Reading 5. Is Quantity Theory Still Alive
Reading 5. Is Quantity Theory Still Alive
Reading 5. Is Quantity Theory Still Alive
This article investigates whether the quantity theory of money is still alive. We demonstrate three
insights. First, for countries with low inflation, the raw relationship between average inflation and the
growth rate of money is tenuous at best. Second, the fit markedly improves, when correcting for
variation in output growth and the opportunity cost of money, using elasticities implied by the
* Corresponding author: Pedro Teles, Banco de Portugal, DEE, Av. Almirante Reis 71, 1150-012, Lisbon,
Portugal. Email: [email protected].
Uhlig’s research has been supported by the NSF grant SES-0922550 and by a Wim Duisenberg fellowship at
the ECB. Teles gratefully acknowledges the financial support of FCT. Uhlig has an ongoing consulting
relationship with a Federal Reserve Bank, the Bundesbank and the ECB. The views here are entirely our own.
[ 442 ]
[ M A R C H 2016] IS QUANTITY THEORY STILL ALIVE? 443
and inflation indeed markedly improves. An even better fit is obtained when using the
(lower) elasticity value suggested by Miller and Orr (1966). We finally estimate the
relationship and find just a small improvement over the Miller–Orr specification.
The estimation of money demand has been under debate recently. The 1990s and
2000s have been testing decades for it, see in particular the discussion in Ball (2001),
Carlson et al. (2000), Coenen and Vega (2001), Ireland (2009), Lucas and Nicolini
(2015), Sargent and Surico (2011) and Teles and Zhou (2005). Motivated mostly by
Ireland (2009) and Sargent and Surico (2011), we split the data into two parts,
choosing as split point for each country the dates coinciding with the implicit or
explicit adoption of inflation targeting.1 We also consider 1990 as an alternative
1
We thank a referee for this suggestion.
2
The Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act of 1980 and the Garn–St Germain
Depository Institutions Act of 1982.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
444 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH
described in Appendix A. Online Appendices and a .zip file provide further graphs and
tables, as well as the data used and the programs for calculating all results.
We conclude that quantity theory is still alive. Whether it should be used as a guide to
long-term monetary policy is more debatable and certainly beyond the scope of this
article. Woodford (2008) has argued that there is no independent role for tracking the
growth rate of money, if a central bank is already willing and able to stabilise inflation
rates at short and medium-term horizons, without making an explicit use of monetary
aggregates. The practice of central banks seems to be reassuring, that it is possible to
keep inflation low using, as it appears to be the case, some form of interest rate feedback
1. The World
Teachers of intermediate macroeconomics may have consulted Barro (1993, 2007) in
order to teach students the relationship between money growth rates and inflation. His
Figure 7.1 in the 1993 edition shows a large sample of countries, and plots this
relationship, having calculated the growth rates of money and prices from, typically,
the 1950s to 1990. The Figure is reproduced here as Figure 1: one apparently gets a
nice fit to the 45 degree line.
However, that picture turns out to be misleading and mainly driven by high inflation
countries. Concentrating on the subset of countries we analyse, whose inflation rates
80
70
Inflation in Percent per Year
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
0 20 40 60 80
Money Growth in Percent
NZ
AU
6
Inflation
IT
DK
CA
AT FIN
CH DEJP UK
NL
2
0
0 5 10 15 20
Money Growth
were all below 12%, the points no longer assemble nicely around a straight line, but
produce a rather randomly looking scatter plot with all the points below the 45 degree
line, see Figure 2. The question is thus: is the relationship between money growth and
inflation too loose to be of any relevance for low inflation countries?
These pictures should be considered disturbing by anybody who believes in a tight
relationship between money growth and inflation and bases monetary policy advice on
such a belief. Additional issues may be of relevance at low rates of inflation, however. In
particular, GDP growth, changes in interest rates, technological progress in transaction
technologies as well as production may make a difference. We next discuss how these
can be taken into account.
