CEFIR July-September 2007
CEFIR July-September 2007
CEFIR July-September 2007
Beyond Transition
July September 2007 Volume 18, No. 3
http://www.worldbank.org/transitionnewsletter www.cefir.ru
Where to Sell? Market Facilities and Agricultural Marketing in India Forhad Shilpi and Dina Umali Deininger 11 The Economics of Farm Organization in Transition Countries Pavel Ciaian, Jan Pokrivcak, Dusan Drabik 12 Land Policy and Farm Efficiency: The Lessons of Moldova Dragos Cimpoies, Zvi Lerman 13 Alternative Non Agricultural Employment in Rural Russia Yevgenia Serova, Dmitry Zvyagintsev, Tatyana Tikhonova, and Olga Shik 14 Health Shocks in Rural China Yang Yao 15 "Ruralization" of Poverty in Russia Christopher J Gerry, Eugene Nivorozhkin, John Rigg
17
The Impact of International Migration on Albanian Family Farming Juna Miluka, Gero Carletto, Benjamin Davis, and Alberto Zezza 18
Photo: ECA, the World Bank
New Findings
Electricity Sector Reforms and the Poor in Europe and Central Asia Julian A. Lampietti, Sudeshna Ghosh Banerjee, and Amelia Branczik 19 Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth in Europe and Central Asia Cheryl Gray, Tracey Lane and Aristomene Varoudakis (eds.) Who Wants to Revise Privatization? Irina Denisova, Markus Eller, Timothy Frye, and Ekaterina Zhuravskaya 23 The Resource Curse and Corporate Transparency Art Durnev and Sergei Guriev 24
Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Transition Economies Kym Anderson and Johan Swinnen 5 The World Food Equation, Rewritten Joachim von Braun 7 Biofuels A Revolution in the Making? Brazil's Experience with Bioenergy Jose Roberto Moreira 9 Can China Continue Feeding Itself? Jinxia Wang, Robert Mendelsohn, Ariel Dinar, Jikun Huang, Scott Rozelle and Lijuan Zhang 10
21
World Bank Agenda 25 New Books and Working Papers 27 Conference Diary 30
Characteristics of the Three Country Types, 2005 Agriculture Transfor Urbanized based countries ming countries countries Rural population (millions), 2005 Share of population rural (%), 2005 Share of agriculture in GDP (%), 2005 Annual agricultural GDP growth, 1993 2005 (%) Annual nonagricultural GDP growth, 1993 2005 (%) Number of rural poor (millions), 2002 Rural poverty rate, 2002 (%) 417 68 29 4.0 3.5 170 51 2,220 63 13 2.9 7.0 583 28 255 26 6 2.2 2.7 32 13
economies were expanding rapidly. In India, the low level and quality of education of most rural workers is mainly responsible for their inability to find jobs in the booming services economy. The main challenge for transforming countries is to reduce the rapidly rising urban-rural income gap and rural poverty. All pathways out of poverty should be mobilized: farming, employment in agriculture and the rural nonfarm economy, and migration. Rapidly expanding markets for highvalue products especially horticulture, poultry, fish, and dairy offer an opportunity to diversify farming systems and develop a competitive and laborintensive smallholder sector. Export markets for such products are also accessible because transforming countries have a comparative advantage in labor and management-intensive activities. The poverty impact of growth in the agricultural sector will thus depend increasingly on the poor connecting to these new growth processes, either as smallholders or laborers. Vertically integrated supply chains may pose particular challenges for them, although recent evidence from China suggests that small and poor farmers take an active part in China's rapidly expanding horticulture economy. Agriculture alone cannot relieve rural poverty; rural nonfarm employment is also important. In India and Indonesia, for example, growth in rural services has contributed at least as much as growth in agriculture toward reducing poverty. Growth in rural nonfarm employment often remains closely linked to growth in agriculture, as agriculture becomes a larger supplier of intermediate inputs to other sectors such as processed foods. However, with urbanization and global-
ization, growth in nonfarm employment occurs increasingly independently of agriculture. Regions in India with the slowest growth in agricultural productivity had the largest increase in the rural nonfarm tradable sector. When capital and products are mobile, investors seek low-wage opportunities in areas that did not increase their incomes through higher agricultural productivity. Faster absorption of the agricultural labor force in the urban economy should be facilitated through investments in human capital and labor market policies, such as vocational training, transport services, and job matching. Complementing these policies with those that foster rural income growth and slow migration out of the traditional sector can provide important synergies.
voice in unequal societies can enhance the size and competitiveness of the smallholder sector. Beyond farming, territorial approaches are being pursued to promote local employment through interlinked farming and rural agroindustry. Agricultural growth is especially important to improve well-being in geographic pockets of poverty with good agricultural potential. For regions without such potential, the transition out of agriculture and the provision of environmental services offer better prospects. But support to the agricultural component of the livelihoods of subsistence farmers will remain an imperative for many years.
Agriculture makes up only 6% of the urbanized economies and contributes proportionately to growth, however the agribusiness and food industry, and services can account for 30% of GDP. Although almost three-quarters of the population of urbanized countries lives in urban areas, 45% of the poor are in rural areas, and 18% of the labor force still works in agriculture. The broad goal is to capitalize on the rapid expansion of modern domestic food markets and booming agricultural subsectors to create opportunities for smallholders and sharply reduce the remaining rural poverty, which remains stubbornly high. The urbanized countries are experiencing the supermarket revolution in food retailing. For smallholders, being competitive in supplyUrban Rural Income Disparity Has Increased ing supermarkets is in Most Transforming Countries a major challenge that requires meetRatio of urban to rural median income ing strict standards and achieving scale 4 Initial year End year in delivery, for 3 which effective producer organizations 2 are essential. Increasing the 1 access of smallhold0 ers to assets, particGuatemala Thailand Cambodia China India Pakistan Vietnam Indonesia Bangladesh ularly land, and 1989 2002 1990 2002 1997 2004 1985 2001 1992 2001 1993 2002 1991 2000 1989 99 1999 2001 increasing their
September 2007
tries in 2000-04 accounted for 89% of the region's agricultural value added, 91% of its population and 95% of total GDP. Our analysis shows that beginning in the early 1990s, many trade and price distortions were removed throughout the region. Price, exchange rate, and trade policies were all liberalized, subsidies were cut, hard budget constraints were introduced, property rights were privatized, and production decisions were shifted to companies and households. Support for agriculture fell to very low levels (Table 1). Between 1992 and 1995, nominal rates of assistance to agriculture (NRA, defined as the percentage by which government policies have raised gross returns to producers above what they would be without the government's intervention) averaged just 12% in the CEE10 and were below zero in Bulgaria, the three Baltic nations, Russia and Ukraine. In the second half of the 1990s, assistance to agriculture increased again, to an average of Table 1. Nominal Rates of Assistance to 22% in 1996-99 for all ECA Agriculture*, 1992 to 2005 (percent) countries, before it fell somewhat to an average of 1992 95 1996 99 2000 03 2004 05 17% in 2000-03. Distortion levels vary Bulgaria 19 10 0 13 considerably among counCzech Rep 20 19 27 na tries and across commodiEstonia 14 20 20 na ties. The CEE-8 countries Hungary 19 18 34 na moved first and most rapidLatvia 15 30 36 na ly towards market-based Lithuania 19 29 32 na systems. The reforms in Poland 10 24 7 na Romania and Bulgaria were Romania 24 30 55 67 initially half-hearted and Slovakia 28 26 30 na involved many inconsistenSlovenia 64 79 80 na cies during most of the CEE 10 12 22 24 na 1990s, with government interventions continuing to Turkey 15 25 22 30 heavily distort incentives. In Russia 8 25 13 22 Russia, Kazakhstan and Ukraine 21 1 11 3 Ukraine, governments conAll ECA studied tinued important controls of countries 3 22 17 na the agricultural economy through a variety of inter* Weighted average, with weights based on gross value of agricul tural production at undistorted prices ventions such as regional Source: Ch. 1 of Anderson. K. and J. Swinnen (eds.), Distortions to trade controls, input supply Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies, Washington controls, and the continuaDC: World Bank, forthcoming 2008.
tion of soft budget constraints. While the Kyrgyz Republic liberalized relatively quickly, the other Central Asian countries have restricted reforms and liberalization. In particular, major controls still remain in place in Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan. In the 1980s virtually all commodities were supported, but some more than others. With transition there is substantial variation among commodities and in the CIS producers of some commodities are now effectively taxed. Government intervention and controls are especially important in a few key commodities within each country, often because of food security concerns or the need to raise government revenue to meet other priorities, or because the government wishes to extract rents from those activities.
trast, price and trade interventions, such as price supports or import tariffs, are much less efficient. The efficiency of policies used by ECA countries is often low. In replacing budgetary transfers to the food sector under the communist system, a different set of inefficiencies has been introduced, such as transfers from consumers to producers by way of import restrictions. Up to the mid-1990s, policies in all countries except Turkey and Slovenia imposed the equivalent of low or negative taxes on food consumers, which thereafter have become positive. Many of the direct subsidies to producers do not reach the farmer. This is due to a combination of institutional constraints and induced reactions to policy changes. For example, benefits targeted at the farms dissipate to other groups, e.g. agribusiness or food industries or landowners; they often go to a subset of the farms, typically those with the best political connections. Other important constraints include poor physical infrastructure; corruption; inadequate human capital; the incompatibility between the large-scale input supplying or food processing firms and the small farmers; as well as policy interventions, such as trade controls by regional authorities.
Table 2: Relative per Capita Income*, Agricultural Comparative Advantage Index**, and NRA, 2000 03 Relative Agricult. compara per tive capita income advantage Slovenia Czech Rep. Hungary Estonia Poland Slovakia Lithuania Latvia Turkey Russia Romania Bulgaria Ukraine 216 135 122 102 93 92 80 76 55 47 41 39 17 52 61 90 199 105 57 176 364 131 53 74 143 112
NRA
80 29 34 20 7 30 32 36 22 13 55 0 11
* Income per capita relative to the world average, 2000 04 ** Agriculture and food's share of national exports as a percentage of agriculture and food's share of global exports, 2000 04 Source: Ch. 1 of Anderson. K. and J. Swinnen (eds.), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies.
