1990a Bpea Cutler Poterba Sheiner Summers Akerlof
1990a Bpea Cutler Poterba Sheiner Summers Akerlof
1990a Bpea Cutler Poterba Sheiner Summers Akerlof
CUTLER
MassachusettsInstituteof Technology
JAMES M. POTERBA
MassachusettsInstituteof Technology
LOUISE M. SHEINER
HarvardUniversity
LAWRENCE H. SUMMERS
HarvardUniversity
1
2 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
per capita incomes by between 7 percent and 12 percent over the next
60 years, but would actuallyincreaseincomes over the next 20 years. In
only one of the next six decades will demographicchanges affect living
standardsas much as the "peace dividend" is likely to affect them in
this decade. The decline in living standardscaused by the increased
dependencewould be fully reversedby a 0.15 percenta year increasein
productivitygrowth.
Second, we consider the consequences of the slower labor force
growththat presages the increase in the retiredshareof the population.
Between 2010 and 2060, the laborforce is expected to decline slightly,
comparedwith an averageincreaseof 1.5percentannuallybetween 1950
and 1990.The projecteddecline in the laborforce growthratewill permit
a 3-4 percent reductionin the share of net investment in total income
withoutreducingcapitalintensity. Since reducedlaborforce growthwill
occur before dependency burdens increase, projected demographic
changes raise the short-termconsumptionpath even if the steady-state
consumptionlevel declines. We show that in a standardgrowth model
with plausibleparametervalues, optimalconsumptiontypically rises in
response to a demographicshock like that experienced in the United
States over the past three decades.
Third,we considerthe implicationsof integratedworldcapitalmarkets
for ouranalysis.The degreeand speed of populationagingin othermajor
industrializedcountries,particularlyWest GermanyandJapan,is more
dramaticthan that in the United States. The increase in dependency
abroadwill coincide with a deceleration in labor force growth rates.
Alongan optimalpath, therefore,the rest of the worldwill exportcapital
to the United States-thus increasingU.S. consumptionand reducing
savingin the shortrun.
Fourth, we go beyond the standardgrowth theoretic approachand
ask whether the coming demographicchanges are likely to affect the
rate of technicalchange. With slow laborforce growth, laboris scarce;
this scarcitymay induce more rapidtechnical change. Such a develop-
mentwould sharpenour conclusion that diminishedfertilityrepresents
an opportunityratherthana problem.Using internationalcross-section
time series data for 1960-85, we find some evidence that nations with
slowerlaborforcegrowthdo experiencemorerapidproductivitygrowth.
The estimatessuggestthatthe reductionin laborforce growthprojected
for the next 40 years may raise productivitygrowth enough to offset
4 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
Sources: Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and the Disability Insurance Trust
Funds (1988, table Al, p. 93) and unpublished data from the Social Security Administration underlying the published
projections.
a. Elderly dependency ratio is the population aged 65 and over divided by the population aged 20-64. Total
dependency ratio is population aged 65 and over plus the population under 20 divided by the population aged
20-64.
6 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
Source: Projected data are from Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and Disability
Insurance Trust Funds (1988, table 11, p. 37). Historical data are from Social Security Area Popuilation Projectionls.
1989 (1989, pp. 3-4).
64
(3) LF1 = E Ni.
i=20
CON2 = E Si Ni,
i =,I
whereSi is the respectiveweightfor an individualat age i.
8. SchneiderandGuralnik(1990).
9. Providedthe "warmglow" of caregivingdoes not affect the marginalutility of
consuminggoods, it shouldnot affect our needs weightingof different-agedhouseholds.
It will affectthe totalutilityof households.
D. M. Cutler,J. M. Poterba, L. M. Sheiner, and L. H. Summers 11
Laborforce
Earnings- Consumption
Population weighted Needs-
20-64 population Unweighted weighted
Period (LF1) (LF2) (CON1) (CON2)
1950-1960 0.74 1.18 1.77 1.66
1960-1970 1.25 1.19 1.23 1.28
1970-1980 1.73 2.05 0.91 1.13
1980-1990 1.29 1.69 0.95 1.08
1990-2000 0.83 1.07 0.70 0.75
2000-2010 0.80 0.48 0.57 0.65
2010-2020 0.06 -0.03 0.48 0.60
2020-2030 -0.26 -0.10 0.29 0.42
2030-2040 0.11 0.07 0.14 0.17
2040-2050 0.00 -0.03 0.04 0.05
2050-2060 -0.06 -0.02 0.03 0.05
Source: Boardof Trusteesof the FederalOld-Ageand SurvivorsInsuranceand DisabilityInsuranceTrustFunds
(1988).Projecteddatafor 1990-2060use alternativeIlb. Data show geometricaverageannualchangesin laborforce
and consumptionneeds underIIb.
