Diversity-Weighted Portfolios With Negative Parameter
Diversity-Weighted Portfolios With Negative Parameter
Diversity-Weighted Portfolios With Negative Parameter
The authors are greatly indebted to Thibaut Lienart, Michael Monoyios, Vassilios Papa-
thanakos, Julen Rotaetxe, and Johannes Ruf for their very careful reading of the manuscript
and their many, insightful, and helpful suggestions. Alexander Vervuurt gratefully acknowl-
edges Ph.D. studentships from the Engineering and Physical Sciences Research Council,
Nomura and the Oxford-Man Institute of Quantitative Finance. Research supported in part
by the National Science Foundation under Grant NSF-DMS-14-05210.
Alexander Vervuurt ( )
Mathematical Institute, University of Oxford, Andrew Wiles Building, Radcliffe Observatory
Quarter, Woodstock Road, Oxford, OX2 6GG, UK
E-mail: [email protected]
Ioannis Karatzas
Department of Mathematics, Columbia University, New York, NY 10027, USA
E-mail: [email protected]
Intech Investment Management, One Palmer Square, Suite 441, Princeton, NJ 08542, USA
E-mail: [email protected]
2 Alexander Vervuurt, Ioannis Karatzas
1 Introduction
1.1 Preview
2 Preliminaries
Our market model is the standard one of Stochastic Portfolio Theory (Fern-
holz, 2002), where the stock capitalizations are modeled as Itô processes.
Namely, the dynamics of the n stock capitalization processes Xi (·), i = 1, . . . , n
are given by
d
X
dXi (t) = Xi (t) bi (t) dt + σiν (t) dWν (t) , t ≥ 0, i = 1, . . . , n ; (1)
ν=1
We shall measure performance, for the most part, with respect to the mar-
ket index. This is the wealth process V µ (·) that results from a buy-and-hold
0
portfolio, given by the vector process µ(·) = µ1 (·), · · · , µn (·) of market
weights
n
Xi (t) X
µi (t) := , i = 1, . . . , n , where X(t) := Xi (t). (5)
X(t) i=1
P V π (T ) ≥ V ρ (T ) = 1 P V π (T ) > V ρ (T ) > 0.
and (6)
An equivalent way to express this notion, is to say that the portfolio π(·)
outperforms portfolio ρ(·) over the time-horizon [0, T ].
We call this relative arbitrage strong, if in fact P V π (T ) > V ρ (T ) = 1 ;
and sometimes we express this by saying that the portfolio π(·) outperforms
the portfolio ρ(·) strongly over the time-horizon [0, T ]. t
u
We introduce the Rn×n -valued covariation process a(·) = σ(·)σ 0 (·) and,
writing ei for the ith unit vector in Rn , the relative covariances
µ 0
τij (t) := µ(t) − ei a(t) µ(t) − ej , 1 ≤ i, j ≤ n. (7)
Finally, we define the excess growth rate γπ∗ (·) of a portfolio π(·) as
n
X n
1 X
γπ∗ (t) := πi (t)aii (t) − πi (t)aij (t)πj (t) . (8)
2 i=1 i,j=1
for any Rn -valued process θ(·). Here ties are resolved lexicographically, always
in favor of the lowest index i . Thus we have
n
X
πi (t) := Di log G(µ(t)) + 1 − µj (t)Dj log G(µ(t)) · µi (t). (13)
j=1
Here and throughout the paper, we write Di for the partial derivative with
respect to the ith variable, and D2ij for the second partial derivative with
respect to the ith and j th variables. Theorem 3.1 of Fernholz (1999) asserts
that the performance of the wealth process corresponding to π(·) relative to
the market, satisfies the decomposition (often referred to as “Fernholz’s master
equation”)
T
V π (T )
Z
G(µ(T ))
log = log + g(t) dt , P-a.s. (14)
V µ (T ) G(µ(0)) 0
The quantity
n
−1 X µ
g(t) := D2 G(µ(t))µi (t)µj (t)τij (t) (15)
2G(µ(t)) i,j=1 ij
One condition that was shown to be sufficient for the existence of relative
arbitrage in the model (1), under the condition (ND), is that of diversity (see
Corollary 2.3.5 and Example 3.3.3 of Fernholz (2002)). This posits that no
single company’s capitalization can take up more than a certain proportion of
the entire market.
