studies, including those by Jong-Wha Lee and Levine
and Renelt.66 Our treatment of these data differs from the earlier studies
in two important ways: first, by our construction of a single indicator
measure of openness (built on several underlying variables); and sec-
ond, by our examination of growth performance within the subset of
open economies, as well as between closed and open economies. To our
knowledge, no earlier studies have pointed out that corivergence applies
to the worldwide subset of open economies.67
In regression 6, we add a dummy variable, POL, to account for ex-
treme political conditions detrimental to long-term investment. The
variable POL takes a value of 1 when any of the following conditions
applies:
-A socialist economic structure, according to the list of countries
compiled by Kornai.68
-Extreme domestic unrest caused by revolutions, coups, chronic
civil unrest, or a prolonged war with a foreign country that is fought on
domestic territory.
-Extreme deprivation of civil and political rights, according to the
Freedom House index reported by McMillan, Rausser, and Johnson.69
We see that the POL variable is statistically significant at the 10 per-
cent level (t = 1.986), suggesting that property rights, freedom, and
safety from violence are additional determinants of growth.70This find-
ing is in accord with other recent studies, including work by A. S. Ales-
ina and others, Barro, Bhalla, and Jakob Svensson.71 In other regres-
sions, not reported here, we have experimented with the three
individual items in the POL index, and have found that each one plays a
role in the growth process.
Dependent variable
Independent
variable INV7089b DS YRc DPYRd
We have shown above that the labor-to-land ratio has been a determi-
nant of the timing of liberalization among developing countries. In re-
gression 7 we include this ratio as a possible independent determinant of
growth, to check whether openness is acting simply as a proxy for rela-
tive factor endowments. The variable is insignificant, while the open-
ness variable maintains its magnitude and statistical significance.
We have found strong evidence that protectionist trade policies re-
duce overall growth when controlling for the other variables. Since poor
trade policies might also affect the rates of investment relative to GDP
and the rates of human capital accumulation, we would expect poor poli-
cies to have indirect adverse growth effects as a result of slower accumu-
lation of capital, both physical and human. In regressions 8-10 in table
12, we therefore check whether open and closed economies differed sys-
tematically in the rates of capital accumulation, once we control for ini-
tial income. In regression 8 we find that the open economies had signifi-
cantly higher investment-to-GDP ratios, and that OPEN raised the
investment ratio by an average of 5.4 percentage points.72 Interestingly,
72. Levine and Renelt (1992), using trade shares as a measure of openness, also find
that investment shares are higher in more open economies. This is one of the few findings
that they classify as robust, using extreme bounds analysis.
there is also some evidence that richer countries have higher investment
rates than poorer countries.
In regressions 9 and 10, we ask whether the increase in educational
attainment between 1970 and 1985 was different for the two subsets of
countries. We find no evidence that the closed economies had less im-
provement in the coverage of primary and secondary education than did
the open economies. It is clear, though, that the more developed econo-
mies had less improvement in educational coverage than did the poorer
countries (as evidenced by the significant negative sign on initial income
in both regressions).
Based on the regression analysis, we may make four conclusions:
-There is strong evidence of unconditional convergence for open
countries, and no evidence of unconditional convergence for closed
countries.7
-Closed countries systematically grow more slowly than do open
countries, showing that "good" policies matter.
-The role of trade policy continues after controlling for other growth
factors, as in a standard Barro cross-country growth equation.
-Poor trade policies seem to affect growth directly, controlling for
other factors, and to affect the rate of accumulation of physical capital.
Using our classification of trade policy, we can examine the two re-
lated propositions that open trade condemns raw materials exporters to
nonindustrialization, and that closed trade promotes industrial exports
in the long term. Based on UNCTAD classifications of trade structure,
we measure the share of primary exports (agriculture, minerals, fuels,
and metals) in total merchandise exports, X. We then examine the
change in X between 1971 and 1989 as a function of trade policy during
the period.
Our basic model is:
(4) X,89 - = (B + yOPEN1) x (X/T - X71).
Estimated Regression
parameter 1 2 3 4
0 - 0.035 -0.044 - 0.044 -0.044
(-0.377) (-0.397) (-0.397) (-0.902)
13 0.049 0.034 0.034 0.036
(0.491) (0.315) (0.315) (0.413)
y 0.317 0.286 0.286 0.318
(1.987) (1.408) (1.408) (2.535)
cx - 0.035 0.055 0.055 0.078
(-0.097) (0.092) (0.092) (0.035)
8 - 0.077 - 0.077 - 0.0013
(-0.339) (-0.339) (-0.058)
E - 0.000004 -0.272
(-0.000) (-0.123)
Summary statistics
R2 0.165 0.162 0.162 0.129
Mean dependent variable - 0.101 - 0.103 -0.103 -0.094
SER 0.160 0.161 0.161 0.151
Sample size 80 78 78 99
Source: Authors' regression based on data described in the appendix.
a. The regressions are from equation 4 in the text, X89 - X71 = 6 + (p + y OPEN) (oe + 8 POPL + e OPEN
- X71). OPEN is a dummy variable set equal to one for open economies. POPL is the ratio of population to land
area in 1960. X71 and X89 are the fraction of primary exports in total exports in 1971 and 1989. The numbers in
parentheses are t statistics.
The next two variants of the regression investigate whether the land-
to-labor ratio and the trade policy affect the long-term levels of X. In the
second regression, we assume that X is a negative function of the endow-
ment of population (POP) relative to land area (L). Economies with a
high population-to-land area ratio would be expected to have a low value
of X, so if XiT = at + i(POPIL)i,we expect 8 < 0. In the third equation
in table 13 we assume that the measure of trade policy during 1970-90
(OPEN = 0 or 1) is also a measure of long-run trade policy (or the mar-
ket's expectation of long-run trade policy), and is therefore a determi-
nant of the long-run value of X, so that X/T = ot + bi(POPIL1) + EOPENi.
