CEO Marital Status
CEO Marital Status
CEO Marital Status
Ahmed Elnahas 1
Md Noman Hossain 2
Siamak Javadi 3
Abstract
We examine the effect of CEO marital status on corporate cash holdings. Consistent with the
classical agency framework, we find that firms with single CEOs hold more cash compared to
otherwise similar firms with married CEOs and that the excess cash held by single CEOs is
significantly discounted by shareholders. Our findings survive a battery of tests to ease
endogeneity and selection bias, confirming that results are not simply reflecting innate
heterogeneity in preferences. Overall, our findings indicate that a variable outside the common
firm- and macro-level determinants, CEO marital status, can significantly influence corporate
policies.
We would like to express our gratitude to the anonymous referees for their thoughtful comments and suggestions.
Further, we are indebted to Hua Cheng (Discussant), Gautam Hazarika, Suin Lee, Yu Liu, Nam Nguyen, Mahdi
Rastad, Bruno Arthur, Incheol Kim, Levent Kutlu, Armando Lopez-Velasco, Andre Mollick, Monika Rabarison,
Jean-Baptiste Tondji, Salvador Contreras, and other seminar participants at the 2020 Southern Finance Association,
the 2021 Southwest Finance Association, and the 2021 economics and finance seminar series at the University of
Texas Rio Grande Valley. All remaining errors are ours. The data that support the findings of this study are available
from the corresponding author upon reasonable request.
1
Robert C. Vackar College of Business and Entrepreneurship, University of Texas Rio Grande Valley, 1201 W
University Dr, Edinburg, TX 78539. Voice: (956) 665-3827; E-mail: [email protected]
2
College of Business, Central Washington University, 400 E University Way, Ellensburg, WA 98926.Voice: (509)
963-1409; E-mail: [email protected]
3
Robert C. Vackar College of Business and Entrepreneurship, University of Texas Rio Grande Valley, 1 W
University Blvd, Brownsville, TX 78520. Phone: (956) 882-8858; E-mail: [email protected]
Abstract
We examine the effect of CEO marital status on corporate cash holdings. Consistent with the
classical agency framework, we find that firms with single CEOs hold more cash compared to
otherwise similar firms with married CEOs and that the excess cash held by single CEOs is
significantly discounted by shareholders. Our findings survive a battery of tests to ease
endogeneity and selection bias, confirming that results are not simply reflecting innate
heterogeneity in preferences. Overall, our findings indicate that a variable outside the common
firm- and macro-level determinants, CEO marital status, can significantly influence corporate
policies.
There is no doubt that a CEO is the single most influential individual in a modern corporation.
Consequently, financial economists have paid significant attention to studying how CEOs'
personal traits affect their firms’ policies and decision-making processes. For example,
researchers investigate the impact of CEOs’ gender (Adhikari, 2018), overconfidence (Aktas,
Louca & Petmezas, 2019; and Malmendier & Tate, 2005), age (Andreou, Louca & Petrou, 2017),
military affiliation (Benmelech & Frydman, 2015), political ideology (Di Giuli & Kostovetsky,
2014; Elnahas & Kim, 2017; and Hossain et al., 2022), and personal debt and risk-taking
(Cronqvist, Makhija, & Yonker, 2012; and Cain & McKeon, 2016). Recently, researchers have
studied the impact of a CEO’s marital status on corporate decision-making. For example, Hilary,
Huang, and Xu (2017) find that firms headed by single CEOs display a higher degree of earnings
management than those headed by married CEOs. Roussanov and Savor (2014) show that firms
headed by single CEOs exhibit higher stock return volatility, have more aggressive investment
policies, and are less likely to respond to changes in idiosyncratic risk. Lu, Ray, and Teo (2016)
conclude that hedge funds run by single managers take more risks than those run by married
managers. Similarly, Belenzon, Patacconi, and Zarutskie (2016) find that firms run by married
couples behave more conservatively than other family-owned firms. Other studies also document
the effect of marital status on risk aversion in terms of asset allocation, saving and portfolio
choices, life insurance policies, and accounting policies (Riley Jr and Chow (1992); Roszkowski,
Snelbecker, and Leimberg (1993); Hallahan, Faff, and McKenzie (2004); Love (2009); Hong &
Ríos-Rull (2012)). In this paper, we extend this literature by investigating the effect of the marital
The recent attention that financial economists have paid to the impact of CEO marital status
on corporate policies is not surprising. Social scientists have always considered marriage as the
3
group of renowned family scholars documents that marital status affects several aspects of human
life that include family (e.g., quality relationships and biosocial effects), economic (e.g., poverty
rates and wealth creation), physical health and longevity (e.g., lower rates of injury, illness,
disability, and life expectancy), and mental health and emotional well-being (e.g., rates of crime,
suicide, and mental illness) (Wilcox et al. (2005)). According to the behavioral consistency
theory, the personal traits of a CEO, such as marital status, not only affect her/his personal
behavior and choices but also the policies and decisions of the firm she/he leads.
Cash holding is one of the corporate policies that has received growing academic attention in
the literature (Opler et al.1999; Harford 1999; Dittmar et al. 2003; Pinkowitz et al. 2006; Dittmar
and Mahrt-Smith 2007; Foley et al. 2007; Harford et al. 2008; Bates et al. 2009; Duchin 2010;
Nikolov and Whited 2014; Gao et al. 2013). Understanding corporate cash holding policy is
important because cash holdings act not only as a safety net in the presence of costly external
financing but also may impact investors’ concerns about managerial self-dealing. Indeed, the two
predominant theories of corporate cash holdings, the precautionary motive and the agency
framework, make mixed predictions about the possible impact of CEO marital status on cash
holdings.
Cash provides a safety cushion against bankruptcy risks and ameliorates adverse cash flow
shocks. Consistent with this view, Bates, Kahle, and Stulz (2009) find that the increase in
corporate cash holdings is positively correlated with the increase in firm-specific risks. Similarly,
Adhikari (2018) provides evidence that firms with more risk-averse managers hold more cash.
Prior literature has characterized single individuals as less risk-averse than married individuals.
Roussanov and Savor (2014) show that single CEOs are less risk-averse compared to married
take more risk than those run by married managers. It follows that a single CEO with a lower
degree of risk aversion is expected to hold less cash than a married CEO. We call this our risk
aversion hypothesis.
