Document 8FCE9E11
Document 8FCE9E11
Document 8FCE9E11
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Indiana University Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to
Africa Today
John Prendergast
John Prendergast is a Research Associate with the Center of Concem, 3700 13th Street NE, Washington, D.C. 20017, and
co-coordinator of the Coalition for Peace in the Hom of Africa.
Consequences of Coaditionalities
1. Economist Intelligence Unit, Sudam Coutry Profile, EIU, Great Britain, 1989, Section 0.
2. Edward Jaycox, 'What Can Be Done in Africa?, in Berg, Robert, Strategies for African Developmet (Berkeley: U. of
Califomia Press, 1986), p. 20.
3. Fantu Cheru, The Slent lRevolitio. In Africa: IMF CoaditomUty or D_nocrac (London: Zed Press, 1988), p. 241.
44 AFRICA TODAY
and deep-ploughed the soil. After a few years without fertilizer, crop yieids
fell below profitable levels and the exhausted and eroded land was abandoned,
while the lease-holders moved on to repeat the cycle elsewhere, leaving
behind landless laborers or migrant workers who were employed on the farm
'The results have been poverty for the displaced farmers, ruined aIn? , pT'.it
for the elite, a good political return for the then Nimeiry government and plent
of sorghum for export to the Middle East - but not much food for poor
Sudanese. The schemes are still continuing"4
Displaced pastoralists have fought unsuccessfully, and s-om efmes
violently, to retain access to their grazing lands. After being forcibly removed
most sought new pastures, often in areas already used by other pastoralists
or smallholders, or else shifted to increasingly marginal ecological zones.
Bloody conflicts over land ensued, particularly in Blue Nile, White Nile, Upper
Nile, and Southern Kordofan provinces.5 Pastoralists are often then the direct
agents of the depletion of fallow and scrub and receive much of the official
blame for the encroachment of the desert, estimated at 10 km per year.6 As
conflict rather than cooperation has come to dominate most relations between
settled and nomadic peoples, herds have come to be barred from agricultural
fields, which consequently lose the fertilizing benefits of their manure.7
Ignoring the disadvantages of dependence on one export, the
extraordinary fluctuation of commodity prices in the world market,
imbalance between price levels for commodity exports and manufactured
imports, the World Bank in 1978 plunged support into the cotton-dominated
Agricultural Rehabilitation Program (ARP). This program included the
overhaul of the government owned Gezira Scheme, the world's largest farm
under single ownership and the major producer of Sudan's long and medium
staple cotton.
Although Bank reports point to increased cotton production as proof of
the success of the ARP, they fail to note that the increase in production per
farm has actually declined. Overall export earnings, meanwhile, have fallen
by 15 percent. In addition, the production of Sudanese cotton, a regular victim
of a fluctuating world market, bears an import dependence of 43 percent.
Although the six IMF-imposed devaluations implemented between 1978 and
1985 may have had the effect of making the country's exports more attractive
4. Nick Cater, Sudan: The Boots of Famine (Oxford: Oxfam, 1986), p. 22.
5. K. el Medani, The Impact of Economic Deveiopment on the Ethnic Groups lshabiting al Reuk Region, thesis, University
of Khartoum, 1978.
6. Jan O'Brien, 'Sowing the Seeds of Famine: the Political Economy of Food Deficits in the Sudan," Reiew of African Poltial
Economy 33, 1986, p. 197.