As table 13 shows, neither the ratio of population to land area nor
openness is a statistically significant determinant of the long-run propor-
tion of primary exports. In fact, the estimated XLT is virtually unaffected
by the inclusion of the other variables. The important result is that the
speed of adjustment is still different in closed and open economies. Open
economies continue to display much greater dynamism in changing their
export structure from primary commodities to manufactures. Indeed,
Macroeconomic No macroeconomic
Openness crisis in 1980s crisis in 1980s
Open in 1970s 1 16
Not open in 1970s (i) 59 14
Source: See appendix.
a. In a test of independence the chi square is 34.8 (significance level <0.000).
There are seventeen developing countries that had an open trade pol-
icy in the 1970s. Of these, only Jordan succumbed to a macroeconomic
crisis after opening: debt reschedulings in 1987 and 1992, and external
payments arrears in 1993. The first episode of macroeconomic difficul-
ties followed a sharp cutback in foreign aid from the oil-rich states of the
region as a result of the collapse of world oil prices in 1986. Following
the 1990 Gulf War, Jordan experienced a more serious macroeconomic
shock, which cost it heavily in remittance and export earnings.
There were seventy-three closed developing countries in the 1970s.
Of these, as many as fifty-nine experienced a severe macroeconomic cri-
sis: forty-nine had a debt crisis; fifty had external payments arrears; and
nineteen had inflation above 100 percent (most manifested more than
one of these crises). Table 14 summarizes the relative frequencies of
openness and macroeconomic crisis. A x2 test on the null hypothesis of
independence between trade policy in the 1970s and macroeconomic cri-
sis in the 1980s is rejected at the 0.000 level.
Rather than focus on the large majority of countries that succumbed
to crisis, it is easier to assess the fourteen that did not: Bangladesh, Bots-
wana, Burundi, China, Colombia, Hungary, India, Iran, Nepal, Papua
New Guinea, Rwanda, Sri Lanka, Tunisia, and Zimbabwe. Of these,
Botswana had opened its economy by 1979; Colombia maintained very
cautious and moderate policies both in trade and in finance; both Hun-
gary and India, in fact, flirted with a debt crisis which was narrowly
averted; China began the 1980s with very little debt because it had bor-
rowed little during the Cultural Revolution of 1966-76; Bangladesh, Bu-
rundi, Nepal, and Rwanda are among the world's poorest countries and
have little, if any, access to loans on commercial terms, which has prob-
ably saved them from generating a debt crisis. Moreover, Burundi and
Rwanda have been subject to extreme internal unrest.
77. See Sachs and Woo (1993) and Sachs (1995c) for comparisons of eastern Europe
and East Asia.
Table 15. Real Per Capita Growth Rates of the Recent Reformersa
Annual averages over subperiods (percent)
Reform
Countmy year tE [-10, -4] tE[-3, -1] tE[O, 2] tE[3, n]
Argentina 1991 -0.10 - 3.83 6.55
Benin 1990 0.25 - 3.25 0.91 0.38
Bolivia 1985 - 1.78 - 5.06 - 2.88 1.14
Botswana 1979 13.96 9.87 7.31 5.31
Brazil 1991 4.08 - 2.32 - 0.08
Cameroon 1993 - 3.47 - 9.17 - 7.68
Chile 1976 1.20 -6.21 4.98 3.44
Colombia 1991 2.54 2.03 1.91
Costa Rica 1986 -3.80 0.87 1.64 2.45
Ecuador 1991 - 1.36 2.05 1.34
El Salvador 1989 -0.93 0.29 0.60 2.83
Gambia 1985 -0.61 -0.14 -1.37 -0.12
Ghana 1985 - 0.55 - 3.93 1.31 1.37
Guatemala 1988 -3.97 - 1.83 0.69 1.21
Guinea 1986 1.40 0.58
Guinea-Bissau 1987 - 1.87 1.15 3.63 0.74
Guyana 1988 - 5.40 - 0.69 -4.50 6.89
Honduras 1991 0.43 -0.08 1.15
India 1994 2.97 4.90 1.00
Israel 1985 3.41 0.38 3.43 1.41
Jamaica 1988 -0.10 0.25 3.22 0.27
Kenya 1993 2.66 - 1.20 - 1.66
Mali 1988 - 2.15 3.21 0.74 0.03
Mexico 1986 3.93 - 1.34 - 1.98 1.03
Morocco 1984 3.01 - 0.46 3.23 -0.00
Nepal 1991 3.35 3.94 0.62
Nicaragua 1991 - 4.45 - 6.25 - 2.84
Paraguay 1991 - 0.27 2.13 - 0.21
Peru 1991 4.09 - 9.68 0.35
Philippines 1988 -2.09 -2.23 2.81 - 1.80
South Africa 1991 - 1.05 - 0.39 - 2.73
Sri Lanka 1991 2.31 2.41 3.90
Tunisia 1989 1.28 -0.45 2.95 3.02
Turkey 1989 - 0.71 4.16 1.67 3.57
Uganda 1988 - 6.58 0.25 3.00 0.96
Uruguay 1990 -0.96 2.56 3.19 0.57
Zambia 1993 - 1.12 -3.90 3.65
Summary statistics
Unweighted average 0.130 -0.718 1.297 1.965
Standard deviation (5.604) (5.347) (3.417) (3.526)
Source: These growth rates are based on real GDP and population data from the World Bank (1994d). When
possible, these data are supplemented with data from national sources.
a. The sample of thirty-seven countries corresponds to the thirty-six countries that opened after 1975, from table
2, and Israel, from table 3.
78. Other statistics for the regression are the number of observations, N = 548, ad-
justed R2 = 0.149; and the F statistic for the overall regression, F = 3.45 (p < 0.001). The
only country dummy that is statistically significant is Botswana, with a dummy variable of
8.14, t = 4.585.
