07quah EJ1996
07quah EJ1996
07quah EJ1996
Danny T. Quah
The Economic Journal, Vol. 106, No. 437. (Jul., 1996), pp. 1045-1055.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0013-0133%28199607%29106%3A437%3C1045%3ATPGACI%3E2.0.CO%3B2-3
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/about/terms.html. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained
prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in
the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.
Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/journals/res.html.
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.
The JSTOR Archive is a trusted digital repository providing for long-term preservation and access to leading academic
journals and scholarly literature from around the world. The Archive is supported by libraries, scholarly societies, publishers,
and foundations. It is an initiative of JSTOR, a not-for-profit organization with a mission to help the scholarly community take
advantage of advances in technology. For more information regarding JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
http://www.jstor.org
Mon Jan 21 00:14:57 2008
The Economic Journal, 106 ( J u l y ) , 1045-1055 0 Royal Economic Society 1996. Published by Blackwell
Publishers, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 IJF, UK and 238 Main Street, Cambridge, MA 02142, USA.
T W I N PEAKS: G R O W T H AND C O N V E R G E N C E I N
MODELS O F DISTRIBUTION DYNAMICS
Danny T. Quah
Convergence concerns poor economies catching up with rich ones. At issue is what happens to the
cross sectional distribution of economies, not whether a single economy tends towards its own
steady state. It is the latter, however, that has preoccupied the traditional approach to convergence
analysis. This paper describes a body of research that overcomes this shortcoming in the traditional
approach. The new findings - on persistence and stratification; on the formation of convergence
clubs; and on the distribution polarising into twin peaks of rich and poor - suggest the relevance
of a class of theoretical ideas, different from the production-function accounting traditionally
favoured.
I. T H E T R A D I T I O N A L A P P R O A C H
11. D I S T R I B U T I O N D Y N A M I C S
t /+s Time
Fig. I. Twin-peaks distribution dynamics.
inform on the dynamics of the poor catching up with the rich. I t would inform
on the poor stagnating within poverty traps; on the poor overtaking those
previously rich; and on convergence club dynamics - sub-groups or clubs
forming, with member countries converging towards each other, and diverging
away from different clubs. I t would shed light on possibilities for the poorest
5 % of the cross section catching up with the richest 5 % ;and on whether global
development takes multi-tier forms. Intra-distribution dynamics include
information on switches in ranks - the leading country falling to seventeenth
position, or vice versa - but, more than that, they also include information on the
distance traversed when such switches happen.
I have just described some characteristics of (cross-country income)
distribution dynamics that will be of interest in discussing convergence.
Formalising this description offers two payoffs: first, precise statistical
quantification; second, theoretical analysis based on economic ideas.
The simplest useful model of distribution dynamics is one where a stochastic
difference equation describes the evolution of the sequence of distributions. Let
Ft denote the time t cross-country income distribution. Associated with each
4 is a probability measure A,, where
with the result being a proxy for A,,. Then, convergence in country incomes
to equality might be represented by ( 2 ) tending, as s + co, towards a
O Royal Economic Society 1996
19961 TWIN PEAKS 1051
degenerate point mass. Alternatively, the world polarising into rich and poor
might be represented by ( 2 ) tending towards a two-point measure : the implied
limit distribution 4+,,s - t co, would then be bimodal or twin-peaked. More
generally, stratification into different convergence clubs might manifest in ( 2 )
tending towards a multi-point, discrete measure, or equivalently, a multi-
modal distribution. How quickly a given initial distribution, F,, evolves into the
limiting distribution, I;E+,, s - t co, can be read off T*'s (spectral) structure.
Finally, T * also contains information on intra-distribution dynamics.
Exploiting that structure, one can quantify the likelihood of the poor catching
up with the rich, and characterise the (random) occurrence times for such
events.
In summary, studying T * informs on all the interesting issues in convergence
analysis. What then does empirical evidence - the Summers-Heston (1991)
data - tell us about T * and Fig. I ? Desdoigts ( 1994), Lam0 ( 1995), Paap and
van Dijk (1gg4), and Quah (1993a, b ; 1996a) take the approach of estimating
- in some form - the operator T*. Some of this work views estimating T * as
Ben-David (1994) takes a different approach, but with end results that have the same interpretation.
0 Royal Economic Society 1gg6
1052 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [JULY
nowhere does he consider T * dynamics - one can reasonably guess that his
findings are more robust to possible misspecification. Here again, twin-
peakedness manifests.
I t is obvious that calculating standard deviations or any other moment of the
cross section distribution can show nothing about twin-peaks dynamics. The
cross-section correlation between growth rates and income levels reveals even
less, its interpretation plagued by a version of Galton's Fallacy.6 However,
operator T * can shed light on that seductive intuition - the poor growing faster
and thereby catching up with the rich - that growth-on-levels regressions wish
to exploit. Quah ( 1 9 9 6 ~ calculates,
) from an estimated T*, the probability
density of passage times from poor parts of the income distribution to rich
parts.' He finds that although growth miracles - the Hong Kongs, the South
Koreas, and the Singapores - can happen with reasonable positive probability,
the passage time from the bottom 5 % percentile to the top, given the
magnitude of the gap extant, averages in the hundreds of years. Thus,
persistence and immobility characterise the world cross section of country
incomes.
