1 Asp
1 Asp
1 Asp
Frederico Belo
University of Minnesota
Xiaoji Lin
London School of Economics and Political Science
Previous studies show that firms with low inventory growth outperform firms with high in-
ventory growth in the cross-section of publicly traded firms. In addition, inventory invest-
ment is volatile and procyclical, and inventory-to-sales is persistent and countercyclical.
We embed an inventory holding motive into the investment-based asset pricing framework
by modeling inventory as a factor of production with convex and nonconvex adjustment
costs. The augmented model simultaneously matches the large inventory growth spread in
the data, as well as the time-series properties of the firm-level capital investment, inven-
tory investment, and inventory-to-sales. Our conditional single-factor model also implies
that traditional unconditional factor models such as the CAPM should fail to explain the
inventory growth spread, although not with the same large pricing errors observed in the
data. (JEL E22, E23, E44, G12)
Inventory investment is highly volatile and positively correlated with the busi-
ness cycle. This observation has led macroeconomists to examine inventory
investment as an important driver in the propagation and the amplification of
shocks in the economy. At the same time, the asset pricing literature docu-
ments substantial variation in risk premiums over the business cycle, both in
the time series and in the cross-section. The previous facts are naturally linked
if inventory investment, like physical capital investment, responds to changes
in risk premiums, a measure of firms’ cost of capital. Thus, understanding the
economic mechanism behind these facts seems important to understand both
the business cycle itself and the variation in risk premiums over the business
cycle, which are central questions in macroeconomics and finance.
This article provides an empirical and theoretical analysis of the link be-
tween inventory investment and risk premiums in the cross-section of publicly
We thank Robert Goldstein, François Gourio, Erica Li (CEPR discussant), Selale Tuzel, Pietro Veronesi (the
editor), and Lu Zhang for helpful comments and suggestions. We are especially grateful to the anonymous
referee for constructive comments that have significantly improved the exposition of the article. We also thank
seminar participants at CEPR/Studienzentrum Gerzensee European Summer Symposium in Financial Markets,
the Econometric Society World Congress, the London School of Economics and Political Science, and the
University of Minnesota. Xiaoji Lin is thankful for the research support of Financial Market Group (FMG)
and STICERD Research Grant. All errors are our own. Send correspondence to Frederico Belo, Department of
Finance, University of Minnesota, 321 19th Avenue South, Office 3-137, Minneapolis, MN 55455; telephone:
(612) 626-7813. E-mail: [email protected].
c The Author 2011. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of The Society for Financial Studies.
All rights reserved. For Permissions, please e-mail: [email protected].
doi:10.1093/rfs/hhr069 Advance Access publication August 25, 2011
The Inventory Growth Spread
traded firms. On the asset price side, as first documented in Thomas and Zhang
(2002), there is a large inventory growth spread: Firms with low inventory
growth rates outperform firms with high inventory growth rates by a value be-
tween 6.6% (value-weighted) and 10.7% (equal-weighted) per annum. The in-
ventory growth spread is pervasive: It shows up in both small and large firms,
although it is larger among small firms. In addition, we show that the stan-
dard CAPM and, to a lesser extent, the Fama and French (1993) three-factor
model cannot explain the size of the inventory growth spread in the data. On
the real quantity side, extending previous work by Khan and Thomas (2007a)
to the firm level, we document that the inventory investment rate is volatile and
strongly procyclical, and the inventory-to-sales ratio is smooth, persistent, and
countercyclical.
To understand the empirical facts, we incorporate an inventory holding
motive into the investment-based asset pricing framework (e.g., Cochrane
1991; Zhang 2005; Cooper 2006). This framework has been successfully
used to explain several asset pricing facts and thus provides a natural frame-
work for understanding the economic determinants of the inventory growth
spread.
The macroeconomics literature has proposed several alternative mechanisms
to rationalize positive holdings of the inventory stock, typically viewed as a
zero return asset. Here, following Ramey (1989), we specify inventories as a
factor of production. Thus, like the physical capital stock, in this specification
the inventory stock provides a flow of services to the firm. This approach can be
motivated in several ways. For example, cars in the showroom are necessary to
generate sales. More generally, the existence of setup costs in the production
process makes it optimal for firms to accumulate half-completed items and
finish them in a batch job. This procedure reduces the number of periods during
which machines must be set up—that is, periods in which workers are idle and
thus unproductive.
In addition to modeling inventories as a factor of production, we consider a
flexible representation of inventory adjustment costs that includes both convex
and nonconvex costs. Adjustment costs have been shown to be important to
match several asset pricing facts both in the cross-section and at the aggregate
level, and we investigate here the importance of these costs in the context of
an investment-based model with inventory holdings.1
In the model, firms make physical capital investment and inventory invest-
ment decisions to maximize the value of the firm for shareholders. Optimal
capital and inventory investment determine firms’ dividends and market value,
thus establishing an endogenous link between the inventory investment rate
and firms’ risk. Through simulations, we then investigate if the model can en-
dogenously generate a sizable inventory growth spread, and simultaneously
1 Examples include Zhang (2005) and Li, Livdan, and Zhang (2009) in the cross-section, and Cochrane (1991)
and Jermann (1998) at the aggregate level.
279
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
280
The Inventory Growth Spread
281
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
well as the time-series properties of inventory. Our work is also related to the
large macroeconomic literature on aggregate inventory behavior and business
cycles.2 Our article contributes to this strand of literature by examining the
asset pricing implications of existent macroeconomic models as well as the
importance of nonconvex costs for matching asset pricing facts. Finally, our
work contributes to the investment-based asset pricing literature with multiple
and heterogeneous capital goods by showing the importance of inventories for
explaining cross-sectional asset pricing moments.3
The article proceeds as follows. Section 1 documents the business cycle
properties of inventory investment and its related asset pricing facts in the
cross-section. Section 2 presents the investment-based model with inventory
holdings. Section 3 calibrates the model and reports the cross-sectional mo-
ments generated from the simulation of the model, which we compare with the
real data. Section 4 provides a detailed analysis of the economic mechanisms
driving the results in the model. Section 5 concludes. An online appendix with
additional analysis and robustness checks is available from the author’s Web
pages.
1. Facts
In this section, we document the business cycle properties of inventory invest-
ment and its related asset pricing facts in the cross-section. To characterize
the business cycle facts, we document the summary statistics of firm-level in-
ventory investment, physical capital investment, sales growth, and inventory-
to-sales ratio. To characterize the asset pricing facts, we construct portfolios
sorted on the firm-level inventory growth rate, as well as portfolios two-way-
sorted on size and inventory growth rate. We then investigate the characteristics
of the portfolio’s average stock returns and perform standard asset pricing tests.
The analysis of the business cycle facts in this section complements the anal-
ysis in Khan and Thomas (2007a) for the aggregate U.S. economy (see their
Table 1). The analysis of the asset pricing facts complements the analysis in
Thomas and Zhang (2002); Lyandres, Sun, and Zhang (2008); and Jones and
Tuzel (2011).4
2 Our approach of modeling inventories as a factor of production follows that of Ramey (1989) and has also
been used in Kydland and Prescott (1982), Christiano (1988), Jones and Tuzel (2011), and several other stud-
ies. Blinder and Maccini (1991) and Ramey and West (1999) emphasize the production-smoothing motive for
holding inventories, while Kahn (1987, 1992) and Bils and Kahn (2000) focus on the stockout avoidance motive
for the firm to hold inventory. More recently, Fisher and Hornstein (2000) and Khan and Thomas (2007b) stress
the importance of (S,s) rules implied by nonconvex costs for explaining inventory investment over business
cycles.
3 For example, Bazdresch, Belo, and Lin (2010), Lin (forthcoming), and Tuzel (2010) also study economies with
multi-capital inputs (labor, R&D capital, and real estate capital, respectively).