79. It is worthwhile responding to two possible criticisms of these results. First, it
could be objected that if growth outcomes were purely random, and countries reformed
only when growth fell below a critical threshold, then although we would tend to observe
higher growth after reform, it would be incorrect to attribute the higher growth to the re-
form. However, we stress that we are comparing growth after the reforms with growth in
the distant rather than the immediate past, and further, that our period for the distant past
spans seven years.
Second, it is possible that countries may have sorted themselves randomly as reform-
ers and nonreformers. If some grew and others did not, and those that did not closed up
again and thus were eliminated from our group of reformers, we would be left with a biased
sample of reformers with high growth. But we have found few examples of countries that
experienced slow growth after true reform. For example, economies that were temporarily
open in the 1950s and 1960s and subsequently closed again, tended to have high growth
rates during the liberal episode. We have also found that certain countries that are some-
times cited as recent reformers, such as the Dominican Republic in the early 1980s and
Nigeria between 1986 and 1992, actually did not reform sufficiently (by our criteria), while
others that did reform temporarily, such as Venezuela, experienced rapid growth during
the episode of liberalization. Hence we find few examples to suggest that sample selection
bias is an important issue when examining the growth performance of recent reformers.
Conclusions
The world economy at the end of the twentieth century looks much
like the world economy at the end of the nineteenthcentury. A global
capitalistsystem is takingshape, drawingalmostall regionsof the world
into arrangementsof open tradeandharmonizedeconomic institutions.
As in the nineteenthcentury, this new roundof globalizationpromises
80. EuropeanBankfor ReconstructionandDevelopment(1994).
Strong reforms
Hungary 4 1990 - 17.94 2.00
Poland 4 1990 - 9.23 5.00
Bulgaria 4 1991 - 26.41 1.40
Czech Republic 4 1991 - 15.49 3.00
Slovak Republic 4 1991 - 19.53 5.00
Slovenia 4 1991 - 13.26 5.00
Albania 4 1992 - 22.89 7.00
Estonia 4 1992 - 29.15 5.00
Romania 4 1992 - 30.79 3.00
Croatia 4 1993 - 31.04 1.00
Latvia 4 1993 - 39.52 3.00
Lithuania 4 1993 - 55.44 2.00
Average - 25.89 3.53
Moderate reforms
Kyrgyzstan 3 1994 -42.30 - 10.00
Russia 3 closed -47.29 - 15.00
Average -42.61 - 12.50
Weak reforms
FYR Macedonia 2 1994 -51.30 -7.00
Moldova 2 1994 - 54.30 - 25.00
Armenia 2 closed - 61.60 0.00
Kazakhstan 2 closed - 51.01 - 25.00
Uzbekistan 2 closed - 11.75 - 3.00
Average -45.99 - 12.00
Weakest reforms
Belarus 1 1994 - 35.93 - 22.00
Azerbaijan 1 closed - 54.32 - 22.00
Georgia 1 closed - 85.35 - 35.00
Tajikistan 1 closed - 70.37 - 25.00
Turkmenistan 1 closed - 38.29 - 20.00
Ukraine 1 closed - 51.36 - 23.00
Average - 55.94 - 24.50
Overall average - 38.63 - 7.58
Source: European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (1994, 1995) with national sources for Bulgaria for
1994.
to lead to economic convergence for the countries that join the system.
In this paper we have provided strong evidence of convergence among
open economies during the period 1970-89, as well as evidence of accel-
erated growth in the countries that have recently undertaken market re-
forms.
Our analysis is necessarily impressionistic and imprecise at several
crucial points. We have used trade policy as our measure of economic
management, but we are strongly aware that trade policy represents just
one element-albeit the most important-of an overall economic policy.
Among developing countries, open trade has tended to be correlated
with other features of a healthy economy, such as macroeconomic bal-
ance and reliance on the private sector as the main engine of growth. To
some extent, opening the economy has helped to promote governmental
responsibility in other areas. To that extent, trade policy should be
viewed as the primary instrument of reform. But to some degree, our
measure of trade policy serves as a proxy for an entire array of policy
actions. Only further cross-country analysis, with a more detailed char-
acterization of the entire policy regime, would allow us to distinguish the
growth effects of the various components of economic policy.
It is tempting, at the end of the twentieth century, to believe that the
birth of a global capitalist economy is inevitable. Some have proclaimed
the "end of history" following the collapse of communism. Similarly, in
1910, Norman Angell declared that European wars had come to an end
because war was simply too costly for any rational European govern-
ment. But our historical review should give us profound pause for
thought. Yes, the late twentieth century has certain key advantages over
1910 for the preservation of emerging market institutions. There is the
spread of sovereignty, so that imperial adventures no longer seem to
threaten the global peace. There is the spread of an international rule of
law, largely through institutions such as the World Trade Organization
and the International Monetary Fund. There is the spread of democracy,
which covered some 108 countries in 1994, according to the estimates of
Freedom House.
And yet there are also profound risks for the consolidation of market
reforms in Russia, China, and Africa, as well as for the maintenance of
international agreements among the leading countries. The consolida-
tion of the emerging global arrangements will require the wisdom and
APPENDIX
Data
THE DATA SET in this paper begins with the sample of 135 countries in-
cluded in version 5.5 of the data described in Summers and Heston
(1991). For most of these countries, the growth variable (G7089) is calcu-
lated directly from the Summers and Heston data. For seven countries,
Comoros, Ethiopia, Liberia, Tanzania, Nicaragua, Iraq, and Nepal,
G7089 is calculated using 1970 and 1985 data on real GDP, rather than
1970 and 1989 data. Swaziland's G7089 is calculated using real per capita
GDP data from the World Bank for the years 1972 and 1989. With the
single exception of Swaziland, G7089 is measured as average annual
growth in per capita real GDP, and is expressed in a common set of
prices (1985 international prices, in the Summers and Heston termi-
nology).