In addition to having low risk aversion, single individuals have always been characterized as
more self-centered by social scientists. DePaulo and Morris (2005) document that single
individuals have been consistently viewed as more self-centered and envious than married
individuals. Similarly, Wilcox et al. (2005) claim that marriage turns individuals’ attention away
from dangerous, antisocial, and self-centered activities. Further, Campbell & Lee (1992) link
singlehood to social isolation and view marriage as an attachment to wider communities and
increased investment in social ties. By definition, a self-centered CEO who is more willing to
seek her/his interest at the expense of those of others (including shareholders) would engage
more in self-dealing, which aggravates the agency problem in firms headed by single CEOs.4
However, how would this aggravated agency problem affect the cash holdings of firms
headed by single CEOs? The agency framework provides opposing predictions regarding the
association between marital status and cash holdings. On the one hand, researchers show that
poorly governed firms with escalated agency issues dissipate more cash (Dittmar and Mahrt-
Consequently, this argument predicts that firms headed by single CEOs dissipate more cash, i.e.,
4
Self-centeredness is defined by Dambrun and Ricard (2011) as “the self takes on a central point of reference with
regard to many psychological activities (i.e., conation, motivation, attention, cognition, affect/emotion, and
behavior). The exaggerated importance given to the self emerges mainly from self-centeredness and refers to the
increased degree with which the individual considers that his own condition is more important than that of others
and this takes unquestionable priority.” Further, they argue that Self-centered psychological functioning includes
characteristics such as biased self-interest, egoism, egocentrism, and egotism.
governance hypothesis.
On the other hand, the classical agency framework pioneered by Jensen (1986) suggests that
corporate insiders generally have a personal incentive to retain cash rather than increase
dividends and that they rely on cash and liquid assets to finance their risky projects, empire-
building and self-dealing, allowing them to avoid the market scrutiny necessary for raising
external finance. This classical agency framework predicts that firms headed by single CEOs,
due to escalated agency issues, hold more cash. The positive association between agency
problems and cash holdings is consistent with the work of Dittmar et al. (2003), Kalcheva and
Lins (2007), and Pinkowitz et al. (2006). We refer to this as our classical agency problem
hypothesis.
The impact of CEO marital status on corporate cash holding is ultimately an empirical
question that depends on how marital status affects a CEO’s risk aversion and agency problem.
Using a sample of 19,864 firm-year observations between 1993 and 2008, we find that firms with
single CEOs hold about 1.3 percentage points more cash compared to firms with married CEOs,
after controlling for the known determinants of cash holdings (Opler et al. (1999)), other CEO
incentives (Vega), CEO ownerships, and the inclusion of industry and year fixed effects. This
effect is economically significant. For the average firm in our sample that has a total asset size
of about $4.3 billion, the above figure is equivalent to holding about $56 Million more cash by
5
Our sample ends in 2008, because CEOs marital status data is available between 1993 and 2008.
early life experience, among other traits, might be jointly correlated with CEO marital status and
cash holdings, leading to an omitted variable bias in our baseline results. For instance, corporate
cash holdings could be affected by the level of CEO overconfidence (Chen, Ho, and Yeh (2020));
(ii) the association between CEO marital status and cash holdings may be spurious and attributable
to the innate heterogeneity in preferences rather than marital status; and (iii) there is a concern that
firms with single CEOs are fundamentally different from those with married CEO, suggesting that
our analysis may suffer from selection bias. We address these concerns in several ways. First, we
employ a Difference-in-Differences (DiD) estimation around CEO turnover events and find that
firms that replace a married CEO with a single CEO experience an increase in their cash holdings
while those that replace a single CEO with a married one experience a decrease in their cash
holdings. Second, to address the concern that our results are driven by CEO innate heterogeneity
rather than by their marital status, we use the instrumental variables (IV) regression approach used
by Roussanov & Savor (2014) and find that our baseline regression results continue to hold. Third,
we use propensity score matching (PSM) to address the selection bias concern. There are
significant differences between firms run by single CEOs and those run by married CEOs. Thus,
we match firms with single CEOs (the treatment) and firms with married CEOs (control groups)
on the firm and CEO characteristics as well as year and industry to mitigate selection bias concerns
(Rosenbaum & Rubin (1983), Roberts & Whited (2013)). We then run our baseline regression
using the matched sample and find that our baseline results continue to hold. We also test our DiD
estimate using the matched sample and find consistent results to our baseline findings. We also
find similar results when we estimate our baseline model while controlling for CEO
Our baseline results are more consistent with the classical agency problem hypothesis rather
than the risk aversion and poor governance hypotheses. However, we note that as an alternative
interpretation of our results, hoarding cash may be explained by precautionary motive rather than
our classical agency problem hypothesis, as our interpretation suggests. We conduct a battery of
tests to rule out precautionary motives as an alternative explanation of our results. First, we
investigate the association between CEO marital status and cash holdings for subsamples of
constrained firms can be greatly driven by precautionary motives (Almeida et al. (2004); Han &
Qiu (2007), Denis & Sibilkov (2009)), such motives are not expected to play a significant role in
financially unconstrained firms. Consequently, finding higher levels of cash holdings for
financially unconstrained firms with single CEOs would refute the possibility that the cash
holdings of single CEOs are driven by precautionary motives. Using several conventional
measures of financial constraint as well as different proxies for cash holding, we find robust higher
levels of cash holdings for unconstrained firms with single CEOs compared to otherwise similar
firms with married CEOs. Next, we conduct a test using subsamples of firms with high and low
firm-specific risk. Following the same intuition, the precautionary motive is not expected to play
a vital role in holding excess cash in firms with low levels of risk. Using several measures of firm-
specific risk, we find robust higher levels of cash holdings for low-risk firms with single CEOs
compared to otherwise similar firms with married CEOs, which is inconsistent with the
precautionary explanation.
6
The results of the test that controls for CEO overconfidence are similar to our baseline results. These results are un-
tabulated and are available upon request.
problem hypothesis which also hints at the possible channels for the positive association between
cash holdings and single CEOs. First, since tax avoidance lowers the firm’s overall tax burden and
thus increases the firm’s net income, managers benefit from tax avoidance activities in the form of
higher compensation. Consequently, self-centered single CEOs may attempt to pump their
compensations by engaging in aggressive tax avoidance practices. Using two proxies of corporate
tax avoidance (Wilson (2009), Frank, Lynch, & Rego (2009)), we find that firms run by single
CEOs are more likely to engage in corporate tax avoidance than those run by married CEOs.
Second, using various measures of dividend payout, we find that firms with single CEOs pay out
significantly lower dividends compared to otherwise similar firms with married CEOs. Third, we
find that single CEOs rely more on cash holdings compared to married CEOs to fund the risky
investments documented in Roussanov and Savor (2014) and that external financing in general is
significantly lower for firms with single CEOs. The findings of these tests are generally consistent
Lastly, we explore the possible impact of the excess cash held by single CEOs on firm value.