4 Because inventory is part of accruals, the asset pricing results reported here are also related to the large literature
on the accruals anomaly initiated with Sloan (1996).
282
The Inventory Growth Spread
The results in this section provide the facts that we use to evaluate the per-
formance of the investment-based asset pricing model with inventory holdings
that we present in Section 2 below.
1.1 Data
Monthly stock returns are from the Center for Research in Security Prices
(CRSP), and accounting information is from the CRSP/Compustat Merged
Annual Industrial Files. The sample is from July 1965 to December 2009. We
exclude from the sample any firm-year observation for which total assets or
the capital stock are either zero or negative. In addition, as standard, we omit
firms whose primary standard industry classification (SIC) is between 4900
and 4999 (regulated firms) or between 6000 and 6999 (financial firms). Fol-
lowing Fama and French (1993), we require each firm to have at least two
years of data in Compustat before it is included in the sample. The data for the
three Fama–French factors (small-minus-big [SMB], high-minus-low [HML],
and market) are from Kenneth French’s Web page.
The key variable for the empirical work is the firm-level inventory invest-
ment rate. We construct this variable as follows. Total inventory stock (Nt ),
which includes raw materials, finished goods, and work-in-progress, is given
by Compustat data item INVT. We transform this variable into real terms by
dividing it by the consumer price index. Net inventory investment is given by
the change in the stock of total inventories in year t from year t −1 (Nt −Nt−1 ).
The inventory investment rate is then given by the ratio of the change in the
stock of total inventories to the beginning of the period stock of inventories
(HNt = (Nt − Nt−1 )/Nt−1 ). Thus, our inventory investment rate is effectively
the real net growth rate of total inventories of the firm. Firms that do not report
inventory holdings are excluded from the sample because the theory in this
article does not apply to those firms.
In addition, we also keep track of several other firm-level variables. To con-
struct the physical capital investment rate (IK), we measure firm-level capital
investment (It ) by data item CAPX (capital expenditures) minus SPPE (sales
of property, plant, and equipment). The physical capital stock (Kt ) is given
by data item PPENT (net property plant and equipment). The physical capital
investment rate is then given by the ratio of physical capital investment to the
beginning of the period capital stock (IKt = It /Kt−1 ) . Firms’ sales are given
by data item SALE. Real sales growth (SG) rate is thus measured by the ratio of
the change in the sales from year t to year t −1 to the sales in year t −1, deflated
by the consumer price index. The inventory-to-sales ratio (NS) is measured as
the ratio of total inventories in year t divided by sales in year t. Market eq-
uity (Size) is price times shares outstanding at the end of December of t, from
CRSP. BM is the book-equity-to-market-equity ratio, in which book equity is
computed as in Fama and French (1993). Physical-capital-to-market-equity ra-
tio (K/ME) is physical-capital stock divided by market-equity. Leverage (Lev)
283
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
Table 1
Summary statistics
Percentile Correlations
Mean S.D. AC1 10th 90th HN SG NS
IK 0.29 0.27 0.17 0.05 0.60 0.26 0.27 0.03
HN 0.04 0.33 −0.07 −0.30 0.40 1 0.43 0.25
SG 0.07 0.23 0.06 −0.18 0.33 0.43 1 −0.1
NS 0.17 0.07 0.50 0.03 0.31 0.25 −0.1 1
This table reports the mean, standard deviation (S.D.), autocorrelation (AC1), the 10th and 90th percentiles,
and the pairwise correlation of the following variables: (1) firm-level physical capital investment rate (IK),
measured by Compustat data items CAPX minus SPPE divided by PPENT; (2) net real inventory growth rate
(HN), measured by the net growth rate in Compustat data item INVT deflated by the CPI; (3) net real sales
growth rate (SG), measured by the net growth rate in Compustat data item SALE deflated by the CPI; and (4)
inventory-to-sales ratio (NS), measured by the ratio of Compustat data items INVT and SALE. To decrease the
influence of outliers, the firm-level data are winsorized at the top and bottom 1%. The data are annual, and the
sample is July 1965 to December 2009.
is book liabilities (given by total assets, Compustat data item AT, minus book
value of equity) in year t divided by the market value of the firm (market equity
plus total assets minus book value of equity).
284
The Inventory Growth Spread
285
286
Table 2
One-way-sorted inventory growth portfolios
Panel A: Returns
Low 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 High L-H MAE
Equal-Weighted Portfolios
rS 15.37 13.17 12.39 11.70 10.76 10.58 10.30 9.24 8.04 4.68 10.68
[t] 3.22 3.37 3.38 3.36 3.28 3.12 2.99 2.52 2.08 1.08 6.64
α 9.17 7.61 6.99 6.38 5.52 5.27 4.86 3.52 2.03 −1.79 10.96 5.31
[t] 3.18 3.72 3.72 3.71 3.54 3.25 2.98 2.07 1.15 −0.80 6.85
α FF 4.90 3.66 2.85 2.36 1.88 1.82 1.53 0.61 −0.75 −4.34 9.24 2.47
[t] 2.65 3.20 2.63 2.39 2.05 2.10 1.74 0.70 −0.71 −3.31 5.88
Value-Weighted Portfolios
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
rS 10.41 8.22 7.25 7.03 5.47 4.91 5.65 5.31 3.22 3.79 6.62
[t] 3.11 2.96 2.68 2.91 2.36 1.98 2.23 1.89 1.00 1.04 3.25
α 4.79 3.26 2.45 2.54 1.16 0.40 0.90 0.27 −2.36 −2.33 7.12 2.04
[t] 2.86 3.04 2.30 2.91 1.17 0.40 1.08 0.28 −2.00 −1.41 3.54
α FF 3.84 2.86 1.86 2.17 0.65 0.19 1.51 1.31 −1.06 −0.38 4.22 1.58
[t] 2.45 2.58 1.76 2.52 0.68 0.20 1.84 1.52 −0.95 −0.27 2.20
Panel B: Accounting Variables
HN −0.43 −0.18 −0.09 −0.03 0.01 0.06 0.11 0.18 0.28 0.57 −1.00
IK 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.18 0.19 0.20 0.22 0.25 0.29 0.36 −0.22
Size 3.45 3.92 4.34 4.63 4.79 4.82 4.80 4.68 4.50 4.29 −0.84
BM 0.88 0.97 0.92 0.88 0.83 0.79 0.75 0.70 0.64 0.56 0.32
K/ME 0.54 0.55 0.52 0.49 0.45 0.41 0.37 0.32 0.27 0.21 0.33
Lev 0.43 0.44 0.43 0.41 0.39 0.38 0.37 0.36 0.34 0.34 0.09
This table reports the average excess returns and alphas of ten portfolios sorted on inventory growth rate. Panel A reports the statistics for the following variables: r S is the average
annualized (×1200) excess stock return; α is the intercept from the monthly CAPM regression in annual percentage; and α FF is the intercept from the monthly Fama–French (1993)
three-factor regression in annual percentage. t are heteroskedastic and autocorrelation-consistent t-statistics. L-H stands for the low-minus-high inventory growth portfolio, and the average
returns of this portfolio is the inventory growth spread. MAE is the mean absolute pricing error. Panel B reports the time-series averages of median characteristics of the ten inventory
growth portfolios. HN is inventory growth rate, IK is the physical capital investment rate, Size is the log market capitalization, BM is the book-equity-to-market-equity ratio, K/ME is the
physical-capital-to-market-equity ratio, and Lev is the leverage ratio. The sample is from July 1965 to December 2009.
The Inventory Growth Spread
variable). Once the portfolios are formed, their value- and equal-weighted re-
turns are tracked from July of year t to June of year t + 1. The procedure is
repeated in June of year t + 1.