3
See also Lucas (2000).
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
446 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH
st ¼ lðAt1 ct ; mt Þ; (1)
where At measures progress in the transactions technology.
Given ct, the agent will want to minimise the cost of transactions, wtst + Rtmt, subject
to (1), where wt is the wage rate and Rt is the opportunity cost of holding money, the
nominal interest rate. The marginal condition:
wt lm ðAt1 ct ; mt Þ ¼ Rt (2)
will have to hold.
Let the transactions function l be:
1 a 1 a
log mt ¼ B log Rt þ log ct þ log wt log At ; (4)
1b 1b 1b 1b
with B = log (gb)/(1b).
To make contact with the data, we wish to examine a panel of countries i = 1, . . ., N
and a time period t = 1, . . ., T. For a country i and a variable xi,t, generally denote
the sample growth rate of that variable between time one and time T with
Dxi ¼ ðlog xi;T log xi;1 Þ=T :
Equation (4) implies:
1 a 1 a
DM
i Di ¼
P
DRi þ Dci þ Dwi DA ; (5)
1b 1b 1b 1b i
in which DM i is the average growth rate of the stock of nominal money in country i and
DPi is the average inflation in that country. This suggests that the long-run relationship
between money and prices ought to be corrected by the variation of nominal interest
rates and by the growth rates of consumption, as a measure of transactions, real wages
and technical progress in transactions. There are implications from the transactions
technology for the relevant elasticities. For instance, for the Baumol–Tobin, with a = 1
and b = 1, the interest elasticity would be one half, and so would be the elasticity to
the growth rate of consumption. For the Miller–Orr technology (a = 2 and b = 2),
the two elasticities are one third and two thirds, respectively.
Before taking the theoretical relationship to the data, we take two further steps. The
first is to use balanced growth to impose that the average growth rate of consumption is
y
equal to the growth rate of real wages, and to the growth rate of output, Di :
y
Dci ¼ Dwi ¼ Di : (6)
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
2016] IS QUANTITY THEORY STILL ALIVE? 447
Notice that with this assumption, the relationship between money and prices is to be
corrected by the growth rate of output with an elasticity of (1 + a)/(1 b). This long-
run elasticity is equal to one for both Baumol–Tobin and Miller–Orr technologies.4
The second step is to assume that the cross-country level shift in the transactions
technology can be captured by a random fixed effect:
a
DA ¼ i ; (7)
1b i
y
where we assume, and this is a strong assumption, that ei is independent of Di and DRi .
With this assumption as well as with (6), we obtain the empirical specification:5
y 1 R
DM
i Di ¼ Di Di i
P
(10)
2
for the Baumol–Tobin specification and
y 1 R
i Di ¼ Di Di i ;
DM P
(11)
3
for the Miller–Orr specification.
4
The unit elasticity of the money demand to output in typical formulations of the money demand, as in
Lucas (2000), is a feature of long-run growth.
5
The specification in (8) is log-log in contrast to a semi-log specification. See the discussion in Bailey
(1956) and Ireland (2009).
6
In earlier versions of this article, we also experimented with M2 and M3, as well as long rates: the data problems
there were generally greater, but preliminary results looked rather similar to the results documented here.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
448 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH
1970*−2005
15
10
PT
Inflation
ES KR
NZ
AU
US CAIE
FR
AT FIN JP
CH DE UK
NL
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
maturity (MZM) could be used. Unfortunately, they are not readily available and are
reliable only in a few countries. The same applies to divisia indices (Barnett, 1980;
Barnett and Serletis, 2000). More information on the data as well as explanations for
the short codes used to denote countries, can be found in Appendix A.