Kym Anderson is George Gollin Professor of Economics at the University of Adelaide, Australia, and a CEPR Research Fellow; Johan Swinnen is Professor of Economics and Director of LICOS Center for Institutions and Economic Performance at the Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium. The article is based on the summary chapter of the World Bank book Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Europe's Transition Economies (forthcoming in mid-2008). BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
risk of droughts and floods due to rising temperatures, crop-yield losses are imminent. The impact of global warming on developing countries will be much more severe than on developed ones. Agricultural output in developing countries is projected to decline by 20%, while output in industrial countries is projected to decline by 6%. Technological change is unlikely to alleviate output losses and increase yields to a rate that would keep up with growing food demand. In addition, the growing power and leverage of international corporations are transforming the opportunities available to small agricultural producers in developing countries. While new prospects have arisen for some farmers, many others have not been able to take advantage of the new opportunities since the rigorous safety and quality standards of food processors and food retailers create high barriers to their market entry. Transactions along the corporate food chain have increased in the past two years. Between 2004 and 2006, total global food spending grew by 16%. In the same period, the sales of food retailers increased by a disproportionately large amount more than 40% for top retailers compared to the sales of food processors and of companies in the food input industry (which grew by 13% and 8% for top companies in the respective field).
sumption is explained not just by growing cereal use for food and feed (which increased by 4 and 7% since 2000, respectively) but also by the use of cereals for industrial purposes such as biofuel production. Supply an demand changes do not fully explain the price increases. Financial investors are becoming increasingly interested in rising commodity prices, and speculative transactions are adding to increased commodity-price volatility. In 2006, the volume of traded global agricultural futures and options rose by almost 30%. Commodity exchanges, which are becoming more relevant in India and China, and some African countries, can help to make food markets more transparent and efficient.
Policy Recommendations
While maintaining a focus on longterm challenges is vital, some policy actions should be undertaken immediately: Developed countries should facilitate flexible responses to drastic price changes by eliminating trade barriers and programs that set aside agriculture resources, except in well-defined conservation areas. A world confronted with greater food scarcity needs to trade more, not less, to spread opportunities fairly. Developing countries should rapidly increase investment in rural infrastructure and market institutions in order to reduce agricultural-input access constraints, since these are hindering a stronger production response. Placing agricultural and food issues onto the national and international climate-change policy agendas is critical for ensuring an efficient and propoor response to the emerging risks.
Joachim von Braun is Director General of the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI). The article is based on the Food Policy Report No. 18 "The World Food Situation: New Driving Forces and Required Actions" published by in December 2007. Full text of the report can be downloaded at: http://www.ifpri.org/pubs/fpr/pr18.asp. BT
Potential Benefits
Energy Security. Current-technology biofuels can only marginally enhance energy security in individual countries because domestic harvests of feedstock crops meet a small part of the demand for transport fuels, with few exceptions (for example, ethanol in Brazil). In 2006/07, around one-fifth of the U.S. maize harvest was used for ethanol but displaced only about 3% of gasoline consumption. Second-generation technologies could potentially make a higher contribution to energy security. Environmental impacts. Global environmental benefits from using renewable fuels reducing greenhouse gas emissions (GHGs) are frequently cited as reasons for policy support to biofuels. Although possibly significant, those benefits cannot be assumed. The emissions from growing feedstocks (including
Brazil is the second largest world producer of ethanol, a biofuel used mainly in automobiles as an additive or alternative to gasoline. Although Brazil's program, started in the mid-1970s, was criticized as being uneconomic during periods of low oil prices, the ethanol industry today is recognized as an efficient sector that brings substantial benefits to the Brazilian economy. All Brazilian ethanol is produced from sugarcane. About 330 privately owned sugar mills each process an average of 1.2 million tonnes of sugar cane per year.
and
The government's reasons for supporting biofuels, at first purely economic and triggered by the oil price spikes of the 1970s, have expanded to include concerns about the country's energy security, greenhouse gas emissions and global climate change, rural employment and equity issues, and local air pollution. Ethanol production has played an important role in guaranteeing fuel security. Since 1975 ethanol has displaced more than 280 billion liters of gasoline and saved more than US$65 billion in the cost of oil imports. Moreover, the sugar/ethanol sector has become a major employer: in 2001 it accounted for roughly one million jobs, of which about 65% were permanent and the remainder seasonal. Another 300,000 jobs were created in manufacturing and other sectors. Sugarcane plantations also represent a major activity for small farmers, as around 30% of sugarcane production is in the hands of 60,000 independent producers. The introduction of gasohol, a combination of gasoline and ethanol, had an immediate positive impact on the air quality of Brazil's large cities, reducing carbon monoxide by more than 25%.
ethanol production if sugar prices fall and vice-versa. Significant productivity improvements in the sugar industry have benefited ethanol production: the cost of producing ethanol declined by an annual average of 5.7% from 1985 to 2005. Synergies with electricity and heat production. Cogeneration of heat and electricity from the by-product, bagasse, supplies all the energy needs of the biofuel production process itself, and allows the surplus electricity to be exported to the grid. Presently more than 1,500 MW of this electricity is being supplied to the grid, mainly in the period of low rainfall, which is a very relevant contribution to energy security since more than 90% of electricity is produced from hydro sources. Programs designed for the supply of more than 3,000 MW are in their final stages, having been developed by the government and the private sector jointly. Institutional support. The Brazilian government has provided necessary incentives to buyers of cars powered by ethanol and service station owners, and has set up a clear institutional framework. The measures included setting technical standards, supporting ethanol production and consumption technologies, providing financial advantages, and ensuring appropriate market conditions. Geographical aspects. An abundant supply of agricultural land, an appropriate climate for growing sugarcane, a developed sugarcane industry, and the presence of more than half of the country's car fleet in Sao Paulo the state with the dominant sugarcane industry have all contributed to the success. In other regions, the government has subsidized the transport costs of ethanol to ensure a wide geographical coverage.
The recent expansion of internal and external markets has triggered the interest of investors, resulting in the planned construction of about 90 new sugar mills between 2006 and 2010, expansion of sugarcane cultivation to new areas, and retrofitting old refineries. Sugar/ethanol production does raise concerns about land use, as it competes with the production of food and export crops. Yet the six million hectares cultivated with sugarcane represent only 8.6% of the total area harvested with essential crops. Moreover, farmers are increasingly rotating between sugarcane and food crops like tomatoes, soy, peanuts, beans, rice, and maize. This has helped maintain the balance between energy and food and has improved land profitability.
Policy Lessons
For countries wishing to improve energy security while promoting rural development, Brazil's experience offers some relevant lessons. The following policies have been most important to Brazil's success: Requiring the auto industry to produce cars running on neat or blended biofuels; Subsidizing biofuels during market development until economies of scale allowed fair competition with oil products; Allowing renewable energybased independent power producers to compete with traditional utilities in the large electricity market; Financing private ownership of sugar mills, which helps guarantee efficient operations; Stimulating rural activities based on biomass energy to increase employment in rural areas.
Positive Outlook
Although ethanol supply and demand have not always been properly balanced, since the launch of flex-fuel cars in early 2003, internal ethanol consumption has increased significantly in Brazil. By 2008, around 90% of new cars manufactured in Brazil are to be flex-fuel models. Export of ethanol has also increased since 2001.
Jose Roberto Moreira is president of the Executive Council of the Brazilian Reference Center on Biomass, Institute of Electrotechnology and Energy, University of Sao Paulo, Brazil. The article is based on the author's policy brief, which first appeared in "Bioenergy and Agriculture: Promises and Challenges", the International Food Policy Research Institute, http://www.ifpri.org/ 2020/focus/focus14.asp. BT
10
For quite some time, global food security issues have been in the center of policy debate. One of the major aspects of this debate has been the role of China, a giant economy with 20% of the world's population. China is also responsible for a significant share in the world's production and consumption of primary agricultural commodities wheat, rice, maize, soybean, and cotton. With projected increases in both population and income in China, feeding larger numbers of more affluent people could become a challenge if not accompanied by increased supply. However, will China be able to increase supply if the climate warms? Growing evidence on rising global temperatures and changes in precipitation patterns makes it ever more important to understand the impacts of global warming on China's agriculture. We measure the sensitivity of Chinese agriculture to warming, employing farm level data and relying on the Ricardian method. The analysis is conducted on 8,405 farms sampled across 28 provinces.
Policy Implications
As is clear from the above, the effects of climate change are not going to be uniform across the country. Warming will assist areas that are currently highly productive and will further handicap areas that have below average productivity. Chinese policy makers need to be aware that warming is likely to impose additional costs on specific regions that already have below average incomes. The ability of Chinese farmers to change and adapt to new conditions has allowed China to outperform other agricultural economies in the world and will continue to be important with respect to climate change. However, it is critical that policies allow China to get the most out of the available factors relating to production and natural resources. An important message of our analysis is that irrigation is critical to China's agriculture system. As nearly 60% of cultivated land in China is irrigated, part of China's ability to cope with future climate change depends on its capacity to use water for irrigation. There could be much larger harmful effects if warming forces many irrigated farms to become rainfed farms. Climate change increases the pressure to develop institutions and infrastructure in water scarce regions to treat water as a valuable resource. China may also consider developing better management practices; adopting new varieties (crops and livestock) suitable for a warmer climate; adapting new technologies in agriculture and educating farmers about them.
Climate Revenue
and
Net
Crop
In general, China's climate is best described as monsoonal, with clear temperature and precipitation differences that vary by region and season. From the south to the north, temperature declines steadily. In the dryer north, more than 70% of a year's precipitation is concentrated in the summer. In the wetter south, precipitation is mainly concentrated in the spring and the summer. Not surprisingly, the net crop revenues also vary by region: they are higher in the south compared to the north and higher in the east compared to the west. Just as significantly, net crop revenues vary between villages that are irrigated and those that are rainfed. On average, the net crop revenue amounted to 10,150 yuan (US$1,353) per hectare across all farms in 2001, however net crop revenue was 12,180 yuan in irrigated villages compared to 7,610 yuan in rainfed villages.
Continue
The agricultural sector as a whole is only mildly vulnerable to global warming. This is because, first, a very large fraction of farms in China are irrigated and, second, the rainfed land in China is largely in temperate or cool regions. The results thus suggest that the answer to the question above is in the affirmative. The likely gains realized by some farmers will nearly offset the losses that will occur to other farmers. An important caveat, however, is that our analysis does not examine the potential harmful consequences of possible reductions in water supply from climate change.