Out of the Summers-Heston universe of 135 countries, there are 13
countries that do not have adequate growth data, either because they are
not available at all, or because they are not available for a sufficiently
long time span. At the time of writing, these countries are Afghanistan,
Bahamas, Bahrain, Dominica, Grenada, Kuwait, Oman, St. Lucia, St.
Vincent, Solomon Islands, Saudi Arabia, Sudan, and United Arab Emir-
ates. After excluding these countries, the sample size falls to 122.
81. See Sachs (1995a) for a discussion of some of the issues facing the advanced coun-
tries as the present global system is consolidated.
Tables 1-5
EPA External payments arrears, as rated by the IMF's
Annual Report on Exchange Restrictions.
DC Country had a multilateral debt rescheduling,
based on data in the World Debt Tables of the
World Bank.
HI Country had inflation above 100 percent, as re-
corded in the International Financial Statistics
Yearbook, 1994, p. 64.
The sources for the dating are described in detail below for each coun-
try. Data for table 5 are from the European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development's Transition Report (1994).
Table 8
POP601LAND Population in 1960 (in thousands) divided by land
area (in square meters).
POP60 Population in 1960.
CW Dummy indicating British Commonwealth status,
from Famighetti (1993).
OLDS Dummy indicating old state, set to 1.0 for coun-
tries that achieved independence before World
War II.
69
Table 11
GDP70 Real GDP per capita in 1970 (1985 international
prices) from Summers and Heston version 5.5.
GDP89 Real GDP per capita in 1989 (1985 international
prices) from Summers and Heston version 5.5.
G7089 Real per capita growth rate of GDP per year:
G7089 = [ln(GDP89) - ln(GDP70)]/19. Note that
this variable is calculated differently for a few
countries, as listed at the beginning of this ap-
pendix.
SEC70 Secondary school enrollment rate. Source: Barro
and Lee (1994).
PRI70 Primary school enrollment rate. Source: Barro
and Lee (1994).
GVXDXE Ratio of real government "consumption" spend-
ing net of spending on the military and education,
to real GDP. Source: Barro and Lee (1994) who,
in turn, used Summers and Heston version 5.5.
REVCOUP Number of revolutions and coups per year, aver-
aged over the period 1970-85. Source Barro and
Lee, 1994.
ASSASSP Number of assassinations per million population
per year, 1970-85. Source: Barro and Lee (1994).
PPI70DEV The deviation of the log of the price level of in-
vestment (PPP investment divided by exchange
rate relative to the United States) from the cross-
country sample mean in 1970. Source: Authors'
calculation based on the PISH5 price data in
Barro and Lee (1994).
Table 12
DS YR Average accumulation of secondary schooling
over the period 1970-85. Specifically, DSYR =
[ln(S YR85) - ln(S YR70)]115,where S YRxxis per-
son years of secondary schooling divided by the
total population over age fifteen.
DP YR Accumulation of primary schooling, calculated in
the same manner as DS YR.
Table 13
X71 Primary export intensity in 1971. Ratio of primary
exports to total exports in 1971, with both numer-
ator and denominator expressed in nominal dol-
lars. Primary exports are defined as agriculture,
minerals, fuels, and metals. These correspond to
SITC (revision 1) categories 0, 1, 2, 3, 4, and 68.
Source: For all countries except Taiwan and
South Africa, World Bank, World Tables, 1994.
Data for Taiwan were obtained from the Taiwan
Statistical Data Book (Republic of China, 1993).
Data for South Africa include exports of raw dia-
monds and gold and were obtained from South Af-
rica's Bulletin of Statistics, December 1972 and
June 1992. Data for Singapore were estimated as
0.01, based on GDP and labor force data indi-
cating that Singapore produces no mining, no pri-
mary energy, and only a very small amount of
agriculture, forestry, and fishing products. The
data for Bangladesh are for 1972 rather than 1971.
The data for Cameroon were set to 1.0; they ex-
ceeded 1.0 using the published data.
Table 14
The growth data for the recent reformers are real per capita growth
from the World Tables of the World Bank. We did not use the data pro-
vided by Summers and Heston because we needed recent growth data.
Burkina Faso Never open. Not rated as open before 1990 be-
cause it has a score of 4 on its export marketing
board (Husain and Faruqee, 1994, p. 238). The
state-controlled export monopsony is still in oper-
ation. There is no evidence in TIDE of a major re-
cent reform effort.
Tunisia Open since 1989. Rated not open in the 1960s be-
cause the black market premium exceeded 20 per-
cent. The dating of reform is based on Nsouli and
others (1993, pp. 26-29). Extensive import licens-
ing was in place in 1985, covering 82 percent of im-
ports. A five-year trade reform program started in
1986, precipitated by the decline in oil prices in
January 1986. The first stage (1986-88) saw liber-
alization of intermediates and capital goods; the
second stage (1988-91) saw further liberalization
of consumer goods. By 1989 the coverage of non-
tariff barriers had fallen below 40 percent for the
first time. The black market premium data show a
small premium (7 percent) starting as early as
1975. The IMF's Annual Report on Exchange Re-
strictions records no current account restrictions
in 1989.
Which are the necessary prerequisites for successful reform? They ar-
gue that relatively free foreign trade and a reasonably convertible cur-
rency are sufficient conditions for the success of economic reform; they
assume, for instance, that macroeconomic stabilization follows.
The correlation between openness to foreign trade and the ability of
poorer countries to catch up is convincing, but the causality needs to be
proven further. What roles do other factors play? Usually, a government
adopts a sensible policy covering many fields, and trade liberalization is
only one aspect. For instance, liberalization and macroeconomic stabili-
zation are usually introduced in parallel, in one package.