The results reported in column L-H of Table 3 show that the inventory
growth spread is a robust feature of the overall economy, although it is larger
among small firms. The inventory growth spread is statistically significant
across small, medium, and large firms for both equal- and value-weighted port-
folios. Across small firms, the inventory growth spread is 7.1% and 5.8% for
equal- and value-weighted portfolios, respectively. Across large firms, the in-
ventory growth spread is 3.3% and 3.8% for equal- and value-weighted port-
folios, respectively. Although the inventory growth spread for large firms is
smaller than that for small firms, the spreads are all more than 2.9 standard
errors from zero for both equal- and value-weighted portfolios.
1.3.3 Asset pricing tests. We also investigate if the spread in the average
returns across the inventory growth portfolios is explained by exposure to stan-
dard risk factors, as captured by the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) and
the Fama and French (1993) three-factor model. To test the CAPM, we run
monthly time-series regressions of the excess returns of each portfolio on a
constant and the excess returns of the market portfolio (Market). To test the
Fama-French three-factor model, we augment the previous CAPM regressions
with the SMB and HML factors.
Panel A in Table 2 reports the intercepts (alphas) for both the CAPM (α)
and the Fama–French three-factor model (α F F ) on the ten portfolios
one-way-sorted on inventory growth. The CAPM cannot explain the pattern
of the returns of these portfolios. The CAPM alphas are large and in general
statistically different from zero, especially for equal-weighted portfolios. The
CAPM mean absolute pricing errors are 5.3% per annum for equal-weighted
portfolios and 2.0% per annum for value-weighted portfolios.
The Fama-French three-factor model is more successful than the CAPM at
explaining the average returns of these portfolios, but the magnitude of the
alphas is still large and in general statistically significant, especially across
equal-weighted portfolios. The Fama–French mean absolute pricing errors are
2.5% per annum for equal-weighted portfolios and 1.6% per annum for value-
weighted portfolios. The analysis of the results for the nine portfolios two-
way-sorted on inventory growth and size reported in Table 3 is qualitatively
similar to the analysis for the one-way-sorted inventory growth portfolios, and
so its analysis is omitted here.
To sum up, the results in this section document an economically large and
statistically significant inventory growth spread: Firms with low inventory
growth significantly outperform firms with high inventory growth. This inven-
tory growth spread is pervasive across the economy: It shows up in small,
medium, and large firms, although it is larger among small firms. Finally, the
287
288
Table 3
Two-way-sorted inventory growth and size portfolios
Inventory Growth Inventory Growth Inventory Growth
Low Mid High L-H Low Mid High L-H Low Mid High L-H MAE
Equal-Weighted Portfolios
rS α α FF CAPM FF
Small 19.23 15.29 12.15 7.08 13.70 10.13 6.48 7.22 8.36 4.95 1.93 6.43 5.28 2.69
Mid 11.09 10.90 5.71 5.39 5.04 5.37 −0.58 5.63 0.87 1.10 −3.80 4.67
Big 8.81 7.74 5.56 3.25 3.22 2.49 −0.56 3.78 1.42 0.70 −1.04 2.47
t rS t(α ) tα
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
Small 3.79 3.54 2.55 5.56 4.06 3.71 2.18 5.73 3.64 2.90 0.95 5.19
FF
Mid 2.78 3.10 1.41 5.21 2.39 2.95 −0.28 5.44 0.76 1.31 −3.49 4.33
Big 2.85 2.70 1.62 3.19 2.81 2.47 −0.47 3.86 1.46 0.84 −1.08 2.70
Value-Weighted Portfolios
rS α α FF CAPM FF
Small 13.49 11.00 7.72 5.78 7.91 5.81 1.90 6.01 3.23 1.14 −2.05 5.28 3.46 1.82
Mid 10.59 10.43 5.57 5.02 4.65 5.04 −0.66 5.30 1.27 1.40 −3.28 4.55
Big 7.77 5.34 3.99 3.78 2.87 0.93 −1.39 4.26 2.63 1.06 0.34 2.28
t(r S ) t(α ) tα FF
Small 2.86 2.71 1.69 4.92 2.67 2.30 0.68 5.13 1.87 0.81 4.53
−1.25
Mid 2.83 3.14 1.46 4.54 2.43 3.02 −0.36 4.84 1.36 2.00 −3.48 3.82
Big 2.90 2.33 1.32 2.93 3.16 1.47 −1.43 3.36 2.85 1.93 0.43 1.99
This table reports the summary statistics of nine portfolios two-way-sorted on inventory growth rate and firm size. r S is the average annualized (×1200) excess stock return. α is the intercept
from the monthly CAPM regression in annual percentage. α FF is the intercept from the monthly Fama–French (1993) three-factor regression in annual percentage. t are heteroskedastic and
autocorrelation-consistent t-statistics. Low, Mid, and High stand for the sorting on inventory growth rates, and Small, Mid, and Big stand for the sorting on size (market capitalization). L-H
stands for the low-minus-high inventory growth portfolio, and the average returns of this portfolio is the inventory growth spread. MAE is the mean absolute pricing error. The sample is
monthly from July 1965 to December 2009.
The Inventory Growth Spread
inventory growth spread is not explained by standard asset pricing models such
as the CAPM and, to a lesser extent, the Fama–French three-factor model.5
where αk > 0 controls the relative weight of the two inputs in the produc-
tion process, 0 < θ ≤ 1 is the degree of returns to scale, and the parameter
ρ determines the elasticity of substitution (ES) between physical capital and
the inventory stock, defined as ES = (1 + ρ)−1 . In the limit, when ρ → 0 the
CES aggregator collapses to the standard Cobb-Douglas case, when ρ → −1
the two inputs are perfect substitutes, and when ρ → ∞ the two inputs are
perfect complements (Leontief). x t is aggregate productivity, and z t is firm’s
specific productivity.
Aggregate productivity follows the process
x
xt+1 = x(1
ˉ − ρx ) + ρx xt + σx εt+1 , (2)
5 In the online appendix for this article, we show that inventory growth retains its strong predictive power in
cross-sectional regressions that include several firm-level stock-return predictors such as the physical capital
investment rate as well as size, book-to-market ratio, momentum, asset growth, and sales growth. In addition,
we show that the inventory growth spread is mostly a within-industry effect, not a cross-industry effect.
289
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
x
where εt+1 is an independently and identically distributed (i.i.d.) standard
normal shock. Firm-specific productivity follows the process
z
z t+1 = ρz z t + σz εt+1 , (3)
z
where εt+1 is an i.i.d standard normal shock that is uncorrelated across all firms
in the economy, and εt+1 x is independent of ε z
t+1 for each firm. In the model, the
aggregate productivity shock is the driving force of economic fluctuations and
systematic risk, and the firm-specific productivity shock is the driving force of
firm heterogeneity.
In every period t, the capital stock K t depreciates at rate δk and is increased
(or decreased) by gross investment It . The law of motion of the capital stock
is given by
K t+1 = (1 − δk )K t + It , 0 < δk < 1. (4)
Following Bils and Kahn (2000) and Ramey and West (1999), net sales are
measured as
Salest = Yt − Ht ;
that is, net sales are specified by total output minus the gross investment in the
inventory stock.
2.1.2 Adjustment costs and operating fixed costs. The production activity
of the firm is subject to three different types of costs: physical capital adjust-
ment costs, inventory adjustment costs, and operating fixed costs.
Capital adjustment costs are specified by the following adjustment cost func-
tion
2
ck+
a+ Kt + 2
It
Kt Kt if It > 0
K adjt ≡ 0 if It = 0 (6)
2
ck−
a− Kt + It
Kt if It < 0,
2 Kt
where ck+ , ck− , a + , a − > 0 are constants. This specification includes both non-
convex adjustment costs, captured by the first term a +,− K t , as well as convex
2
c+,− It
adjustment costs, captured by the last term k2 Kt K t . In addition, we al-
low these costs to be asymmetric, as in Zhang (2005), to capture the fact that
290
The Inventory Growth Spread
cutting the capital stock may be more costly than expanding it. The nonconvex
costs capture the costs of adjusting capital that are independent of the size of
the investment (e.g., Abel and Eberly 2002). To scale these costs across firms
with different sizes, we make the size of the nonconvex cost to be proportional
to the firm’s size of capital stock. As standard from the q-theory of investment
literature, the nonconvex and convex capital adjustment costs include planning
and installation costs, learning the use of new equipment, or the fact that pro-
duction is temporarily interrupted.