Jinxia Wang is an Associate Professor in the Center for Chinese Agricultural Policy (CCAP), Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing. Robert Mendelsohn is a Professor, Yale University, USA, and a consultant to the World Bank. Ariel Dinar is a Lead Economist in the Development Research Group, the World Bank. Jikun Huang is a Professor and Director in CCAP. Scott Rozelle is a Professor and Senior Fellow, Stanford University, USA. Lijuan Zhang is a Senior Research Assistant in CCAP. Full text of the paper is available at: http://go.worldbank.org/HRW0P2R1V0 (WB Policy Research Working Paper 4470). BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
11
In our study the interaction of market facilities and distance to market from a farmer's village is captured by a market access index, which is a ratio of a number of facilities available at market to the square of the travel time from farmer's village to that market.
decision to sell at the market, as wealth allows farmers to gain access to market facilities easily cutting waiting time in the congested market place. Wealthy farmers are thus able to capture disproportionate benefits from the existing market facilities in a congested market place. They are perhaps able to avail of cheaper modes of transportation and to reduce waiting time and costs in utilizing the market facilities.
Market characteristics Market area (average), acre Number of shops (average) Shop area (average), sq. feet Storage capacity (avg), sq. feet Facilities Parking (all vehicles), % Bus station, % Commercial banks, % Post office, % Police station, % Factory/mills, % Guard, % Equipments Large scale weighing machine, % Grading machine, % Fumigation equipment, % Cold storage, % Warehouse, %
The World Bank & CEFIR
Forhad Shilpi is a senior economist at Development Economics Research Group, and Dina Umali-Deininger is a lead economist at South Asia Sustainable Development unit, the World Bank, Washington, DC. Full text of the paper can be accessed at: http://go.worldbank.org/1Z71VSQQF0 (WB Policy Research Working Paper 4455) BT
12
tage. The comparative advantage of large corporate farms is in capital intensive products for which monitoring of labor is relatively low and in which specialization in labor is possible. Small family farms have comparative advantage in products in which labor monitoring is important, measurement of labor effort is difficult and capital intensity is unimportant. Significant transaction costs explain why corporate farms can keep their dominant position in Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) and the FSU. However, corporate farms compete with family farms for land resources and in domestic and international output markets. High transaction costs protect the existence of corporate farms, but they still have to choose the production structure that most strengthens their competitiveness on the land market relative to growing family farms, and on the output market relative to domestic family farms and international competitors. Thus, in transition countries the crucial choice is not between farm organization, but rather what production structure is chosen by corporate farms and family farms, respectively. Our empirical investigation of agriComparative Advantages cultural commodities, in which family Farms choose the production structure farms and corporate farms, have comparin which they have comparative advan- ative advantage, takes into account labor monitoring requirements and capital Farm Structures in Selected Transition Countries intensity by farm types in ten transiTransformed coopera Family Farms tion countries in tive farms CEE and in the EUShare of total Average Share of total Average 15. We find that: agricultural size (ha) agricultural size (ha) Corporate land (%) land (%) farms have comparaAlbania 96 4 tive advantage in Czech Rep. 28 20 72 937 cereals and oilseed Hungary 59 4 41 312 production, which Kazakhstan 20 80 have low labor Latvia 90 12 10 297 requirement and are Lithuania 89 4 11 483 capital intensive; Poland 87 8 13 Family farms Russia 11 89 6100 have comparative Ukraine 17 83 2100 advantage in permaNote: data from various years from 1997 to 2003 from national ministries of nent crops (such as
agriculture/statistical offices
fruits), which have high labor requirement and low capital intensity; Additional empirical tests confirm that the observed product specialization is indeed as stated above and is similar both in CEE and the EU-15. However, the evidence is mixed for animal sector and field crops (potatoes and sugar beet). In CEE small farms (which use more labor intensive technology) specialize in field crops, while the opposite is true for the EU-15 (where production is more capital intensive). Consistent with the above, a test at the country level finds that in countries where the share of family farms on land use is higher, a smaller area is allocated to cereals and oilseeds and more to labor intensive crops. In these countries the number of livestock and pigs per ha is higher than in countries with a lower share of family farms on the land.
Conclusions
Thus, the farm structure determines which products the country will be competitive in on international markets. As high transaction costs hinder the change of farm organization in transition countries, the choice of product structure is more important than the choice of farm organization. Moreover, when comparing efficiency of family and corporate farms, the transaction costs of using markets should also be taken into consideration. In many transition countries, output markets suit large corporate farms and prevent the development of family farms. Labor intensive products usually require different types of contracting and vertical integration than, for example, capital intensive products.
Pavel Ciaian is a researcher at Katholieke Universiteit, Belgium, and Slovak Agricultural University in Nitra, Slovakia, Jan Pokrivcak, Dusan Drabik are from Slovak Agricultural University in Nitra, Slovakia. The paper was presented at the joint IAAE-104th EAAE Seminar "Agricultural Economics and Transition" in Budapest in 2007. BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
13
As a result of the agrarian reform in Moldova, which started in the early 1990s and was virtually completed by 2000, over one million residents became landowners. Many of them used their privately owned land to establish independent family farms, while others entrusted their land to managers of newly created corporate farms. As of today, 50% of agricultural land in Moldova is used by individual producers. This is in stark contrast to the prereform situation, when individuals cultivated only 2% of agricultural land. The shift of agricultural land from corporate to individual farms has led to significant changes in the production structure of Moldovan agriculture. While at the beginning of the reforms, the individual sector was producing 20% of agricultural output on less than 10% of agricultural land, in 2003 individual farms produced three-quarters of agricultural output on half the agricultural land. We analyze the efficiency and performance of Moldovan farms along two dimensions organizational form and farm size.
Land and Labor Productivity for Corporate and Individual Farms
a) Productivity of agricultural land
000 lei/ worker (2000 prices)
Individual Efficient
Farms
More
20 15 10 5 0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
Corporate Individual
35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002
Corporate Individual
The partial productivities of land and labor estimated using national statistics decreased over time in both corporate and individual farms (see Figure). Yet, the land productivity of individual farms was significantly higher than that of corporate farms over the entire period of 1990-2003. This is similar to other transition countries. The difference in labor productivity (which is usually higher for corporate farms in other transition countries) was not statistically significant in Moldova during this period. Our calculations of total factor productivity (TFP) using national statistics show that the TFP for individual farms was higher than for corporate farms over 1990-2003. The respective means for 1990-2003 were 11.5 for individual farms and 4.4 for corporate farms. When comparing the efficiency of specific farms to the production frontier (constructed using survey data) we find that while all farms surveyed are relatively inefficient, individual farms achieve higher efficiency scores than corporate farms, implying that they utilize land and labor more efficiently than the corporate farms. The partial productivity measures for small and large farms in four recent surveys in Moldova show a mixed picture. Small farms have a higher partial productivity of land (output per hectare) and a lower partial productivity of labor (output per worker); moreover, they employ a much higher number of workers per hectare than large farms. We resolve the ambiguity in partial productivity measures by calculating TFP from survey data. This measure conclusively shows decreasing returns to scale: large farms produce less per unit of inputs in the margin than small farms. Since large farms are typically corporate farms while small farms are family farms, we tried to disentangle the farm size effect and the organizational form effect by looking at two homogeneous samples: one of corporate farms and the
other of family farms. Our analysis of corporate farms shows that the land productivity clearly increases with farm size, whereas labor productivity does not. Most importantly, TFP shows a definite increase with farm size. In a sample of family farms, the standard of living of rural families (a proxy for farm performance) increased with farm size. Family farmers reporting a 'comfortable' standard of living had 11 hectares on average, compared with less than 5 hectares for farmers with 'subsistence' standard (sufficient to buy food and necessities) and those on a 'poverty' income (not sufficient to buy food). Thus, policy measures should facilitate augmentation of the small family farms.
Conclusions
Our results thus demonstrate that family farms are more productive than corporate farms. Farm performance improves with increasing size for farms of the same organizational form, but not across different organizational forms. Higher efficiency of family farms does not necessarily imply that corporate farms should be eliminated. Market economies have achieved an equilibrium farm structure, which includes a mix of individual farms (the dominant majority) and corporate farms (a small minority) determined by resource availability, managerial capacity, and personal preferences of farmers and investors. A similar process can unfold in Moldova, but the development of corporate farms must be left to market forces, free from government intervention. At the same time the government should focus on improving the environment for small individual farms.
Dragos Cimpoies is associate professor at the State Agricultural University of Moldova, Chisinau. Zvi Lerman is professor and chair at the Department of Agricultural Economics and Management, the Hebrew University, Rehovot, Israel. The article is based on the authors' paper prepared for the 2007 IAAE 104th EAAE Seminar in Budapest. BT
14
In comparison to developed countries Soviet agriculture was noted for its low labor productivity and an accordingly high rate of employment. Modernization of agriculture during transition was bound to reduce employment in agricultural production. In Russia employment has indeed shrunk at major agricultural enterprises, mainly due to a falling demand for farm produce. Simultaneously, employment on private subsidiary plots increased. As a result, the share of those employed in agriculture dropped by just 2.5 percentage points since 1990 to 10.4% today. The official unemployment in rural areas is fairly low, but the actual rate is variously estimated at between 27 and 37%, and this does not take into account partial employment and low wages. Further modernization would release still more labor in agriculture, but at the same time would set higher requirements for the quality of manpower. Yet the quality of the rural labor force has deteriorated during the reform period. The education level of agricultural workers is lower than of those in other sectors. For example, the share of people with higher education in agriculture is three times less than in the economy as a whole. The rural population is ageing while its more productive and energetic representatives migrate to the cities. The possiFamily Income Structure
bilities of daily commuting to other labor markets are restricted by long distances and poor communications. Young people, as the potential workforce, are not overly eager to work in agriculture. Our survey of 1,385 students in several higher education institutions in Voronezh, Perm, Kostroma, Astrakhan and Ivanovo conducted in 2006 has shown that only 11% of students intended to work in rural areas, and most of them were rural dwellers who majored in agriculture. Thus a paradoxical situation exists in the rural labor market: the excess of manpower coexists with a shortage of skilled labor. This situation is a consequence of rural underdevelopment, in the first place, and a lack of opportunities for rural people to be employed in the non-agricultural sector. As experiences of other countries show, economic development will further reduce employment in agricultural production and only the growth of the nonagricultural sector will be able to cut unemployment, diversify the sources of income of the rural population and improve its living standards, which may in turn attract skilled workers to rural areas and enable rural communities to survive.
and assess the efficiency of rural labor market policies in two Russian regions: Perm Krai and Ivanovo Oblast. The study draws on a survey of about 800 rural households conducted in 2006. In each of the two regions we have chosen two pairs of rural districts with matching characteristics. In one pair of the districts the authorities implemented special measures to create alternative jobs, and in the other pair no such measures were taken. Perm Krai, more economically developed and prosperous (unemployment there is 1.5 times less and per capita monthly income is more than double that in Ivanovo Oblast) renders greater assistance to agriculture and rural development than Ivanovo Oblast. Perm Krai proclaims an alternative employment policy to be a priority, with special funding allocated for the purpose. The authorities in Ivanovo Oblast, by contrast, support agricultural production mainly at private farms and private subsidiary plots. It is important to bear in mind that the share of agriculture in the gross regional product in Ivanovo Oblast is twice that in Perm Krai (7.3% and 3.6% respectively).