In recent years Sachs has presented a number of alternative lists of
the four to six factors essential to the success of economic reform. ' All
of them seem quite sensible. It would be useful to test these factors as far
as possible to find the truly crucial preconditions of success. Common
suggestions have been: openness to foreign trade, domestic liberaliza-
tion, convertibility, macroeconomic stabilization, international finan-
cing, a pegged exchange rate, mass privatization, a social safety net, and
certain political criteria (strong leader, insightful political elite, civil so-
ciety, manageable interest groups, political pluralism, public educa-
tion). Apart from international financing, all of these criteria are institu-
tional, which makes testing more complicated.
The liberalization of foreign trade and the introduction of a convert-
ible currency are hardly sufficient conditions for economic growth. A
country with a very open economy can have bad incentives in the form
of excessive taxes and public expenditures, and stay at a suboptimal
equilibrium for decades. Sweden is an obvious example. In a recent pa-
per Sachs has written about the entitlement trap in eastern Europe, par-
ticularly in Hungary.2
Similarly, the importance of a social safety net has been exaggerated
in the discussion of former socialist countries. I am struck by its absence
in discussions of East Asia. It is difficult to understand why a social
safety net is enormously important in eastern Europe and of no conse-
quence in East Asia. Clearly the social safety net has a bigger place in
political rhetoric than in sound economic analysis. Even Russia had so-
cial expenditures of 21 percent of GDP in 1994.3No country at this level
of economic development has been successful with such large social ex-
penditures.
An issue that is likely to prove important, and that applies to third
world countries as well, is privatization. The degree of privatization will
contribute to our understanding of the transition of the former commu-
nist countries in the longer run. Therefore we should include the relative
size of the private sector as a plausible precondition for success.
Previously, Sachs made a strong case for international financing, but
that is missing from this paper.4 It would have been interesting to have
seen a discussion of the role of international financing in successful eco-
nomic reform here. However, the case may be hard to prove because
international financing has been connected with very different kinds of
conditionality.
The, Soviet Union gave a lot of foreign aid, but it was conditional on
devastating economic policies. The Nordic countries have given huge
amounts of aid to socialist countries in Africa, particularly to Tanzania,
on the understanding that they build African socialism. The West gave
export credits to benign communist states such as Yugoslavia under
Josip Broz Tito, Poland under Edward Gierek, and Hungary under
Janos Kadar, so that they could maintain liberal communist policies.
None of this aid did much good.
Clearly, international financing is beneficial only if it is accompanied
by the right conditionality, but views of what is right have changed very
fast. As a result there is great skepticism of the benefits of foreign finan-
cing. A key question is: Under what conditions is international financing
objectively beneficial? Which conditions are really necessary, and
which are superfluous or even harmful? Until we can provide clear an-
swers to these questions, it will be difficult to convince people of the
need to provide international financing to developing countries.
Probably the most fun part of the paper is the discussion of why re-
forms happen, but it is not fully elaborated. It contains very interesting
points, for example, that ideology and elites are more important than in-
terest groups in countries with poor political structures. But the number
of possible causes is large and more factors should be brought into the
discussion. For instance, the paper discusses the significance of land,
although natural resource endowment in general appears more relevant.
I know that Sachs and Warner are writing another paper on the theme
4. Sachs (1995d).
that natural resources imply rents, and that if there are a lot of rents in a
society, rent-seeking develops, which is the opposite of profit-seeking
and the sound economic policies that lead to growth. This kind of rea-
soning should be included in the first part of this paper.
It is surprising that the authors do not find statistical evidence that
small countries can liberalize their foreign trade regime more easily than
large ones. There are strong reasons why small countries should tend to
liberalize earlier than large ones. The politics of reform is much easier in
a country with less political complexity, and the costs of the economic
distortions caused by protectionism are much more forceful in a small
economy than in a large economy, such as China. I wonder if this lack
of evidence may reflect some flaw in methodology. If you distinguish be-
tween regions, it might turn out that the smallest countries in each region
tend to liberalize most. Notably there are many small countries in Af-
rica, which has not been very liberal overall, but few in the generally
more liberal Asia.
A minor point concerns the comment that the Meiji restoration was
the first shock therapy in history. While it certainly can qualify as shock
therapy, it was not the first. The big liberalizations in Europe in the mid-
dle of the nineteenth century were outstanding examples, especially the
massive deregulation in Britain in 1846. It is noteworthy that this was
followed by three decades of laissez faire because the legal system and
the public administration were too weak to be effective, and excessive
reliance on them would have exacerbated corruption.
Finally, on the outlook for the future the paper compares our time
with the end of the nineteenth century to argue that a global capitalist
system is taking shape. Yet this builds upon two assumptions: first, that
trade policy is the driving force, and second, that trade policy is set
firmly on a liberal track. Considering how difficult it was to conclude the
Uruguay Round and to convince the U.S. Congress to vote for the rati-
fication of the GATT and the NAFTA, the commitment to trade liberal-
ization does not appear all that strong.
If we focus on something other than trade liberalization, the parallel
with the end of the nineteenth century does not hold. Another key fea-
ture of the period before 1914 was financial stability and currency stabil-
ity, whereas our time is characterized by extreme financial instability.
Failure to deal with currency instability typically leads to protectionism.
So which comes first, financial stability or foreign trade regime? I fear
that our understanding of the causality between these two factors is too
limited to warrant the degree of optimism that Sachs and Warner ex-
press.
This worry is further aggravated by the state of international politics.
As the authors rightly point out, the period before 1914 was character-
ized by British world dominance. The end of the cold war appears to
have brought an end to U.S. world dominance. Today the United States
neither perceives sufficient international threats nor has sufficient inter-
est to spend the resources on foreign policy necessary to stay a world
leader. Nobody else is prepared to take up world leadership. Therefore
the current political situation is reminiscent of the situation immediately
after World War I, at the time of the Versailles peace treaty.