Following the valuation models of Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007) and Pinkowitz and
Williamson (2007), we find robust evidence consistent with our classical agency problem
hypothesis that shareholders heavily discount the additional cash that single CEOs hold.
This study makes several contributions to the existing literature. First, this study adds
additional evidence to the small but growing finance literature on behavioral consistency theory.
Prior studies provide evidence of behavioral consistency in corporate policies of firms, such as
CEO overconfidence (Malmendier & Tate (2005)), personal tax aggressiveness (Chyz (2013)),
CEO political ideology (Hutton et al. (2014)), and pilot CEOs (Sunder, Sunder, & Zhang (2017)).
holdings. It is worth noting that in almost all prior research that investigates CEO marital status,
risk aversion and agency framework do not necessarily have opposing predictions. For example,
Roussanov and Savor (2014) investigate the association between marital status and aggressive
investment policies. Nicolosi and Yore (2015) examine the association between marital status and
deal-making as well as risk-taking behavior, while Hilary, Huang, and Xu (2017) analyze the
association between marital status and earnings management. Across all these studies, both the
risk aversion and the agency frameworks mostly have similar predictions regarding the decision-
making process of single CEOs. However, due to the competing predictions of the risk aversion
hypothesis and the classical agency problem hypothesis of the cash holdings literature, cash
holding provides an appropriate setting to disentangle risk-taking motives and agency issues. The
closest paper to ours is a concurrent study by Al Mamun et al (2021). While it is reassuring that our
main results and theirs are similar in that single CEOs hold more cash than married CEOs, our
paper is different from their paper in several important ways. First, our paper rules out the
possibility that excess cash holdings by single CEOs are driven by precautionary motives. Second,
our paper provides some insights into the possible channels by presenting empirical evidence on
the engagement of single CEOs in tax avoidance, dividend cuts, and risky investment policies.
Further, our tests employ a wider set of measures of cash holding, measures of dividends payout
policy, as well as varying cash valuation models including those of Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith
Further, this study contributes to the corporate cash holdings literature. Most studies in this
literature assume that cash holding is a function of firm-level (Opler et al. (1999); Bates et al.
10
however, provide robust evidence that CEO personal traits also affect cash holdings.
The paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data sources, sample construction, and
summary statistics. Section 3 presents the empirical results and the steps we took to address
present additional tests regarding possible channels, risky investments, and valuation of excess
2.1. Data
We use the data on CEO's marital status provided by Roussanov & Savor (2014).7 They collected
the names, biographical information, and compensation of all CEOs covered by the Compustat
Executive Compensation (ExecuComp) database which covers firms in the S&P 1500 index from
1993 to 2008. To identify the CEOs' marital and family status, they use several public sources such
as the Marquis Who’s Who in Finance and Industry, the Notable Names Database, the U.S.
Securities and Exchange Commission’s insider filings, and various media mentions.8 Following
their study, we define the CEO’s marital status as Single which is an indicator variable that equals
We then merge this database with Compustat to construct the cash-holding measures and firm-
level control variables. Following prior studies, we exclude financial firms (SIC codes between
6000 and 6999) and utilities (SIC codes between 4900 and 4999) since these industries are highly
7
We thank Roussanov & Savor (2014) for sharing their CEOs marital status data, which is available at
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2014.1926
8
We request readers to go through Roussanov & Savor (2014) for more details about the data collection process,
biases, and accuracy of the CEOs’ marital status.
11
positive cash holding and sales. Our final sample includes 19,864 firm-year observations of 2,305
unique firms.
Following Bates, Kahle, & Stulz (2009), we define firms’ cash holdings, Cash, as the ratio of cash
plus marketable securities to the book value of assets. We also construct an alternative measure of
cash holdings for robustness check, NetCash which is the ratio of cash to net assets, where net
assets are defined as the book value of assets minus cash following Dittmar et al. (2003). We also
construct FCash which is the one-year forwarded value of Cash (Casht+1) and FNetCash
(NetCasht+1) which is the one-year forwarded value of NetCash. We use these two alternative
measures in our estimation to address the cash-flow identity issue (Kalcheva & Lins (2007). We
report the descriptive statistics of the key variables used in our analyses in Table 1.
Statistics in Table 1 show that the mean value of Single is 0.173, indicating that 17.3% of the
firm-year observations have single CEOs, which is consistent with statistics reported by
Roussanov & Savor (2014), and Hilary et al. (2017). The mean value of Cash is 0.144 indicating
that, on average, firms hold 14.4% of their total assets in cash and marketable securities, which is
consistent with the statistics reported by Opler et al. (1999), Bates et al. (2009), and Nguyen et al.
(2018). Similarly, the mean value of NetCash implies that, on average, firms hold 18.6% of their
net assets in net cash, which is consistent with the statistics reported by Dittmar et al. (2003).
9
See more at Dittmar et al. (2003), and Faulkender & Wang (2006).
12
our sample firms pay dividends. We report Pearson correlation coefficients in Table 2.
Table 2 shows that the correlation between Single and Cash is 0.13, indicating that single CEOs
hold more cash than married CEOs. The positive correlations between Single and R&D,
Acquisition, and Industry_sigma are consistent with the higher risk-taking propensity of single
CEOs. The negative relation between Single and Ln(Age) indicates that the older the CEO, the
higher the likelihood of her/him being married.10 The negative correlation between Cash and
Ln(Age) indicates that older CEOs are less likely to hold cash as compared to younger CEOs. The
positive correlation between Cash and Ln(Tenure) indicates that entrenched managers hold more
cash as CEO entrenchment increases with their tenure (Coles, Daniel, & Naveen (2014), Jiang &
Lie (2016)).
To test the relation between CEO marital status and cash holdings, we estimate the following
regression model:
where 𝐶𝑎𝑠ℎ𝑖𝑗𝑡 is our measure of cash holdings for firm i that belongs to industry j in year t as
defined in Section 2.2. Single is an indicator variable that equals 1 if a CEO is unmarried and zero
otherwise. The coefficient of Single (β1) measures the effect of the CEO’s marital status on the
10
Roussanov & Savor (2014) mention that “According to U.S. census data, 70% of men in the 35-59 age range were
married in 2000.” Thus, it is logical that we find only 17.3 % of the CEOs are Single in our sample period and the
correlation between Single and CEO age is negative.