7. Richard Franke and Barbara Chasin, Seeds of Famine (Totowa, NJ: Allan Held Publishers, 1980), p. 46.
2. Devaluation
The rationale for currency devaluations as part of structural adjustment
packages are three-fold; to stimulate export production, curtail import
demand, and discourage the black market. Yet despite six major devaluations
since 1978, the balance of payments, inflation and the budget were not
affected as projected. The current account deficit went from six percent of GDP
in 1977 to eleven percent in 1983.11
One of the reasons devaluation failed to improve the performance of
exports was that the price of cotton declined in the world market. This is no
fluke. "Many of these [developing] countries produce more or less the same
commodities for export. With the sort of competitive devaluation the Fund
seems to encourage among them, we have witnessed continuous increases
8. Gayle Smith, Case Studr:. Sida (Washington, D.C.: Development Group for Alternative Policies, 1989), p. 8.
9. Ibid.
10. Ibid.
11. World Bank, Sudaa: Mecag hie.s and Stuctural Ialmce, 1983, p. 218.
46 AFRICA TODAY
in output and export volumes, but reduced foreign exchange earnings. The
net beneficiaries are the developed countries importing these commodities"12
Another reason for the decline in export performance was the fear on
the part of producers that they would not get govemment support for essential
inputs. Irrigation, which is highly import dependent, suffered from import
restrictions and foreign exchange shortages resulting from devaluations. Credit
was less available because of credit ceilings. "Thus a devaluation without the
backing of considerable foreign exchange for inputs resulted directly in
shortages throughout the production structure and led to a contraction of the
economy"13.
3. Balancing Budgets
Attempts to reduce government expenditure have caused increased
suffering and instability. Development and social service spending were cut
in half during the adjustment period of 1978 to 1985, leading to a decline
in nutritional standards and access to health care, clean water, and affordable
food supplies. On the other hand, expenditures for general administration
and defense more than tripled during this same period. 14
The IMF Stabilization Program maintained through 1985 exacted a high
price and met with sweeping resistance. IMF-imposed austerity measures
which abohished subsidies on basic commodities provoked major riots in 1982,
and in 1985 demonstrators against bread and sugar price hikes chanted "We
will not be ruled by the World Bank! We will not be ruled by the IMF!" Those
demonstrations marked the beginning of a ten day popular uprising that
unseated the Nimeiri government and, for a time, ended IMF involvement
in the country.
12. E.IM. Mtei, 'Comments,' in Africa amd the IMF, Gerald Hellinger, ed., (Washington, D.C.: IMF, 1985), p. 98.
13. D. Hansohm, 'The 'Success' of IMF/World Bank Policies in Sudan,' in World Rose#lom amd the African Food Crb1a,
(Birmingham: James Currey Ltd., 1986), p. 153.
6. Pricing policy
To stimulate production, higher farm-gate prices have been offered to
producers. By giving higher prices ostensibly to producers, in Sudanese reality
the big traders are being enriched, not the farmers. The trader's position is
enforced by the lack of alternative credit sources. No coordinated serious
attempts have been made to control this wasteful and destructive speculation.
7. Economic Indicators
None of the IMFs stabilization objectives were met during the seven year
period from 1977-8 to 1983-4. The results:
'(A) in terms of balance of payments:
- the current account deficit increated from 6% of GDP in
1977-8 to 11% in 1983-4
- officially estimated total foreign debt increased from US $2
bn to US $8 bn (1984)
18. Mannshya Hu Case Study: Sudan: in IMF ComdItIomilty aad Stabiliuatloa Policies: Sudan, Brazil, md Megco
(Ann Arbor, MI: University Microfilms Intl, 1988), p. 86.
48 AFRICA TODAY
- the debt service ratio rose from 19% (1978) to over 150%
(1984)
- the Sudanese pound depreciated to 27% of its pre-1978
value
- the multiple exchange rate system remained intact, with
gaps between the various rates having been widened
"(B) in terms of the domestic economy:
- GDP declined in real terms, and GDP per capita fell from
US $483 to US $344
- Gross national savings became negative, falling from about
2% of GNP to 0.3% in 1982-3
- the growth of the money supply increased to almost 60%
in 1983-4 in comparison to less than 30% before 1978
- the government's budgetary recurrent deficit rose from 5 to
9% of GDP
- the annual rate of inflation rose from 20% to over 40% in
1982-3.719
The economic analysis that leads to IMF and World Bank presciptions
is based on an ideological model of the Sudanese economy that is
fundamentally flawed. Its basic assumptions are:
A) the free play of market forces will produce an acceptable pattern
of investment, production, and trade;
B) internal and external imbalances (inflation and balance of
payments deficits) are caused by excessive intemal demand; and
C ) 'market forces will be able to produce a sustained growth in
production and employment, if not disturbed by government
intervention or inflation'"20
The IMF/World Bank analysis of the 'mismanagement of the Sudanese
economy fundamentally misreads what the 'state' really is in Sudan. State
policies do not represent the general interest of the Sudan but the interests
of a few social groups; the military, the national capitalists, and the state
employees. The states shrinking economic and social basis restricts its options
greatly. The overall policy aim of 'developmenf has been replaced by the fight
for survival of the government.21
19. R. Brown, 'The Rationale and Effects of the IMF Stabilization Programme in Sudan," in Pblitical Dimeseloms of the
iateartioal Dekt Crisi B. Campbell, ed., International Political Economy Series (London: Macmillan, 1988), p. 28.