Figure 3 ‘corrects’ the money growth rate by subtracting the GDP growth rate. The
points scatter loosely below the 45-degree line. Figure 4 removes the yield effect with the
coefficient of 0.5 on the interest rate change as suggested by the Baumol–Tobin
specification (10), as well as suggested by Lucas (2000) and close to the one estimated for
Italy by Alvarez and Lippi (2009). The correction with the yield considerably improves
the fit, shifting the data points upwards, that now line up nicely along the 45-degree line.
Figure 5 contains the result for the Miller–Orr specification, while Figure 6 finally
contains the correction implied by estimating (8) with c = 1 and including a constant,
using as variables the averages from 1970 until 2005, per ordinary least squares.7
Information about the quality of fit, by calculating an R2 and the variances of ei is in
Table 1, including results for subsamples, see Section 3. The results from the regression
imposing c = 1 are in Table 2, including results for subsamples, see also Section 3. Full
results with c unrestricted can be found in the online Appendices. The estimated interest
rate elasticity is below the Baumol–Tobin and Miller–Orr values. For the full sample, the
7
We provide results including a constant, which would not be motivated by the theory above but instead
by the desirability to control (if one thinks in the equation in levels) for movements in velocity not captured
by changes in the interest rates, due, e.g. to financial innovation.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
2016] IS QUANTITY THEORY STILL ALIVE? 449
1970*−2005
15
10
PT
Inflation
ES KR
NZ
AU
CA
FR IE
US
AT
FIN
CHJP DE UK
NL
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
Baumol–Tobin fits worse than the other three specifications that control for yields, all of
which provide essentially the same quality of fit.
We complement this analysis with the estimation of the following panel cointegra-
tion model:
Mit
log ¼ a0;i þ a1 t þ c logðYit Þ a logðRit Þ þ uit ; (12)
Pit
with
logðYit Þ
D ¼ k0;i þ vit ; (13)
logðRit Þ
0
where D is the first-difference operator. wit := (uit,vit) is possibly serially correlated but
assumed independent across i = 1, . . ., N. (1, c,a) is a cointegrating vector and the
equilibrium error (log(Mit/Pit) c log(Yit) a log(Rit)) is allowed, in its most
general configuration, to have country-specific fixed effects and a common time
trend. Interestingly, panel tests indicate clearly that log(Mit/Pit), log(Yit) and log
(Rit) are integrated of order one and cointegrated.8 Next, we consider several
variations of the dynamic OLS (DOLS) and fully modified OLS (FMOLS) panel
8
We employ the tests implemented in E-views due to Breitung (2000), Choi (2001), Hadri (2000), Im et al.
(2003), Levin et al. (2002) and Maddala and Wu (1999) to test for unit roots and those due to Kao (1999),
Maddala and Wu (1999) and Pedroni (1999, 2004) for cointegration.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
450 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH
1970*−2005
15
10
PT
Inflation
ES KR
NZ
AU
US CA
IE
FR
ATFIN
CHJP DE UK
NL
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
estimators (Phillips and Moon, 1999; Kao and Chiang, 2000; Pedroni, 2000, 2001; Mark
and Sul, 2003). Using DOLS the uit are allowed to be correlated with at most pi leads
and lags of vit, which controls for the possible endogeneity one hardly can get rid of in
the simple regression setting. For all the details and full results of this exercise, see
online Appendices. Partial results obtained with the restriction c = 1 are in Table 1. In
this setting, the estimates of a obtained within the 1970–2005 sample are in the range
0.10–0.29, i.e. below the 0.33 of the Miller–Orr specification.
3. Subsamples
3.1. The Quantity Theory with Inflation Targeting
We now draw attention to the results before and after the implicit or explicit adoption
of inflation targeting (IT). For each country we split the full sample in IT and non-IT
periods and consider this splitting to calculate averages, run regressions with these
averages or consider (unbalanced) panel cointegration regressions. The specific dates
and justification for these choices are in Appendix A.