-
0.96 , . Earnings-weightedpopulation!
" ,' .- ~~~~~~~~~needs-weighted
consumption
0.84 _'-' .< Eatnings-weightedEpopulation! (LF21CON2)
unweighted consumption
0.82 . . (LF2/ CON1)
0.8 l
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060
Year
Source: Table 2.
A X Tota change
a~~~~~~~~~~
-8 t\ e ~ ofeldet-iyA,
~~~~Sha-e \
-10lo. - Shat-eof childi-en'
-12 _ - ...s
- 16 X l l l l l l l l l l l l l l l l l l l
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060
Year
Source: Authors' calculations using equation 6. The earnings-weighted labor force measure (LF2) and the needs-
weighted consumption measure (CON2) are used. See text for details.
those between 1960 and 1990. With our preferredmeasures, LF2 and
CON2, the supportratio was 14.0 percent lower in 1970than 1990. By
2060, it is projectedonce again to be below the 1990level, this time by
11.8percent. Oursupportratiopeaks around2010. One reason why the
slow growthof real wages in the U.S. economy since 1973has been less
burdensomethan it might have otherwise been is that the labor force
participationrate has risen. The figures show clearly that the gains in
sustainable consumption from demographic developments are now
nearlyexhausted.
Finally, while the decline in the supportratio by the middle of the
next century is large, there is still substantialuncertaintyabout the
ultimateburden.Figure5 presents supportratios using LF2 and CON2
underthe three Social SecurityAdministrationdemographicforecasts.
Thereare substantialdifferencesin the scenarios, particularlybetween
the more pessimistic alternative III and alternative II, which is our
16 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
-4 \- lesntv
-18 a 0 | l | l | i i*
-16 AlternativeIII iv
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060
Year
Source: Authors' calculations using Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and
Disability Insurance Trust Funds (1988) and the needs-weighted consumption (CON2)and earnings-weighted labor
force (LF2) measures.
Earnzings-weighted
laborforce (LF2)
1960 - 16.5 1.1 - 15.4 - 13.2 1.2 - 12.1
1970 - 16.9 -0.4 - 17.3 - 14.0 -0.4 - 14.4
1980 - 7.0 -1.9 -9.0 -5.8 -2.0 - 7.8
1990 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
2000 3.7 2.2 5.9 3.2 2.2 5.4
2010 2.8 3.5 6.3 1.4 3.5 4.9
2020 -2.3 4.4 2.1 -4.8 4.2 -0.6
2030 -6.0 3.7 -2.3 -9.6 3.6 -6.0
2040 -6.6 3.6 - 3.0 - 10.5 3.5 -7.0
2050 -7.3 3.9 -3.5 - 11.2 3.7 -7.5
2060 -7.8 3.6 -4.1 - 11.8 3.5 -8.3
2065 -7.8 3.7 -4.2 - 12.0 3.5 -8.4
Source:Authors'calculations.
a. The table shows the steady-statechangein consumptionrelativeto the 1990base if demographicchangewere
to reacha steady state at the level of the indicatedyear.
Initial c* -----------
New c*
k* ~~~~~~~~~~Capital-labor
ratio (k)
1995 2015
102 1990
98-
2025
96
2030
94 2 35
2040
2050
92 2060
Nev steady state
270 274 278 282 286 290
Capitalper effective worker
Source: Authors' calculations. Elasticities used are , = 1, a= 1. Labor force measure is earnings-weighted (LF2);
consumption measure is needs-weighted (CON2). Consumption at the initial steady state is normalized to 100. The
resulting index yields capital per effective worker equal to 274 in the initial steady state.
6.5 -
5.5
4.5-
4-
3.5-
3 -
2.5-
2 l l l l l l l
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070
Year
Source: Authors' calculations. Elasticities used are , = 1, a= 1. The consumption measure is needs-weighted
(CON2); the labor force measure is earnings-weighted (LF2).
Simulation in 1970
stat-ting
-2
X _ Simulation
star-ting 19809*.0. in ----
Simulations
st*.igin180. ... .............
