Fiscal Federallism
Fiscal Federallism
Fiscal Federallism
Introduction:
Principles of Fiscal Federalism
a n wa r s h a h
A large and growing number of countries are re-examining the roles of var-
ious orders of government and their partnerships with the private sector
and civil society in order to improve their ability to serve their people more
effectively and efficiently. This rethinking has led to a resurgence of inter-
est in the principles and practices of fiscal federalism. Federal systems are
seen to provide safeguards against the threat of centralized exploitation as
well as decentralized opportunistic behaviour while bringing decision mak-
ers closer to the people. The principles of fiscal federalism are concerned
with the design of fiscal constitutions – that is, how taxing, spending, and
regulatory functions are allocated among governments and how intergov-
ernmental transfers are structured. These arrangements are of fundamen-
tal importance to the efficient and equitable provision of public services.
This chapter begins by reviewing basic concepts in federalism. This is
followed by a discussion of the conceptual underpinnings of federal fiscal
constitutions. The principles of fiscal federalism outlined in this chapter are
primarily based on economic premises; hence, they are limited in their ap-
plication to economic criteria. Some nations may well consider political, so-
ciological, and historical criteria of greater relevance in their circumstances.
A discussion of the conceptual basis of expenditure assignment is
followed by a review of the theory of tax assignment. Tax-base and reve-
nue-sharing concepts and transfer mechanisms are then introduced
briefly. A concluding section brings together the main themes of the
fiscal federalism literature.
4 Anwar Shah
Unitary Government
Federal Government
6 Anwar Shah
Confederal Government
Home Rule
8 Anwar Shah
and (2) people should have the right to vote for the kind and amount
of public services they want.
These principles suggest that decision making should occur at the order
of government closest to the people consistent with the goals of alloca-
tional efficiency. Thus the optimal size of a jurisdiction would vary with
specific instances of economies of scale and benefit-cost spill-outs.
Fiscal Equivalency
A related idea on the design of jurisdictions has emerged from the public
choice literature. Mancur Olson argues that, if a political jurisdiction and
benefit area overlap, the free-rider problem is overcome and the marginal
benefit equals the marginal cost of production, thereby ensuring the opti-
mal provision of public services.11 Equating the political jurisdiction with
the benefit area is called the “principle of fiscal equivalency” and requires
a separate jurisdiction for each public service. Wallace Oates proposes a re-
lated idea, the so-called “correspondence principle.”12 According to this
principle, the jurisdiction determining the order of provision of each pub-
lic good should include precisely the set of individuals that consume it.
This generally requires a large number of overlapping jurisdictions.
a l l o c at i o n o f r e s p o n s i b i l i t i e s
Efficient Provision of Public Services Public services are provided most effi-
ciently “by the jurisdiction having control over the minimum geographic
area that would internalize benefits and costs of such provision,” because:15
10 Anwar Shah
• Spatial externalities. Spatial externalities arise when the benefits and costs
of public services are realized by non-residents. In the case of benefit
spill-outs, the jurisdiction providing the service does not consider the
proportion of benefits of a public service accruing to non-residents and
therefore underprovides such a service. The reverse result is obtained in
the case of cost spill-outs, where the public service could not be financed
by exporting taxes to other jurisdictions. There are also public services
whose benefits are considered national in scope, such as defence and
foreign affairs. As a corollary, these services would be best provided by
the federal government.
• Economies of scale. Certain services require areas larger than a local ju-
risdiction for cost-effective provision, for example, public transportation
and sewerage in metropolitan areas.
• Administrative and compliance costs. Centralized administration generally
leads to lower administrative costs associated with financing public services.
The Redistributive Role of the Public Sector It is commonly argued that effec-
tive redistribution is possible only through national programs (i.e., progres-
sive income taxes and transfers to persons), suggesting that local jurisdictions
attempting to carry out redistributive policies are likely to drive out the rich.