Starting with the corrections to average money growth, we note that in all samples
the Miller–Orr specification as well as the estimated specifications, which point to a
lower interest rate elasticity, clearly fit better than the Baumol–Tobin specification. But
what is more striking is that while the fit for all specifications in the non-IT part of the
sample is essentially as good as for the whole sample, the fit, as measured by an R2 is
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
2016] IS QUANTITY THEORY STILL ALIVE? 451
1970*−2005
15
10
PT
Inflation
ES KR
NZ
AU
US CA
IE
FR
ATFIN
CHJP DE
NL
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
Regression based
Corrections corrections
c = 1, c = 1,
Period Not GDP a est. with a est.
benchmark corrected growth Baumol–Tobin Miller–Orr constant no constant
Notes. R2 is calculated as 1 SSR/SST, where SSR is the sum of squared residuals, where the residuals are the
differences between average inflation and (possibly adjusted) average money growth and SST is the total
variation in real money growth). SD (ei) is the estimated standard deviation of the residuals. SD (Dlog(M/P))
is the standard deviation of real money growth. Averages of the variables are from 1970 (or whenever data are
available) until 2005, denoted 1970*–2005; from 1970 (or whenever data are available) until IT adoption,
denoted 1970-IT and from IT adoption until 2005, denoted IT-2005. Countries included: AU, AT, CA, DK,
FIN, FR, DE, IE, IT, JP, KR, NL, NZ, PT, ES, CH, US (17 observations). 1970-IT does not include DE and CH.
IT-2005 does not include JP.
Preferred spec.
c=1 c=1
Notes. Regression of (averages of) real money growth on real output growth and the nominal interest rate.
Standard errors below the estimates. R2 is calculated as 1 minus (sum-of-squared of residuals divided by total
variation of real money growth). Averages of the variables are from 1970 (or whenever data are available) until
2005, denoted 1970*–2005; from 1970 (or whenever data are available) until IT adoption, denoted 1970*-IT and
from IT adoption until 2005, denoted IT-2005. Countries included: AU, AT, CA, DK, FIN, FR, DE, IE, IT, JP, KR,
NL, NZ, PT, ES, CH, US (17 observations). 1970*-IT does not include DE and CH. IT-2005 does not include JP.
much worse for the IT part of the sample, as Table 1 shows. Also, not including a
constant in the regression, i.e. not controlling for movements in velocity (through a
linear trend) not attributable to movements in the short rate deteriorates dramatically
the fit in the more recent sample.
The Figures provide an even more revealing story. Figure 7 shows the results for the
Baumol–Tobin specification across samples, Figure 8 for the Miller–Orr specification,
and Figure 9 shows the results for the estimated specification.
Results for the simple regression with averages are in Table 2 and those for the panel
cointegration regression imposing a unitary output elasticity (c = 1) are in Table 3.
More complete versions of the results, including choosing 1990 as the split point, can
be found in the online Appendices.9 We should mention that, in our view, the most
appropriate specifications include a constant in the simple regression and, addition-
ally, a trend in the cointegration equation.10
We want to stress two points here. The first is that the estimated interest elasticity is
lower for the IT part of the sample. This result has been observed in the literature on
the stability of the money demand using time series data, as for example in Ireland
(2009). Part of the explanation for the low elasticity is the increasing role of money
substitutes that are not included in M1, as argued by Teles and Zhou (2005) and,
recently, also by Lucas and Nicolini (2015).
The second result, more important for our purposes, is the apparent poor fit of a
money growth-inflation relationship in the IT part of the sample compared to the non-
9
The main messages do not change if we consider that alternative split point.