More formally, a market is said to be diverse over the time-horizon [0, T ],
for some real number T > 0, if
∃ δ ∈ (0, 1) such that: P µ(1) (t) < 1 − δ , ∀ t ∈ [0, T ] = 1 . (D)
Models of the form (1) with the property (D) were explicitly shown to exist in
Remark 6.2 of Fernholz et al. (2005). Other constructions have been proposed
by Osterrieder and Rheinländer (2006) and Sarantsev (2014). Fernholz et al.
(2005, see Eq. (4.5)) showed that the portfolio (16) outperforms the market
index µ(·) strongly, in markets satisfying (ND) and (D), for any p ∈ (0, 1), and
over time-horizons [0, T ] with
2 log n
T ∈ ,∞ . (17)
εδp
In Theorem 1 below, we show that a similar property holds for the diversity-
weighted portfolio with negative parameter p, in markets with the following
no-failure condition:
∃ ϕ ∈ (0, 1/n) such that P µ(n) (t) > ϕ, ∀ t ∈ [0, T ] = 1 . (NF)
We note that this condition implies diversity with parameter δ = (n − 1)ϕ .
3 Main Result
a negative number. Using assumption (NF) and the lower bound from (21),
we obtain
(p) (µ(n) (t))p ϕp (nϕ)p
π(1) (t) = Pn p
< 1−p = < 1, (23)
i=1 (µi (t)) n n
where the last (strict) inequality follows from (18). In conjunction with (23),
the inequality (11) gives
Z T
ε T (nϕ)p
Z
∗ (p) ε
γπ(p) (t) dt ≥ 1 − π(1) (t) dt ≥ T 1− . (24)
0 2 0 2 n
Finally, straightforward computation shows that the drift process of the port-
folio (16), as defined in (15), is equal for all p ∈ R to
We apply now (25), (22) and (24) to Fernholz’s master equation (14), and
conclude that the relative performance of π (p) (·) over [0, T ], with respect to
the market, is given by
(p) T
V π (T )
Z
Gp (µ(T ))
log = log + (1 − p) γπ∗(p) (t) dt (26)
V µ (T ) Gp (µ(0)) 0
(nϕ)p
ε
> log(nϕ) + (1 − p) T 1 −
2 n
> 0, P-a.s.,
provided T satisfies (19). Hence the portfolio π (p) (·) outperforms the market
strongly over sufficiently long time-horizons [0, T ], as indicated in (19). t
u
8 Alexander Vervuurt, Ioannis Karatzas
4 Rank-Based Variants
Real markets typically do not satisfy the (NF) assumption (as stocks can
crash), so it is desirable to weaken this condition of Theorem 1. One possible
modification of (NF), is to posit that “no-failure” only holds for the m stocks
ranked highest by capitalization, for some fixed 2 < m < n, namely
∃ κ ∈ (0, 1/m) such that P µ(m) (t) > κ , ∀ t ∈ [0, T ] = 1 . (LF)
with bxc the largest integer less than or equal to x ∈ R. To see this, note that,
as long as (k − 1)(1 − δ) < 1, for 1 < k ≤ n, we have the implication
1 − (k − 1)(1 − δ)
µ(k−1) (t) < 1 − δ ⇒ µ(k) (t) > . (28)
n − (k − 1)
We identify the inequality on the right hand side of (28) as a version of (LF).
The largest integer for which this lower bound is positive, is k = b1/(1 − δ)c,
giving (27). t
u
Under the assumption (LF), one can attempt to construct a relative arbitrage
using a variant (introduced in Example 4.2 of Fernholz (2001)) of the diversity-
weighted portfolio with parameter p = r ∈ R which only invests in the m =
m highest-ranked stocks (and thus naturally avoids investing in “crashing”
stocks), namely:
r
P (µ(k) (t))
, k = 1, . . . , m,
m
πp#t (k) (t) = `=1 (µ(`) (t))
r
(29)
0, k = m + 1, . . . , n.
Here, pt (k) is the index of the stock ranked k th at time t (with ties re-
solved “lexicographically” once again, by choosing the lowest index), so that
µpt (k) (t) = µ(k) (t).