100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0%
Total sample Ivanovo Oblast Perm Krai
We found that the probability of deriving income from non-agricultural self-employment increases due to: The presence of unemployed household members; Ownership of farm machines (the possibility of providing services for members of the community); The community's remoteness from the districts center; The existence of a place of interest in the area; A lower level of economic development in the district (for Ivanovo Oblast). To what extent does non-agricultural employment compete with other types of employment? In terms of workload, we found that alternative employment and working one's private subsidiary plot cannot be seen as mutually complementary because they involve comparable workloads with employment peaking in the same season. Indeed, households with both a core employment and a private plot hardly have any time left for alternative employment, except in the off season. An absolute majority of respondents (88%) prefer to earn a living as hired workers and only 12% as entrepreneurs, with the share of potential entrepreneurs among those engaged in the non-agricultural sector standing a little higher, at 17%. Among those employed in the nonagricultural sector, a larger share than in the average sample plan to change jobs or are afraid to lose their job, which indicates a lower job satisfaction. This may be due to greater social vulnerability of the non-agricultural sector workers. Considering the above, it is not surprising that in order to diversify incomes households will seek employment in a more stable sector of the economy and not in the non-agricultural sector. Selfemployment is likely to develop towards increased activity working private subsidiary plots and not expanding nonagricultural employment.
15
The reason why policy has had no pronounced effect is firstly due to the fact that support for non-agricultural activities does not as yet figure prominently in rural development programs. Far more attention is paid to the informal employment in working subsidiary plots, which does not remove the problems of rural employment and is fraught with aggravated and persistent rural poverty. Unfortunately, there is also inertia in ways of thinking among the rural population. It is thought to be reprehensible not to cultivate land if you live in a rural area. Despite the fact that investments in private subsidiary plots are often not recouped by proceeds from the sale of produce, this activity takes so much time and effort as to leave no room for engaging in alternative activities. The development of rural areas requires the development of rural infrastructure; coordinated policies in the field of education and healthcare; the financial support of small rural enterprises, including a cut of interest rates on entrepreneurial loans; information support and consultancy services to rural entrepreneurs; and educational campaigns among the rural population to change their attitude to non-agrarian activities.
Yevgenia Serova is the President, Tatyana Tikhonova and Olga Shik are researchers with the Analytical Center of Agricultural and Food Economy at the Institute of Economies in Transition (IET); and Dmitry Zvyagintsev is Senior Lecturer at the Higher School of Economics (Moscow). The full text of the paper is available at: www.iet.ru. BT
short run, the family has to reduce its consumption due to imperfect insurance; in the long run, it may fail to accumulate enough productive assets including children's education. As a result, experiencing a major health shock may well send a family into both short-term poverty and a prolonged poverty trap. Using household-level data over the period of 1986-2002 from 48 villages in
eight Chinese provinces, we assess the impact of major health shocks on farm households' long-term income, children's school attainment and the role played by village elections in attaining more equal income distribution in the village and helping households to mitigate the negative impacts of health shocks. Continued on p. 16
16
Negative
In 2002, only 20% of Chinese rural residents had some form of health insurance. The most popular insurance system still was the traditional cooperative medical system, financed by the commune budget. A 2003 survey asked households to recall health shocks i.e. illnesses requiring treatment in hospital or a total medical expenditure of over 5,000 yuan (roughly twice of the average annual percapita income) happening to their
Girls are more susceptible than boys to the damage of health shocks, and this adds to a 5.6% gender gap that exists without any shock happening. Having a seriously sick adult member forces a family to reduce its daughters' chances to attend middle school by 12.5%. We have found that birth order matters, too. On average, the third or higher order child trails the first child by 13% in his/her chances to get into middle school. Interestingly, the misfortune is reversed when health shocks happen to a family. In this case, the family reduces the first and second child's chances to
In the first 16 years after a major health shock a households income drops below its normal trajectory by over 12%
family members in the period of 19872002. The 5,000 yuan cutoff was chosen in 2002. Among the 676 reported cases of health shocks, 28.0% were inpatient treatments with a cost of more than 5,000 yuan, and 5.9% were illnesses with a cost of more than 5,000 yuan but without inpatient treatment. What are the negative impacts of health shocks? Our estimations show that a major health shock has strong and persistent negative impacts on household income. In the first 16 years after the shock, the affected household's income drops below its normal trajectory by an average of 12.3%. Therefore, health shocks lead to a prolonged poverty trap. attend middle school, but leaves the third and higher order children intact. Although China set a law for compulsory nine year education as early as 1986, the record shown in our sample has not been impressive. Among people who entered primary school in or after 1986, only 58.4% completed nine years of schooling. Therefore, while providing better school facilities and more qualified teachers is important, more attention should be paid to farm households' weak abilities to deal with unexpected risks, among which health shocks are the most important.
coefficient on average by 14.3% during 1987-2002. This is despite the rising income inequality during the same period (from 0.29 in 1987 to 0.35 in 2000 in rural China). Moreover, elections tend to increase the income shares of poorer portions of population, so the reduction of the Gini coefficient has been a result of pro-poor policies. Moreover, elections significantly increase per-capita public expenditures. Since the level of public goods provision is generally low in rural China, it is reasonable to believe that poor households would benefit more from increased public investment because the rich can rely more on their own investment to generate income. Have the elections specifically helped the villages mitigate the negative impacts of health shocks? We have found that this is the case. By our most conservative estimate, households living in villages, which have elections, are able to avoid the income reduction due to health shocks by 8.3 percentage points. In addition, villages are more likely to set up a health care plan after it has started elections.
Policy Recommendations
Since 2003, the Chinese government has begun to establish a new insurancebased rural cooperative medical scheme. By September 2006, about half of China's 2,600 counties had established the new system. Despite limited benefits provided by the system, this is a good start. The system should preferably be combined with provision of educational loans to shock-hit households to release temporary liquidity constraints. Because dropping out in primary school will most likely result in a permanent deficiency in a person's educational attainment, providing health insurance and shock-related educational loans will bring large benefits to the children and the society as a whole.
the
Village elections may help farm households to deal with health shocks and, more generally, to ensure better provision of public goods. They can also reduce income inequality. Democracy does this by enhancing the accountability of the village government; conducting pro-poor policies (e.g. income redistribution or more spending on public projects that enhance the income capability of the poor); and providing an institutionalized mechanism for villagers to take collective action, for example, a health care plan that benefits both the rich and the poor. China began to experiment with village elections in 1987, and 12 of the villages in the sample were among the first in the nation to introduce elections. By 1990, more than half of the sample villages had held at least one election. Our estimations show that the introduction of elections has indeed had the direct effect of reducing the village Gini
Yang Yao is Professor at the China Center for Economic Research, Peking University, China. The article is based on the author's working papers: "Health Shocks and Children's School Attainments in Rural China" (jointly with Ang Sun), "Health Shocks, Village Elections, and Long-term Income: Evidence from Rural China" (jointly with Li Gan and Lixin Colin Xu), and "Grassroots Democracy and Income Distribution: Evidence from Village Elections in China" (jointly with Yan Shen). The papers are available on request from the corresponding author, e-mail: [email protected]. BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
17
all urban areas is found to be broadly similar and substantially higher than the aggregate rate. It is true that the sharpest decline was observed in Moscow and St. Petersburg but the overall impact of this on the growth in the urban-rural poverty differential is negligible, since poverty among individuals in Moscow and St. Petersburg accounts for less than 5% of total poverty.
Poverty rate
2000 2004 Rural Moscow and St. Petersburg Other cities > 500,000 Cities < 500,000 39.3 18.4 24.3 28.9 20.7 2.7 5.6 7.2
ulation characteristics or shares; it is not dependent on the use of a particular poverty line; nor is it driven by the rapid expansions that have occurred in Moscow, St. Petersburg or other booming urban areas. The proportionate poverty reduction across
18
More than 15 years into transition, Albania remains predominantly rural: 54% of the population reside in rural areas and agriculture still employs approximately 50% of the workforce, providing an income source to more than 90% of the households in the more remote north-eastern part of the country. The agricultural reforms carried out in the post-communist period, and the resulting land redistribution, led to a highly fragmented sector.
plethora of problems, including low productivity and outdated technologies. The labor market for agricultural work is very thin, while formal rural credit and insurance markets remain virtually nonexistent. How can rural out-migration ameliorate some of these constraints? How has migration affected farming investment decisions? Our empirical investigation, which is based on data from the 2005 Living Standards Measurement Study survey,
Concurrently with conducting a rapid and intense land reform, Albania experienced extraordinary migration outflows
Albania's land reform was unique among transition countries for its rapidity and intensity: by the mid-1990s, 94% of farmland had been privatized, with 550 state and collective farms split into 460,000 privately owned farms, averaging only 1.1 hectares per farm. Albania has had the highest decollectivization index of all transition economies in Eastern and Central Europe, but as opposed to these other countries, redistribution was not based on restitution and benefited all rural households. aims at evaluating the impact of migration on farm's technical efficiency, resource allocation to, and income from, agricultural production of farm households.
such as chemical fertilizers and farm equipment. Despite the overall low levels of investments in farm inputs, migrant households spend comparatively even less than their non-migrant counterparts. This quite troublesome finding is indicative of a generalized divestment in agriculture as a result of migration. On the contrary, migrant households appear to invest more in livestock production. Despite the reduced labor effort, however, agriculture income does not seem to decline as a result of migration, and total income (as expected) increases significantly. The latter result may be due to the direct effect of remittances, but also to increased income from other non-farm sources. Thus, migration of one or more household members, and the remittances it generates, is being used by rural households in Albania as part of a strategy to move out of agriculture. Migration has no significant impact on a farm's technical efficiency, thus reinforcing the idea that migration is not being used to improve agricultural productivity. While from a development perspective, it may be reasonable for policymakers to put a considerable amount of faith in the mending power of remittances to revive sluggish sectors of the economy, such as agriculture, the fact that rural households are not investing migrants' resources or their time in crop production indicates that agriculture continues to give little prospects for growth and individual betterment for rural Albanians.