13
problem hypothesis whereas a negative sign would be consistent with our risk aversion and poor
governance hypotheses. Following the prior literature (Opler et al. (1999), Dittmar et al. (2003),
Almeida, Campello, & Weisbach (2004), Dittmar & Mahrt-Smith (2007), Acharya, Almeida, &
Campello (2007), Bates et al. (2009), Nguyen, Phan, & Sun (2018), and Javadi et al. (2021)), we
control for a vector of firm- and CEO-level control variables (𝛾𝑖𝑗𝑡−1). For instance, prior studies
argue that there are economies of scale to holding cash, thus we control for firm size (Ln(assets)).
The value of cash is more important for firms with better investment opportunities and financially
constrained firms, so we control for the ratio of market-to-book value (MB). We control for
Leverage because firms with debt constraints may use cash to reduce leverage, whereas the
hedging argument of Acharya et al. (2007) predicts a positive relationship between cash holdings
and leverage. We also control for R&D because firms with higher R&D expenditures have a higher
cost of financial distress and may require more cash holdings. We control for Cash_Flow because
firms with higher cash flow accumulate more cash. We control for NWC because prior research
shows a negative relationship between net working capital and cash holdings.
Prior studies demonstrate that if capital expenditures are used as a proxy for the cost of
financial distress or investment opportunities then they could be positively related to cash, whereas
expenditures create assets that can be subsequently used as collateral, then they could lower cash
holdings. Consequently, we control for capital expenditures (CAPX). We control for Dividend
because dividend-paying firms are less risky and less financially constrained and have greater
access to capital markets reducing the precautionary motive for cash holdings. We control for
acquisition expenditure (Acquisition) due to the expected effect of acquisition expenditures on cash
14
With regard to the CEO-level controls, prior studies suggest that CEO tenure and age are
related to career concerns (Gibbons & murphy (1992)) and that older CEOs are more risk-averse
due to career concerns (Chevalier & Ellison (1999), Ali & Zhang (2015), Andreou, Louca, &
Petrou (2017)). Similarly, Duru, Iyengar, & Zampelli (2016), and DeBoskey, Luo, & Zhou (2019)
argue that CEO tenure and CEO-chairman duality affect firms’ policies (i.e., earnings
announcement tone and firm performance.) Thus, we control for CEO tenure (Ln(Tenure)), CEO
age (Ln(Age)), and Duality. We control for CEO risk-taking incentive (Ln(Vega)) since prior
research finds a positive relation between Vega and cash holdings and a negative relation between
Vega and the value of cash to shareholders (Tong (2010), Liu & Mauer (2011), Aktas et al. (2019)).
Following Opler et al. (1999), we control for CEO ownership (CEO_Own) which is the percentage
of shares outstanding owned by a CEO. We also control for CEO pay-performance sensitivity
(Ln(Delta)) where Delta and Vega are measured following Guay (1999), and Core and Guay
(2002). All the control variables are in the lagged form to address the possible simultaneity
concerns (Kalcheva & Lins (2007)). In all our models, we include a set of dummy variables to
capture year (𝜏𝑡 ) and industry fixed effects (𝐼𝑗 ) to control for time-varying unobservable industry
characteristics, and clustered robust standard errors at the firm level are used. This model accounts
for correlation among unobservable time-invariant industry effects and explanatory variables,
unobservable aggregate time trends, and within-firm serial correlation. Table 3 presents the results
of our baseline regression model of the association between CEO marital status and cash holdings.
15
The coefficient estimates of Single in models (1) and (2) are positive and statistically significant
indicating that firms headed by single CEOs hold more cash than those run by married CEOs. To
mitigate concerns related to simultaneity, we also use the one-year forwarded values, FCash, and
FNetCash in models (3) and (4), respectively.11 Similar to the models that use contemporaneous
values of cash measures, the coefficient estimates of Single are positive and statistically significant
in models (3) and (4). Specifically, on average, firms run by single CEOs hold about 1.0 to 1.8
percentage points more cash than those run by married CEOs. Taking the average of the
coefficients on Single, our results indicate that firms with single CEOs hold about 1.3 percentage
points more cash relative to firms with married CEOs. This impact is economically significant.
For the average firm in our sample that holds 14.4% of its total assets ($4.3 Billion) in cash, this
figure is equivalent to a 9% rise in cash holdings and translates into about $56 Million more cash
The signs of the coefficients of other control variables are similar to prior studies. For instance,
we find a negative relationship between firm size (Ln(assets)) and cash holdings and a positive
relationship between firms’ growth opportunities (MB) and cash holdings. Similarly, high
dividend-paying firms hold less cash, whereas firms with higher cash flow volatility hold more
cash. Further, consistent with the agency problems framework, we find a positive and significant
11
We note that for these two specifications, unlike the specification in equation (1), all the explanatory variables are
in time t since the dependent variable is shifted one time-step forward (t+1). In this setup all the explanatory variables
are essentially lagged.
12
It is worth noting that the average firm size in our sample is relatively smaller than that reported in Roussanov and
Savor (2014), possibly due to the exclusion of financial firms in our sample.
16
support in other fields, outside of financial economics. Psychology literature directly links marital
status and hoarding behavior. This literature indicates that several factors drive hoarding behavior
such as anxiety avoidance, fear of losing information, and feelings of pleasure associated with
possessions (Bubrick et al. (2004); Grisham et al. (2006)). Canale & Klontz (2013) note that
individuals hoard to shield themselves from potential future loss and avoid future uncertainty, and
argue that hoarding cash is similar to hoarding possessions. Grisham et al. (2006) document that
individuals who hoard are typically single and lack personal connections with others, leading to
stronger attachments to their possessions which become a part of their identity. Thus, the
psychology literature predicts that firms with single CEOs would hoard more cash than firms with
married CEOs.
Our baseline results show a positive and statistically significant relationship between Single and
cash holdings. However, CEOs' marital status and cash holdings could be jointly correlated with
unobservable variables, such as CEO social, economic, physical, and demographic characteristics,
implying that our findings could be subject to the omitted variable bias. For instance, Xu,
Hudspeth, & Bartkowski (2005), and Uecker (2014) find a relation between the timing of marriage
and individual religious tradition, religious service attendance, and religious commitment. Other
scholars focus on marriage timing and economic factors (Oppenheimer (1988), Oppenheimer,
Kalmijn, & Lim (1997), Sweeney & Cancian (2004)) and marriage timing and cultural factors
(Lesthaeghe & Surkyn (1988), Jennings, Axinn, & Ghimire (2012)). Thus, the relationship
between single CEOs and cash holdings may be attributable to the innate heterogeneity in
preferences rather than marital status. Also, there is another concern that firms with single CEOs
are different from those with married CEOs, giving rise to selection bias. Lastly, Chen, Ho, and
17
our results could be affected by omitted CEO overconfidence. We address these concerns in the
(IV) regression, a propensity score matching (PSM) approach, and a test that controls for CEO
overconfidence.