Firms also incur in inventory adjustment costs, which are specified by the
following functional form:
+ 2
b + N + cn Ht
Nt if Ht > 0
t 2 Nt
N adjt = 0 if Ht = 0 (7)
c − 2
b− Nt + n Ht Nt if Ht < 0,
2 Nt
where cn+ , cn− , b+ , b− > 0 are constants. For symmetry, this specification is
similar to the specification of capital adjustment costs. Naturally, because the
two capital inputs are different, the adjustment cost parameters will be dif-
ferent in the two specifications as well. The convex component of inventory
adjustment cost in Equation (7) follows from Gomes, Kogan, and Yogo (2009)
and, apart from its asymmetries, it is the standard specification used in stan-
dard q-theory of investment. The nonconvex adjustment cost specification for
inventories was first proposed in Scarf (1960) and captures a fixed cost in-
curred when the firm adjusts its stock of inventories. This fixed cost includes,
for example, the number of labor hours that the firm hires to undertake in-
ventory investment, irrespective of the size of the investment. Using firm-level
U.S. data, McCarthy and Zakrajsek (2000) provide evidence that the inventory
adjustment is nonlinear and asymmetric. These features are both captured here
by the asymmetry and nonconvexity of the adjustment cost function. We dis-
cuss the magnitude of the adjustment cost parameters in the calibration section
below.
Finally, the firm also incurs in operating fixed costs of production that are
independent of firm size, which are captured by a positive parameter f . The
positive fixed cost captures the existence of fixed outside opportunity costs for
some scarce resources, such as managerial labor used by the firms.
γt = γ0 + γ1 (xt − x)
ˉ , (9)
291
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
where Mt,t+1 denotes the stochastic discount factor from time t to t + 1. The
parameters {β, γ0 , γ1 } are constants satisfying 1 > β > 0, γ0 > 0 and γ1 < 0.
According to this specification, the risk-free rate (R f,t ) and the maximum
Sharpe ratio (S Rt ) in the economy are given by
1 1 ˉ 12 γt2 σx2
R f,t = = e−γt (1−ρx )(xt −x)− (10)
E t Mt,t+1 β
q
σt Mt,t+1 2 2
S Rt = = eγt σx − 1. (11)
E t Mt,t+1
subject to the capital and inventory accumulation Equations (4) and (5) and
the flow of funds constraint (12) for all dates t. The operator Et [.] represents
the expectation over all states of nature given all the information available at
time t.
In the model, risk and expected stock returns are determined endogenously
along with the firm’s optimal production decisions. To make the link explicit,
292
The Inventory Growth Spread
where Equation (14) is the Bellman equation for the value function, the Euler
Equation (15) follows from the standard formula for stock return Rt+1 s =
cum
V cum (st+1 )/ V (st ) − Dt , and Equation (16) follows from simple algebra
−1
using Equation (15) and R f t = E t Mt,t+1 . According to Equation (16),
firms whose stock returns have a high negative covariance with the stochastic
discount factor (i.e., provide low returns when the marginal utility of consump-
tion is high) are risky, and thus the average stock returns of these firms must
be high in equilibrium to compensate investors for bearing the risk of holding
these assets.
3.1 Calibration
The model is solved at monthly frequency. Because all the quantity variables in
the data are available only at the annual frequency, we aggregate the monthly
quantity variables to the annual frequency and we calibrate the model to match
selected annual moments as closely as possible.
Table 4 reports the set of parameter values used to solve the model. The
first set of parameters specifies the technology of the firm. The second set of
parameters describes the exogenous stochastic processes that the firm faces, in-
cluding the aggregate and idiosyncratic productivity shock, and the stochastic
discount factor. The choice of the parameter values is based on the parameter
values reported in previous studies whenever possible, or by matching known
293
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
Table 4
Parameter Values
Parameter Symbol Value
Technology
Weight of physical capital in the production function αk 0.78
Returns to scale θ 0.70
Elasticity of substitution between capital and inventory ρ 0.5
Rate of depreciation for capital δk 0.01
Rate of depreciation for inventory δn 0.02
Convex parameter in capital adjustment cost ck /ck−
+ 3/30
Convex parameter in inventory adjustment cost cn+ /cn− 6.5/65
Nonconvex parameter in capital adjustment cost a + /a − 0.05/0.12
Nonconvex parameter in inventory adjustment cost b+ /b− 0.20/0.07
Operating fixed cost f 0.007
Stochastic Processes
Persistence coefficient of aggregate productivity ρx 0.951/3
Conditional volatility of aggregate productivity σx 0.007/3
Persistence coefficient of firm-specific productivity ρz 0.97
Conditional volatility of firm-specific productivity σz 0.10
Time-preference coefficient β 0.994
Constant price of risk γ0 50
Time-varying price of risk γ1 −1000
This table presents the calibrated parameter values of the baseline investment-based model.
Firm’s technology. We set the returns to scale in the production function (1)
to be θ = 0.7, roughly in the lower end of the estimates in Basu and Fernald
(1997) and Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (1995). The share of capital in
the production function is set to be αk = 0.78 and the elasticity of substitution
between capital and inventory stock to be ρ = 0.5 to match the inventory-
to-sales ratio of 17%. The capital depreciation rate δk is set as 1% per month
as in Zhang (2005). The depreciation rate of inventory is set at δn = 2% per
month, following Jones and Tuzel (2011), who argue that the depreciation rate
for inventory is higher than that of physical capital.
The empirical evidence on inventory adjustment costs is scarce. Although
intuition suggests that inventory adjustment costs are likely to be low, the
empirical evidence is mixed. Chirinko (1993) estimates inventory adjustment
costs to be small. However, Chirinko’s analysis takes the data (e.g., firms’ sales
and inventory investment) as given, and thus it ignores the importance of ad-
justment costs in a setup in which the data are endogenously determined, as we
have here. Ramey and Vine (2006) document that a typical plant in the U.S.
automobile industry closes for about 4% of the total working weeks in a typical
year due to inventory adjustments. Similarly, Hall (1996) reports average plant
shutdowns of about 8.5 weeks each year for inventory adjustments. Although
these costs have been interpreted as evidence of fixed setup costs of production
294
The Inventory Growth Spread
(e.g., the fixed cost of opening a plant for a week), they also show that inven-
tory adjustments are associated with substantial losses due to interruptions in
the production process for relatively long periods.
Since the inventory adjustment cost parameters determine the dynamics of
inventory investment, we calibrate these parameters to match as closely as pos-
sible the volatility and autocorrelation of the firm’s level inventory growth rate.
Convex adjustment costs are important in determining the volatilities, while
nonconvex adjustment costs are crucial to match the autocorrelation. We set
the convex inventory adjustment costs to be cn+ = 6.5, ck− = 65 and the non-
convex inventory adjustment costs to be b+ = 0.20, b− = 0.07. The asym-
metry in the adjustment cost function is consistent with the empirical evidence
in McCarthy and Zakrajsek (2000), who show that firm-level inventory adjust-
ment is nonlinear and asymmetric.
Similarly, we calibrate the physical capital adjustment costs to match as
closely as possible the firm-level volatility and autocorrelation of the phys-
ical capital investment rate. This exercise leads to the following combina-
tions of parameters: The convex capital adjustment costs are set to ck+ =
3, ck− = 30, and the nonconvex capital adjustment costs are set to be a + =
0.05, a − = 0.12. The asymmetry between upward and downward costs is set
to be ck− /ck+ = 10, consistent with Zhang (2005).