So what are we to expect in this situation? We are likely to see inter-
national crises developing, perhaps in the currency sphere, and no one
will be, strong enough to deal with them. For global economic success,
we need international institutions that can handle major international
economic problems. However the institutional innovations since the
end of the cold war have been miserable: the European Bank for Recon-
struction and Development, the Maastricht treaty, and the Common-
wealth of Independent States. The League of Nations and the Interna-
tional Labor Organization, which emanated from the Versailles peace
process, appear masterpieces in comparison.
1. My LSE tutor, the late Leonard Schapiro, once asked me why no one studies the
successful international organizations, like the UPU, rather than those that do not work. I
did not take the hint, but perhaps someone else will.
The Evidence
After providing us with their Olympian view of world economic his-
tory over the last century, Sachs and Warner turn to the evidence of the
last quarter century. One of their main conclusions is quite extraordi-
nary: that countries with open economies will converge to the same level
of income, although admittedly it will take a long time.3 This result pro-
vides so much comfort to the international agencies that in my official
role, I should accept the conclusion and move on. But it is nonetheless
necessary to check the details of the argument.
First, while it is impossible to categorize countries perfectly, the
groupings used in this paper do raise difficulties. I feel about them much
as I do about most newspapers, that they are very accurate on matters
about which I know little. I know for sure that Zimbabwe was not a so-
cialist country in 1970; I do not believe that Jordan has been consistently
open since 1970; Israel's trade reforms began in 1963, certainly not in
1985, and it did suffer from macroeconomic crises after opening; it is odd
to have both India and Hong Kong classified as open in 1995, when their
degrees of openness are so different; it is unclear why Lesotho and Swa-
ziland are categorized as open and South Africa as closed, when all three
belong to a customs union. Of course, any such summary scheme is
bound to have difficulties.
Second, by starting in 1970, the authors stack the deck against the
import-substituting strategy. Whatever happened later, Latin American
and African countries did quite well in the 1950s and 1960s, despite their
perverse regimes. We should not be surprised that it took so long for
them to open up.
The strength of the Sachs-Warner results is surprising, given that the
question that is being looked at, that of the influence of openness on
growth, has been extensively studied before. While the early result that
openness contributes to growth finds increasing support from recent
work, no one has found such extraordinarily categorical results. Per-
haps they have to do with the noncontinuous nature of the openness
variable here, whereas it is generally continuous in other papers. It is
3. Ben-David (1994) shows greater convergence among countries that trade more with
each other, a result that points in the same direction as Sachs and Warner, but is more
qualified.
Conclusions
This paper does not address the implications of the major change in
the international system since Bretton Woods-the opening of the capi-
tal account. Sachs and Warner's results show that countries that open
to trade tend to converge. What about countries that open to capital
movements? Logically, opening to capital movements should speed
convergence. But, of course, globalization of capital flows also tends to
punish bad policies and reward good policies more than before. With
monetary instability likely to impede capital flows, the need for a credi-
ble monetary policy becomes greater: that may help explain why the
gold standard was part of the institutional structure within which capital
flowed internationally a century ago.
Appropriately, Sachs and Warner conclude on a sober note. Open-
ness is not enough to produce growth; stable macroeconomic policies,
structural policies, and institutions are needed too. There are huge prob-
lems of development in Africa, and also in some other countries. There
is no assurance that this moment of ideological convergence will last in
economics. The sobriety is justified, but so is much of their optimism.
General Discussion
Whether the correlation between openness and growth can be largely
attributed to the beneficial effects of trade received a range of com-
ments. T. N. Srinivasan noted that trade policy and growth are both en-
dogenous variables, making it hard to establish causality. He criticized
growth regressions in general because of such endogeneity and because
of measurement errors. He referred to some unpublished papers of Mar-
cel Dagenais, at the University of Montreal, which show serious biases
in such regressions due to measurement errors. Andrew Warner replied
that the timing of events supported the causal interpretation in the pa-
per. Policy choices on openness after World War II were generally made
early in the postwar period or at the start of independence, before the
1970-89 period used in calculating the growth rates. The discussion of
the postwar period in the paper indicates that policy choices at this time
were based largely on intellectual and political considerations. In addi-
tion, the evidence in the paper on openness and macroeconomic crises
measures openness in the 1970s and crises in the 1980s.
Srinivasan also pointed out that the simplest version of neoclassical
trade theory suggests that openness should have only a level effect, not
a long-run growth effect. Making trade into an engine for growth re-
quired a resort to vague externalities. Greg Mankiw interjected that the
level effect predicted by the neoclassical model still takes time to fully
work itself out, and so appears to cause growth in time series. James
Duesenberry suggested another scenario linking trade and growth.
Combining restrictive trade practices with overvaluation leads to an ex-
change crisis in which scarce export revenue gets used up by the import-
Discussion turned to the political economy of trade policy and the im-
portance of ideology in the choice of economic paths after the war.
Dornbusch noted that anti-fascism was as strong a motivation for eco-
nomic liberalism in postwar Europe as anti-communism. Srinivasan
noted that Nehru was heavily influenced by the Soviet model, citing the
1938 document of the Indian Congress Party's National Planning Com-
mittee which envisioned a number of state interventions including state-
led development of heavy industry and development by import substitu-
tion. He found this influence unsurprising, and felt that the real question
is why governments did not change their policies when the failure of
their initial postwar path became evident, which in India was the case by
the mid-1960s. Why were Korea, Taiwan, and Singapore able to switch,
while India was not?
Duesenberry suggested that two kinds of selection bias might be af-
fecting the paper's results. First, since most countries turned to open-
ness following periods of severe crisis, the new policy was bound to look
good. Second, ignoring reforms that are not maintained until the end of
the sample period means that trade reforms that are not working are
omitted from the sample. He noted that quite a few countries have re-
neged on reform. Ghana, the Gambia, and Kenya have all, at some
point, pulled an about-face. Warner replied that to lessen the effect of
the first bias they compared growth after reform with growth in the dis-
tant past, rather than in the immediate past. And as to the second bias,
they failed to find hard evidence of a country that really had liberalized
(by their standards), and then did an about-face because of slow growth.