-5 -
I I i I. I Il
1970 1.980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060 2070
Year
Source: Authors'calculationsusing Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Ageand SurvivorsInsuranceand
Disability Insurance Trust Funds (1988).
a. This figurepresentsthe percentagepoint differencein saving rates from the initialsteady state followinga
demographic Thethreelinesrepresent
shock. saving
paths arerunstarting
whenthesimulations and
in1970,1980,
1990. These saving plcuations u sinBardof Tusg needs-weighted
n consumption(CON2) and the earnings-
weightedlaborforce (LF2),and unitelasticitiesof substitutionin both productionand consumption(, = 1, a= 1).
Figure 10. Actual and Projected Elderly Dependency Ratios, United States, Japan,
and European Community, 1950-2050
Percent
42
40 -
38 -
36-
34-
32 Japat -
30 - .
24~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~J
22 t EulopeanCommruni/y
........./. t
14 - -J
18 _ UniteStates
122/
10
I I I I I I I II
1950 1970 1990 2010 2030 2050
Year
Source: OECD (1988). Working-age population includes all those aged 15-64.
Figure 11. Actual and Projected Support Ratios, United States, Japan, and European
Community, 1950-2050
Supportratio (1990 = 1)
United States
1.00- J n
0.95
_
***;/..*....
/ "v^^ s~~~ ~~~~~Eur-opean
0.90 *. ......... Community
_~~~~~ s
_ .
0.95 -l
I S
deogevrapi changesitheUnatveitcedsi
Stthes Japain,-theEuopelantCom-
aesnd thmoetotalnED3 consumptionpeprsn
muity,ethesnon-pu.S OECD hs
usming
patsore simuan,thed previusesection. Fornth
themodelphofthanes
32. The table uses the case of unit elasticities of substitutionand production.We
assumethatdepreciationratesandratesof labor-augmenting technicalprogressare equal
in all countriesand are the same as the Social SecurityAdministrationforecasts for the
United States. The assumptionof equal productivitygrowth is obviously wrong but
probablydoes not havea largeimpacton estimatesof the changein savingdue to changes
in demographicstructure.
32 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
A Two-CountrySimulationModel
Ouropen-economysimulationsaggregatethe EuropeanCommunity,
Japan,and the other countriesof the OECD to form a non-U.S. OECD
index. Figures 12 and 13 show the supportratio and laborforce growth
rates for the United States and this aggregate.The supportratios are
consistentwith those in figure11. The United States has a 5 percentage
point highersupportratioin 2050 than the non-U.S. OECD, and unlike
the restof the OECDhas a risingsupportratioover the next two decades.
By 2050the laborforce in both areas is projectedto stabilize, not grow.
Between now and then they fluctuate,but with U.S. laborforce growth
always higher.
To assess the optimalresponse of U.S. saving in an open-economy
context, we extend the modelof the previoussection to allow for capital
mobility. We distinguishasset ownershipfromasset locationby denoting
periodt asset ownershipper person in country 1 by a1 t. Asset accumu-
lationis given by
(15) a1,t = wt + a1,t(rt - ni,t) -(cl,t1o,),
where the wage, wt, and the interest rate, rt, are equalized across
countries.The laborforce growthrate, the supportratio, and the level
of percapitaconsumptioncan differacross countriesandthereforehave
both time and countrysubscripts.
Thecommoncapital-laborratiois a weightedaverageof asset holdings
in the two nations:
(16) kt = 01t a1,t+ (1 - 01,t)a2 t,
where 01,tis country I's share of world population. From equation 16 we
derivethe capitalaccumulationconstraintfor the two-countrymodel:
(17) k,= 61,t (a1,t - a2,t) + 01,t bl,t + (I 01,t) a2,t
34 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
Figure 12. Actual and Projected Support Ratios, United States and Non-U.S.
OECD, 1960-2050
Supportratio (1990 = 1)
UnitedStates
1.00
0.90 _ %%s
*.85 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
Year
Source: Authors' calculations based on data in OECD (1988). Non-U.S. OECD includes all OECD countries
except the United States, weighted by GDP. The consumption measure is needs-weighted (CON2), with the same
weights as for the United States. The labor force is the population 15-64 (LF1).
