IS and LM Curve

Download as docx, pdf, or txt
Download as docx, pdf, or txt
You are on page 1of 3

Method of Derivation of the IS and

LM Curves (With Diagram)


In this article we will discuss about the method of derivation of the IS
and LM curves, explained with the help of suitable diagrams.

(a) Derivation of the IS curve:


The IS curve is frequently derived graphically with a four-part diagram
as shown in Fig. 13. Employing simple linear functions, part (a) of Fig.
13 is a plot of the investment function (the MEI); part (c) plots the saving
function, part (b) is simply a 45°-identity line; and part (d) plots the
commodity market equilibrium, or IS curve.

Picking an initial interest rate level (say, r 0) fixes the level of investment
(at I0) and, thus, the volume of saving (S0) necessary for equilibrium.
Given the volume of saving required, the saving function defines the
level of income (Y0) necessary for equilibrium.
This establishes one point on the IS-LM schedule. Altering the initial
interest rate selected by any amount and tracing through the diagram
counter-clockwise will yield another point on the IS curve. The resulting
IS curve will slope downward from left to right as shown.

The slope depends on two factors, viz.:


(i) Interest-elasticity of investment and

(ii) The numerical value of the multiplier

(b) Derivation of the LM curve:


Making use of Keynes’ original distinction between transactions and
speculative money demands, the LM schedule is frequently derived
graphically using the four-part diagram. See Fig 14. The schedule in part
(b) of the diagram represents transactions demand for money, assuming
demand to be proportional (with proportionality constant k) to Y.

The schedule in (c) is simply an identity line that mechanically divides


the total money supply into transactions and speculative components.
This part of total money balance (M) not held in one form must be held in
the other. The schedule in (a) is the LM curve.
ADVERTISEMENTS:

Beginning in (d), with a known interest rate (assume it is r 0), the volume
of speculative demand is defined [M (spec.) 0]. Given the total money supply
M, that portion not held as speculative balances must be held in
transaction balances [M0t] as shown in (c).
The schedule in (b) shows what level of real income (Y 0) must prevail in
order to get the public to willingly absorb the money available for
transactions balance in that form. Thus, as we see in (a) for interest rate
r0, the only possible money market equilibrium value of income is Y 0.
Should the interest rate rise to r 1, the only possible equilibrium level of
income would be Y1 as we can see by again starting in (d) and proceeding
clockwise through our diagram. Thus, the LM curve slopes upward from
left to right.
Simultaneous Equilibrium:
By combining the commodity and money market equilibrium schedules
(the IS and LM curves) as in Fig. 15, we can see that only one
combination of r and Y (the combination r 0 and Y0) can simultaneously
clear both the money and commodity markets.

That is, given the money supply and demand schedules that underlay the
LM curve, and the consumption and investment schedules that underlie
the IS curve, the only possible equilibrium values of r and Y are the
combination at the IS- LM intersection.

At any other combination of an interest rate and an income level the


commodity market or the money market, or both markets, will be in
disequilibrium. If, for example, the level of income should rise (say to Y 1),
the rate of interest determined in the money market (r 1) would exceed
the interest rate that is necessary (r 2) to stimulate sufficient investment
to make Y1 the equilibrium level of income in the commodity market.

You might also like