22728_MR.book Page 11 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
While such arguments have merit, they leave a number of questions un-
answered. National governments often prefer to strengthen their own
power bases rather than to benefit citizens at large. In such situations, the
national government may not redistribute from the rich to the poor in a
symmetric fashion in the nation as a whole. Furthermore, views on stan-
dards for equity and methods to achieve such standards are likely to vary
across a nation, making subnational government involvement critical to
determining policies appropriate for each area. While the centre may as-
sume a dominant role in pursuit of vertical equity, the involvement of sub-
national governments in implementing specific programs can be tailored
to meet the circumstances of individual jurisdictions.17
12 Anwar Shah
the national government not to backstop state and local debt and not to al-
low ownership of the banks by any order of government. Transparency of
the budgetary process and institutions, accountability to the electorate,
and general availability of comparative data encourage fiscal discipline.
Fiscal federalism poses significant challenges for macroeconomic man-
agement. These challenges require careful design of monetary and fiscal
institutions to overcome the adverse incentives associated with “common
property” resource-management problems or with rent-seeking behav-
iours. The experiences of federal countries indicate significant learning
and adaptation of fiscal systems to create incentives compatible with fair
play and to overcome incomplete contracts. This explains why decentral-
ized fiscal systems appear to do better than centralized fiscal systems on
most aspects of monetary and fiscal policy management and transparent
and accountable governance.19
14 Anwar Shah
Table 1
Representative assignment of expenditure responsibilities
Table 1
Representative assignment of expenditure responsibilities (Continued)
Sources: Anwar Shah, The Reform of Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in Developing and Emerging Market Economies
(Washington, dc: World Bank, 1994); Anwar Shah, “Fiscal Decentralization in Transition Economies and
Developing Countries,” in Federalism in a Changing World: Learning from Each Other, ed. R. Blindenbacher
and A. Koller, 432–60 (Montreal and Kingston: McGill-Queen’s University Press, 2003).
Note: U = supranational responsibility, icb = independent central bank, N = national government, S = state
or provincial government, L = local government, and P = nongovernmental sectors or civil society.
16 Anwar Shah
with regard to the provision of local public services. That is why there is
an insignificant role for local governments in Australia but an expansive
role in Brazil and Switzerland.
The fiscal federalism literature, however, does provide a normative
framework for assigning responsibilities to local governments. The assign-
ment of public services to local governments or to metropolitan or re-
gional governments can be based on considerations such as economies of
scale, economies of scope (appropriate bundling of local public services to
improve efficiency through information and coordination economies, and
enhanced accountability through voter participation and cost recovery),
cost-benefit spillovers, proximity to beneficiaries, consumer preferences,
and budgetary choices about the composition of spending. The particular
order of government to which a service is assigned determines the public
or private production of the service in accordance with considerations of
efficiency and equity.
Large metropolitan areas with populations in excess of one million
could be considered for subdivision into a first tier of municipal govern-
ment of smaller size responsible for neighbourhood-type services and a
second tier of metropolitan-wide government responsible for area-wide
services. The first-tier governments could be directly elected, and elected
mayors of these governments could form the metropolitan council at the
second tier. Two-tier structures for metropolitan governance have been
practised in Melbourne, Australia; Vancouver, Canada; Allegheny County,
Pennsylvania, United States; and Stockholm, Sweden.
In mature federations, special-purpose agencies or bodies deliver a wide
range of metropolitan and regional public services, including education,
health, planning, recreation, and environmental protection. Such bodies
can include education and library boards; transit and police commissions;
and utilities providing water, gas, and electricity. These agencies deal with
public services whose delivery areas transcend political jurisdictions and
that are better financed by loans, user charges, and earmarked benefit
taxes, such as a supplementary mill rate on a property tax base to finance a
local school board. If kept to a minimum, such agencies help fully exploit
economies of scale in the delivery of services where political boundaries
are not consistent with service areas. A proliferation of these agencies
can undermine accountability and budgetary flexibility in the local arena.