We set the operating fixed cost f to match as closely as possible the value
premium in the data (5.46% per annum), defined as the difference in the av-
erage value-weighted returns of the high-minus-low decile portfolio sorted on
book-to-market ratio, and at the same time generate a reasonable firm-level
physical-capital-to-market-equity ratio (K/ME) of 0.41.6
295
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
three aggregate return moments: the average real interest rate, the volatility
of the real interest rate, and the average Sharpe ratio in the U.S. economy
(approximately 0.4). This procedure yields β = 0.994, γ0 = 50, and γ1 =
−1000.
The previous parameter values specify the main calibration of the model,
which we define as the baseline model (specification 1). To help understand
the economic determinants of inventory investment and risk in the model, we
also consider six additional alternative specifications (specifications 2 to 6),
which we analyze in Section 4.
7 We do not report the mean of physical investment rate because it is pinned down by, and hence is equal to, the
physical capital depreciation rate. Similarly, the mean inventory growth and sales growth are pinned down by the
aggregate growth rate in the economy. Because there is no growth in the model, these values are approximately
zero.
296
Table 5
Data versus model-implied moments across alternative calibrations
Panel A: Real Quantities
Avg S.D. Autocorrelation Correlation
The Inventory Growth Spread
Spec. NS σ (IK) σ (HN) σ (NS) σ (SG) AC(IK) AC(HN) AC(NS) AC(SG) ρ(IK,HN) ρ(IK,SG) ρ(HN,SG) ρ(NS,SG)
Data
− 0.17 0.27 0.33 0.07 0.23 0.17 −0.07 0.50 0.06 0.26 0.27 0.43 −0.10
Baseline model
1 0.17 0.26 0.30 0.05 0.40 0.22 0.11 0.54 0.21 0.84 0.79 0.73 −0.61
Alternative specification without nonconvex inventory adj. costs (b+ = b− = 0)
2 0.76 0.23 0.21 0.27 0.33 0.36 0.50 0.72 0.29 0.90 0.77 0.77 −0.51
(continued)
297
298
Table 5
Data versus model-implied moments across alternative calibrations (cont.)
Panel B: Asset Prices
Inventory Growth Spread
Sharpe Value Equal-weighted Value-weighted
Spec. Ratio Rf σ Rf K/ME Premium All Small Mid Big All Small Mid Big
Data
− 0.43 1.80 3.00 0.41 5.46 10.68 7.08 5.39 3.25 6.62 5.78 5.02 3.78
Baseline model
1 0.41 1.84 2.78 0.32 5.58 5.56 3.92 1.59 2.80 4.61 3.78 1.57 2.40
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
This table presents selected moments in the data and implied by the simulation of the model under alternative specifications (Specifications 1 to 7). The reported statistics are averages
from 200 samples of simulated data, each with 3,600 firms and 480 monthly observations. Panel A reports firm-level moments–real quantities. It reports the mean of the inventory-to-sales
ratio (Avg NS) as well as the standard deviation, denoted by σ (.), the autocorrelation, denoted by AC(.), and the correlation, denoted by ρ(x, y), of the firm-level investment rate (IK), net
inventory growth rate (HN), inventory-to-(net) sales ratio (NS), and real sales growth (SG). Panel B reports aggregate and cross-sectional asset pricing moments: the aggregate Sharpe ratio,
the mean and the standard deviation of the risk-free rate, the physical-capital-to-market-equity ratio (K/ME), the value-weighted value premium, as well as the equal- and value-weighted
inventory growth spread across the ten one-way-sorted inventory growth portfolios (All), as well as across the portfolios two-way-sorted on inventory growth and size (Small, Mid, and Big).
The Inventory Growth Spread
8 We compute the model-implied levered return as R e = R a + Lev × (R a − R ), where R a is the return of the
t t t ft
all-equity firm in the model, R f is the risk-free rate, and Lev is the portfolio-level average leverage ratio from
Panel B in Table 2.
299
300
Table 6
Inventory growth portfolios on simulated data
Panel A: One-Way-Sorted Inventory Growth Portfolios
Low 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 High L-H MAE
Equal-Weighted Portfolios
rS 16.79 15.51 15.13 14.50 13.71 13.02 12.48 12.24 11.92 11.24 5.56
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
[t] 4.84 4.68 4.75 4.66 4.66 4.48 4.38 4.38 4.23 4.18 3.03
α 1.67 1.31 1.21 0.97 0.50 0.18 0.12 0.11 −0.06 −0.23 1.90 0.63
[t] 3.60 3.66 3.42 2.63 1.08 0.51 0.37 0.40 −0.20 −0.81 3.52
α FF 0.22 0.24 0.21 0.21 −0.18 −0.16 0.09 0.08 0.09 0.16 0.06 0.16
[t] 0.53 0.63 0.54 0.52 −0.49 −0.40 0.24 0.23 0.28 0.49 0.13
Value-Weighted Portfolios
rS 14.77 13.59 13.37 12.81 11.98 11.35 10.88 10.72 10.58 10.16 4.61
[t] 4.54 4.43 4.45 4.38 4.38 4.18 4.09 4.10 4.01 3.99 3.04
α 1.15 0.80 0.69 0.45 −0.03 −0.31 −0.33 −0.31 −0.45 −0.57 1.72 0.51
[t] 3.05 2.96 2.29 1.43 −0.07 −1.03 −1.21 −1.21 −1.63 −2.25 3.54
α FF 0.15 0.13 0.10 0.06 −0.32 −0.31 −0.03 −0.01 0.00 0.03 0.12 0.11
[t] 0.39 0.38 0.29 0.15 −0.85 −0.75 −0.12 −0.03 0.01 0.11 0.29
(continued)
Table 6
Inventory growth portfolios on simulated data (cont.)
Panel B: Two-Way-Sorted on Size and Inventory Growth Portfolios
Inventory Growth Inventory Growth Inventory Growth
Low Mid High L-H Low Mid High L-H Low Mid High L-H MAE
Equal-Weighted Portfolios
The Inventory Growth Spread
rS α α FF CAPM FF
Small 18.46 17.46 14.54 3.92 2.25 1.88 0.60 1.65 0.31 0.39 −0.08 0.39 0.85 0.17
Mid 13.92 13.58 12.33 1.59 0.71 0.51 0.10 0.61 0.21 0.03 0.16 0.05
Big 12.71 10.39 9.92 2.80 0.39 −0.59 −0.67 1.06 0.17 −0.16 −0.02 0.18
tr S t(α ) tα
Small 5.11 5.07 4.67 6.08 4.46 3.31 1.56 3.52 0.86 0.75 0.79
FF
−0.17
Mid 4.48 4.55 4.34 3.00 2.31 1.85 0.30 1.45 0.65 0.14 0.44 0.10
Big 4.25 4.03 3.97 4.66 1.15 −2.09 −3.29 2.50 0.47 −0.53 −0.08 0.41
Value-Weighted Portfolios
rS α α FF CAPM FF
Small 16.61 15.35 12.83 3.78 1.79 1.24 0.16 1.62 0.12 0.17 −0.19 0.31 0.65 0.14
Mid 12.70 12.60 11.14 1.57 0.37 0.21 −0.26 0.63 0.05 −0.11 0.07 −0.02
Big 11.75 9.67 9.35 2.40 0.13 −0.81 −0.86 1.00 0.06 −0.32 −0.17 0.24
t rS t(α ) tα FF
Small 4.87 4.75 4.39 6.19 4.44 2.72 0.55 3.59 0.36 0.39 0.65
−0.52
Mid 4.33 4.38 4.12 3.60 1.29 0.95 −0.98 1.62 0.15 −0.62 0.22 −0.03
Big 4.14 3.92 3.89 4.57 0.42 −3.32 −4.55 2.61 0.20 −1.33 −1.00 0.58
This table reports the average excess returns, alphas, and corresponding t-statistics of ten one-way-sorted inventory growth portfolios (Panel A) and nine two-way-sorted inventory growth
rate and size portfolios (Panel B), constructed from data simulated by the baseline investment-based model. r S is the average annualized (×1200) excess stock return. α is the intercept
from the monthly CAPM regression in annual percentage. α FF is the intercept from the monthly Fama and French (1993) three-factor regression in annual percentage. t are heteroskedastic
and autocorrelation-consistent t-statistics. Low, Mid, and High stand for the sorting on inventory growth rates, and Small, Mid, and Big stand for the sorting on size (market capitalization).