References
Famighetti, Robert, editor. 1993. The World Almanac and Book of Facts. Mah-
wah, N.J.: Funk and Wagnalls.
Favaro, Edgardo, and Pablo T. Spiller. 1991. "Uruguay." In Liberalizing For-
eign Trade, vol. 1, The Experience of Argentina, Chile, and Uruguay, edited
by Demetris Papageorgiou, Michael Michaely, and Armeane M. Choksi.
Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell.
Frankel, Jeffrey A., and David Romer. 1995. "Trade and Growth." Unpublished
paper. University of California, Berkeley (January).
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Galy, Michel, Gonzalo Pastor, and Thierry Pujol. 1993. Spain: Converging with
the European Community. Occasional Paper 101. Washington: International
Monetary Fund (February).
Gamir, Luis, and others. 1986. Politica Econ6mica de Espafia. Madrid:
Alianza.
Garay, Luis Jorge. 1991. Apertura y Protecci6n: Evaluaci6n de la Politica de
importaciones. Bogota: Tercer Mundo Editores.
Garay, Luis Gorge, and Antoni Estevadeordal. 1995. "Proyecto Sobre Amplia-
ci6n de Mercados, Competencia y Protecci6n en el Hemisferio Americano."
Unpublished paper. Interamerican Development Bank (April).
Garcia Garcia, Jorge. 1991. "Colombia." In Liberalizing Foreign Trade, vol. 4,
The Experience ofBrazil, Colombia, and Peru, edited by Demetris Papageor-
giou, Michael Michaely, and Armeane M. Choksi. Cambridge, Mass.:
Blackwell.
Gerschenkron, Alexander, and Nancy Nimitz. 1952. A Dollar Index of Soviet
Petroleum Output, 1927-28 to 1937. Project Rand research memorandum
RM-804. Santa Monica, Calif.: Rand Corporation.
Graham, Andrew, and Anthony Seldon, editors. 1990. Government and Econo-
mies in the Postwar World: Economic Policies and Comparative Perfor-
mance, 1945-85. New York: Routledge.
Grossman, Gene M., and Elhanan Helpman. 1991. Innovation and Growth in
the Global Economy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Guisinger, Stephen, and Gerald Scully. 1991. "Pakistan." In Liberalizing For-
eign Trade, vol. 5, The Experience of Indonesia, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka,
edited by Demetris Papageorgiou, Michael Michaely, and Armeane M.
Choksi. Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell.
Haberler, Gottfried. 1988. International Trade and Economic Development.
San Francisco: International Center for Economic Growth.
Halevi, Nadav, and Joseph Baruh. 1991. "Israel." In Liberalizing Foreign
Trade, vol. 3, The Experience of Israel and Yugoslavia, edited by Demetris
Papageorgiou, Michael Michaely, and Armeane M. Choksi. Cambridge,
Mass.: Blackwell.
Hamilton, Alexander. 1790. "Report on the Subject of Manufactures." In State
Papers and Speeches on the Tariff, edited by F.W. Taussig. New York: Au-
gustus M. Kelley, 1892.
Harberger, Arnold C., editor. 1984. World Economic Growth. San Francisco:
Institute for Contemporary Studies.
Headrick, Daniel R. 1981. The Tools of Empire: Technology and European Im-
perialism in the Nineteenth Century. New York: Oxford University Press.
Heckscher, Eli F. 1955. Mercantilism, second ed., translated by Mendel Sha-
piro and edited by E. F. Soderlund. New York: Macmillan.
Helliwell, John F. 1992. "International Growth Linkages: Evidence from Asia
and the OECD." Working Paper 4245. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research (December).
Hobson, J. A. 1902. The Evolution of Modern Capitalism: A Study of Machine
Production. London: W. Scott Publishers.
Husain, Ishrat, and Rashid Faruqee, editors. 1994. Adjustment in Africa: Les-
sons from Country Case Studies. Washington: World Bank.
Intal, Ponciano S., Jr., and John H. Power. 1990. Trade, Exchange Rate, and
Agricultural Pricing Policies in the Philippines. Washington: World Bank.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). Various years. Annual Report on Ex-
change Restrictions. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
. Various years. Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions.
Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Islam, Nurul. 1981. Foreign Trade andEconomic Controls in Development: The
Case of United Pakistan. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Ito, Takatoshi, and Anne 0. Krueger, editors. 1995. Growth Theories in Light
of the East Asian Experience. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Keefer, Philip, and Stephen Knack. 1993. "Why Don't Poor Countries Catch
Up? A Cross-National Test of an Institutional Explanation." Working Paper
60. College Park, Md.: Center for Institutional Reform and the Informal Sec-
tor (June).
Keynes, John Maynard. 1919. The Economic Consequences of the Peace. Re-
printed as The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol. 2. London:
Macmillan, 1971.
. 1933. "National Self-Sufficiency." In The Collected Writings of John
Maynard Keynes, vol. 21, Activities 1931-1939: World Crises and Policies in
Britain and America, 233-46. London: Macmillan, 1982.
Kindleberger, Charles P. 1973. The World in Depression, 1929-1939. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
King, Robert G., and Ross Levine. 1993. "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter
Might Be Right." Quarterly Journal of Economics 108(3): 717-37.
Knack, Steve. 1994. "Institutions and the Convergence Hypothesis: The Cross-
National Evidence." Working Paper 59. College Park, Md.: Center for Insti-
tutional Reform and the Informal Sector (May).
Kormendi, Roger C., and Philip G. Meguire. 1985. "Macroeconomic Determi-
nants of Growth: Cross-Country Evidence." Journal of Monetary Econom-
ics 16(2): 141-63.