10
This way we control, even if in a crude way, for movements in velocity not attributable to changes in
interest rates or output. Not including a constant in the regressions (or a trend in the cointegration
equation) has a big impact in the estimated elasticities for the IT-2005 sample due to the fact that these
movements are being attributed to the fall in interest rates over this period. This is a typical bias due to the
omission of deterministics.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
2016] IS QUANTITY THEORY STILL ALIVE? 453
1970*−2005
15 10
Inflation
PT
ES KR
NZ
AU
IT
DK
5
US IECA
FR
AT
FIN
CHJP DE UK
0 NL
1970*−IT
15
NZ
PT ES
10
Inflation
KR
AU
US CA
IT DK
FIN
UK
5
FR IE
JP AT
NL
0
−5 0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
IT−2005
15 10
Inflation
5
IE
ES
US CH PT DE KR
NZ DKIT AU
NL
CA FRAT UK
FIN
0
−5 0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
15 10
Inflation
PT
ES KR
NZ
AU
IT
DK
5
US CA
IE
FR
AT
FIN
CH JP DE UK
NL
1970*−IT
15
NZ
PT ES
10
Inflation
KR
AU
US CADK
IT
FIN
5
FR IE UK
JP AT
NL
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
IT−2005
1510
Inflation
5
IE
US ES CH PT DE KR
NZ DKIT AU
NL
CA FRAT UK
FIN
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
15
10
Inflation
PT
ES KR
NZ
AU
IT
DK
5
US CA
IE
FR
AT
FIN
CH JP DE
NL
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
1970*−IT
15
NZ
PT ES
10
KR
Inflation
AU
US CA DK
IT
FIN
IE
5
FR
JPAT
NL
0
0 5 10 15
Corrected Money Growth
IT−2005
15
10
Inflation
5
IE
US PT
CHDE
ES KR
AU
NZ NL
ITDK
FRAT
CA
FIN
0
−5 0 5 10 15
Preferred specification
Period benchmark c=1 c=1
Notes. Estimation by DOLS and FMOLS considering country fixed-effects only and country fixed-effects and a
common time trend in the cointegration equation. In each setting we consider Grouped and Pooled
(weighted) estimation of the panel. Pooled (weighted) estimation considers cross-section estimates of the
error covariances. With FMOLS we consider heterogeneous first-stage long-run coefficients. Using DOLS the
uit are allowed to be correlated with at most pi leads and lags of vit. We choose pi according to the AIC
criterion. HAC standard errors are below the estimates. For each country, data are from 1970 (or whenever
available) until 2005, denoted 1970*–2005; from 1970 (or whenever data are available) until IT adoption,
denoted 1970*-IT and from IT adoption until 2005, denoted IT-2005. Countries included: AU, AT, CA, DK,
FIN, FR, DE, IE, IT, JP, KR, NL, NO, NZ, PT, ES, CH, US. 1970*-IT does not include DE and CH
IT part of the sample or the whole sample, see Table 1. It is still the case, however, and
very importantly so, that the residual variance, or variability around the 45 degree line
in the inflation-(adjusted) money growth plots, is comparable to the other samples.
The reason for the apparent poor fit of the quantity theory relationship in the IT
sample is that inflation is nearly the same across countries. Without variation in
inflation there can be no one-to-one relationship between inflation and money growth.
Examining Figures 7, 8 and 9 makes this point in a striking way. The explanation is
simple. Central banks have increasingly focused on achieving a low and roughly
common target for the inflation rate. Apparently, they have been successful in
achieving this goal. Central banks choose a money growth rate that offsets shocks to
the money-inflation relationship, in order to achieve their common target.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
2016] IS QUANTITY THEORY STILL ALIVE? 457
There is residual dispersion in money growth, probably due to differing experiences
in deregulation and innovation in transactions technologies, but not enough to
question the tightness of the relation as measured by the residual variance.
The fact that the quantity theory one-to-one relationship between money growth and
inflation cannot be found in the data does not mean that it is not a feature of a model
that generates comparable data. In the simple model of Section 3, if inflation was equal
to 2% for every country and if interest rates were constant over time (possibly equal to
4%), that would make it impossible to identify the relationship in the data generated
by the model, regardless of the interest elasticity. Even if the relationship is indeed a
4. Conclusions
A cross-section of long-term averages for inflation and money growth plotted one
against the other as in e.g. McCandlees and Weber (1995) has those averages line up
nicely along a 45 degree line. In his Nobel lecture, Lucas (1996) claims that there is no
sharper evidence in monetary economics.11 But the evidence is by no means as sharp
when the sample excludes countries with very high inflation. For countries with
moderate inflation, the overwhelming evidence is just not there.