Diversity-Weighted Portfolios with Negative Parameter 9
We shall denote by Lk,k+1 (t) ≡ ΛΞk (t) the semimartingale local time ac-
cumulated at the origin, over the time-interval [0, t], by the continuous, non-
negative semimartingale
Ξk (·) := log µ(k) (·)/µ(k+1) (·) , k = 1, . . . , n − 1. (30)
Definition 2 Let us consider the local times at the origin of all continuous,
nonnegative semimartingales of the form
log µ(k) (·)/µ(k+r) (·) , k = 1, . . . , n − r , r ≥ 2 ,
The reader should consult Banner and Ghomrasni (2008) for general theory
on ranked semimartingales, as well as Ichiba et al. (2011) for sufficient condi-
tions that ensure the evanescence of such higher-order collision local times.
When attempting to construct a relative arbitrage with the portfolio (29),
one encounters a problem. To wit: an application of Theorem 3.1 of Fernholz
(2001) asserts that the following master equation holds for this rank-based
portfolio:
π# ! Z T
Gr# (µ(T ))
V (T )
log = log + (1 − r) γπ∗# (t) dt (31)
V µ (T ) Gr# (µ(0)) 0
Z T π # (t)
pt (m)
− dLm,m+1 (t),
0 2
with Gr# the generating function of π # (·); compare with (26). Due to the
unbounded nature of semimartingale local time, the final term in (31) (referred
to as “leakage” by Fernholz (2001)) admits no obvious almost sure bound. Thus
there is no lower bound on the market-relative performance of π # (·) that holds
under reasonable conditions.
Since in real markets this local time term is typically small, we do still
expect this portfolio to have a good performance, and therefore include it in
our empirical study — see Section 6.
With this new dispensation, the local time term in (31) changes sign for π [ (·)
(see equation (38) below) and the problems mentioned in the previous subsec-
tion disappear. In fact, we can show that the new portfolio in (32) outperforms
the market under the assumptions (ND), (LF), for certain positive values of
the parameter r ; as well as under the assumptions (ND), (NF), when r is
within an appropriate range of negative values.
4 log n−m
1 − r log (m + 1)κ
κ< and T > T+[ := 2 . (34)
2(m + 1) εr(1 − r) 2 − (m + 1)−r κ−r
(ii) If (NF) also holds, the small-stock diversity-weighted portfolio of (32) with
parameter
log(n − m)
r∈ ,0 (35)
log((m + 1)ϕ)
is a strong arbitrage relative to the market µ(·) over the time-horizon [0, T ],
provided
−2(n − m) log((m + 1)ϕ)
T > T−[ := . (36)
ε(1 − r) n − m − (m + 1)r ϕr
n
!1/r
X r
Gr (x) := x(`) , (37)
`=m+1
Case (i): With r ∈ − log(2)/ log((m + 1)κ), 1 as in (33), we have
1 log(2)
κ< =⇒ r>− > 0. (39)
2(m + 1) log((m + 1)κ)
Recalling (LF) and m = m − 2 , we have the following bounds
n
X
2κr < (µ(m−1) (t))r + (µ(m) (t))r + (µ(`) (t))r
`=m+1
n
X r
= (µ(`) (t))r = Gr (µ(t)) (40)
`=m+1
n r
X 1 −r
≤ = (n − m) m + 1
m+1
`=m+1
in conjunction with (11) and (42). Whereas the nonnegativity of πp[ t (m) (t) ,
coupled with the nondecrease of the local time Lm,m+1 (·), shows that
Z T πp[ t (m) (t)
dLm,m+1 (t) ≥ 0 . (44)
0 2
We use this and apply (41) and (43) to the rank-based master equation (38),
to obtain
π[
V (T ) 1 n−m
log > log (m + 1)κ − log (45)
V µ (T ) r 2
ε 1
+ (1 − r) T 1 −
2 2(m + 1)r κr
> 0, P-a.s.,
if and only if T > T+[ as defined in (34). We conclude that, under these
conditions, π [ (·) strongly outperforms the market over the horizon [0, T ].