Accountability and responsiveness to voters are weakened if members of
special-purpose bodies are appointed rather than elected. Budgetary flexi-
bility is diminished if a majority of local expenditures fall outside the
control of local councils.
Table 2 provides a subjective assessment of how various allocation criteria
favour local or metropolitan assignment and whether public or private pro-
duction is favoured for efficiency or equity. The criteria and the assessment
22728_MR.book Page 17 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
Table 2
Assignment of local public services to municipal and regional/metropolitan governments
Fire fighting L L L L L M L P G P
Police protection L L L L L M L P G G
Refuse collection L L L L L M L P P P
Neighbourhood parks L L L L L M L P G G
Street maintenance L L L L L M L P P P
Traffic management L M L L L M L P P P
Local libraries L L L L L M L G G G
Table 2
Assignment of local public services to municipal and regional/metropolitan governments (Continued)
Refuse disposal M M M M M M M P P P
Public health M M M M M M M G G G
Electric power M M M M M M M P p P
Special police M M M M M M M G G G
20 Anwar Shah
decentralize must be made with care, balancing the need to achieve and
sustain fiscal and political autonomy and accountability at regional and lo-
cal orders of government against the disadvantages of having a fragmented
tax system. The trade-off between increased accountability and increased
economic costs from decentralizing taxing responsibilities can be miti-
gated by fiscal arrangements that permit joint occupation and harmoniza-
tion of taxes to overcome fragmentation. In addition, fiscal equalization
transfers can reduce the fiscal inefficiencies and inequities that arise from
different fiscal capacities across regional and local governments.
Table 3 shows the assignment of major taxation instruments to various
orders of government based on the criteria discussed earlier. Box 1 pre-
sents guidance on local finances.
22 Anwar Shah
Table 3
Representative assignment of taxing powers
Determination of
Collection and
Type of tax Base Rate administration Comments
Table 3
Representative assignment of taxing powers (Continued)
Determination of
Collection and
Type of tax Base Rate administration Comments
Taxation of “bads”
Carbon N,U N,U N,U To combat global/national
pollution
BTU taxes N,S,L N,S,L N,S,L,P Pollution impact may be
national, regional, or local
Motor fuels N,S,L N,S,L N,S,L,P Tolls on federal/provincial/
local roads
24 Anwar Shah
Box 1
Key considerations and tools for local government finances
key considerations
The overall objective of local governments is to maximize social outcomes for residents
and to provide an enabling environment for private-sector development through efficient
provision of public services. This requires that local financing should take into account
the following considerations:
• Business should be taxed only for services to businesses and not for redistributive pur-
poses.
• Current period services should be financed out of current year operating revenues, and
future period services should be financed by future period taxes, user charges/fees,
and borrowing.
• Residential services should be financed by taxes and fees on residents.
• Business services should be financed on site/land value taxes and user charges. Profit,
output, sales, and moveable asset taxes may drive business out of the jurisdiction.
• User charges for services with private goods characteristics – water, sewerage, solid waste
• Development charges for financing growth with higher charges for developing land on
local government boundaries
• Public-private partnerships for infrastructure finance but keeping public ownership and
control of strategic assets
• Tax increment financing districts to deal with urban blight. For this purpose, the area
should be designated for redevelopment and annual property tax revenues frozen at
pre-vitalization levels. For a specified period, say fifteen to thirty-five years, all tax reve-
nues above base are used for redevelopment. Capacity improvements are undertaken
through municipal borrowing/bonds against expected tax increments.
Source: Robert P. Inman, “Financing Cities,” nber Working Paper 11203, National Bureau of Economic
Research, Cambridge, ma, 2005; and Anwar Shah, ed., Local Governance in Developing Countries (Washington,
dc: World Bank, 2006).