L-H stands for the low-minus-high inventory growth portfolio, and the average return of this portfolio is the inventory growth spread. MAE is the mean absolute pricing error. The reported
statistics are averages from 200 samples of simulated data, each with 3,600 firms and 480 monthly observations.
301
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
Figure 1
Histogram of the levered inventory growth spread across simulations
The figure shows the histogram of the equal-weighted (top panels) and value-weighted (bottom panels) levered
inventory growth spread across ten one-way-sorted inventory growth portfolios (left panels) as well across small
firms (middle panels) and big firms (right panels) generated by the baseline investment-based model with inven-
tory holdings. The histograms are based on data simulated by the model across 200 samples, each with 3,600
firms and 480 monthly observations. The arrow in each panel shows the corresponding inventory growth spread
in the real data reported in Panels A and B of Table 2.
the data is well inside the distribution of the levered inventory growth spread
generated by the model across all firms, for both equal- and value-weighted
portfolios (top and bottom left panels).
3.3.3 Asset pricing tests. Finally, we investigate if the model can replicate
the failure of the unconditional CAPM and, to a lesser extent, of the Fama and
French (1993) three-factor model in explaining the inventory growth spread.
302
The Inventory Growth Spread
Table 6 shows that the unconditional CAPM in the simulated data performs
significantly better than in the real data. Panel A shows that the model gen-
erates a pattern of abnormal returns across the ten one-way-sorted inventory
growth portfolios that is qualitatively consistent with the data: Firms with low
inventory growth rates have higher abnormal returns than firms with high in-
ventory growth rates. For equal-weighted portfolios, the CAPM alpha of the
low-minus-high spread portfolio is economically large, 1.9% per annum, and
this value is more than 3.5 standard errors from zero. For value-weighted port-
folios, the CAPM alpha of the spread portfolio is 1.7% per annum, and this
value is also more than 3.5 standard errors from zero. However, the sizes of
the CAPM alphas in the model are considerably lower than those observed
in the data. The mean CAPM absolute pricing errors in the model are 0.6%
and 0.5% per annum for equal-weighted and value-weighted portfolios, re-
spectively, whereas in the data the corresponding values are 5.3% and 2.0%.
The analysis of the results for the Fama–French three-factor model in the
simulated data, as well as the asset pricing test results across the portfolios
two-way-sorted on size and inventory growth (Panel B), is qualitatively sim-
ilar to the analysis of the unconditional CAPM across the ten portfolios
one-way-sorted on inventory growth, and so its discussion is omitted
here.
The inability of the investment-based model to quantitatively replicate the
failure of the CAPM is perhaps surprising in light of the results reported in
Gomes, Kogan, and Zhang (2003, Table 7) and Li, Livdan, and Zhang (2009,
Table 3). These studies examine a production economy with only one aggre-
gate shock, as we have here, and conclude that their theoretical models are con-
sistent with the failure of the CAPM. Specifically, using firm-level Fama and
MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions, they show that betas estimated
using standard rolling regressions (as in Fama and French 2002) based on past
return data are negatively correlated with firms’ future stock returns. In addi-
tion, standard firm characteristics such as size and book-to-market ratio have
predictive power for stock returns even controlling for the firm’s estimated
beta.
The asset pricing tests reported here are different because we test the
CAPM using the Fama–French portfolio approach, whereas the previous stud-
ies use Fama–MacBeth cross-sectional regressions. This difference is impor-
tant. Consistent with the previous studies, our model replicates the failure
of the CAPM using firm-level cross-sectional regressions as well (results re-
ported in the online appendix). As emphasized in the previous studies, the
standard empirical procedures used to estimate the unobserved time-varying
firm-level betas are subject to large measurement errors, which in turn helps
explain the weak performance of the CAPM both in the data and in the
model.
By performing the asset pricing tests at the portfolio level, the effect of
measurement errors in the betas is significantly reduced in our approach.
303
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
9 In the simulated data, the average cross-sectional correlation between firms’ inventory growth rate and condi-
tional beta is −50%. In addition, as reported in the online appendix, the standard deviation of the estimated
rolling beta is 7.65 at the firm level but only 0.88 at the portfolio level.
304
The Inventory Growth Spread
Figure 2
Inventory investment policy function
This figure plots the policy functions of gross inventory investment H (K t , Nt , xt , z t ) against the current inven-
tory stock across four alternative specifications of the investment-based model with inventory holdings: Panel A
is the baseline model with both convex and nonconvex inventory adjustment costs; Panel B is a specification with
only nonconvex inventory adjustment costs; Panel C is a specification with only convex inventory adjustment
costs; and Panel D is a specification without any inventory adjustment costs. In the plots, we fix the aggregate
productivity xt and capital K t at their respective long-run average levels of xˉ and Kˉ . The inventory stock is
normalized to be between zero and one. Each of these panels has two curves corresponding to the low firm-level
productivity z t (solid line) and high productivity z t (dashed line).
h i
10 Specifically, we can write Equation (16) in the standard expected return-beta form as E R s
h i
t t+1 = R f t + βt ×λt ,
s ,M −1
in which βt ≡ −Covt Rt+1 t,t+1 × V art Mt,t+1 is the quantity of risk of the asset, and λt ≡ R f t ×
V art Mt,t+1 is the price of risk.
305
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
Figure 3
Fundamental determinants of risk h i
This figure plots the firm’s conditional beta β(K t , Bt , xt , z t ), given by βt ≡ −Covt Rt+1 s ,M
t,t+1 ×
−1
V art Mt,t+1 , which follows from Equation (16), against the current level of inventory stock. Each panel
reports the conditional beta for the baseline model as well as for an alternative specification of the model: Panel
A is the baseline model across two different levels of productivity (high and low); Panel B is a model with only
nonconvex inventory adjustment costs; Panel C is a model with only convex inventory adjustment costs; Panel
D is a model without inventory adjustment costs; Panel E is a model with no fixed operating costs; and Panel
F is a model with two different levels of physical capital and inventory elasticity of substitution (ES) (high and
low). In Panels B to F, we fix the aggregate productivity xt , firm-level productivity z t , and physical capital K t
stock at their respective long-run average levels of xˉ , zˉ , and Kˉ . The inventory stock is normalized to be between
zero and one.
306
The Inventory Growth Spread
costs of adjusting inventory are equal to the difference between the marginal
benefits and marginal convex costs of making the adjustment. The region in-
side the thresholds is the inaction region where firms find it optimal not to
make any changes in the inventory stock. The baseline model’s implied opti-
mal inventory investment policy is close to an (s, S) type rule, which leads to
lumpiness in inventory investment.
In the model with only nonconvex inventory adjustment costs (Panel B), the
firm makes full inventory adjustments to the optimal frictionless level except
across a small range of current inventory stock (again, the inaction region) in
which the fixed costs of inventory adjustment are too large relative to the ben-
efits from adjusting the inventory stock. In the model with only convex adjust-
ment costs (Panel C), firms continuously adjust their inventory stock (except
at the point of zero inventory investment), but at a diminishing rate up to a
certain level, which gives rise to the concave policy function. Finally, without
any inventory adjustment costs (Panel D), firms always adjust to the optimal
inventory stock level.
The qualitative properties of the inventory investment policy function help
explain the poor fit of the alternative specifications 2 to 4 reported in Table 5.