20. Richard Tetzlaff, The World Bak: Powr lstrunteat of the USA or Aid for Developing Couatries, (Munchen, Koln:
Weltforum Verlag, 1980), p. 249.
For seven years the IMF fulfilled three major functions in Sudan. F
it conducted a 'holding operation' until 1985 by negotiating stand-by
agreements with the government during each of a series of balance-of-
payments crises, despite the fact that its own conditions had not been met.
Second, it coordinated the international donor bail-out of the Nimeiri regime.
During negotiations for Sudan's 1984-85 stand-by agreement with the Fund,
for example, the U.S. Agency for International Development (USAID) twice
intervened and paid Sudan's outstanding debt to the IMF, only to be repaid
with IMF funds when the agreement was finally negotiated. Third, successive
IMF-Sudanese government agreements paved the way for the increased
bilateral funding that helped keep the Nimeiri government in power.
The people of Sudan are unlucky to have been born in a region the U.S.
considers strategic. Up until the last year (1985) of large scale IMF involvement,
the U.S. used the IMF to legitimize and facilitate the flow of external resources,
for the following reasons. First, the Reagan Administration was still deeply
immersed in its 'Evil Empire" approach to the Soviets, who were still firmly
committed to their invasion of Afghanistan. Second, the Iran-Iraq war
continued to rage, jeopardizing oil supplies to the West. Third, U.S. policy-
makers felt that Sudan's neighbors, Ethiopia, Libya, and South Yemen,
represented a menacing threat to U.S. interests in the Red Sea and Gulf of
Aden. Fourth, Presidents Nimeiri in Sudan and Siad Barre in Somalia were
seen as reliable U.S. allies who could help ensure the free flow of oil, the
containment of regional anti-Western adventurism, and access to air fields and
harbors for U.S. military forces. Fifth, Nimeiri was the only African head of
State other than President Anwar Sadat, who was a party to the agreement,
to support the Camp David accords. And last, Sudan controls the flow of the
Nile River northward to water-starved U.S ally Egypt.
50 AFRICA TODAY
In February 1986, less than a year after Nimeiri was overthrown, the IMF
declared Sudan ineligble for further borrowing due to the government's
inability to settle its arrears to the Fund. Despite this, the IMF has maintained
'its role as mediator in the management of Sudan's balance of payments crisis,
and between the donor community and the Sudanese Government.23 In
July, 1987, a 'Program of Action' was jointly prepared by the Government
and the IMF, detailing the same mix of policies as the usual stand-by
arrangements.
Even without U.S. pressure, it is impossible for the IMF to simply walk
away from the nearly $1 billion arrears the Sudanese Government owes.
Consequently the Fund is again at the negotiating table with the current
government of General Bashir. Exchange rates, price decontrol, and
privatization are on the agenda, with a view to a resumption of payments on
arrearages and the development of a structural adjustment program.
Structural Transformation
26. P. Oesterdiekhoff, see The Developnent Peapectves of the Sudan, (Munchen, Koln: Wetforum Verlag, 1983) G. Hunter,
Ealsting the Snail Farmer the Rasge of Requirenta, (London: John Bennet, Overseas Development Institute, 1982),
The Hunger Machine, (Cambridge: Polity Press, 1980).
52 AFRICA TODAY
28. United Nations Economic Commission on Africa, Afrca. AltermtIve Fraa.wok for Stuctal Adjuatm t Program.
(New York: UNECA, 1989), Table 5.2, p. 38.