22728_MR.book Page 25 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
Intergovernmental Transfers
26 Anwar Shah
The design of fiscal transfers is critical to ensuring the efficiency and equity
of local service provision and the fiscal health of subnational govern-
ments.25 A few simple considerations can be helpful in designing these
transfers:
28 Anwar Shah
Some of these criteria may be in conflict with others. Grantors may therefore
have to assign priorities to various factors in comparing design alternatives.26
As noted earlier, for enhancing government accountability to voters, it
is desirable to match revenue means (the ability to raise revenues from
own sources) as closely as possible with expenditure needs at all orders of
government. However, the national and state governments must be al-
lowed greater access to revenues than is needed to fulfill their own direct
service responsibilities. This is so that they are able to use their spending
power through fiscal transfers to fulfill national and regional efficiency
and equity objectives.
Six broad objectives for national fiscal transfers can be identified.
Each of these objectives may apply to varying degrees in different coun-
tries, and each calls for a specific design of fiscal transfers. Lack of atten-
tion in these designs to specific objectives leads to negative perceptions
of these grants.
Bridging Vertical Fiscal Gaps The terms vertical fiscal gap and vertical fiscal
imbalance have been mistakenly used interchangeably in recent literature
on fiscal decentralization. A vertical fiscal gap is defined as the revenue de-
ficiency arising from a mismatch between revenue means and expenditure
needs, typically of state and local orders of government. A national govern-
ment may have more revenues than warranted by its direct and indirect
spending responsibilities, while regional and local governments may have
less revenues than their expenditure responsibilities.
A vertical fiscal imbalance occurs when the vertical fiscal gap is not
adequately addressed by the reassignment of responsibilities or by fiscal
transfers and other means. Boadway argues that vertical fiscal imbalance
incorporates an ideal or optimum view of expenditures by different orders
of government and is therefore difficult to measure.27
A vertical fiscal gap may arise due to (1) inappropriate assignment of
responsibilities; (2) centralization of taxing powers; (3) pursuit of beggar-
thy-neighbour tax policies (wasteful tax competition) by subnational
governments; or (4) lack of tax room at the subnational orders due to
heavier tax burdens imposed by the national government. To deal with
the vertical fiscal gap, it is important to deal with its sources through a
combination of policies such as the reassignment of responsibilities, tax
decentralization or tax abatement by the centre, and tax-base sharing
(by allowing subnational governments to levy supplementary rates on a
national tax base). Only as a last resort should revenue sharing, or
22728_MR.book Page 29 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
Bridging the Fiscal Divide through Fiscal Equalization Transfers Fiscal equaliza-
tion transfers are advocated to deal with regional fiscal equity concerns.
These transfers are justified on political and economic considerations. Large
regional fiscal disparities can be politically divisive and may even create
threats of secession.28 This threat is quite real. Since 1975, about forty new
countries have been created by the break-up of existing political unions. Fis-
cal equalization transfers could forestall such threats and create a sense of
political participation, as is demonstrated by the impact of such transfers on
the separatist movement in Quebec, Canada.
Decentralized decision making results in differential net fiscal benefits
(imputed benefits from public spending minus tax burden) for citizens de-
pending on the fiscal capacities of their place of residence. This leads to
both fiscal inequity and fiscal inefficiency in resource allocation. Fiscal
inequity arises as citizens with identical incomes are treated differently
depending on their place of residence. Fiscal inefficiency in resource
allocation results from people in their relocation decisions comparing
gross income (private income plus net public-sector benefits minus cost of
moving) at new locations; economic efficiency considerations warrant
comparing private income minus moving costs, only without any regard to
public-sector benefits. A nation that values horizontal equity (the equal
treatment of all citizens nationwide) and fiscal efficiency needs to correct
the fiscal inequity and inefficiency that naturally arise in a decentralized
government. Grants from the national government to states and/or local
governments can eliminate these differences in net fiscal benefits if the
transfers depend on the tax capacity of each state relative to others and on
the relative need for and cost of providing public services. The more de-
centralized the tax system is, the greater the need for equalizing transfers.