This paper a product of the Development Research Group is part of a broader collaboration with the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations to study the impact of migration on investments and rural development in source countries. Full text of the paper can be accessed at: http://go.worldbank.org/ WO38MQ1E00 (Policy Research Working Paper 4367). The contacting author is Gero Carletto, [email protected]. BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
New Findings
19
Electricity Sector Reforms and the Poor in Europe and Central Asia
Contrary to perceptions, the poor benefited more than the non poor from reform
Julian A. Lampietti, Sudeshna Ghosh Banerjee, and Amelia Branczik The socialist legacy in Eastern the closure of borders with Azerbaijan Europe and Central Asia, where access to and Turkey. The landlocked geographical electricity had been extended to virtually position and dependency on imported oil all consumers at nominal cost, was an and gas compounded the effects of rising electricity sector dependent on a compli- energy prices. At the same time, residencated system of fiscally unsustainable tial electricity prices remained very low. budget transfers, while simultaneously Unable to cover internal maintenance seeing dramatic deterioration of its infra- costs and crippled by weekly interrupstructure. In the worst affected countries, tions in gas supply, by 1992 electricity service was failing and electricity was utilities were on the verge of collapse. unavailable for large parts of the day. From 1992 to 1995, most of the populaThe only option open in this situation tion received only two to four hours of was immediate implementation of a electricity per day. With district heating wide-reaching reform program. As with also gone, residents of the capital all utility reforms, policy makers were Yerevan burned trees, telephone poles, faced with the mismatch between the and books to get through the winter. timing of costs and benefits associated In 1995-1996 the Armenian governwith reform, exacerbated by expecta- ment embarked on reforms, which tions rooted in communist times that the included restructuring and regulating the state would take care of utility provision. energy sector, improving payment disciThree case studies below undertaken pline, and making the electricity supply in Armenia, Georgia and Moldova ana- more reliable. Armenia soon made lyze the reform patterns, the conse- progress, and by 1999, 98% of housequences for households, and the effec- holds reported having electricity. tiveness of various mitigating strategies A tariff increase in 1999 was a pivfor the poor. otal moment in the reform. Introduction of a single uniform tariff removed subsidies and led to a sizable increase in elecRaising Prices in Armenia tricity prices. To soften the impact of the Burden for the Poor? increase, the poorest households were In the late 1980s and early 1990s, compensated with a direct cash payment. Armenia's economy suffered a cataAfter the increase, the poor constrophic earthquake, the breakup of the sumed 20-30% less of each energy type, Soviet Union, protracted conflict, and yet they devoted close to 30% of their
The Poor Spend More (Percent of Income on Electricity, 2002)
10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0%
Bu lg ar ia G eo rg ia Hu ng ar y Ka za kh st an Ky rg yz Re p. M ol do va Po la nd Ro m an ia Ru ss ia Al ba ni a A rm en ia Az er ba ija n Be la ru s Tu rk ey Se rb ia Ta jik ist an U kr ai ne
Bottom 20%
Top 20%
Notes: Conditional on households reporting positive expenditures. Figures for Bulgaria and Tajikistan are for 2003. Source: Author's calculations based on household survey data from World Bank ECA database.
The World Bank & CEFIR
monthly expenditure to energy, compared with 18% for the non-poor (and with 3%-7% in western countries). The burden of tariff increases appeared to be highest among the urban poor, with 16% of their total monthly expenditures going to electricity alone. In response to the price change poor households: Lowered consumption by an average of 20%, especially among rural households, who apparently had greater access to substitutes; Paid only a fraction of the bill, maintaining service while accumulating arrears. The percentage of such households increased from 27% to 46% between 1998 and 1999; Substituted electricity in heating and cooking, with the effort highest among the rural poor (71%). Despite reduced consumption by the poor, their average bills increased by 13%. Yet, only 55% of the poor households received cash transfers. We conclude that the initial impact of reform was underestimated, as the tariff increase was in reality 50% greater than originally conceived. This highlights the need for careful calculation and accurate price response prediction in forecasting and mitigating the impact of reform. Although the tariff increase was aimed at creating a more sustainable sector, the utility revenue increase of about 6% was less than expected, thanks to falling consumption and a simultaneous increase in arrears. This suggests that the benefits of the reform program did not materialize as quickly or easily as intended, and that tariff increases must be accompanied by moves to encourage greater payment. In years after the study was conducted, Armenia continued to reorganize the electricity sector, transforming it into one of the region's success stories. By 2004, collections had reached almost 100%. The social protection system has become better targeted, and efforts to improve it have continued further.
20
New Findings
with high theft levels, routine sabotage or destruction of meters, and protests against increasing collections proved to be major obstacles to improving cost recovery for AES Telasi. Since changes in collection rates increased uniformly across the lowest and highest 20% of households, we conclude that free-riding rather than affordability was behind the arrears. Increasing collections did not necessarily hurt the poor. In 2002, reform stalled. Dissatisfaction with higher tariffs and greater enforcement was expressed through resentment at the presence of a western player in the electricity sector. In late 2003, AES sold Telasi to Russian utility RAO UES. Georgia's experience highlights the difficulties encountered by utilities in pushing for cost recovery in a hostile environment. The main lessons include: Remetering, in conjunction with tariff increases, should be a high priority, to generate the maximum amount of revenue; An aggressive approach to reducing nonpayment, such as in Georgia, does not necessarily have a disproportionate adverse impact on low-income households, particularly if suitable subsidy and transfer mechanisms are in place; An ambitious reform agenda cannot work without a strong regulator and a high-level political commitment, which were lacking in Georgia. In later years such problems as continuing nonpayment, accumulated debts, theft, and possibly corruption remained, as evidenced in the 2005 World Bank report, and Georgia's energy sector remained financially bankrupt. increases. In 2000, the government adopted a law on energy compensation for vulnerable groups, and sold three of five regional electricity distribution companies to the Spanish utility Union Fenosa (two others remained in state hands). Although reform produced substantial improvements in supply to consumers, particularly in rural areas, reform and privatization elicited acrimonious debate on their costs and benefits. The Communist government, elected in 2001, openly announced its intention to reverse privatization in the energy sector. Did reform really affect the poor and the non-poor differently, as was charged by its opponents? Were household electricity consumption patterns different in private and public distribution networks? Our findings suggest that: On electricity consumption, the poor were catching up with the nonpoor. On average, the poor consumed 26% less electricity than the non-poor. But since 2000, they were increasing monthly electricity consumption by 14.6%, while the non-poor were increasing consumption by only 3.2%. Availability of electricity greatly improved. The poor, disproportionately affected by blackouts, benefited the most from the return to a 24-hour service. Consumption and expenditure patterns of households served by Union Fenosa and those served by the public companies were found to be roughly similar, as was the quality of service. Thus, contrary to perceptions, the poor benefited more than the non-poor from reform, having increased their consumption more than the non-poor despite rising costs. The private company had a significant positive impact on the government budget, while service quality improved, and collection rates have risen to almost 100%. Moreover, the presence of a private operator in a chronically underperforming sector may have had a significant positive spillover effect, putting pressure on the public utilities to improve their performance.
The article is based on the World Bank publication "People and Power: Electricity Sector Reforms and the Poor in Europe and Central Asia" by Julian A. Lampietti, Sudeshna Ghosh Banerjee, and Amelia Branczik. The volume brings together a series of studies conducted between 1999 and 2004. The full text of the volume is available at: www.worldbank.org/eca/publications. BT
21
Economic growth in most transition countries in Europe and Central Asia (ECA) since the late 1990s has been accompanied by significant reforms in public finances. Government spending has fallen in line with the changing role of the state, and tax revenues have picked up from low levels as tax policies have been restructured and tax administrations strengthened. Fiscal deficits have narrowed as a result of increasing revenues and controls on spending, and public debt ratios have fallen. Even with this progress in fiscal adjustment however, ECA governments are still relatively large on average (see Figure 1) compared with those in nonECA countries at similar levels of per capita income. Governments are particularly large in Central and Southeast Europe (SEE), where total public spending averages close to 45% of GDP. Generous social protection schemes, which mirror those in higher-income countries, account for most of this size difference.
nomic growth rates in ECA, but that this effect depends on the state of governance. Bigger governments can hinder growth in countries with weak governance, but this effect is nonlinear: below about one-third of GDP, the size of government is not correlated with growth, but once public spending exceeds 35% or so of GDP, increasing government size can have a negative impact on growth. Strong governance mitigates this negative effect, which is one reason that big governments do not necessarily reduce economic growth in some higher-income OECD countries. Multiple reasons explain why large governments can impede growth in countries with weak governance: Large governments are more likely to run fiscal deficits during economic downturns, particularly where public spending is inflexible because of weak budgeting systems, reliance on earmarks, and high public employment; The high rates of taxation needed to fund big governments can distort private activity, particularly if tax administrations are weak; A large government presence in particular sectors may be accompanied by anticompetitive regulations on private sector participation;
Government spending may be misallocated as a result of corruption or poor capacity, sapping productive resources from the economy. While strong and capable governments may be able to avoid many of these problems through tight budget planning and efficient tax administration, countries with weaker governance should keep public spending and taxation to more modest levels if they want to spur economic growth.