Clearly, both nonconvex and convex inventory adjustment costs are crucial for
the model to match the data, both on the quantity side and on the asset pricing
side. In terms of real quantities (Panel A), specification 2 shows that by remov-
ing nonconvex inventory adjustment costs, the model counterfactually gener-
ates an investment growth rate that is too persistent (50% here versus 11% in
the baseline model and −7% in the data). Consistent with the analysis in Panel
C of Figure 2, with only convex inventory adjustment costs, firms spread the
inventory investment over time due to increasing marginal adjustment costs. In
turn, this makes the inventory investment considerably more persistent than in
the data.
The results for specification 3 show that by removing convex adjustment
costs, the model generates an investment growth rate that is too volatile (77%
here versus 30% in the baseline model and 33% in the data). Consistent with
the analysis in Panel B of Figure 2, with only nonconvex inventory adjust-
ment costs, inventory investment is lumpy, with occasional infrequent but very
large inventory investments. In turn, this makes the unconditional volatility of
inventory investment too high relative to the data. Specification 4 shows that
this unreasonably large volatility of inventory investment remains the main
problem in a specification of the model in which both convex and nonconvex
adjustment costs are eliminated.
Turning to the analysis of the effects of inventory adjustment costs on as-
set prices, Panels A to D of Figure 3 plot the firm’s conditional beta in the
baseline model and across the alternative specifications of the inventory ad-
justment cost function considered here. According to Panel A, all else equal, a
firm’s risk is decreasing in the firm’s productivity and decreases with the inven-
tory stock. Because inventory investment is increasing in productivity, this fact
307
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
helps explain the negative correlation between firms, inventory growth rates
and future returns observed in the data.
Importantly, eliminating either convex (Panel B), nonconvex (Panel C), or
both (Panel D) significantly reduces the firm’s risk relative to the baseline
model. In addition, without any inventory adjustment costs, the firm’s condi-
tional beta is flat as a function of the inventory stock. The positive relationship
between the size of adjustment costs and the firm’s risk is well known (e.g.,
Jermann 1998; Zhang 2005). In production economies, the firm’s risk is in-
versely related to its flexibility in using investment to mitigate the effect of
shocks on its dividend stream. The more flexible a firm is in this regard, the
less risky it is. The size of the adjustment costs controls the firm’s ability to
smooth its dividends, and hence controls its flexibility. Thus, here, the lower
the inventory adjustment costs a firm faces, the more flexible it is in adjusting
its stock of inventories, and thus the less risky the firm is.
Consistent with the analysis of the firm’s conditional beta in Figure 3, Panel
B of Table 5 shows that eliminating the inventory adjustment costs substan-
tially reduces the return’s spreads, and thus deteriorates the fit of the model
on the asset pricing dimension as well. Specification 2 shows that by removing
nonconvex adjustment costs, the model generates a tiny value premium (0.63%
here versus 5.58% in the baseline model and 5.35% in the data) and reduces
the inventory growth spread of both equal- and value-weighted portfolios to
about half the size of the spreads in the baseline model. Specification 3 shows
that removing convex adjustment costs has a smaller effect on spreads than
removing nonconvex costs, but the model-implied spreads are still lower than
those generated by the baseline model. Finally, when both convex and noncon-
vex adjustment costs are removed in specification 4, the model-implied spreads
are too small, especially the value premium (1.17% here versus 5.58% in the
baseline model and 5.35% in the data).
The previous analysis makes an important point about the endogenous de-
termination of risk in investment-based models with multi-capital inputs. Even
though the model has physical capital adjustment costs, which in a one-capital-
good investment-based model can endogenously generate a sizeable risk dis-
persion (e.g., the value premium in Zhang 2005), the addition of a costlessly
adjustable capital input (inventory) destroys the large risk dispersion gener-
ated by the model. Intuitively, without inventory adjustment costs, firms take
advantage of the costlessly adjustable inventory input (a storage technology)
to smooth their dividends. This extra flexibility endogenously reduces overall
risk in the economy to the point that the model loses its ability to match the
size of the stock return spreads observed in the data.
308
The Inventory Growth Spread
zero. On the real quantity side, Panel A of Table 5 shows that shutting down
operating fixed costs has a negligible impact on firm quantity moments. In
fact, the real quantity moments generated by this alternative specification of
the model are almost indistinguishable from those generated by the baseline
model. Because operating fixed costs are essentially sunk costs, these costs
have a negligible impact on the inventory investment and physical investment
policy functions.
On the asset pricing side, however, shutting down operating fixed costs has
a strong negative effect on the ability of the baseline model to match the data.
Panel E of Figure 3 shows that eliminating fixed operating costs reduces sig-
nificantly the firm’s risk relative to the baseline model. This result is con-
sistent with that of Carlson, Fisher, and Giammarino (2004), who argue that
operating leverage increases risk: When a firm is hit with negative shocks,
its operating profits fall relative to the fixed costs. As a result, cash flows
are more sensitive to aggregate shocks (see Li, Livdan, and Zhang 2009 for
a similar analysis in the context of an investment-based model with one capital
input).
Panel B of Table 5 reports the quantitative effect of eliminating the operating
fixed costs on the model’s fit. Without operating fixed costs, the value premium
is tiny (1% here versus 5.58% in the baseline model and 5.35% in the data) and
the inventory growth spread for both equal- and value-weighted portfolios is
too low, approximately half the spread in the baseline model. In addition, the
inventory growth spread is slightly larger across larger firms than across small
firms, in sharp contrast with the data. This suggests that operating fixed costs
are especially important for the risk dispersion across small firms, consistent
with the analysis in Li, Livdan, and Zhang (2009).
Finally, without operating fixed costs, the model generates firm values that
are too large, reflected by the low average physical-capital-to-market-equity
ratio (18% here versus 32% in the baseline model and 41% in the data). Taken
together, these results show that without operating fixed costs, the overall risk
in the economy is reduced, which generates small stock return spreads as well
as firm-level market values that are too high due to low discount rates.
309
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
ratio: When the ES is low, firms hold too much inventory (average inventory-
to-sales ratio of 21%), and when the ES is high, firms hold too few inven-
tories (average inventory-to-sales ratio of 10%), relative to the data (average
of 17%). In addition, when the ES is high, the inventory growth volatility is
higher.
The most interesting analysis is the effect of the ES on firms’ risk. Panel F
of Figure 3 shows that, all else equal, firms’ risk decreases with the elasticity
of substitution between physical capital and inventory stock. This result is in-
tuitive. When the ES between the two inputs is high (i.e., capital and inventory
are more substitutable), firms are more flexible because they can use relatively
more of the capital input with lower adjustment costs to smooth the impact
of shocks on dividends. As a result, firms’ overall risk is lower when the ES
is high. Consistent with this analysis, Panel B of Table 5 shows that, all else
equal, the magnitude of the inventory growth spread is negatively related with
the size of the ES: Relative to the baseline model, the inventory growth spread
is higher with a low ES, and the spread is lower with a high ES.
5. Conclusion
We incorporate an inventory holding motive into the investment-based asset
pricing framework by modeling inventory as a factor of production subject to
convex and nonconvex adjustment costs. The model replicates the large inven-
tory growth spread observed in the data, as well as the firm-level properties
of physical capital investment, inventory investment, and inventory-to-sales
ratio. Our conditional single-factor model also implies that traditional fac-
tor models such as the CAPM and, to a lesser extent, the Fama and French
(1993) three-factor model should fail to explain the inventory growth spread,
although not with the same large pricing errors observed in the data. This result
suggests that introducing additional sources of aggregate risk in the standard
investment-based model may be necessary to capture the size of the CAPM
violation observed in the data.
Our results have implications for both the asset pricing and the macroeco-
nomics literatures. For asset pricing, our results, based on a model with ratio-
nal expectations and firm value maximization, suggest that the large inventory
growth spread observed in the data is in principle consistent with a risk-based
interpretation. Firms with low inventory investment rates have a high cost of
capital (risk), which explains the high average returns of these firms in the data.