Figure 13. Actual and Projected Growth Rate of Labor Force, United States
and Non-U.S. OECD, 1960-2050
Annualgrowthrate (percentagepoints)
1.8
1.6-
1.4 UnitedStates
1.2 A
1 "____\
0.8
0.6-
-
0.4 Non-U.S. OECD\
0.2 -%
-0.2 -
-0.4
-0.6 -
I I l l l
1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
Year
Source: Sameas figure12.
Figure 14. Net Saving and Investment Rates, United States, from Two-Country
Simulations, 1990-2050
Percentof GNP
5.5
Investmentrate
5 J1/
4.5
4 %
%
Saving l-ate
3.5-
-
3
2.5-
2-
35. Simon(1981)andWattenberg(1987).
36. Wattenberg(1987,p. 65).
37. Habakkuk(1962).
38. Romer(1990).
D. M. Cutler, J. M. Poterba, L. M. Sheiner, and L. H. Summers 39
S OJapan
4-
*Italy
3 00 France
Germanya
2_ Canad
Kingdom _
1 * * ~~~~~~~~~~UnitedSt
O I I I I I I I I I I * I I I I
0.4 0.8 1.2 1.6 2 2.4 2.8 3.2
Laborforce growth (percentannually)
Source: Authors' calculations based on data in Summers and Heston (1990). The G-7 countries are labeled on the
figure.
a. Japan is included in the figure but not in the regression line.
The fourth row of the table presents the results of treatingthe two
sampleperiodsas a panelandestimatinga fixed-effectsregression.This
specificationcontrolsfor otherfactorsthatcan explainpersistentdiffer-
ences in growth rates across countriesbut that are not includedin our
set of explanatoryvariables.The resultsarequalitativelysimilarto those
without the fixed effects. The coefficient in the multivariateregression
(- 0.446)is withinthe rangeof the estimatesfor the two sampleperiods,
althoughthe coefficient is not statistically significantlydifferentfrom
zero when we controlfor initialincome and the investmentrate.
The lower panel of the table reportsinstrumentalvariablesestimates
of the sameequations,usingthe populationgrowthrateas an instrument
for labor force growth. If rapidproductivitygrowth leads to less rapid
increases in labor force participation,the ordinaryleast squares esti-
mates will be biased, but the instrumentalvariablesregressionswill not.
The instrumentalvariablesestimatesstronglyconfirmthe ordinaryleast
squares estimates. In the 1960-85 regression, the coefficient on labor
force growth becomes more negative in the instrumentalvariables
regression( - 0.742) and is still statisticallysignificant.The coefficients
on the othervariables,in contrast,changelittle.
As the second and third rows of the bottom panel suggest, this is
principallydue to a more pronouncednegative relationbetween labor
force growthandproductivitygrowthduring1973-85.This is consistent
with RichardFreeman'sclaim thatthe decline in productivitygrowthin
post-1973 Europe discouragedlabor force participation,leading to a
positive bias in the coefficienton laborforce growthrates.42
The final row presents the results for the instrumentalvariables
regressionwith the fixed-effects specification.While the coefficient in
the bivariateregressionis similarto the ordinaryleast squaresestimate,
the coefficient in the multivariateregressionis positive. In both cases,
the coefficientson laborforce growthare not statisticallydifferentfrom
zero.
Because reductions in the labor force growth rate tend to increase
capitalintensity,one would expect themto be associatedwith increases
in labor productivitygrowth even if they had no impact on technical
change.43We doubtthatthe equationsin table 7 areprimarilypickingup
42. Freeman(1988).
43. Mankiw,Romer,andWeil(1990)explorethis possibilitywith particularattention
to the role of humancapitalaccumulation.
D. M. Cutler, J. M. Poterba, L. M. Sheiner, and L. H. Summers 43
this effect for two reasons. First, its theoretical magnitudeis much
smallerthanthe effects impliedby the cross-countryequations. Over a
25-year period, a 1 percentage point reduction in labor force growth
holding the saving rate constant would raise labor productivityby at
most 0.17 percentagepoint assuminga Cobb-Douglasproductionfunc-
tionwith a 67 percentlaborshare." Second, for a smallsampleof OECD
countrieswith available data (18 countries) we estimated productivity
growthequationsusing both laborproductivityand total factor produc-
tivity andfound only negligibledifferencesin the results.45
These regressions imply substantivelylarge effects of demographic
changeon futuregrowth. Because the annuallaborforce growthrate is
predicted to fall by about 1 percentage point between 1990 and 2050,
with most of the changeoccurringbetween 1990and2010, ourestimates
imply an increase of about 0.6 percentagepoint in annualproductivity
growth. Such effects are large enough to offset the decline in living
standardsthatwe presentedabove. Even a 0.2 percentagepointincrease
in annualproductivitygrowth between 1990and 2040 would offset the
roughly 10 percent decrease in per capita consumptionas a result of
rising dependency burdens over that period. Thus, even if the effects
aremuchsmallerthanthose fromourregressions,they are likely to have
a largeimpacton futureliving standards.