Figure 1. Total Public Sector Spending, by Country in ECA, 1995 and 2005
Percent of GDP 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Kazakhstan Kyrgyz Rep. Estonia Slovak Rep. Czech Rep. Moldova Slovenia Armenia Azerbaijan Albania Tajikistan Georgia Romania Bulgaria Ukraine Poland Turkey Bosnia Russia Latvia Lithuania Macedonia Belarus Croatia Serbia&Mont. Hungary 1995 2005
22
New Findings
But the primary emphasis still needs to be on promoting efficiency and strengthening governance, particularly in the SEE and CIS regions. There is also scope for more private sector participation, whether through divestiture or management contracts. Yet, the role of government will continue to be critical, especially in ensuring financial viability and promoting fair competition. In education, public spending is achieving reasonably good results in many ECA high-growth countries, which have above-average school enrollment and learning outcomes given their share of public education spending in GDP. Yet the countries could benefit from moving to financing on a per capita basis; integrating relatively expensive technical and vocational with general education schools; decentralizing school financing and management; and relying to a larger extent on private sources of financing for tertiary education to free up public resources for primary and secondary education. In health, the ECA countries tend to spend more than countries elsewhere for comparable outcomes, a sign of inefficiency and poor governance. The primary emphasis in ECA needs to be on
enhancing the quality and efficiency of spending, e.g. through consolidating hospitals, moving toward standard basic benefits packages, containing the growth of pharmaceutical costs; putting in place adequate mechanisms for financing and risk sharing with a reasonably modest level of copayments (not to limit access for the poor). In pensions, ECA countries have a higher level of spending than fastgrowing countries at similar income levels elsewhere. This is due to low retirement ages, broad coverage for disability, and the falling share of the population paying into public pension systems, aggravated by declining birth rates and the overall aging of the population. For middle-income countries, the best option would be to make the public contributory pension system fully self-financing and complement it with means-tested social assistance for those who are not covered. For lower-income countries, a universal or means-tested low-rate pension financed out of general revenues may be the best option.
mined potential improvements in compliance. The experience in ECA suggests that flat tax reform is less likely to have a negative impact on revenue collection if it is adopted during a period of strong economic growth and is complemented by improvements in tax administration. However, even though income tax rates have been lowered dramatically in many ECA countries, payroll taxes remain high, discouraging compliance and imposing a tax wedge of 30-50% on employment. High labor taxes have a negative effect on rates of formal employment, on the return to capital and on growth. The best way to reduce the labor tax burden and its effect on employment is to reform the social security system (most notably pensions and health care). In some countries relief from payroll taxes should be provided to those with the highest "elasticity" of labor demand, including low-skilled workers and new labor market entrants. ECA countries can also move towards replacing some social insurance benefits financed by employer and employee contributions with universal benefits financed out of general taxation, as some Western European countries have done.
Figure 2. Changes in Personal (PIT) and Corporate Income Tax (CIT) Revenue Collection after Flat Tax Reform
a. PIT Revenue Collections 8 7 6 As % GDP 5 4 3 2 1 0 Lithuania Russia Slovak Rep. Ukraine
Conclusions
World-wide experience offers some lessons that ECA countries can use as they try to formulate public finance policies that will promote economic growth while meeting the need for fundamental public goods: Macroeconomic stability is essential, because large budget deficits retard growth; Moderate levels of public spending about one-third of GDP or less are preferable when governance and public administration are not strong; Lower income and payroll tax rates can spur investment and employment.
Cheryl Gray is Sector Director, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Department, ECA Region; Aristomene Varoudakis is Country Director for Armenia, and Tracey Lane is Senior Economist, at the World Bank, Washington, DC. Full text of the report "Fiscal Policy and economic Growth: Lessons for Eastern Europe and Central Asia" can be viewed at www.worldbank.org/ eca/fiscal. BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
23
For the last 20 years, the privatization of state enterprises has been a central element of economic reform. By most accounts, the beneficial effects of privatization have outweighed the costs in most settings. Yet privatization seems to be unpopular with the mass public in many reforming countries. We analyze the attitudes towards privatization, relying on a dataset from the 2006 survey by the World Bank and EBRD entitled "Life in Transition", which covers 28,000 individuals in 28 transition countries. We find strong support for revision of privatization in all post-communist countries, with more than one half of the population in each country supporting some form of revision, from levying additional taxes on current owners of privatized assets to their full expropriation. Re-nationalization and keeping companies in state hands is strongly preferred in Central Asia and the South Caucasus (see Table). The highest support for re-nationalization followed by re-privatization using a more transparent process is observed in the South Caucasus and in Croatia. In contrast, respondents in Albania, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Hungary, and Romania have a strong preference for leaving property with current owners, provided that they pay what the privatized assets are worth. Leaving most privatized companies in the hands of current owners
their personal holdings may be adversely affected by such a change in policy. We also find that institutions do affect the link between transition-related histories and support for the revision of privatization. In particular, in countries with better governance, stronger democracy, and more extensive private ownership respondents moving from work for wages to self-employment are significantly more likely to oppose revising privatization than their counterparts in countries with weaker institutions. Inequality does not directly affect the link between individual transition histories and attitudes towards revising privatization, but it does decrease the differences in the belief of the superiority of state over private property between those with relatively successful and unsuccessful transition histories. Finally, in countries where privatization has been extensive, those who moved from wage work to self-employment during transition are more likely to oppose revising privatization.
Policy Implications
Understanding who supports the revision of privatization and the reasons for this support has different implications for policy. If public support is rooted in relative losses from declining returns to human capital, then retraining programs may prove to be an effective tool. However, if public support for the revision of privatization is driven by concerns of fairness, governments may have to turn to redistributive policies. An optimistic lesson from our results is that most of the support for the revision of privatization due to unfairness comes from negative personal experiences during the transition, which are likely to play a smaller role in shaping attitudes over time.
Irina Denisova is a Lead Economist, and Markus Eller is an economist at CEFIR; Timothy Frye is Professor at Columbia University and member of the Harriman Institute at Columbia University, US; Ekaterina Zhuravskaya is Academic Director at CEFIR and a professor at NES. Full text of the paper is available at www.cefir.ru (WP 105). BT
24
New Findings
High oil prices have rekindled interest in the negative effect of resource abundance on economic growth. Known as the "resource curse", it has recently been linked to the deterioration of economic and political institutions. In particular, economists have hypothesized that if resources are discovered in an economy with immature institutions, the resulting rent-seeking slows down or even reverses institutional development, which in turn, negatively affects growth. In contrast, countries with mature institutions (such as Norway or Australia) may benefit from their resource wealth and channel newly discovered resources to the development of other sectors. Testing this hypothesis empirically is not easy. As most institutions change slowly, one has to rely on cross-sectional evidence which is vulnerable to reverse causality and omitted variable bias. In order to understand the mechanisms of the resource curse we need to use microeconomic data. In our recent research we have studied the effect of resource abundance on growth through its effect on corporate transparency and property rights, using data on 72 industries in 51 countries over the period 1990-2005. We argue that during periods of high commodity prices, corporate profits in the natural resource industries represent rents that are relatively easy for governments to capture. Firms in such industries face a trade-off. On the one hand, to attract external capital, they desire transparency. On the other hand, higher transparency involves a risk of expropriation by the government or rival companies. Various forms of government expropriation include the extortion of bribes, overregulation, disregard for property rights, confiscatory taxation, and the outright seizure of firm assets. Transparency would therefore be lower in industries that are more vulnerable to expropriation, particularly in countries that have poor protection of property rights.
Timeless Regrettably
Relevance
The argument is not new. In the "Wealth of Nations", Adam Smith wrote: "In those unfortunate countries, indeed, where men are continually afraid of the violence of their superiors, they frequently bury and conceal a great part of their [capital] stock". The quintessential example is the story of Yukos, once Russia's largest and most transparent oil company, and its founder Mikhail Khodorkovsky. Khodorkovsky and his partners acquired a stake in a notorious loans-for-shares auction and then diluted the stakes of other shareholders, including foreign investors and the government. Once they assumed control over the majority of voting and cash flow rights, the firm's transparency and corporate governance improved substantially. Khodorkovsky was the first of the Russian oligarchs to disclose his personal stake in a major company and to invite reputable foreigners to join the corporate board. This raised Yukos market capitalization fifteen-fold in less than four years but also eventually resulted in the full expropriation of the company by the government and imprisonment and exile of the key owners and managers. While the official charges against Khodorkovsky were related to tax fraud, there is a widespread belief that the government's assault was driven by a combination of Khodorkovsky's political ambitions and the firm's openness about its high value. The Yukos affair was certainly not an isolated case and its relevance goes well beyond Russia, extending to Expropiacion Petrolera in Mexico in 1935 and recent nationalizations in Venezuela, Bolivia, and Ecuador.
ulation and withholding of information, and the predation index, which encompasses information on countries' rule of law, risk of government expropriation, corruption, quality of bureaucracy, regulation of competition, etc. We find that: Companies around the world respond to government predation with lower corporate transparency. This is especially true for oil and gas industries, and more so when the price of oil is high and property rights are poorly protected; Opacity increases when a government is more autocratic or when it favors redistributive policies, i.e. has a left-leaning political orientation. The opacity also increases during election years reflecting the increased uncertainty about future government policies; Lower transparency in oil pricesensitive industries results in less efficient capital allocation and eventually lower corporate growth. The difference in corporate growth between an expropriation-sensitive industry (e.g. oil and gas) and an industry with little expropriation risk (e.g. agriculture) is not trivial in a predatory country. For example, in Venezuela the oil and gas industry would grow slower by 1.8% compared to agriculture. This can be compared to Norway the country with high-quality institutions, where the differential growth rate between oil and gas extraction and agriculture would only reach 0.1%. Thus, it turns out that the resource curse is indeed a corporeal phenomenon. It affects in a very tangible way corporate transparency in actual firms. This results in material consequences for capital allocation and the growth of these firms.
Art Durnev is Assistant Professor of Finance at McGill University, Canada. Sergei Guriev is Associate Professor of Economics and Rector of New Economic School, Moscow. Full text of the paper is available at: http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstr act_id=1020476. BT
Beyond Transition July September 2007
Agenda
25
The World Bank Outlines Cooperation with Croatia Scales Up Use of Environmentally Serbia Friendly Agricultural Practices
The World Bank Board of Executive Directors discussed a Country Partnership Strategy for Serbia for the period until 2011 on December 13, 2007. Executive Directors welcomed Serbia's recent initialing of a Stabilization and Association Agreement with the European Union, and acknowledged Serbia's significant development since the country's succession to World Bank Group membership in 2001. Over the last six years, average incomes have almost doubled and poverty has declined by more than one third. These gains have been underpinned by major structural economic reform, although Serbia still faces considerable issues to complete its economic transition. It was noted that regional stability would be especially important at this time to ensure that Serbia and the region can build on economic gains and move as quickly as possible towards European accession. On December 6, 2007 the World Bank approved a US$5 million Global Environment Facility Grant for the Agricultural Pollution Control Project for Croatia. The Project will assist the government in increasing the use of environmentally friendly agricultural practices by farmers in Croatia's Pannonian plain in order to reduce nutrient discharge from agricultural sources to surface and ground waters. The project will also help Croatia on its path towards EU accession, as project activities will help the country comply with European Union Nitrates Directives while assisting the government in establishing a competitive agricultural sector. The Agricultural Pollution Control Project will be implemented as a pilot activity in three selected counties: Osijecko-Baranjska, Vukovarsko-Srijemska and Varazdinska. These counties have been selected because of the high density of livestock, concentration of medium scale livestock farms as well as war related damages to manure storage and water monitoring infrastructure in some areas.