The elimination of net fiscal benefits requires a comprehensive fiscal
equalization program that equalizes fiscal capacity (the ability to raise reve-
nues from own basis using national average tax rates) to a national average
standard, and it provides compensation for differential expenditure needs
and costs due to inherent cost disabilities rather than differences that
reflect different policies.
Fiscal equalization programs, especially if they are too generous, can
have some adverse unintended consequences for interjurisdictional factor
mobility and the economic well-being of disadvantaged regions. To the
extent such programs discourage factor mobility and dampen market ad-
justment mechanisms, they can create “transfer dependencies”; that is, in-
centives and magnitudes of transfers serve to counteract the natural forces
of adjustment or lead to decisions that are not in the economic interests of
22728_MR.book Page 30 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
30 Anwar Shah
32 Anwar Shah
Negative Lessons: Types of Transfers to Avoid Policy makers should avoid de-
signing the following types of intergovernmental grants:
Table 4
Principles and better practices in grant design
Examples of Examples of
Grant objective Grant design better practices practices to avoid
Bridge fiscal gap Reassignment of Tax abatement and Deficit grants, wage
responsibilities, tax tax-base sharing grants (China), tax
abatement, tax-base (Canada) by tax sharing (China)
sharing
Reduce regional General non-matching Fiscal equalization with General revenue
fiscal disparities fiscal capacity explicit standard that sharing with multiple
equalization transfers determines total pool factors (Brazil
as well as allocation and India); fiscal
(Canada, Denmark, equalization with a fixed
and Germany) pool (Australia, China)
Compensate Open-ended matching Grant for teaching Closed-ended
for benefit transfers with matching hospitals (South Africa) matching grants
spillovers rate consistent with
spill-out of benefits
Set national Conditional non- Road maintenance Conditional transfers
minimum matching output-based and primary education with conditions on
standards block transfers with grants (Indonesia spending alone (most
conditions on before 2000) countries), pork barrel
standards of service transfers (usa e.g.,
Education transfers
and access $200 million earmark
(Brazil, Chile,
in 2006 for a “bridge to
Colombia),
nowhere” in Alaska),
Health transfers
ad hoc grants
(Brazil, Canada)
Conditional capital Capital grant for Capital grants with no
grants with matching school construction matching and no future
rate that varies inversely (Indonesia before upkeep requirements
with local fiscal capacity 2000), highway
construction matching
grants to states
(United States)
Influence local Open-ended matching Matching transfers Ad hoc grants
priorities in transfers (preferably for social assistance
areas of high with matching rate (Canada before 2004)
national but low varying inversely with
local priority fiscal capacity)
Provide Capital grants, Capital grants with Stabilization grants
stabilization provided maintenance matching rates that vary with no future upkeep
and overcome possible inversely with local requirements
infrastructure fiscal capacity
deficiencies
Source: Anwar Shah, “A Practioner’s Guide to Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers,” in Intergovernmental Fiscal
Transfers, ed. Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, 1–53 (Washington, dc: World Bank, 2007).
22728_MR.book Page 34 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
34 Anwar Shah
1 Keep it simple. In the design of fiscal transfers, rough justice may be bet-
ter than full justice if it achieves wider acceptability and sustainability.
2 Focus on a single objective in a grant program and make the design con-
sistent with that objective. Setting multiple objectives in a single grant
program runs the risk of failing to achieve any of them.
3 Introduce ceilings linked with macro indicators and floors in order to
ensure stability and predictability in grant funds.
4 Introduce sunset clauses. It is desirable to have the grant program re-
viewed periodically – say, every five years – and renewed (if appropriate).
In the intervening years, in order to provide certainty in budgetary
programming for all governments, no changes should be made to the
grant program.