Theregressionsthusfarpresentlittleevidenceforthemorepessimistic
view of demographicchange. It may be, however, thatpartof the effect
of demographicchange occurs throughthe investment rate. If slower
laborforce growthreduces the rate of innovationbecause of decreased
demand for capital goods, that will show up as a positive effect of
investmentrateson productivitygrowth,ratherthanas an effect of labor
force growth.
To considerthis hypothesis, we reestimatedthe equationsin table 7
withoutcontrollingfor the rate of investment. The results change little
fromthose reported.For the fulltimeperiod,for example,the coefficient
44. The predictedeffect is this largeonly if the base year for our observations(1960)
is the firstyearof the new laborforce growthrates. If the countrieswerealreadyin steady
state with differentlabor force growth rates, there would be no predicted effect on
productivityfromthis explanation.
45. Withoutcontrolsfor initialproductivityand investmentrates, the coefficienton
the growthrateof the laborforce is - 0.788 (0.207)in the equationfor laborproductivity
and - 0.696 (0.257) in the equation for total factor productivity.In the multivariate
regression,the coefficientsare - 0.305 (0.216)and - 0.259 (0.324)in the two equations.
44 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
Figure 16. Consumption Response with Induced Productivity, United States, 1990-2065
Per capita consumption (index, 1990 = 100)
420
380 -
340 -
300 IIncreasingproductivity
220-
100~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~1
180 - --- -Constant pr-oductivity
140-
100 I
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060
Year
Source: Authors' calculations. For increasing productivity, it is assumed that productivity grows 0.5 percent for
each I percent decline in annual labor force growth. The consumption measure is needs-weighted (CON2), and the
labor force is earnings-weighted (LF2). The simulations assume unit elasticities of substitution in production and
consumption.
The preceding section suggests that, other things being equal, the
optimal response to recent and projected demographicchanges is a
laborforce andneeds-
48. Weuse the supportratiodefinedwiththe earnings-weighted
weighted consumptionmeasure. We also assume unit elasticities of substitutionin
productionandconsumption.
46 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1.1990
5.0 -
native H
k ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Alt
4.5 - Altei-native I
AlternativeIII
4.0_ .
1 1, 1 1 1 l l I I l I l l I
1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060
Year
Source: Summers and Carroll (1987); Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and
Disability Insurance Trust Funds (1988).
a. The calculations assume that the saving rate is held constant by age.
elderly are much larger than those to any other group. Efficiency
considerationsargue for higher current taxes to fund foreseeable in-
creases in governmentoutlays. Because the deadweightloss of taxation
increaseswith the squareof the tax rate, financingthe anticipatedrise
in governmentoutlays on a pay-as-you-gobasis, with lower tax rates
duringthe next few decades and higherones in the middle of the next
century, entails a larger deadweight burden than a constant tax rate
policy.52 This argumentparallels the traditionaljustificationfor using
debtto financewarsandothertransitoryshocksto governmentspending.
To evaluate the empirical significanceof tax-smoothingconsidera-
tions, we begin by describingthe age-specific pattern of government
outlays.Wethenpresenta simpleframeworkforevaluatingtheefficiency
(22) E
t=l
Ttt =
t=1
ht8t + do - d7ZT,
Table 10. Efficiency Gains from Smoothing Taxes, United States, 1990-2050a
Percent
Average
deadweight
loss as
Year petcent of
avetrage
Tax rate 1990 2010 2030 2050 GNP
Constant debt-GNP ratiob
Variable rate 32.6 33.5 36.8 37.1 6.23
Constant rate 35.3 35.3 35.3 35.3 6.22
Constant pritnaty slurplusc
Variable rate 32.3 33.9 37.2 37.6 6.52
Constant rate 35.7 35.7 35.7 35.7 6.51
Source: Authors' calculations based on sources described in table 9.