We use a cross-section of countries with moderate inflation to re-establish the one-to-
one close relationship between long-term inflation and money growth. For that we
need to take into account the effect of long-term movements in nominal interest rates,
according to elasticities that match the ones suggested by both theory on transactions
technologies, as in Baumol (1952), Tobin (1956), Miller and Orr (1966), and
estimation using time series data for the US and other countries. Once we take into
account the effect of movements in interest rates for the whole sample, between 1970
and 2005, what appeared to be a random scatter of points is now a 45 degree line
through the origin.12
The data are split into two subsamples with the data break coinciding with the
explicit or implicit adoption of inflation targeting. We find that for the later part of the
sample the one-to-one relation between inflation and money growth seems to
deteriorate. Such deterioration is only apparent since the residual variance is
comparable to the one found for the full sample. The reason for all this is moderate
11
‘Central bankers and even some monetary economists talk knowledgeably of using high interest rates to
control inflation, but I know of no evidence from even one economy linking these variables in a useful way,
let alone evidence as sharp as that displayed in Figure 1. The kind of monetary neutrality shown in this
Figure needs to be a central feature of any monetary or macroeconomic theory that claims empirical
seriousness’ (Lucas, 1996, p. 666)
12
For the line to be through the origin, the effect of output growth must also be taken into account.
© 2015 Royal Economic Society.
458 THE ECONOMIC JOURNAL [MARCH
dispersion in money growth coupled with successful inflation targeting at a low
common rate. In the later sample the variability of inflation is indeed considerably
reduced. The points seem to form an horizontal line at low inflation. With very low
variability of inflation it is hard to find any relationship between inflation and money
growth. A similar difficulty was described by Whiteman (1984) and met by Sargent and
Surico (2011) in their review of Lucas (1980). Sargent and Surico also find that
inflation targeting around low inflation, reducing its variability, made it hard to extract
from the more recent US data the one-to-one relationship that Lucas found. Our
results here complement their findings, using a cross-country analysis compared to
Table A1
Country Codes
Code Country
AU Australia
DK Denmark
DE Germany
FI Finland
FR France
IE Ireland
IS Iceland
IT Italy
JP Japan
CA Canada
KR South Korea
NZ New Zealand
NL Netherlands
NO Norway
AT Austria
PT Portugal
CH Switzerland
ES Spain
UK United Kingdom
US United States
An original version of the data used was collected by Jan Auerbach, an undergraduate RA in
Berlin 2006, using EcoWin, a commercial data base, which was available and existent then. Ding
Xuan, an undergraduate RA in Chicago 2012, corrected a few entries, using IMF and World Bank
Data. A number of further issues then were dealt with by the authors. In a nutshell, the latest
version of annual CPI and real GDP data is in most instances from the IMF-IFS. As for the short
nominal interest rate the main source is also the IMF-IFS. Data from the OECD, the ECB and
from St. Louis Fed’s FRED database is also used. As for M1, we rely on FRED, the IMF-IFS and the
ECB. Euro area countries do not have an independent series for M1 for the whole sample but
data for their contribution to M1 is provided by the ECB from 1980 onwards. For Germany, the
M1 as well as the real GDP series was ‘spliced’ across unification, by extending the series
backwards using the growth rates of West Germany. Details can be found in Table A3. Since the
article at hand focuses on prices, M1, real GDP and short-term interest rates, the data regarding
M2, M3 and long-term rates would need further corrections before full use, but appears to be
sufficient to provide a ‘first pass’ at the results.