(Although their being stated with T*-induced preciseness is new with the
body of research that I have just summarised, all such empirical facts have long
been used informally in work such as Lucas (1988, 1993)).
What new economic ideas do these distribution dynamics suggest? These
dynamics draw attention towards the nature of cross-country interactions -
although, to be clear, not entirely away from production function accounting.
They suggest that an appropriate test of economic ideas about the convergence
hypothesis will come from looking at implications on how the entire cross
section distribution evolves, not from studying the behaviour of a single,
representative economy.
A theoretical model of distribution dynamics - in generational earnings -
was developed by Loury ( I 98 I ) . Many of those technical modelling ideas apply
here as well, although the current emphasis on clustering and coalition
formation across individual elements of the distribution is novel. This focus on
cross-sectional grouping does, however, mesh with recent econometric research
(Brock and Durlauf, 1995; Manski, 1993).
That particular economic features - threshold externalities, capital market
imperfection, heterogeneity, country size, club formation - might produce
'twin peaks' dynamics across countries can be seen in theoretical models in
Azariadis and Drazen ( I ggo), Galor and Zeira ( I 993)) Quah ( I 995 b, 1996"))
and Tamura (1992). Quah (1995b, 1996a) most closely relates the theoretical
message in these papers to empirical analysis.
The theoretical model in Quah (19953) describes economic forces that
determine coalition or convergence club formation. That model shows why
' This connection is made in Friedman ( I 992) and Quah (1993b, 1996 b). Quah ( I 996b) also details why
no combination of,'-convergence and u-convergence (in the terminology of Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992)
and Sala-i-Martin (1995, 1996)) can provide a satisfactory work-around.
' Durlauf and Johnson (1994) have studied similar phenomena in the dynamics of personal income
distribution.
0 Royal Economic Society 1996
I 9961 TWIN PEAKS 1°53
'conditional convergence' in the traditional approach can be misleading:
when different convergence clubs form, factor inputs (e.g. human capital) and
social characteristics (e.g., democracy) will endogenously align around values
determined by each country's convergence club. Conditioning on such
'explanatory variables' leads the researcher using the traditional approach to
conclude, erroneously, that it is those variables that determine a country's
economic position. By contrast, in the model, it is the factors deciding club
membership that determine everything. The traditional researcher never finds
those, and incorrectly attributes growth and convergence to factor inputs and
social characteristics. Moreover, because in that traditional approach, the
researcher only estimates a cross-section regression, he sees only the behaviour
of the (conditional) representative economy. He will never detect the multi-
peakedness that arises in the cross-country distribution.
Similar lessons manifest in the model in Quah ( 1 9 9 6 ~ )Here,
. it is varying
degrees of capital market imperfection that lead to twin-peaks dynamics in the
model. I n the traditional approach, the researcher might simply proxy the
capital market imperfectness by interest rates, say. However, in the model, all
countries eventually have equal rates of return for borrowing and investment.
The traditional researcher, therefore, never finds out the reason why twin-peaks
dynamics occur - not that he ever even realises their presence. Moreover, the
model predicts that every country converges (in a univariate sense) to its own
steady state at an identical rate shared by all other countries. The traditional
researcher then finds exactly a globally stable, constant rate of 'convergence'
in the traditional conditional convergence regression. Such a finding, however,
sheds no light on the actual distribution dynamics occurring.
111. C O N C L U S I O N
With hindsight, the key point in this paper is obvious. Convergence concerns
poor economies catching up with rich ones. What one wants to know here is,
what happens to the entire cross sectional distribution of economies, not
whether a single economy is tending towards its own, individual steady state.
However, it is the latter that has preoccupied the traditional approach.
Proposed fixes to that approach (e.g., the increased emphasis on g-convergence
in Sala-i-Martin (1995)) continue to miss the principal important features of
economic growth and convergence.
Such criticisms would be merely idle if there were no alternative empirics
that appropriately address the key issues relevant to convergence analysis. This
paper has described a rich and growing body of research that does exactly that.
The new findings reported here - on persistence and stratification; on the
formation of convergence clubs; on the distribution polarising into twin peaks
of rich and poor - suggest the relevance of a class of theoretical ideas, different
from the production-function accounting favoured by the traditional approach.
It might, ultimately, be those factors that are important for growth, not just
crudely boosting the inputs in a neoclassical production function.