Kornai, Janos. 1992. The Socialist System: The Political Economy of Commu-
nism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Little, Ian, Tibor Scitovsky, and Maurice Scott. 1970. Industry and Trade in
Some Developing Countries: A Comparative Study. London: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Lucas, Robert E., Jr. 1988. "On the Mechanics of Economic Development."
Journal of Monetary Economics 22(1): 3-42.
Lundahl, Mats. 1992. Politics or Markets? Essays on Haitian Underdevel-
opment. London: Routledge.
Maddison, Angus. 1991. Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development: A Long-
Run Comparative View. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. "A Contribution
to the Empirics of Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal of Economics
107(2): 407-37.
Marx, Karl, and Friedrich Engels. 1848. "The Communist Manifesto." In Karl
Marx: Selected Writings, edited by David McLellan. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press, 1977.
McEvedy, Colin, and Richard Jones. 1979. Atlas of World Population History.
Great Britain: Penguin Books.
McMillan, John C., Gordon C. Rausser, and Stanley R. Johnson. 1994. "Eco-
nomic Growth, Political and Civil Liberties." Occasional Paper 53. San Fran-
cisco: International Center for Economic Growth.
Nam, Koon Woo. 1989. South Korean Politics: The Search for Political Consen-
sus and Stability. Lanham, Md.: University Press of America.
Naya, Seiji, and others, editors. 1989. Lessons in Development: A Comparative
Study ofAsia and Latin America. San Francisco: Institute for Contemporary
Studies.
Ndlovu, Lindani B. 1994. The System ofProtection and Industrial Development
in Zimbabwe. Aldershot, England: Avebury.
Nsouli, Saleh M., and others. 1993. "The Path to Convertibility and Growth:
The Tunisian Experience." Occasional Paper 109. Washington: International
Monetary Fund (December).
. 1995. "Resilience and Growth Through Sustained Adjustment: The Mo-
roccan Experience." Occasional Paper 117. Washington: International Mon-
etary Fund (January).
OGrada, Cormac, and Kevin O'Rourke. 1994. "Irish Economic Growth." Dis-
cussion Paper 975. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research (June).
O'Rourke, Kevin, and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1994. "Late Nineteenth Century
Anglo-American Factor-Price Convergence: Were Heckscher and Ohlin
Right?" Journal of Economic History 54(4): 892-916.
Owen, Thomas C. 1994. "Autocracy and the Rule of Law in Russian Economic
History." Paper prepared for John M. Olin Lecture Series. Harvard Univer-
sity, Russian Research Center (October).
Pack, Howard. 1971. Structural Change and Economic Policy in Israel. New
Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Papageorgiou, Demetris, Michael Michaely, and Armeane M. Choksi, editors.
1991. Liberalizing Foreign Trade, 7 vols. Cambridge, Mass.: Blackwell.
Patinkin, Don. 1978. "The Process of Writing the General Theory." In Keynes,
Cambridge, and the General Theory, edited by Don Patinkin and J. Clark
Leith. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Phongpaichit, Pasuk. 1992. "Technocrats, Businessmen, and Generals: Democ-
racy and Economic Policy-Making in Thailand." In The Dynamics of Eco-
nomic Policy Reform in South-East Asia and the South-West Pacific, edited
by Andrew J. Maclntyre and Kanishka Jayasuriya. New York: Oxford Uni-
versity Press.
Pitt, Mark M. 1991. "Indonesia." In Liberalizing Foreign Trade, vol. 5, The Ex-
perience of Indonesia, Pakistan, and Sri Lanka, edited by Demetris Papa-
georgiou, Michael Michaely, and Armeane M. Choksi. Cambridge, Mass.:
Blackwell.
Pritchett, Lant. 1993. "Measuring Outward Orientation in Developing Coun-
tries: Can It Be Done?" Working Paper WPS 566. Washington: World Bank
(October).
Razin, Assaf, and Efraim Sadka. 1993. The Economy of Modern Israel: Malaise
and Promise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Republic of China. 1993. Taiwan Statistical Data Book. Taipei: Council for Eco-
nomic Planning and Development.
Reynolds, Lloyd G. 1985. Economic Growth in the Third World, 1850-1980.
New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Rodriguez, Carlos Alfredo. 1974. "The Non-Equivalence of Tariffs and Quotas
under Retaliation." Journal of International Economics 4(3): 295-98.
Rogowski, Ronald. 1989. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Do-
mestic Political Alignments. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Romer, Paul M. 1986. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth." Journal of
Political Economy 94(5): 1002-37.
. 1990. "Endogenous Technological Change." Journal of Political Econ-
omy 98(5): S71-S102.
Rosendale, Phyllis. 1981. "The Balance of Payments." In The Indonesian Econ-
omy During the Soeharto Era, edited by Anne Booth and Peter McCawley.
Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press.
Rosenstein-Rodan, P. N. 1943. "Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and
South-Eastern Europe." Economic Journal 53(210): 202-11.
Sachs, Jeffrey D. 1985. "External Debt and Macroeconomic Performance in
Latin America and East Asia." BPEA, 2:1985, 523-64.
, editor. 1990. Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance,
vol. 2, Country Studies: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico. Chicago: Uni-
versity of Chicago Press.
1992. "The Grand Bargain." In The Post-Soviet Economy: Soviet and
Western Perspectives, edited by Anders Aslund. London: Pinter.
. 1994. "Notes on the Life Cycle of State-Led Industrialization." Paper
prepared for the Ninth Annual Japan-U. S. Technical Symposium (March).
1995a. "Consolidating Capitalism." Foreign Policy 98(Spring): 50-64.
1995b. "Postcommunist Parties and the Politics of Entitlements." Tran-
sition 6(3): 1-4.
. 1995c. "Reforms in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union in