12 Alexander Vervuurt, Ioannis Karatzas
Case (ii): With r ∈ log(n − m)/ log(nκ), 0 and under the condition (NF),
we have the following bounds
n
−r
X r
(n − m) (m + 1) ≤ (µ(`) (t))r = Gr (µ(t)) < (n − m) ϕr . (46)
`=m+1
For the first inequality, we have used the simple fact that µ(`) (t) ≤ µ(m+1) (t) ≤
1/(m + 1) holds for ` = m + 1, · · · , n . Whereas, from (35), we have
[ (µ(n) (t))r ϕr
π(1) (t) = Pn < <1 (47)
`=m+1 (µ(`) (t))
r (n − m) (m + 1)−r
by analogy with (23). The inequalities (46) lead to the lower bound
Gr (µ(T ))
log > log (m + 1)ϕ ; (48)
Gr (µ(0))
and the non-degeneracy condition (ND), in conjunction with (11) and the
[
upper bound (47) on the largest portfolio weight π(1) (·), give
T T
(m + 1)r ϕr
Z Z
ε εT
γπ∗[ (t) dt [
≥ 1− π(1) (t) dt > 1− . (49)
0 2 0 2 n−m
Again, we use (44) and apply (48) and (49) to the master equation (38), to
obtain
[
V π (T ) (m + 1)r ϕr
εT
log > log (m + 1)ϕ + (1 − r) 1 − (50)
V µ (T ) 2 n−m
> 0, P-a.s.,
5 Further Considerations
We present now some other results, the first of which shows that the diversity-
weighted portfolio (16) with p ∈ (0, 1) is outperformed by its negative-para-
meter counterpart under sufficient conditions. We also study a particular com-
bination of these two types of diversity-weighted portfolios, showing that it
outperforms a non-degenerate diverse market — see Proposition 3 further be-
low.
Diversity-Weighted Portfolios with Negative Parameter 13
By Lemma 3.5 of Fernholz and Karatzas (2009), the bounded variance condi-
tion (BV) implies that for long-only portfolios π(·) we have the almost sure
inequality
γπ∗ (t) ≤ 2K 1 − π(1) (t) , ∀ t ≥ 0.
(51)
Proposition 2 Let us place ourselves in the market model (1), under the
conditions (ND), (BV) and (NF).
−
The diversity-weighted portfolio π (p ) (·) with negative parameter
log n
p− ∈ ,0
log(nϕ)
+
is then a strong arbitrage relative to the diversity-weighted portfolio π (p ) (·)
with positive parameter
−
ε(n − (nϕ)p )(1 − p− ) o
n
+
p ∈ max 0, 1 − ,1 , (52)
4K(n − 1)
−2 log(nϕ)
T > . (53)
C
Here the positive constant C is defined as
−
!
ε (nϕ)p 2K
1 − p− − (n − 1)(1 − p+ ) .
C := 1− (54)
2 n n
±
Proof To simplify notation a bit, we write π ± (·) and G± for π (p ) (·) and Gp± ,
respectively. Note that for p+ > 0 the inequalities in (21) reverse, i.e.,
+ p+ +
nϕp ≤ G+ (µ(t)) ≤ n1−p , (55)
which again gives the lower bound of (22) for p = p+ . Using (51) with the
+
observation π(1) (t) ≥ 1/n, we get that
Z T Z T
γπ∗+ (t) dt ≤ 2K +
1 − π(1) (t) dt ≤ 2KT 1 − (1/n) . (56)
0 0
14 Alexander Vervuurt, Ioannis Karatzas
Hence, recalling (25), we see that by virtue of (55) and (56) the master equa-
tion (14) for π(·) = π + (·) leads to the upper bound
+
V π (T )
≤ − log(nϕ) + 2(1 − p+ )KT 1 − (1/n) ,
log P-a.s. (57)
V µ (T )
provided that
CT > −2 log(nϕ) > 0 . (59)
Here, the constant C is given by (54). An easy calculation shows that (52)
implies C > 0, whereas the last inequality in (59) comes from ϕ < 1/n. It
follows that the first inequality in (59) is equivalent to the condition posited
in (53), and that in this case π − (·) outperforms π + (·) strongly over the time-
horizon [0, T ]. t
u
+
Proposition 2 shows that, as long as the diversity-weighted portfolio π (p ) (·)
is “sufficiently similar” to the market portfolio µ(·) (and thus “far enough”
−
from π (p ) (·)), it is outperformed strongly, over sufficiently long time-horizons,
−
by the diversity-weighted portfolio π (p ) (·) with negative parameter – pro-
vided, of course, that the aforementioned conditions on the volatility structure
and non-failure of stocks hold.
5.2 Mixing
Since the no-failure assumption (NF) does not hold in real markets, it is of
interest to find variants of (16) which exhibit similar performance, but require
weaker assumptions. The rank-based variant in Proposition 1 is one attempt
at this; Proposition 3 right below is another.