Many issues remain to be researched in this alternative approach. The
0 Royal Economic Society 1996
1°54 T H E ECONOMIC JOURNAL [JULY
empirical analyses of distribution dynamics can be substantially refined : Quah
( I 995 a, C) explore some ways to do this. Theoretical models for cross-country,
or more general social, interaction (e.g., Benabou (1995); Brock and Durlauf
( I 995) ; Quah ( I 995 b), among many others) provide new insights on how
economies evolve - and, in turn, generate intriguing new predictions to be
studied empirically.
London School of Economics
Atkinson, Anthony B. (1970). ' O n the measurement of inequality.' Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 2 (3),
pp. 244-63 (September).
Azariadis, Costas and Drazen, Allan (1990). 'Threshold externalities in economic development.' Quarterly
Journal of Economics, vol. 105 (2), pp. 501-26 (May).
Barro, Robert J. and Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (1990). 'Convergence.' Journal of Political Economy, vol. 100 (2),
pp. 223-5 1 (April).
Ben-David, Dan (1994). 'Convergence clubs and diverging economies.' Working paper 922, Centre for
Economic Policy Research, London (February).
BCnabou, Roland (1995). 'Heterogeneity, stratification, and growth: macroeconomic implications of
community structure and school finance.' Working paper, Economics Department, New York
University (March).
Bianchi, Marco (1995).'Testing for convergence: a bootstrap test for multimodality.' Working paper, Bank
of England (May).
Brock, William A. and Durlauf, Steven N. (1995). 'Discrete choice with social interactions.' Working paper,
University of Wisconsin, Madison (April).
Desdoigts, Alan ( I 994). 'Changes in the world income distribution: a nonparametric approach to challenge
the neoclassical convergence argument. PhD thesis, European University Institute, Florence (June).
Durlauf, Steven N. and Johnson, Paul (1994). 'Nonlinearities in intergenerational income mobility.'
Working paper, University of Wisconsin, Economics Department.
Durlauf, Steven N. and Johnson, Paul (1995).'Multiple regimes and cross-country growth behavior.' Journal
of Applied Econometrics, vol. 10. (Forthcoming).
Friedman, Milton (1992).'DOold fallacies ever die?'. Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 30 (4), pp. 2 129-32
(December).
Galor, Oded and Zeira, Joseph (1993).'Income distribution and macroeconomics.' Review of Economic Studies,
vol. 60 ( I ) , pp. 35-52 (January).
Griliches, Zvi and Ringstad, Vidar (1971). Economies of Scale and the Form of the Production Function,
Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Lama, Ana R. (1995). 'Cross-section distribution dynamics.' Ph.D thesis, London School of Economics,
London. (In progress).
Loury, Glenn C. (1981).'Intergenerational transfers and the distribution of earnings.' Econometrica, vol. 49
(41, PP. 843-67 (July).
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1988) ' O n the mechanics of economic development.' Journal of Monetary Economics,
vol. 22 (3), pp. 3-42 (June).
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1993).'Making a miracle.' Econometrica, vol. 61 (2), pp. 251-71 (March).
Manski, Charles F. (1993). 'Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem.' Review of
Economic Studies, vol. 60 (3), pp. 531-42 (July).
Paap, Richard and van Dijk, Herman K. (1994). 'Distribution and mobility of wealth of nations.' Working
paper, Tinbergen Institute, Erasmus University (October).
A A
LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 1 of 3 -
This article references the following linked citations. If you are trying to access articles from an
off-campus location, you may be required to first logon via your library web site to access JSTOR. Please
visit your library's website or contact a librarian to learn about options for remote access to JSTOR.
[Footnotes]
2
The Measurement of Mobility
A. F. Shorrocks
Econometrica, Vol. 46, No. 5. (Sep., 1978), pp. 1013-1024.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28197809%2946%3A5%3C1013%3ATMOM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-X
6
Do Old Fallacies Ever Die?
Milton Friedman
Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 30, No. 4. (Dec., 1992), pp. 2129-2132.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-0515%28199212%2930%3A4%3C2129%3ADOFED%3E2.0.CO%3B2-7
References
NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org
LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 2 of 3 -
Convergence
Robert J. Barro; Xavier Sala-i-Martin
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100, No. 2. (Apr., 1992), pp. 223-251.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0022-3808%28199204%29100%3A2%3C223%3AC%3E2.0.CO%3B2-L
Making a Miracle
Robert E. Lucas, Jr.
Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 2. (Mar., 1993), pp. 251-272.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0012-9682%28199303%2961%3A2%3C251%3AMAM%3E2.0.CO%3B2-M
NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.
http://www.jstor.org
LINKED CITATIONS
- Page 3 of 3 -
The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950-1988
Robert Summers; Alan Heston
The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, No. 2. (May, 1991), pp. 327-368.
Stable URL:
http://links.jstor.org/sici?sici=0033-5533%28199105%29106%3A2%3C327%3ATPWT%285%3E2.0.CO%3B2-D
NOTE: The reference numbering from the original has been maintained in this citation list.