5 Equalize per capita fiscal capacity to a specified standard in order to
achieve fiscal equalization. Such a standard would determine the total
pool and allocations among recipient units. Calculations required for
fiscal capacity equalization using a representative tax system for major
tax bases are possible for most countries. In contrast, expenditure-need
equalization requires difficult and complex analysis, inviting much con-
troversy and debate; as desirable as it is, it may, therefore, not be worth
doing. In view of this practical difficulty, it would be best to deal with
fiscal-need equalization through output-based sectoral grants that also
enhance results-based accountability. A national consensus on the stan-
dard of equalization is critically important for the sustainability of any
equalization program. The equalization program must not be looked at
22728_MR.book Page 35 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
36 Anwar Shah
of the Parliament. This system allows for explicit political input from the
jurisdictions involved and attempts to develop a common consensus. Typi-
cally, such forums opt for simplicity in design so as to make the system
transparent and politically acceptable.
Finally, a variant of the above involves using an intergovernmental cum
legislative cum civil society committee with equal representation from all
constituent units, chaired by the federal government, to negotiate changes
in federal-provincial fiscal arrangements. The Finance Commission in
Pakistan is an example of this model, which is constituted periodically to
determine allocations for the next five years. Pakistan also follows the same
approach by having provincial finance commissions for designing and allo-
cating provincial-local fiscal transfers. An advantage of this approach is that
all stakeholders – donors, recipients, civil society, and experts – are repre-
sented on the commission. Such an approach keeps the system simple and
transparent. An important disadvantage of this approach is that, due to the
unanimity rule, such bodies may be permanently deadlocked, as has re-
cently been witnessed at the federal order in Pakistan.
38 Anwar Shah
Federal fiscal constitutions have been recommended for large and di-
verse countries because they create incentives for multiple orders of gov-
ernment to provide services to their citizens in a competitive, efficient,
equitable, and responsible manner. This is accomplished while respect-
ing diversity in local identities and preferences. Federal fiscal constitu-
tions pay special attention to regional economic and digital divides to
ensure a level playing field and to strengthen the economic union. A re-
view of comparative practices shows that federal countries do better than
unitary countries on all aspects of public governance – citizen participa-
tion, political freedom, political stability, rule of law, bureaucratic effi-
ciency, absence of corruption, human development, egalitarian income
distribution, and fiscal and economic management.36 This is because, as
elaborated in this chapter, federal fiscal constitutions pay a great deal of
attention to clarifying the roles, responsibilities, and accountabilities of
various orders of governments and designing fiscal institutions compati-
ble with responsive, responsible, and accountable results-based gover-
nance. The synthesis of the principles of fiscal federalism documented in
this chapter will, I hope, assist policy makers and practitioners in reform-
ing their fiscal systems.
22728_MR.book Page 40 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
40 Anwar Shah
notes
Author’s note: The author is grateful to John Kincaid for his helpful
comments.
1 Anwar Shah, “Fiscal Decentralization and Macroeconomic Management,” Interna-
tional Tax and Public Finance 13, 4 (2006): 437–62.
2 Daniel J. Elazar, “The Political Theory of Covenant: Biblical Origins and Modern
Developments,” Publius: The Journal of Federalism 10 (1980): 3–30.
3 Robert Inman, “Why Federalism?” unpublished paper, Wharton School, University
of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, September 2006.
4 Not all federal countries are decentralized and not all unitary countries are
centralized. For example, Canada is highly decentralized, but Australia and
Germany are centralized federations, as is indicated by the share of subnational
expenditures in consolidated public expenditures. Nordic unitary countries are
more decentralized than are Australia and Germany.
5 William H. Riker, Federalism: Origin, Operation, Significance (Boston, ma: Little-
Brown, 1964), 11.
6 See Pierre Salmon, “Horizontal Competition among Governments,” in Handbook of
Fiscal Federalism, ed. Ehtisham Ahmad and Giorgio Brosio, 61–85 (Cheltenham,
uk: Edward Elgar, 2006); and Albert Breton, “Modeling Vertical Competition,”
in Handbook of Fiscal Federalism, ed. Ehtisham Ahmad and Giorgio Brosio, 86–105
(Cheltenham, uk: Edward Elgar, 2006). See also Daphne A. Kenyon and John
Kincaid, eds., Competition among States and Local Governments: Efficiency and Equity in
American Federalism (Washington, dc: Urban Institute Press, 1991).