Gp+ (µ(t))
p(t) = ∈ (0, 1). (61)
Gp+ (µ(t)) + Gp− (µ(t))
Diversity-Weighted Portfolios with Negative Parameter 15
In the market model (1), with assumptions (ND) and (D), the portfolio π b(·)
is a strong arbitrage relative to the market µ(·), over time-horizons [0, T ] with
− + −
2(1 + n(1/p )−1 ) log n(1/p )−1 + n(1/p )−1
T > T := . (62)
εδ(1 − p+ )
as this holds for any long-only portfolio by Lemma 3.3 of Fernholz and Karatzas
(2009), which together with the observation that p(t) < 1 allows us to obtain
the bound
g(t) ≥ (1 − p+ )p(t)γπ∗+ (t).
b (65)
We note the simple bounds
n n
X X p+ p+ +
1= µi (t) ≤ µi (t) = G+ (µ(t) ≤ n1−p , (66)
i=1 i=1
and that the lower bound in (21) holds even without (NF), so now
n
X 1/p−
p− −
0 ≤ µi (t) = G− (µ(t)) ≤ n(1/p )−1
. (67)
i=1
Using the lower bound from (66), and the upper bound from (67), we assert
that −1
G− (µ(t)) 1
p(t) = 1 + ≥ > 0. (68)
G+ (µ(t)) 1 + n(1/p− )−1
One can easily see that in the positive-parameter diversity-weighted portfo-
lio, one’s proportion of wealth invested relative to the market portfolio is
16 Alexander Vervuurt, Ioannis Karatzas
The non-degeneracy condition (ND) implies (11), which by (69) and the di-
versity assumption (D) leads to
ε ε ε
γπ∗+ (t) ≥ +
1 − π(1) (t) ≥ 1 − µ(1) (t) > δ . (70)
2 2 2
Finally, applying (65) to the master equation (14), and then using the
bounds (66), (67) and (68), (70), we conclude that
Z T
V πb (T )
G+ (µ(T )) + G− (µ(T ))
log ≥ log +
+ (1 − p ) p(t)γπ∗+ (t) dt
V µ (T ) G+ (µ(0)) + G− (µ(0)) 0
+ − ε δT
≥ − log n(1/p )−1 + n(1/p )−1 + 1 − p+
2 1 + n(1/p− )−1
> 0 , P-a.s. (71)
We have shown that the long-only portfolio (60) outperforms strongly the
market over sufficiently long time-horizons, under the assumptions of non-
degeneracy and diversity. This is a property that the portfolio π + (·) also has
on its own, as proved in the Appendix of Fernholz et al. (2005).
We remark also that, since the “threshold” T of (62) is strictly decreasing
in p− , and the lower bound (71) is strictly increasing in p− for fixed T , our
result becomes stronger the closer the negative parameter p− gets to the
+
origin. As we take p− ↑ 0, we recover the well-known result that π
b(·) = π (p ) (·)
is a strong arbitrage relative to the market.
t
u
Diversity-Weighted Portfolios with Negative Parameter 17
We should note here that, since both the (NF) and (LF) conditions imply
diversity, by Lemma 8.1 and Example 8.3 of Fernholz et al. (2005) it follows
that short-term relative arbitrage exists. That is, using the “mirror portfo-
lios” of Fernholz, Karatzas and Kardaras, one can construct a portfolio which
outperforms the market over any time-horizon [0, T ].
We mention briefly two other variants of the portfolio (16) with p < 0, which
exhibit similar behavior for mid- and upper-range market weights (in the sense
that they invest in stocks which decrease in value relative to the market, and
sell stock when a company’s market weight increases), but start selling stock
once a firm’s market weight falls below a certain threshold. The idea behind
this threshold is that it represents a value below which the investor fears
bankruptcy of the firm, and wishes to liquidate the position in the firm so as
to minimize losses. The two portfolios we propose have weights
and
µi (t)α (1 − µi (t))β
Bi (t) = Pn α β
, i = 1, . . . , n . (74)
j=1 µj (t) (1 − µj (t))
Here, k, θ and α, β are all positive constants; the threshold values below which
the portfolio weights become increasing functions of market weights are θk and
α/(α + β), respectively. So far, our results regarding these portfolios remain
restricted to empirical ones (see Section 6).
6 Empirical Results
of the total absolute value traded. We rebalance the portfolio using a simple
Total Variance criterion, that is, we only rebalance when the total variance
“distance”
n
X
TV(eπ (t), π(t)) = π ei (t) − πi (t)
ei (t) π (75)
i=1
where π̄(t − 1) is the portfolio that was actually implemented in the previous
time step.