To establish a stronger causal relationship between CEO marital status and cash holding, we
employ a DiD regression around the CEO turnover events. For this analysis, we first restrict the
sample to outgoing CEOs who had held their position for at least three years before their departure
and to incoming CEOs who held their position for at least 3 years after taking the position. This
setup assures that CEOs could imprint their personal preferences in corporate policies. Then, to
mitigate the effect of other confounding events, we restrict our DiD estimation window to the -3,
+3 years surrounding CEO turnover events. Table 4 presents the results of our DiD estimation
tests.
The dependent variable in models (1) and (2) is Cash, while the dependent variable in models
(3) and (4) is NetCash. After is a dummy variable equal to 1 for the post-turnover period and 0 for
the pre-turnover period. Treated is a dummy variable equal to 1 if a firm replaces a married CEO
with a single CEO, and 0 otherwise. Our variable of interest is the difference-in-difference
coefficient on this interaction term since a change from a married CEO to a single CEO should
cause an increase in cash holding. All models include firm and CEO-level characteristics, and
industry and year fixed effects, and we cluster the standard error at the firm level. Focusing on the
18
statistically significant in both models indicating that firms that replaced a married CEO with a
Further, our framework also predicts the opposite effect, a reduction in cash holdings, when a
married CEO replaces a single CEO. Thus, in models (3) and (4), Treated is equal to 1 if a firm
replaces a single CEO with a married CEO. The coefficients on the interaction term in both models
are significantly negative. We note that these results are not the mirror image of the results in the
first two columns, because a firm could replace a married CEO with another married CEO, or a
Further, in models (5)-(8) of Table 4, we repeat our DiD analysis surrounding the CEO
turnover events using a propensity score matched sample.13 Consistent with the results for the
overall sample, the coefficient of the interaction term After*Treated is positive and statistically
significant in models (5) and (6), and significantly negative in models (7) and (8). These results
suggest that in a matched sample, firms replacing a married CEO with a single CEO experience
an increase in cash holdings while cash holdings decrease when a married CEO succeeds a single
CEO. Together, these results provide strong empirical support for the association between CEO
marital status and corporate cash holding and enhance the causal interpretation of our results.
Following Roussanov & Savor (2014), we examine the cost of getting married by differentiating
between firms located in states that adopt community property and those that adopt equitable
division divorce laws. In the community property system, a divorce would result in an equal
13
We discuss our matching procedure in detail in Section 3.2.3.
19
judge based on multiple factors in the equitable division system. Since, on average, CEOs are
expected to be wealthier than their spouses, marriage will be costlier for them under community
property laws. Therefore, a CEO is more likely to be single if he/she resides in a state with a
community property law. Further, it is unlikely that this law can affect corporate cash holdings
other than through its impact on CEO’s marital status. Thus, following Roussanov & Savor (2014),
we employ the instrument, Community, which is an indicator variable equal to 1 if a firm is located
in a state that has adopted the community property system, and zero otherwise.14 Table 5 presents
Model 1 in Table 5 reports the results of the first stage estimate. Even though the community
property system has been adopted regardless of the economic conditions of the state, we control
for state-level real per capita income and Coincident Economic Activity Index (CEAI) to address
the possibility that state-level economic conditions might predict the individuals’ marital status.15
In the first stage (model (1)), we find that the coefficient of community is positive and statistically
significant (i.e., 𝛽1= 0.126 with a t-stat = 1.99), indicating that CEOs who are residing in a
Our second stage test results are reported in model (2) in Table 5 where the dependent variable
is Cash and the explanatory variable is the predicted values from the first stage regression
Singlepred. The coefficient on the instrumented Single, Singlepred, is positive and statistically
14
In the United States, nine states have adopted the community property system: Arizona, California, Idaho, Louisiana,
Nevada, New Mexico, Texas, Washington, and Wisconsin. Puerto Rico is also a community property jurisdiction.
15
Roussanov & Savor (2014) argue that the community property system is not related to the state characteristics such
as rich vs poor states, large vs small states or political preference of the populations, such as liberal vs conservative.
In addition, they argue that as the community property system was adopted well before the sample period (1993-
2008), the potential endogeneity concern of political economy consideration is likely to be muted for these states.
20
determinant of corporate cash holdings. Moreover, the instrumental variable approach potentially
mitigates the effect of the CEO's innate heterogeneity that could potentially bias our estimates. It
also reduces the possible effect of measurement error bias that could arise due to the classification
In this section, we first examine the differences in the characteristics of firms with single CEOs
Statistics in Panel A of Table 6 show that the differences in cash holdings (both Cash and
NetCash) are positive and statistically significant which indicates that single CEOs have higher
cash holdings compared to married CEOs. Additional descriptive statistics demonstrate that firms
run by single CEOs have a higher investment in R&D and Acquisition and have higher
Industry_sigma, which are consistent with the risk-taking preference by single CEOs documented
by Roussanov & Savor (2014). Further, these descriptive statistics also reveal that Single CEOs
are, on average, younger and have less wealth and share ownership compared to married CEOs,
which is consistent with the literature that relates wealth to success in the market for marriage
(Korenman & Neumark (1991), Chun & Lee (2001), Roussanov & Savor (2014), Nicolosi and
Yore (2015)). Moreover, firms run by single CEOs are on average smaller, have high growth
potential (MB), and have lower cash flows compared to those run by married CEOs. These
16
We note that the coefficient estimated using the IV approach is substantially larger than those reported in Table 3
which could be due to the IV model identifying the local average treatment effect of the endogenous variable on the
outcome variable (Imbens & Angrist, 1994). Moreover, Jiang (2017) also argues that “there is no reason to expect that
the causal effects in close to 85% of all the cases studied by researchers should be predominantly higher than the
simple correlational effect”. Thus, while the results of this IV estimation alleviates the endogeneity concerns, we are
hesitant to draw conclusion on the magnitude of the effect.
21
with our baseline results. Although we control for firm and CEO characteristics in our regression
models, we alleviate this concern by applying the propensity score matching (PSM) approach. In
this section and onward, we run our analyses using the PSM sample.