7 See Ronald L. Watts, Comparing Federal Systems (Montreal and Kingston: McGill-
Queen’s University Press, 1999).
8 Barry Weingast, “Second Generation Fiscal Federalism: Implications for Decentral-
ized Democratic Governance and Economic Development,” discussion draft,
Hoover Institution, Stanford University, 2006, 6.
9 This refers to civic republics as termed by John Kincaid, “Municipal Perspectives in
Federalism,” unpublished paper, cited in Ann O. Bowman and Robert C. Kearney,
State and Local Government (Boston, ma: Houghton Mifflin Company, 1990).
10 George Stigler, “The Tenable Range of Functions of Local Government,” in The
Economics of Fiscal Federalism and Local Finance, ed. Wallace E. Oates, 3–9 (Cheltham,
uk: Edward Elgar, 1998).
11 Mancur Olson, “The Principle of Fiscal Equivalence: The Division of Responsibili-
ties among Different Levels of Government,” American Economic Review 59,
2 (1969): 479–87.
12 Wallace Oates, Fiscal Federalism (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1972).
13 Ibid., 55.
14 Bruno Frey and Reiner Eichenberger, The New Democratic Federalism for Europe:
Functional Overlapping and Competing Jurisdictions ( Cheltenham, uk: Edward Elgar,
1999).
22728_MR.book Page 41 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
15 Ibid., 55.
16 Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, “Fiscal Federalism in Developing/Transition
Economies: Some Lessons from Industrialized Countries,” paper presented at the
National Tax Association Meetings, St. Paul, Minnesota, November 1994; National
Tax Journal, proceedings issue, April 1994, 64–71; Robin Boadway, Sandra Roberts,
and Anwar Shah, “The Reform of Fiscal Systems in Developing and Emerging
Market Economies: A Federalism Perspective,” Policy Research Working Paper
1259, World Bank, Washington, dc, 1994; Robin Boadway, Sandra Roberts, and
Anwar Shah, “Fiscal Federalism Dimension of Tax Reform in Developing
Countries.” in Fiscal Reform and Structural Change in Developing Countries, vol. 1,
ed. G. Perry, J. Whalley, and G. McMahon, 171–200 (London: Macmillan, 2000).
17 Robin Boadway, The Constitutional Division of Powers: An Economic Perspective (Ottawa:
Economic Council of Canada, 1992).
18 Ibid.
19 Anwar Shah, “Fiscal Decentralization and Macroeconomic Management,”
International Tax and Public Finance 13, 4 (2006): 437–62; and Anwar Shah,
“Corruption and Decentralized Public Governance,” in Handbook of Fiscal Federal-
ism, ed. Ehtisham Ahmad and Giorgio Brosio, 478–98 (Cheltenham, uk: Edward
Elgar, 2006).
20 Robin Boadway, The Constitutional Division of Powers: An Economic Perspective (Ottawa:
Economic Council of Canada, 1992).
21 See Anwar Shah with Sana Shah, “The New Vision of Local Governance and the
Evolving Roles of Local Governments.” In Local Governance in Developing Countries,
ed. Anwar Shah, 1–46 (Washington, dc: World Bank, 2006), 1–46.
22 Robert P. Inman, “Financing Cities,” nber Working Paper 11203, National Bureau
of Economic Research, Cambridge, ma, 2005.
23 Izabella Barati and Akos Szalai, “Fiscal Decentralization in Hungary” (Center for
Public Affairs Studies, Budapest University of Economic Sciences, 2000), p. 21.
24 Anwar Shah, “The New Fiscal Federalism in Brazil,” Discussion Paper 124, World
Bank, Washington, dc, 1991.