We use R to program our simulations — the code is available upon request.
We summarize our findings in Table 1, which displays the average annual rel-
ative returns in excess of the market (denoted “Market-RR”), and the Sharpe
ratios of our portfolios over the entire 25-year period that we use; the latter is
computed as
Rπ T
SharpeRatio(π(·)) = π
· . (76)
StdDev(R ) 25
Here, Rπ = {Rπ (t), t = 1, . . . , T } are the daily returns of the portfolio π, with
mean Rπ , namely
V π (t)
Rπ (t) = π (t
− 1, t = 2, . . . , T, (77)
V − 1)
and the sample standard deviation StdDev is defined as follows for any se-
quence of numbers x1 , . . . , xk ∈ R with average x:
k
2 1 X
StdDev(x1 , . . . , xk ) := (xi − x)2 . (78)
k − 1 i=1
Table 1 Some measures of performance for the studied portfolios when traded between 1
January 1990 and 31 December 2014 on the constituents of the S&P 500 index, over which
the market had an average annual return of 9.7190%. We write π E (·) for the equally-weighted
portfolio πiE (·) = 1/n, i = 1, . . . , n. The parameter “TV threshold” determines over which
value of TV as in (75) we rebalance, which we determine in-sample by trial-and-error.
From Table 1 and Figure 1, we can see that all portfolios outperform the
market by quite a margin (however, only after the year 2000), both in terms
of the market-relative return, as well as the Sharpe Ratio. We also note that
the simulated realizations of wealth processes are much more volatile than
that of the market; the portfolios seem to exploit market growth much better,
but also lose value more quickly when the market does poorly. Moreover, the
negative-parameter portfolios we study appear to perform better than their
positive-parameter versions over the period studied. The reader will notice
that the positive-parameter portfolio π (p) (·) with p = 0.5, and the mixing
portfolio π
b(·), give identical results, which is because the weight (61) of the
positive-parameter diversity-weighted portfolio is always very near 1 (namely
1 − p(t) ∼ 1e-11). Finally, we wish to stress that the above portfolio and
threshold parameters were optimized only heuristically, and therefore there
is considerable room for improvement (that is, through more systematic opti-
mization) — our empirical study is merely a demonstration of outperformance
of the market with the portfolios studied.
We wish to point out that all of our results require certain assumptions on
the volatility structure of the market, as well as on the behavior of the market
weights. The no-failure condition (NF) definitely does not hold in real mar-
kets, since typically some companies do crash. The weaker (LF) assumption
is an improvement on this, and can be argued to hold for m not too close
20 Alexander Vervuurt, Ioannis Karatzas
Fig. 1 The wealth processes corresponding to the portfolios in Table 1, namely: the market
portfolio µ(·); the diversity-weighted portfolios π (p) (·) with p = 0 (i.e. the equally-weighted
portfolio), p = 0.5, and p = −0.5; the rank-based diversity-weighted portfolios π # (·) with
r = −0.5, m = 470 and π [ (·) with r = 0.5, m = 30, and r = −0.5, m = 30; the mixed
b(·) from (60), with p+ = 0.5, p− = −0.5; and the portfolios (73) and (74), with
portfolio π
k = 0.65, θ = 1e-4 and α = 1e-4, β = 2, respectively.
portfolio. A first attempt at this was made by (Fernholz, 2002, Section 6.3),
where R. Fernholz estimates the turnover in a diversity-weighted portfolio.
Another idea is to replace the almost sure assumptions (D), (LF), and
(NF), by probabilistic versions of these assumptions, where the corresponding
bounds on market weights hold with a probability close to but smaller than
1. It would be interesting to see whether probabilistic relative arbitrages could
be constructed, which have a certain “likelihood of outperforming” the market
— see Bayraktar et al. (2012) for a first study in this direction.
One could also incorporate additional information on expected drifts and
bankruptcies, to improve the simple portfolios set forth in this paper. The
approach by Pal and Wong (2013) might be applied to achieve this. Moreover,
it would be of interest to develop methods for finding the optimal relative
arbitrage within the class of functionally-generated portfolios; an attempt at
this was made in Pal and Wong (2014), and for more general strategies in
Fernholz and Karatzas (2010) and Fernholz and Karatzas (2011). Limitations
on the existence of relative arbitrages with respect to certain portfolios have
been established in the recent paper Wong (2015).
References