Table A3
Data Description
M
Monetary aggr. M1, National Annual US, KR IMF IFS 1970–2005
Currency, SA
Monetary aggr. M1, National Annual AU FRED MANMM101AUA189S 1970–2005 December values from monthly series
Currency, SA
Monetary aggr. M1, National Annual CA FRED MANMM101CAA189S 1970–2005 December values from monthly series
Currency, SA
Monetary aggr. M1, National Annual CH FRED MANMM101CHA189N 1970–2005 December values from monthly series
Currency, NSA
461
(Continued)
Additional Supporting Information may be found in the online version of this article:
References
Alvarez, F. and Lippi, F. (2009). ‘Financial innovation and the transactions demand for cash’, Econometrica,
vol. 77(2), pp. 363–402.
Assenmacher-Wesche, K. and Gerlach, S. (2007). ‘Money at low frequencies’, Journal of the European Economic
Association, vol. 5(2–3), pp. 534–42.
Atkeson, A., Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, P.J. (2010). ‘Sophisticated monetary policies’, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, vol. 125(1), pp. 47–89.
Attanasio, O.P., Guiso, L. and Jappelli, T. (2002). ‘The demand for money, financial innovation and the
welfare cost of inflation: an analysis with household data’, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 110(2), pp. 317–
51.
Bailey, M.J. (1956). ‘The welfare costs of inflationary finance’, Journal of Political Economy, vol. 64(2), pp. 93–
110.
Ball, L. (2001). ‘Another look at long-run money demand’, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 47(1), pp. 31–44.
Barnett, W.A. (1980). ‘Economic monetary aggregates: an application of aggregation and index number
theory’, Journal of Econometrics, vol. 14(1), pp. 11–48.
Barnett, W.A. and Serletis, A. (2000). The Theory of Monetary Aggregation. Contributions to Economic Analysis
245, Amsterdam: North-Holland.
Barro, R. (1993). Macroeconomics, 4th edn. New York: John Wiley & Sons.
Barro, R. (2007). Macroeconomics: A Modern Approach. Cincinnati, OH: South-Western College Pub.
Baumol, W.J. (1952). ‘The transactions demand for cash: an inventory theoretic approach’, Quarterly Journal
of Economics, vol. 66(4), pp. 545–56.
Benati, L. (2009). ‘Long run evidence on money growth and inflation’, Working Paper No. 1027, European Central
Bank.
Benhabib, J., Schmitt-Grohe, S. and Uribe, M. (2001). ‘The perils of Taylor rules’, Journal of Economic Theory,
vol. 96(1–2), pp. 40–69.
Breitung, J. (2000). ‘The local power of some unit root tests for panel data’, in (B.H. Baltagi, T.B. Fomby and
R. Carter Hill, eds.), Advances in Econometrics: Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels,
vol. 15, pp. 161–78, Amsterdam: JAI Press.
Carlson, J.B., Hoffman, D.L., Keen, B.D. and Rasche, R.H. (2000). ‘Results of a study of the stability of
cointegrating relations comprised of broad monetary aggregates’, Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 46
(2), pp. 345–83.
Choi, I. (2001). ‘Unit root tests for panel data’, Journal of International Money and Finance, vol. 20(2), pp. 249–
72.
Coenen, G. and Vega, J.L. (2001). ‘The demand for M3 in the euro area’, Journal of Applied Econometrics, vol.
16(6), pp. 727–48.
Fischer, B., Lenza, M., Pill, H. and Reichlin, L. (2006). ‘Money and monetary policy: the ECB experience
1999–2006’, mimeo, European Central Bank.
Friedman, M. (1956). ‘The quantity theory of money – a restatement’, in (M. Friedman, ed.), Studies in the
Quantity Theory of Money, pp. 3–21, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Hadri, K. (2000). ‘Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data’, Econometrics Journal, vol. 3(2),
pp. 148–61.