World Bank Approves Support for Kosovo in Education and Financial Sector
On December 13, 2007, the World Bank's Board of Executive Directors approved US$12 million support for Kosovo through two new education and finance sector projects, which will support the Bank's ongoing support strategy for Kosovo. The strategy was prepared in partnership with the Provisional Institutions of Self Government and the United Nations Interim Administration Mission in Kosovo. The strategy will be financed by an IDA grant allocation of US$12 million for both projects. The Institutional Development for Education Project, financed by a US$10 million IDA grant, will support the government in its implementation of the strategies for the Development of Pre-University and Higher Education in Kosovo. The Financial Sector Technical Assistance Project, financed by a US$2 million IDA grant, will contribute towards greater financial sector stability and development by supporting stronger prudential regulation and supervision by the Central Banking Authority of Kosovo (CBAK) for bank and non-bank financial institutions; the institutional strengthening of CBAK; and the strengthening of the banking and microfinance industry through capacity building.
Belarus: World Bank Announces New Country Assistance Strategy and Additional Support to Social Infrastructure Retrofitting
The World Bank's Board of Executive Directors discussed the new Country Assistance Strategy for Belarus for the period 2008-2011 on December 4, 2007. The new Strategy supporting the country's development agenda was prepared in consultations with the government of Belarus and representatives of civil society organizations, the private sector, and international organizations. The World Bank expects to provide about US$100 million a year in long-term loans to support Belarus in addressing global environment and energy challenges, enhancing the competitiveness of its economy to assure rising incomes, and protecting the welfare of the most vulnerable over the next four years. In the past, the World Bank loan funds have been used to retrofit 600 schools, kindergartens, community homes for the
26
Agenda
for the Integrated Nutrient Pollution Control project on October 30, 2007. Total project costs have been estimated at US$81.6 million. The project supports Romania's commitments to meet EU environment standards through an integrated program demonstrating links with other environmental investments, especially sanitation and waste management, and will help reduce nutrient discharges to water bodies; (ii) promote behavioral change at community level; and (iii) strengthen institutional and regulatory capacity.
elderly, hospitals, and outpatient clinics in Minsk as well as other regions in Belarus. Accordung to estimates, retrofitting of each facility leads to 20-25% reduction in energy consumption it is sufficient for heating an additional small block of twelve 70-apartment buildings or 10-15 schools for a year.
This part has been provided courtesy of Merrell Tuck and Dorota Kowalska, Europe and Central Asia External Affairs
Integrating Environment into Key Economic Sectors: A Prerequisite for Sustainable Development
The transition to a market economy presents both a challenge and an opportunity to put in place policies and incentives that would minimize the environmental impact of increased development while ensuring the sustainable management of natural resources and the environment. Integrating environment in key sectors energy, agriculture, forestry, extractive industries and transportation is central to the long-term sustainability of economic development in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. These are the main messages coming out of two World Bank reports Integrating Environment in Key Economic Sectors in Europe and Central Asia, and Integrating Environment into Agriculture and Forestry: Progress and Prospects in Eastern Europe and Central Asia prepared as part of its contribution to the Environment for Europe conference, held in Belgrade, October 10-12, 2007. To access the two World Bank reports, please visit: http://www.worldbank.org/eca/environmentintegration.
Customs
The World Bank's Board of Executive Directors approved a US$18.5 million loan for the Kazakhstan Customs Development Project. The project, approved November 27, 2007 will help reform and modernize customs administration in Kazakhstan by increasing revenue collection, and improving transparency of customs operations promoting the use of internationally accepted practices.
World Bank Opens New Centre for Financial Reporting Reform in Vienna
The World Bank opened the Vienna Centre for Financial Reporting Reform November 30, 2007 in an effort to bring its services closer to European clients and better target the emerging needs of middle income countries in the region. The new office will aid countries in Europe and Central Asia in meeting the financial reporting standards necessary for EU accession, provide advice and analysis on targeted accounting policy reforms, build capacity with civil servants from governments in the region, and provide support for the Bank's other operations in the region. The Centres activities are both fee-for-service based and funded by donors. It is currently supported by the European Commission, SECO, Austrian Development Agency and Austrian Government, USAID, and the Foreign Ministries of the Netherlands, Japan and Norway.
World Bank and Global Environment Facility Support Integrated Nutrient Pollution Control Project in Romania
The World Bank's Board of Executive Directors approved a new IBRD loan (50 million Euro) and a Global Environmental Facility Grant (US$5.5 million) to Romania
27
more systematically; and more clearly demonstrate best practice to deliver impact beyond the Bank's limited direct role. To download the report or order hardcopies, please visit: http://www.worldbank.org/ieg/mic
28
ferent. Only one product refined petroleum appears in the top 25 products for both countries, and services exports are roughly twice as important for India as for China, which is much better integrated into global production networks. Even assuming India also begins to integrate into global production chains and expands exports of manufactures, there seems to be an opportunity for rapid growth in both countries. Accelerated growth through efficiency improvements in China and India, especially in their high-tech industries, will intensify competition in global markets leading to a contraction of the manufacturing sectors in many countries. Improvement in the range and quality of exports from China and India has the potential to create substantial welfare benefits for the world, and for China and India, and to act as a powerful offset to the termsof-trade losses otherwise associated with rapid export growth. However, without efforts to keep up with China and India, some countries may see further erosion of their export shares and high-tech manufacturing sectors. Neeltje Van Horen Customer Market Power and the Provision of Trade Credit: Evidence from Eastern Europe and Central Asia WPS4284, July 2007 Statistics show that the sale of goods on credit is widespread among firms even when they are capital constrained and thus face relatively high costs in providing trade credit. This study provides an explanation for this by arguing that customers who possess strong market power are able to increase their customer surplus by demanding to purchase the goods on credit. This gain in customer surplus increases with the degree of asymmetric information between buyer and seller with respect to product quality. Therefore, firms that are perceived as risky are especially subject to the market power of the customer and have to sell their goods on credit. Using detailed firm-level data from a large number of firms in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, the study finds a strong positive correlation between customer market power and trade credit provision. Furthermore, this relationship is especially strong in countries with limited financial sector development or a weak legal system.
Other Publications
Christopher Gerry and Carmen Li Consumption Smoothing and Vulnerability in Russia July 2007, the William Davidson Institute WP No. 885 http://www.wdi.umich.edu/Publications/WorkingPapers/ The authors examine the channels through which individuals experience and seek to cope with changes in consumption. They find that married individuals living in small households, with educated heads in urban areas are better equipped to smooth consumption. Furthermore, the labor market is an important transmission mechanism allowing households to smooth their consumption but also exposing them to risk, mainly through job loss. Outside of pension payments the formal social safety net does not facilitate consumption smoothBeyond Transition July September 2007
ing, thus heightening the importance of informal coping institutions. It transpires that both support from relatives/friends and home production act as important insurance mechanisms for the most vulnerable. Simeon Djankov, Yingyi Qian, Gerard Roland, Ekaterina Zhuravskaya What Makes a Successful Entrepreneur? Evidence from Brazil CEFIR/NES WP 104, July 2007, www.cefir.org The authors report the results of a new survey on entrepreneurship in Brazil. In September 2006, they interviewed 400 entrepreneurs and 550 non-entrepreneurs in 7 Brazilian cities, who were matched with regard to age, gender, education and location. The authors test three competing hypotheses on entrepreneurship: the role of economic and legal institutions (security of property rights; access to credit); the role of sociological characteristics (family background, social networks); and the role of individual features (attitude towards risk, I.Q., self-confidence) in becoming an entrepreneur. In line with the previous research in China and Russia, they find that sociological characteristics have the strongest influence on becoming an entrepreneur. In contrast, success as an entrepreneur is primarily determined by the individual's smartness and higher education in the family. Entrepreneurs are not more self-confident than non-entrepreneurs; and overconfidence is bad for business success. Robert Poppe The Matching Approach on Expenditure Patterns of Migrant Households: Evidence from Moldova Kiel Advanced Studies Working Paper No. 444, July 2007 http://www.ifw-kiel.de/asp/aspwp/2007/aspwp444.pdf Today workers' remittances are recognized as an important and stable source of development finance. The paper examines the effect of temporary and permanent migration on household expenditures and on asset/durables ownership. Using household survey data from Moldova, the paper compares expenditure patterns of non-migrant and migrant households, distinguishing between temporary migrant and permanent migrant households. The remittance behavior of temporary and permanent migrants is likely to be different, with permanent migrants remitting less as community and family ties become weaker. The paper finds that temporary migrant households have additional expenditures for food compared to non-migrant households. Further, non-migrant and temporary migrant households have higher expenditures for the repayment of loans than permanent migrant households. Concerning the ownership of goods or assets in 2006 compared to the regional crisis in 1998, temporary migrant households are more likely to own more assets or goods than non-migrant households. Jan Hoem, Aiva Jasilioniene, Dora Kostova, Cornelia Muresan The Second Demographic Transition in Selected Countries in Central and Eastern Europe: Union Formation as a Demographic Manifestation Max Planck Institute for Demographic Research WP 2007026, August 2007 www.demogr.mpg.de/papers/working/wp-2007-026.pdf
The World Bank & CEFIR
29
Using data from the first round of the national Gender and Generations Surveys in Russia, Romania, and Bulgaria, and from a similar survey for Hungary, the authors study the growth of nonmarital cohabitation as a competitor to conventional marriage in the first union formed. The issue is considered within the framework of the so-called Second Demographic Transition theory of value change in the direction of increasing tolerance in family matters and of women's autonomy. Among the findings is a strong drop in most marriage-formation risks from 1980 to 2001-2005 (depending on the sample) in all four countries and an increase in risks of entry into nonmarital unions in Russia, Romania, and Hungary, but surprisingly not in Bulgaria. It is also evident that this demographic change did not start simultaneously in all countries, and above all it began well before the fall of communism. William Pyle Organized Business, Political Regimes and Property Rights across the Russian Federation BOFIT Discussion Paper No. 18, August 2007 http://www.bof.fi/bofit The paper explores the inter-relationship of collective action within the business community, the nature of the political regime and the security of firms' property rights. Drawing on a pair of surveys recently administered in Russia, the author presents evidence that post-communist business associations have begun to coordinate business influence over state actors in a manner that is sensitive to regional politics. A firm's ability to defend itself from government predation and to shape its institutional environment as well as its propensity to invest in physical capital is strongly related to both its membership in a business association and the level of democratization in its region. Of particular note, the positive effect of association membership on securing property rights increases in less democratic regions. The evidence, that is, suggests that collective action in the business community substitutes for democratic pressure in constraining public officials. Balazs Egert and Dubravko Mihaljek Determinants of House Prices in Central and Eastern Europe The Bank of International Settlements Working Paper No. 236, September 2007 http://www.bis.org/publ/work236.pdf The paper studies the determinants of house prices in eight transition economies of Central and Eastern Europe and 19 OECD countries. Although house prices in the CEE countries remain on average far below western European levels, they have been catching up rapidly, with sustained real annual increases into double-digits not uncommon. The main question addressed is whether the conventional fundamental determinants of house prices, such as GDP per capita, real interest rates, housing credit and demographic factors, have driven observed house prices in CEE. The authors show that house prices in CEE are indeed determined to a large extent by these fundamentals, as well as some transition-specific factors, in particular institutional development of housing markets and housing finance. Countries that have implemented greater and faster improvements in housing market and housing finance institutions have also experienced BT faster growth of house prices.