a. For each spending category, total government expenditures are projected to 2060, as described in table 9. The
two cases are described in more detail in the text.
b. Constant debt-GNP ratio is fixed at 1989 level of 50.2 percent.
c. Constant primary surplus assumes that a federal and state-local surplus equals its 1989 share of GNP throughout
1990-2000.
to-GNP ratio, fixed at its 1989level of 50.2 percent. In this case the pay-
as-you-gotax raterises from32.6 percentof GNP in 1990to 37.1 percent
by 2050.The averagedeadweightloss fromthis policy, shown in the last
column, is 6.23 percent of the average value of GNP. The constant tax
rate that achieves the same debt-to-GNPratioof 50.2 percentin 2050is
35.3 percent. Under this plan, taxes would rise by 3 percent of GNP-
roughly $150 billion-in 1990. Despite this large change in the debt
trajectory,however, the change in excess burdenis small. The average
value of deadweightloss is 6.22 percentof averageGNP when tax rates
are smoothed. The improvementin deadweight loss averages 0.017
percent of GNP annually,or less than $1 billion a year in 1990dollars.
The changein the present value of deadweightlosses between 1990and
2060equals 1.1 percentof 1990GNP, or approximately$55 billion.
The lower panel in table 10 shows parallelcalculationsassumingthe
combinedfederal and state-local primarysurplusequals its 1989 share
of GNP value throughoutthe 1990to 2050 period. The results indicate
that the averageexcess-burden-to-GNPratiounderthis scenariois 6.52
percent, comparedwith 6.51 percent if the tax rate is smoothed. The
difference between these two efficiency costs is similarto that in our
firstcase, 0.017 percentof GNP. Plausiblevariationsin ourassumptions
D. M. Cutler, J. M. Poterba, L. M. Sheiner, and L. H. Summers 53
Conclusions
55. Aaron,Bosworth,andBurtless(1989).
54 Brookings Paipers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
57
58 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
increase in the nationalsaving rate." But I also agree with the popular
wisdom that the as yet inadequateresponse to the baby boom, which
began in the 1940s, partly accounts for the inadequacy of the current
capitalstock.
The authorstell us: do not worryaboutthe futuredependencyof the
baby boomers. If you had saved a great deal in response to the baby
boomers(as the plannerwould have in theirmodel), now is the time for
an increase in consumption. However, most peoples' worry is the
opposite: they worry that we have not saved in response to the baby
boom and, therefore,that saving should increase now while some time
remainsto preparefor the dependencybulge.
An analogyis apt. A travelerleaves Chicagoboundfor CedarRapids.
He notes that his plane is travelingeast. He tells the stewardess about
his anxiety, sayingthat CedarRapidsis west of Chicagoandthe planeis
headingin the wrong direction.The stewardess is reassuring.She tells
him that if he had begun his trip in Salt Lake City, where, on her
assumptions,he should have startedit, then he should be headed east,
as the planeis currentlygoing.
The correct moral to draw from the authors' paper is subtle. They
have rightlyreassuredus thatthe consequences of ourprofligacyarenot
as dire as imagined, since the baby busters will requirerelatively little
investmentto satisfy capital-wideningrequirements.
The authorsalso examine the implicationsof populationagingin the
context of an explicit open-economy model. As they show, the trade
partnersof the United States will experience increases in dependency
that are even more pronouncedthan those in the United States. More-
over, the near-termdecline in dependency projected for the United
States will not occur abroad.Accordingto a naive view, these develop-
ments abroadare cause for concern. The United States is now highly
dependenton foreign saving to finance its current spending. If saving
abroadfalls as dependencythere increases, foreignlendingmay dry up,
resultingin risinginterestrates and a decliningdollar.The authorspoint
out the flaw in this naive scenario. The demographicchanges that are
occurringalter not only optimal consumptionbut also optimal invest-
ment.Overthe next severaldecades, investmentneeds will declinemore
quicklyin other countries than in the United States. In the absence of
internationalcapital flows, the returnto investment should fall abroad
andriseinthe UnitedStates. Inresponseto this differential,international
60 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
2. Tobin(1988,p. 42).
D. M. Cutler, J. M. Poterba, L. M. Sheiner, and L. H. Summers 63
1. RivlinandWiener(1988).
64 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990
forces them to save for their retirement. Then to mimic the rational
privatedecision, the trustfund shouldnow buildup a surplus.Whydoes
this not show up in the authors'results?