25 For a comprehensive treatment of the economic rationale for intergovernmental
fiscal transfers, see Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, eds., Intergovernmental Fiscal
Transfers (Washington, dc: World Bank, 2007); and Anwar Shah, “A Practioner’s
Guide to Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers,” in Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers,
ed. Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, 1–53 (Washington, dc: World Bank, 2007).
26 Anwar Shah, The Reform of Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in Developing and Emerg-
ing Market Economies (Washington, dc: World Bank, 1994); Government of
Canada, Achieving a National Purpose: Putting Equalization Back on Track (Ottawa:
Department of Finance, 2006); Government of Canada, Restoring Fiscal Balance in
Canada (Ottawa: Department of Finance, 2006); and Anwar Shah, “A Prac-
tioner’s Guide to Intergovernmental Fiscal Transfers,” in Intergovernmental Fiscal
Transfers, ed. Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, 1–53 (Washington, dc: World
Bank, 2007).
22728_MR.book Page 42 Tuesday, July 3, 2007 11:48 AM
42 Anwar Shah
27 Robin Boadway, “The Vertical Fiscal Gap: Conceptions and Misconceptions,” paper
presented at Canadian Fiscal Arrangements: What Works, What Might Work Better,
Winnipeg, Manitoba, 16–17 May 2002.
28 Raja Shankar and Anwar Shah, “Bridging the Economic Divide within Nations: A
Scorecard on the Performance of Regional Development Policies in Reducing
Regional Income Disparities,” World Development 31, 8 (2003): 1421–41.
29 Wallace Oates, Fiscal Federalism (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1972). For a
more elaborate discussion of absence of fiscal equalization in the United States, see
Daphne A. Kenyon and John Kincaid, “Fiscal Federalism in the United States: The
Reluctance to Equalize Jurisdictions,” in Finanzverfassung im Spannungsfeld zwischen
Zentralstaat und Gliedstaaten, ed. Werner W. Pommerehne and George Ress, 34–56
(Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, 1996).
30 On examples of state-local transfers from Australia, Brazil, and Canada, see Anwar
Shah, The Reform of Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in Developing and Emerging Market
Economies (Washington, dc: World Bank, 1994).
31 Anwar Shah, The New Fiscal Federalism in Brazil (Washington, dc: world bank,
1991).
32 For an evaluation framework and comparative reflections on alternate institutional
arrangements, see Anwar Shah, “Institutional Arrangements for Intergovernmental
Fiscal Transfers and a Framework for Evaluation,” in Intergovernmental Fiscal Trans-
fers, ed. Robin Boadway and Anwar Shah, 293–317 (Washington, dc: World Bank,
2007).
33 Raja Shankar and Anwar Shah, “Bridging the Economic Divide within Nations:
A Scorecard on the Performance of Regional Development Policies in Reducing
Regional Income Disparities,” World Development 31, 8 (2003): 1421–41.
34 See Anwar Shah, “Interregional Competition and Federal Cooperation: To Com-
pete or to Cooperate – That Is Not the Question,” paper presented at the Interna-
tional Forum on Federalism in Mexico: Local and Global Challenges, held in
Veracruz, Mexico, 14–17 November 2001.
35 Anwar Shah, “Corruption and Decentralized Public Governance,” in Handbook of
Fiscal Federalism, ed. Ehtisham Ahmad and Giorgio Brosio, 478–98, (Cheltham, uk:
Edward Elgar, 2006).
36 Anwar Shah, “Balance, Accountability, and Responsiveness: Lessons about
Decentralizations,” Policy Research Working Paper Number 2021, World Bank,
Washington, dc, 1998; Anwar Shah, “Fiscal Decentralization and Macroeconomic
Management,” International Tax and Public Finance 13, 4 (2006): 437–62; and
Robert Inman, “Why Federalism?” unpublished paper, Wharton School, University
of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, 2006.