For the macroeconomics literature, our results show that time-varying risk is
an important determinant of inventory investment. Given the importance of
inventory investment in business cycle fluctuations, our results suggest that in-
corporating time-varying risk premiums in current macroeconomic models of
inventory behavior is important for an accurate understanding of the inventory
investment dynamics over the business cycle and how inventory investment
propagates and amplifies the effect of shocks in the economy.
310
The Inventory Growth Spread
References
Abel, A., and J. C. Eberly. 2002. Investment and q with Fixed Costs: An Empirical Analysis. Working Paper,
University of Pennsylvania.
Basu, S., and J. G. Fernald. 1997. Returns to Scale in U.S. Production: Estimates and Implications. Journal of
Political Economy 105:248–83.
Bazdresch, S., F. Belo, and X. Lin. 2010. Labor Hiring, Investment, and Stock Return Predictability in the
Cross-section. Working Paper, University of Minnesota and London School of Economics and Political Science.
Belo, F. 2010. Production-based Measures of Risk for Asset Pricing. Journal of Monetary Economics 57:146–63.
Bils, M., and J. A. Kahn. 2000. What Inventory Behavior Tells Us About Business Cycles. American Economic
Review 90:458–81.
Blinder, A. S., and L. J. Maccini. 1991. Taking Stock: A Critical Assessment of Recent Research on Inventories.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 5:73–96.
Burnside, C., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo. 1995. Capital Utilization and Returns to Scale. NBER Macroeco-
nomics Annual 10:67–110.
Campbell, J., and J. Cochrane. 1999. By Force of Habit: A Consumption-based Explanation of Aggregate Stock
Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy 107:205–51.
Carlson, M., A. Fisher, and R. Giammarino. 2004. Corporate Investment and Asset Price Dynamics: Implications
for the Cross-section of Returns. Journal of Finance 59:2577–603.
Chen, L., R. Novy-Marx, and L. Zhang. 2011. An Alternative Three-factor Model. Working Paper, Ohio State
University.
Chirinko, R. S. 1993. Multiple Capital Inputs, Q , and Investment Spending. Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control 17:907–28.
Christiano, L. 1988. Why Does Inventory Investment Fluctuate So Much? Journal of Monetary Economics
21:247–80.
311
The Review of Financial Studies / v 25 n 1 2012
Cochrane, J. H. 1991. Investment-based Asset Pricing and the Link Between Stock Returns and Economic
Fluctuations. Journal of Finance 46:209–37.
Cooley, T. F., and E. C. Prescott. 1995. Economic Growth and Business Cycles. In Thomas F. Cooley (ed.),
Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.
Cooper, I. 2006. Asset Pricing Implications of Nonconvex Adjustment Costs and Irreversibility of Investment.
Journal of Finance 61:139–70.
Fama, E. F., and K. R. French. 1992. The Cross-section of Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Finance 47:427–
65.
. 1993. Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds. Journal of Financial Economics
33:3–56.
Fama, E. F., and J. D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests. Journal of Political
Economy 81:607–36.
Fisher, J., and A. Hornstein. 2000. (S,s) Inventory Policies in General Equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies
67:117–45.
Gomes, J. F., L. Kogan, and M. Yogo. 2009. Durability of Output and Expected Stock Returns. Journal of
Political Economy 117:941–86.
Gomes, J. F., L. Kogan, and L. Zhang. 2003. Equilibrium Cross-section of Returns. Journal of Political Economy
111:693–732.
Hall, G. 1996. Nonconvex Costs and Capacity Utilization: A Study of Production and Inventories at Automobile
Assembly Plans. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.
Jermann, U. 1998. Asset Pricing in Production Economies. Journal of Monetary Economics 41:257–75.
Jones, C., and S. Tuzel. 2011. Inventory Investment and the Cost of Capital. Working Paper, University of
Southern California.
Kahn, J. A. 1987. Inventories and the Volatility of Production. American Economic Review 77:667–79.
. 1992. Why Is Production More Volatile Than Sales? Theory and Evidence on the Stockout Avoidance.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:481–510.
Khan, A., and J. Thomas. 2007a. Explaining Inventories: A Business Cycle Assessment of the Stockout Avoid-
ance and (S,s) Motives. Macroeconomic Dynamics 11:638–64.
. 2007b. Inventories and the Business Cycle: An Equilibrium Analysis of (S,s) Policies. American Eco-
nomic Review 97:1165–88.
Kogan, L., and D. Papanikolaou. 2010. Growth Opportunities and Technology Shocks. American Economic
Review, Papers and Proceedings 100:532–36.
Kydland, F., and E. Prescott. 1982. Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations. Econometrica 50:1345–70.
Li, E. X. N., D. Livdan, and L. Zhang. 2009. Anomalies. Review of Financial Studies 22:4301–34.
Lin, X. Forthcoming. Endogenous Technological Progress and the Cross-section of Stock Returns. Journal of
Financial Economics.
Liu, L. X., T. M. Whited, and L. Zhang. 2009. Investment-based Expected Stock Returns. Journal of Political
Economy 117:1105–39.
Lyandres, E., L. Sun, and L. Zhang. 2008. The New Issues Puzzle: Testing the Investment-based Explanation.
Review of Financial Studies 21:2825–55.
312
The Inventory Growth Spread
McCarthy, J., and E. Zakrajsek. 2000. Microeconomic Inventory Adjustment: Evidence from U.S. Firm-level
Data. Working Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
McGrattan, E. R. 1999. Application of Weighted Residual Methods to Dynamic Economic Models. In Ramon
Marimon and Andrew Scott (eds.), Computational Methods for the Study of Dynamic Economies. Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press.
Patton, A. J., and A. Timmermann. 2010. Monotonicity in Asset Returns: New Tests with Applications to the
Term Structure, the CAPM, and Portfolio Sorts. Journal of Financial Economics 98:605–25.
Ramey, V. A. 1989. Inventories as Factors of Production and Economic Fluctuations. American Economic Re-
view 79:338–54.
Ramey, V. A., and D. Vine. 2006. Declining Volatility in the U.S. Automobile Industry. American Economic
Review 96:1876–89.
Ramey, V. A., and K. D. West. 1999. Inventories. In M. Woodford and J. Taylor (eds.) Handbook of Macroeco-
nomics, pp. 863–922. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.
Rouwenhorst, K. G. 1995. Asset Pricing Implications of Equilibrium Business Cycle Models. In Thomas Cooley
(ed.), Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Scarf, H. 1960. The Optimality of (S,s) Policies in the Dynamic Inventory Problem. In K. J. Arrow, S. Karlin,
and H. Scarf (eds.), Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Sloan, R. G. 1996. Do Stock Prices Fully Reflect Information in Accruals and Cash Flows About Future Earn-
ings? Accounting Review 71:289–315.
Tauchen, J., and R. Hussey. 1991. Quadrature-based Methods for Obtaining Approximate Solutions to Nonlinear
Asset Pricing Models. Econometrica 59:371–39.
Thomas, J. K., and H. Zhang. 2002. Inventory Changes and Future Returns. Review of Accounting Studies 7:
163–87.
Tuzel, S. 2010. Corporate Real Estate Holdings and the Cross-section of Stock Returns. Review of Financial
Studies 23:2268–302.
Vuolteenaho, T. 2001. What Drives Firm-level Stock Returns? Journal of Finance 57:233–64.
Whited, T. 1994. Problems with Identifying Adjustment Costs from Regressions of Investment on QQ. Eco-
nomics Letters 46:339–44.
Wu, J., L. Zhang, and F. Zhang. 2010. The q -theory Approach to Understanding the Accrual Anomaly. Journal
of Accounting Research 48:177–223.
313
Copyright of Review of Financial Studies is the property of Society for Financial Studies and its content may
not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written
permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.