Withouttinkeringat length with the optimalgrowthconditions, I am
not sure, but I thinkit is relatedto one of the thingsthatCharlesSchultze
and I pointed to in a recent paper.5The steady-state rate of growth of
the U.S. economy has declined, and so the rate of profit is declining.
The projecteddecline in the growth of the labor force will drive down
the rate of profitfurther.The decline in the warrantedrate of growth is
drivingthe authors'conclusionthat the optimalsavingrate will decline.
This result is very much a steady-stateconclusion, however, and there
is no guaranteethat the same result should hold even over periods of
severaldecades.
It is not clear from theory that a decline in the rate of profit should
reduce savingby rationalindividuals,and it is not clear from empirical
evidence that actual people do reduce saving when the rate of return
declines. I would expect the life-cycle effect to dominateover the rate
of profiteffect so that the aggregatesavingrate of rationalsavers would
increase as the baby boomers hit their peak earningsyears. If so, the
social securitytrustfund shouldfollow theirlead.
Of course social security is not only a forced retirementprogram;it
is also redistributive.And therethe authorshave a good point. The baby
boomers have had it tough competing against their own large cohort.
They are entitledto expect latergenerationsto contributeto the support
of the low-incomeelderly in the next century. The build-upof the trust
fund shouldnot try to do it all.
This is a provocative and importantpaper that questions a conven-
tional wisdom about the appropriateway to respond to demographic
changes. The model has not settled some importantissues, but it is not
wrongeither. It raises legitimatequestions about the level of saving we
shouldexpect or seek.
General Discussion
References
Aaron, Henry J., BarryP. Bosworth, and Gary Burtless. 1989. Can America
Afford to Grow Old?Paying for Social Security. Washington:Brookings.
Auerbach,Alan J., and Laurence J. Kotlikoff. 1989. "Demographics,Fiscal
Policy, and U.S. Saving in the 1980s and Beyond." WorkingPaper 3150.
Cambridge,Mass.: National Bureauof Economic Research (October).
. 1987.DynamicFiscal Policy. New York: CambridgeUniversityPress.
Auerbach,Alan J., and others. 1989. "The Economic Dynamics of an Aging
Population:The Case of Four OECD Countries. OECDEconomic Studies
12: 97-130.
Baily, MartinN. 1981. "Productivityand the Services of Capitaland Labor."
BPEA, 1:1981, 1-50.
Baily, Martin Neil, and Charles L. Schultze. 1990. "The Productivity of
Capital in a Period of Slower Growth." BPEA: Microeconomics, 1990,
369-406.
Ballard, Charles L., John B. Shoven, and John Whalley. 1985. "General
EquilibriumComputationsof the MarginalWelfare Costs of Taxes in the
United States." AmericanEconomic Review 75: 128-38.
Bishop,John. 1989."Is the Test Score Decline Responsiblefor the Productivity
GrowthDecline?" AmericanEconomic Review 79: 178-97.
Blanchard,OlivierJ., andStanleyFischer. 1989.Lectureson Macroeconomics.
Cambridge,Mass.: MIT Press.
Barro, Robert J. 1979. "On the Determinationof the Public Debt." Journal
of Political Economy 87: 940-71.
Board of Trustees of the Federal Old-Age and Survivors Insurance and
DisabilityInsuranceTrust Funds. 1988. 1988Annual Report. Washington:
Social Security Administration.
. 1990.1990AnnualReport.Washington:Social SecurityAdministration.
Board of Trustees of the Federal SupplementaryMedical Insurance Trust
Fund. 1988.1988AnnualReport. Washington:Social SecurityAdministra-
tion.
Borjas, George J. 1990. Friends or Strangers:The Impact of Immigrationon
the U.S. Economy. New York: Basic Books.
Calvo, GuillermoA., and MauriceObstfeld. 1988. "OptimalTime-Consistent
FiscalPolicy with Finite Lifetimes:Analysis and Extensions." In Economic
Effects of the GovernmentBudget, edited by Elhanan Helpman, Assaf
Razin, and EfraimSadka. Cambridge,Mass.: MIT Press.
DeLong, J. Bradford.1988."ProductivityGrowth,Convergence,and Welfare:
Comment."AmericanEconomic Review 78: 1138-54.
Denison, EdwardF. 1985. Trendsin American Economic Growth, 1929-82.
Washington:Brookings.
72 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1990