Specifically, we employ PSM and match firms based on their characteristics and their CEO
attributes to mitigate selection bias (Rosenbaum & Rubin (1983), Roberts & Whited (2013)). We
also include year and industry fixed effects in this matching process. In the first step of our PSM,
we estimate a logistic regression of Single on multiple firms and CEO characteristics. Using the
estimated coefficients from the logistic model in the first step, we then compute the propensity
scores (i.e., the predicted likelihood of Single = 1) for all firms in our sample. We then match firms
with Single CEOs (treatment groups) with those with married CEOs (control groups) using the
nearest neighbor-matching technique where one married CEO firm-year enters into the sample
only once. Panel B of Table 6 shows the differences in the characteristics of treatment and control
for the matched sample. There are no significant differences between the treatment and control
groups, indicating that the matching was conducted successfully. In the next step, we re-estimate
our baseline regression models using the PSM sample and report the results in Table 7.
The dependent variables in Table 7 are Cash, NetCash, FCash, and FNetCash, in turn. Models
(1-4) include firm characteristics, while models (5-8) include both firm and CEO characteristics.
All models include industry and year fixed effects, and we cluster standard error at the firm level.
Consistent with our baseline results (in Table 3), we find a positive and statistically significant
association between Single and cash holdings in all regression models for the PSM sample,
alleviating concerns that our findings may suffer from selection bias.
22
Our finding that single CEOs hold more cash than married CEOs is consistent with our classical
agency problem hypothesis. However, CEOs may hold excess cash for precautionary motives,
giving rise to the concern that our results could have an alternative interpretation based on the
precautionary motive framework rather than the agency problem. In this section, we attempt to
Prior studies document that single CEOs are less risk-averse. For instance, firms run by single
CEOs experience higher stock return volatility, pursue more aggressive investment policies, are
less likely to respond to changes in idiosyncratic risk, and behave less conservatively (Roussanov
and Savor (2014), Lu, Ray, and Teo (2016), Belenzon, Patacconi, and Zarutskie (2016)). Because
single CEOs are less risk-averse, their cash holdings policies are less likely to be motivated by
precautionary motives. However, any rational managers might hold more cash when facing
financial constraints. Han & Qiu (2007), and Denis & Sibilkov (2009) argue that financially
constrained firms hold more cash compared to unconstrained firms due to precautionary motives.
They show that higher future cash flow volatility and constraints on external financing induce
financially constrained firms to hold excess cash. Similarly, Almedia et al. (2004) show that
financially constrained firms save more cash out of their cash flow. Consistent with this argument,
financial constraints may encourage managers to increase cash holdings due to precautionary
motives regardless of their marital status. Thus, to formally rule out the possibility that our results
are driven by the precautionary motives associated with financial constraints, we conduct a cross-
sectional test for subsamples of financially constrained and unconstrained firms. While cash-
holding policies in financially constrained firms can be greatly shaped by precautionary motives,
23
holdings for unconstrained firms with single CEOs would refute the possibility that the
Specifically, we use five different proxies to identify financially constrained firms: Dividends,
annual payout, bond rating, commercial paper rating, and KZ index. The financially constrained
[FC] (Financially unconstrained [Non-FC]) subgroup includes firms not paying (do paying)
dividends, below (above) median values of Annual Payout, below (above) S&P long-term credit
ratings investment grade, below (above) S&P short-term credit ratings investment grade, and
above (below) medium scores on the KZ index. Table 8 presents the results for this cross-section
test using our full sample, reported in the left panels, as well as the PSM sample, reported in the
right panels.
The dependent variables in Table 8 are Cash and NetCash, in turn. All regression models
include firm and CEO characteristics, year and industry fixed effects, and we cluster the standard
errors at the firm level. Focusing on the left panels, models 1 to 4, across all measures of financial
constraints, we report a positive and significant coefficient for Single only in the subsamples of
financially unconstrained firms. This finding cannot be explained by the precautionary motives
which are expected to have a negligent effect on cash holdings policies of financially unconstrained
firms. In contrast, the coefficient estimates of Single are not statistically significant in the
financially constrained subsamples. This result indicates that in the presence of financial
constraints, there is no difference in firms’ cash holdings due to CEO’s marital status. It seems
that, regardless of their marital status, managers in financially constrained firms are facing a more
binding cash-holding policy that restricts their ability to implant their preferences into firms’ cash-
24
example, focusing on the results based on the KZ index, we find that firms with single CEOs hold
about 2 percentage points more cash relative to otherwise comparable firms with married CEOs
only when the firms are unconstrained. These results are consistent with our earlier findings and
further alleviate the concerns about our findings being spurious. Overall, these results suggest that
the potential reason that Single CEOs hold more cash in these unconstrained firms cannot be
attributed to precautionary motives (which may affect the constrained sample), but rather they are
more consistent with our classical agency problem hypothesis. In the next section, we further
Similar to financially constrained firms, managers of firms with high specific risk might hold
excess cash for precautionary motives. Consequently, an alternative way to rule out the
precautionary hypothesis is to investigate our results in subgroups of firms with high vs. low levels
of firm-specific risk. If the precautionary motives are the reason behind the excess cash holdings
of single CEOs, we should observe stronger results in the high firm-specific risk subsample. To
formally test this conjecture, we use four proxies to capture firm-specific risk; Idiosyncratic
Volatility which is the standard deviation of the residual from a regression of monthly stock returns
on the CRSP value-weighted market portfolio return, Total Volatility which is the annualized
standard deviation of monthly stock returns over the previous year, Industry_sigma which is the
average of the standard deviation of the ratio of cash flow to book value of assets over the last 10
17
It is worth noting that our un-tabulated statistics show that financially unconstrained firms (regardless of the marital
status of the CEO) have lower average cash holdings ratio than financially constrained firms. On average, financially
constrained firms have, a cash holding ratio of 19-23%, while financially unconstrained firms have, a cash holding
ratio of 8-11% (depending on a CEO’s marital status). These statistics are consistent with Han & Qiu (2007), and
Denis & Sibilkov (2009).
25
divided by the book value of total assets. We report the results of this test in Table 9.