30
Conference Diary
Outcomes:
Transatlantic
January 11-12, 2008, Paris, France The conference is organized by the EDHEC business school and the University of Le Mans, France. The aim of the conference is to show the role played by institutions and the consequences of macroeconomic shocks in explaining labor market differences between European countries and the US. It is particularly concerned with modeling and assessing the main mechanisms at work behind these heterogeneous labor market outcomes. Key note speakers include O. Blanchard, MIT, E. Prescott, Nobel Laureate 2004, Arizona State University, and J.O. Hairault, University of Paris I. More information: http://professoral.edhec.com/87294683/ 0/fiche___pagelibre/#contact
Bibliography
"Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Transition Economies" by K. Anderson and J. Swinnen Anderson, K., 1995. "Lobbying Incentives and the Pattern of Protection in Rich and Poor Countries", Economic Development and Cultural Change 43(2): 401-23. Anderson, K. and Y. Hayami (eds.), 1986. "The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection: East Asia in International Perspective", London: Allen and Unwin. De Gorter, H. and J. Swinnen, 2002. "Political Economy of Agricultural Policies", Ch. 36 in B. Gardner and G. Rausser (eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science/North Holland. OECD (various years), "Agricultural Policies, Markets and Trade in the Central and Eastern European Countries and the New Independent States: Monitoring and Outlook", Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development. Swinnen, J., 2002. "Transition and Integration in Europe: Implications for Agricultural and Food Markets, Policy and Trade Agreements", The World Economy 25(4): 481-501. Swinnen, J. and S. Rozelle, 2006. "From Marx and Mao to the Market: The Economics and Politics of Agricultural Transition", New York: Oxford University Press. "Where to Sell? Market Facilities and Agricultural Marketing in India" by F. Shilpi and D. Umali-Deininger Acharya, S.S., 2004. "Agricultural Marketing in India, Part of the Millennium Study of Indian Farmers", Report # 17, Academic Foundation Publishers, New Delhi. Fafchamps M. and R. Hill, 2005. "Selling at the Farmgate or Traveling to Market," American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol 87(3), p.717-734. World Bank, 2007. "India: Taking Agriculture to Market, Sustainable Development Unit", World Bank, Washington DC. forthcoming. "The Economics of Farm Organization in Transition Countries" by P. Ciaian, J. Pokrivcak, D. Drabik Allen, D.W., Lueck, D., 2002. "The nature of the Farm, Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture", Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Ciaian, P., Pokrivcak, P., 2007. "AgricultureReforms and Development in East-Central Europe", in: Sergi, B. S., Bagatelas, W. T. and Kubicova, J. (eds.), Industries and Markets in Central and Eastern Europe, Aldershot; Burlington: Ashgate, 2007. Ciaian, P., Swinnen, J.F.M., 2006, "Land Market Imperfections and Agricultural Policy Impacts in the New EU Member States: A Partial Equilibrium Analysis", American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 88(4), pp. 799-815. Schmitt, G., 1991. "Why is the Agriculture of Advanced Western Countries still Organised by Family Farms? Will this continue to be so in the Future?" European Review of Agricultural Economics 18:443458. "Land Policy and Farm Efficiency: The Lessons of Moldova" by D. Cimpoies, Z. Lerman Lerman, Z., Cimpoies, D., 2006. "Land Consolidation as a Factor for Rural Development in Moldova," Europe-Asia Studies, Vol. 58, No. 3, pp. 439-455. Lerman, Z., Csaki, C., Moroz, V., 1998. "Land Reform and Farm Restructuring in Moldova: Progress and Prospects", World Bank Discussion Paper 398, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lerman, Z., Csaki, C., Feder, G., 2004. "Agriculture in Transition: Land Policies and Evolving Farm Structures in Post-Soviet Countries", Lexington Books, Lanham, MD.
The World Bank & CEFIR
31
World Bank, 2005, "Moldova Agricultural Policy Notes: Agricultural Land", Draft analytical report, World Bank, Washington, DC (unpublished). "Alternative Non-Agricultrual Employment in the Rural Areas in Russia" by Ye. Serova, D. Zvyagintsev, T. Tikhonova, and O. Shick Bogdanovsky, V., 2005. "Labor and employment in agriculture", Voprosy Ekonomiki, No.6, pp. 72-83 (in Russian). Gimpelson, V., 2004. "Employment in the informal sector in Russia: a threat or a boon?", Almanac by Association of Russian Economic Think-Tanks, Issue 2, "Present-day problems of social policy in Russia", Moscow, www.arett.ru (in Russian). Kapelyushnikov, R.I., 2005. "Household employment", Working Paper WP3/2005/01/WP3 collection/Problemy rynka truda (Labor market issues). Moscow: Higher School of Economics (in Russian). Buchenrieder, G., 2003. "Overview of Poverty Impacts of and Policy Options for Non-Farm rural Employment", in "Proceedings of the Mini-Symposium". 25th International Conference of Agricultural Economists, Durban, South Africa. University of Hohenheim, Stuttgart, August 16-22, 2003, pp. 1-23. Greif, F., 1997. "Off-farm income sources and uses in transition economies", Rome, I: Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO). Mollers (nee Knupfer), J. and G.Buchenrieder, 2003. "Basic model of welfare gains through demand-pull and distress-push labour movements", Stuttrart, D: University of Hohenheim, Department of Agricultural Development Theory and Policy in Tropics and Subtropics (490a), mimeo. "Ruralization" of Poverty in Russia" by Ch. Gerry, E. Nivorozhkin, and J. Rigg Ravallion M., Chen S., and Sangraula P. (2007) New Evidence on the Urbanization of Global Poverty, Development Research Group, World Bank, March 2007 "Electricity Sector Reforms and the Poor in Europe and Central Asia" by J. Lampietti, S. Ghosh Banerjee, and A.Branczik Freund, C. L., and C. I. Wallich. 1995. "Raising household energy prices in Poland: Who gains? Who loses?" Policy Research Working Paper 1495, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kennedy, D. 1996. "Competition in the Power Sector of Transition Economies." Working Paper 41, European Bank of Reconstruction and Development, London Krishnaswamy, V., and G. Stuggins. 2003. "Private Participation in the Power Sector in Europe and Central Asia, Lessons from the Last Decade." WB Working Paper No. 8, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lampietti, J. A., ed. 2004. "Power's Promise: Electricity Reforms in Eastern Europe and Central Asia". Working Paper No. 40, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lampietti, J. A., and A. Meyer. 2002. "Coping with the cold: Heating strategies for ECA's urban poor." Technical Paper No. 529, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lampietti, J. A., A. A. Kolb, S. Gulyani, and V. Avenesyan. 2001. "Utility pricing and the poor: Lessons from Armenia." Technical Paper No. 497, World Bank, Washington, DC. Lampietti, J. A., H. Gonzalez, E. Hamilton, and M. Wilson. 2003. "Revisiting reform: Lessons from Georgia." Mimeo, ECSSD, World Bank, Washington, DC. Saavalainen, T. O., and J. ten Berge. 2003. "Energy Condition-ality in Poor CIS Countries." Mimeo, IMF, Washington, DC. Sargsyan, Gevorg, Ani Balabanyan, and Denzel Hankinson. 2005. "Unexpected Light: Armenia's Experience with Power Sector Reform." World Bank, Washington, DC. World Bank. 2004. "Moldova Sharing Power: Lessons Learned from the Reform and Privatization of Moldova's Electricity Sector." December 10, Washington, DC.
32
Order Form
The Beyond Transition Newsletter is FREE of charge. Please fill in the order form below if you would like to receive a complementary subscription to the English version. Please indicate if you would like to receive an electronic version (a .pdf file) or a printed copy. Please print out this form and fax or mail to: Centre for Economic and Financial Research Nakhimovsky prospekt 47, office 720 117418 Moscow, Russia Fax +7 (495) 105 5003 e-mail: [email protected] Name and Title: Address: City: State: Postal Code: Country: Telephone: E-mail: Editor in Chief: Olga Mosina (CEFIR at NES, Moscow) E-mail: [email protected] Co-ordinating Editor: Andrew Austin (CERGE-EI, Prague) Production Manager: Julia Babich (CEFIR at NES, Moscow) Layout: Ekaterina Yakovleva The World Bank 1818 H Street, N. W. Mail Stop: MC3-302 Washington D.C. 20433, USA http://www.worldbank.org CEFIR at NES Centre for Economic and Financial Research at New Economic School Nakhimovsky prospekt, 47, office 720 117418 Moscow, Russia Tel. +7 495-105 5002 http://www.cefir.ru CERGE-EI P.O. Box 882, Politickych veznu 7 111 21 Praha 1, Czech Republic http://www.cerge-ei.cz
Beyond Transition
Managing Editor: Ksenia Yudaeva (Center of Strategic Research, Moscow) Editorial Board: Alan Gelb, Director, Development Policy (The World Bank, Washington, DC) Pradeep Mitra, Chief Economist Europe & Central Asia Region (The World Bank, Washington, DC) Boris Pleskovic, Research Manager, Development Economics (The World Bank, Washington, DC) Erik Berglof (EBRD, London)