Industry_sigma, and Leverage, respectively. Models (1) and (2) report the results for high firm-
specific risk, while models (3) and (4) report the results for low firm-specific risk. Consistent with
the results of the financial constraints test (Table 8), the coefficient estimates of Single are positive
and statistically significant only in the models of low firm-specific risk. This finding is robust
across all four measures of firm-specific risk. Since the precautionary motives are not expected to
play a vital role in determining cash holdings of the low-risk firms, these results provide strong
In this section, we investigate a few self-centered behaviors that may explain the mechanism for
the positive association between single CEOs and corporate cash holdings. Self-centered CEOs
avoidance. The traditional view suggests that corporate tax avoidance can increase shareholder
value by transferring wealth from the government to shareholders. Managers, particularly single
CEOs who suffer from higher personal income tax levels, also benefit from corporate tax
avoidance activities in the form of higher compensation because tax avoidance potentially reduces
the overall tax burden and increases the firm’s net income. Consequently, the notion that single
CEOs are more self-centered would predict a positive association between single CEO and
corporate tax avoidance, possibly enabling them to receive higher compensation. Prior studies
26
(2007), Wang (2015), Khuong et al. (2019)). Thus, we investigate the association between CEO
marital status and tax avoidance and present the results in Panel A of Table 10.
The dependent variables in Panel A of Table 10 are measures of corporate tax avoidance.
Following prior studies, we employ two different proxies for corporate tax avoidance. Our first
proxy is DTAX which is the discretionary permanent book-tax difference for firm i in year t (Frank
et al. (2009)). Following Wilson (2009), our second proxy is BTD which is the total book-tax
difference defined as book income less taxable income scaled by lagged assets. The coefficient of
Single is positive and statistically significant in all models, indicating that firms run by single
CEOs are more likely to avoid taxes than those run by married CEOs. In sum, this set of results
suggests that tax avoidance could be a potential mechanism for the higher levels of cash holdings
Next, we investigate corporate payout policy as another mechanism through which the agency
problem in firms headed by single CEOs may manifest itself. Prior studies argue that asset
liquidity, such as cash and/or cash equivalent assets is a key determinant of a firm’s dividends
policy (Holder, Langrehr, & Hexter (1998), Aivazian, Booth, & Cleary (2003), Ferreira & Vilela
(2004)). Ozkan & Ozkan (2004) suggest that there might be a positive relationship between cash
holdings and dividends. Further, Jiang & Lie (2016) argue that self-interested managers are
reluctant to disburse excess cash allowing cash levels to stockpile unless the firms face external
pressure. Motivated by these studies, we argue that the self-centered single CEOs are expected to
be more reluctant to pay dividends than married CEOs, predicting a negative relationship between
Single and measures of dividend payment. To test this conjecture, we use multiple measures of
27
ratio, dividend yield, natural log of dividends, and dividends per share. Panels B1 and B2 in Table
10 report the result of this test. We find that the coefficients of Single in all models, whether we
use the full or the PSM sample, are significantly negative, indicating that firms run by single CEOs
are less likely to pay dividends and on average, they pay lower dividends compared to otherwise
similar firms run by married CEOs. This set of results also provides evidence that higher levels of
cash held by single CEOs could be explained, at least partly, by the lower amount of dividend
payout. We note that this result is also more consistent with our classical agency problem
hypothesis.
Overall, these tests indicate that single CEOs engage in more tax avoidance and pay less
dividends compared to married CEOs, possibly to enrich themselves in the form of higher
compensation and entrench themselves through holding larger piles of cash, potentially indicating
elevated agency issues for firms headed by single CEOs. Tax avoidance and lower dividend
payouts can then be viewed as two potential underlying channels that may explain the positive
association between Single and cash holdings we report in this paper. Further, these results are
more consistent with our classical agency problem, rather than the precautionary hypothesis.
Our main result that firms with single CEOs tend to hold more cash seems to contradict the main
result of Roussanov and Savor (2014) that firms with single CEOs tend to be riskier and pursue
more aggressive investment policies. Also, their main result raises the question of how single
CEOs fund these risky projects. In this section, we provide evidence that reconciles this seeming
contradiction.
28
have a personal incentive to retain cash rather than increase dividends and that they rely on cash
and liquid assets to finance their risky projects, allowing them to avoid the market scrutiny
necessary for raising external finance. This framework predicts that compared to married CEOs,
single CEOs should raise a significantly lower amount of external finance and would rely more on
cash holdings to fund future risky and aggressive investment policies. In this section, we provide
We follow Roussanov and Savor (2014) and Guay (1999) and use R&D as a proxy for risky
investment. Roussanov and Savor (2014) argue that R&D investment is a proxy for firm risk-
taking behavior while Guay (1999) uses R&D as a measure for CEO risk-taking. We use a lead-
lag regression setup in panel A of Table 11 and compare the link between cash holdings in year t-
1 and R&D investment in year t between firms with single and married CEOs. We find that the
association between Casht-1 and R&Dt is twice as strong for firms with single CEOs (β=0.127 with
t-stat= 2.86 for the single subset vs. β=0.063 with t-stat= 3.9 for the married subset) after
controlling for the lagged value of R&D as well as a set of firm and CEO characteristics. This
result continues to hold when we control for future values of cash holdings. Removing the lagged
value of R&D or including more lags of cash does not alter this result.18 These results also reconcile
the seeming contradiction between our findings and those of Roussanov and Savor (2014). While
they show single CEOs are less risk averse and increase the riskiness of firms by pursuing
aggressive investment policies, we show that they hoard cash and rely on this internal source to
18
We have not reported these results for brevity.
29
finance to avoid market scrutiny as predicted by the agency framework. Our measure of external
finance is calculated as the sale of common and preferred stocks minus the purchase of common
and preferred stocks plus the issuance of long-term debt minus the reduction of long-term debt
(Leary and Roberts (2014)). We regress the natural log of this variable on the single dummy along
with a set of variables controlling for firm and CEO characteristics. Whether we estimate the
regression using the full sample or the PSM sample, the coefficient on the single dummy is
negative and statistically significant. Specifically, firms with single CEOs raise about 20% less
external finance than otherwise similar firms with married CEOs (β=-0.198 with t-stat= 3.20).
The stronger association between cash holdings and future R&D expenditure for firms with
single CEOs combined with significantly lower external financing by these firms and lower
dividend payout are all consistent with our classical agency problem hypothesis.
A natural question that follows immediately from the above discussion is how would the excess
cash held by single CEOs, presumably due to the agency problem, affect firm value? Prior studies
show that shareholders discount the value of excess cash holdings when there are concerns about
agency problems. For instance, Harford (1999) argues that cash-rich firms are more likely to make
diversifying acquisitions that are value-destroying and experience abnormal declines in operating
performance. In a similar vein, Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007) document that cash in poorly
find an optimal level of cash holdings and argue that deviating from that optimal level of cash
holdings decreases the firm value. Based on these arguments, we examine whether and how cash
holdings by single CEOs affect firm value. Our classical agency problem hypothesis predicts that
prior literature. First, we employ the valuation of the excess cash model following Dittmar and
Mahrt-Smith (2007), where excess cash is measured as the residual from the normal level of cash
model based on Opler, Pinkowitz, Stulz, and Williamson (1999).19 Next, we employ the valuation
models of change in, and level of, cash following Pinkowitz and Williamson (2007).20 Lastly, we
run a model that captures the association between our baseline measure of cash, Cash, and Tobin’s
Q. We run each of these valuation models of cash separately for subgroups of firms with single
The test that follows Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith’s (2007) valuation model of excess cash is
reported in Panel A of Table 12. For the PSM sample, the excess cash held by single CEOs is
valued at around 16 percent less as compared with cash held by married CEOs (β=1.191 with t-
stat= 3.73 for the single subset vs. β=1.385 with t-stat= 3.87 for the married subset.) A similar, but
more economically significant, results are reported when using Pinkowitz and Williamson’s
(2007) change in, and level, of cash valuation models which are reported in Panels B and C of
Table 12. In Panel B, the PSM coefficient estimates indicate that a lagged change in cash by single
CEOs is valued at around 30 percent less as compared to a similar change in cash by married CEOs
(β=2.195 with t-stat= 6.00 for the single subset vs. β=2.852 with t-stat= 8.45 for the married
subset.) Similarly, In Panel C, the PSM coefficient estimates indicate that cash held by single
CEOs is valued at around 30 percent less than cash held by married CEOs (β=1.733 with t-stat=
19
The specification used in this test is similar to model (2) in Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007), PP 616. Due to the
use of excess cash, this model suffers less from the endogeneity concern inherent in the other cash valuation models.
20
The specification of change in the value of cash is similar to model (1), while the specification of level of cash is
similar to model (2) in Pinkowitz and Williamson (2007), PP 76.
31
robust to the use of Tobin’s Q as an alternative measure of firm value in Panel D of Table 12.
These findings are consistent whether we use the matched sample or the full sample. The
coefficient on cash for the single subset is significantly lower (by about 50%) than that for the
married subset, indicating that the cash held by single CEOs is discounted by the shareholders.
These findings are consistent with our agency hypothesis and suggest that firms headed by single
6. Conclusion
This study examines the relationship between CEO marital status and corporate cash holdings.
Our empirical analysis provides evidence that firms headed by single CEOs hold more cash than
those by married CEOs. To address the concern that our results are driven by CEO innate
heterogeneity, rather than their marital status, we first employ a Difference-in-Differences (DiD)
estimation around the CEO turnover events and find that firms that replaced a married CEO with
a single CEO experience an increase in cash holdings. We also document the opposite effect, a
decrease in cash holdings, when a single CEO is replaced with a married one. Second, we use the
instrumental variables (IV) regression approach and find that our baseline regression results
continue to hold. Third, we use the propensity score matching (PSM) approach to address the
selection bias concern. We also test our DiD estimate for the matched sample and find consistent
results to our baseline findings. Further, we control for CEO overconfidence which has been shown
in previous research to affect corporate cash holdings. Together, these results are more consistent
with and suggestive of a causal relationship between CEO marital status and corporate cash
holdings.
32
hypotheses. To investigate the precautionary explanation of our results, we first test the association
between CEO marital status and cash holdings for financially constrained and unconstrained firms
and find robust higher levels of cash holdings for unconstrained firms with single CEOs compared
to otherwise similar firms with married CEOs. Next, we test the association between CEO marital
status and cash holdings for subgroups of firms with high vs. low levels of firm-specific risk. The
results of this test show that firms with single CEOs hold more cash than those with married CEOs
in the subsample of firms with low firm-specific risk. Together, these tests refute the possibility
that single CEOs hold cash for precautionary purposes. Consistent with the agency hypothesis, we
find that firms with single CEOs engage in more corporate tax avoidance activities, pay smaller
dividends, and hold more cash to fund future aggressive investment policies (Roussanov and Savor
(2014)). Lastly, our cash valuation models indicate that excess cash held by single CEOs is
Overall, we find a robust relationship between CEO marital status and corporate cash holdings
and argue that CEOs' marital status plays a crucial role in shaping their corporate policies. Our
results contribute to the growing literature that provides evidence that corporate policies are
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
Industry_sigma
Cash_Flow
Acquisition
Ln(Tenure)
CEO_Own
Ln(assets)
Ln(Delta)
Ln(Vega)
Leverage
Dividend
Ln(Age)
Duality
Capex
Single
NWC
R&D
Cash
MB
Single 1.00
Cash 0.13 1.00
Ln(assets) -0.20 -0.33 1.00
MB 0.02 0.39 -0.16 1.00
Leverage -0.06 -0.38 0.29 -0.27 1.00
R&D 0.07 0.53 -0.21 0.27 -0.13 1.00
Cash_Flow -0.03 -0.18 0.05 0.22 -0.17 -0.45 1.00
NWC 0.03 -0.18 -0.28 -0.11 -0.15 -0.17 0.12 1.00
Capex -0.02 -0.16 -0.05 0.06 0.03 -0.10 0.25 -0.14 1.00
Dividend -0.15 -0.35 0.36 -0.14 0.09 -0.25 0.06 0.06 -0.01 1.00
Acquisition 0.02 -0.13 0.00 -0.04 0.14 -0.03 0.02 0.01 -0.13 -0.01 1.00
Industry_sigma 0.09 0.28 -0.08 0.17 -0.18 0.22 -0.05 -0.15 -0.16 -0.20 0.05 1.00
Ln(Tenure) -0.10 0.04 -0.06 0.04 -0.05 0.01 0.05 0.06 0.04 -0.02 0.00 -0.01 1.00
Ln(Age) -0.11 -0.16 0.14 -0.12 0.06 -0.13 0.03 0.09 -0.04 0.22 -0.01 -0.09 0.32 1.00
Duality -0.14 -0.14 0.20 -0.03 0.08 -0.11 0.04 -0.02 0.00 0.16 0.00 -0.09 0.26 0.28 1.00
Ln(Delta) -0.15 0.04 0.42 0.33 -0.06 -0.03 0.23 -0.16 0.03 0.04 0.03 0.06 0.32 0.11 0.22 1.00
Ln(Vega) -0.09 -0.05 0.53 0.05 0.09 0.03 0.07 -0.21 -0.09 0.08 0.03 0.11 -0.03 -0.02 0.11 0.42 1.00
CEO_Own -0.04 0.08 -0.19 0.07 -0.09 -0.06 0.05 0.06 0.06 -0.06 -0.03 -0.04 0.30 0.11 0.12 0.43 -0.31 1.00
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53