Assembly Trade Technology Transfer - The Case of China
Assembly Trade Technology Transfer - The Case of China
Assembly Trade Technology Transfer - The Case of China
net/publication/4795590
CITATIONS READS
186 997
3 authors, including:
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Deniz Ünal on 09 September 2015.
Work
CEPII
9, rue Georges Pitard
75015 Paris
France
Tel : 33 1 53 68 55 32
Fax : 33 1 53 68 55 03
E-mail : [email protected]
Home
16 rue de l’Ouest
75014 Paris
France
Tel: 33 1 43 35 01 25
Work
CEPII
9, rue Georges Pitard
75015 Paris
France
Tel : 33 1 53 68 55 05
Fax : 33 1 53 68 55 04
E-mail : [email protected]
Home
79 rue Dutot
75015 Paris
France
Tel : 33 1 42 50 76 13
-2-
Summary. — The paper shows that China’s outstanding export performance is directly linked to its integration
in the international segmentation of production processes. China has engaged in production sharing with Asian
countries and has specialized in assembly operations, which has allowed for a rapid diversification of its
manufactured exports, from textiles and clothing to the electric and electronic industries. Assembly has
considerably helped the technological upgrading of China’s trade. Up to now, these outward-oriented and highly
competitive industries, which are based on imported technology and foreign affiliates, seem to have had limited
impact on local production and on the diffusion of technology in China’s domestic industry.
Key words — China, Asia, technology transfer, trade specialization, FDI, international production sharing
-3-
1. INTRODUCTION
For the last twenty years China’s foreign trade has expanded at an outstanding pace (almost 15% per year) and
its share in world trade has more than trebled, from less than 1% to about 3.5%. Most remarkable have been the
rapid expansion and the diversification of its industrial manufactured exports which have risen at the rate of 20%
a year. They accounted for almost 90% of its total exports in 2001, as against 40% in 1980. During the 1980s,
China’s exports were driven by textile products, and during the 1990s by electric and electronic products. This
article shows that China achieved such a performance thanks to its strong involvement in the international
segmentation of production processes. It argues that China’s specialization in assembly trade has given rise to a
highly competitive and internationalized manufacturing sector, which has been the main channel of technology
transfers, while the traditional export sector has lagged behind. The second section of the paper reviews the
international experience pertaining to the links between trade and catch-up. The paper then examines how
China’s trade policy in favor of processing trade has enhanced production sharing with Asian partners, and
allowed for a rapid diversification of China’s exports (section 3). Then, it presents an original analysis of
China’s trade by stages of production and by technology content, showing that intermediate goods have played a
crucial part in the technological upgrading of China’s foreign trade (section 4). Section 5 gives some evidence
that the outward-oriented sector has had relatively limited linkage effects with the rest of industry, and section 6
discusses whether China’s accession to the WTO may alleviate this dualism.
According to the classical or neo-classical theory of international trade, countries’ specialization is determined
by their comparative advantages. Given its almost unlimited resources in cheap labor, China’s rise in
international trade can be explained by its comparative advantage in labor-intensive products. However this
explanation falls short of accounting for the rapid changes in its sectoral trade pattern and for the successful
The dynamic of the creation of new comparative advantage in Asian countries has often been interpreted within
the framework of the “flying geese model” developed by Akamatsu (1961), who observed that “diffusion of new
techniques to rising industrial nations proceeds rapidly, and these nations approach the technological level of
advanced nations” and that “the underdeveloped nations are aligned successively behind the advanced industrial
nations in the order of their different stages of growth in a wild-flying geese pattern”. According to this model,
innovations spread from the innovating nation to the other nations and the development trajectory of the late-
-4-
comers replicates the development experience of the countries ahead of them. “Their economic rise is tightly
linked to the emergence, maturation and decline of particular industrial sectors” (Bernard & Revenhill, 1995).
This interpretation thus incorporates Vernon’s product-cycle theory, which examines how the life-cycle of
products affects the locus of their manufacturing production. The production of new products requires
innovation and R&D and thus occurs in high income countries. As the product becomes mature, its input
requirements change (capital expenses and labor costs take a greater importance) and the production tends to
migrate to less advanced countries. Finally, at the standardized production stage, production requires mainly
unqualified labor and moves to the countries which have lower labor costs.
Numerous empirical studies have underlined that the development of East Asian economies has proceeded in
waves, Japan coming the first, followed by successive tiers of economies which have tended to catch up
(ESCAP, 1991; Kojima, 2000; UNCTAD, 1996). Since 1980, the first tier of New Industrialized Economies
(NIEs, i.e. South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Hong-Kong) has gradually shifted its specialization from labor
telecommunication equipment). They moved their production capacity in low-tech sectors to overseas export
platforms, through foreign direct investment and out-processing operations. This migration has helped the
emergence of the second and third tier of New industrialized economies (first Thailand, Malaysia, Philippines,
then China and Indochina). Initially, these countries have developed comparative advantages in resource-based
and low-tech sectors but they have progressively upgraded their industrial capacities and exports. “Recycling
comparative advantages” has thus been at the core of East Asian industrialization.
However, the changes in the global economy, together with the development in technology and production
techniques have precluded homogeneous trajectories. Although late-comers may export similar products as the
leaders did in earlier stages, their structures of production are quite different (ESCAP, 1991;
Bernard & Ravenhill, 1995; OECD, 1999; Guerrieri, 2000; UNCTAD, 1996). In fact, while Japan has
developed a strong indigenous innovative base, prior to the increase of its global economic presence in the
1950s, Taiwan and Korea have remained dependant on imported technology, components and equipment from
the industrialized economies (mainly Japan). The late-comers, South-East Asian countries, have industrial
structures which are characterized by the lack of a domestic manufacturing tradition, their high dependence on
foreign controlled firms, a high import content of exports and limited backward linkage with local component
suppliers.
-5-
The heterogeneity of the trajectories can be traced back to the globalization process which has enhanced the
fragmented and firms located in different countries take part in the production of a commodity, but at different
stages of the value-added chain, which is split-up across countries. Multinational firm strategies have developed
outsourcing policies which rely on foreign and even distant suppliers, and have localized the production of
components in different countries, with the aim of better utilizing different countries’ comparative advantages.
The different stages of production correspond to different production functions so that a country may have a
comparative advantage in some stages of production, and a comparative disadvantage in other stages. Two types
of specialization can thus be distinguished: “horizontal” specialization, when a country has a comparative
advantage in the whole process of production of a given product, from upstream to downstream stages; “vertical”
1
specialization when a country has a comparative advantage only in some stages of production, and a
2
disadvantage in others. As a consequence, trade in intermediate products , which results from the interruption of
the domestic production processes, has taken on a growing importance and assembly trade has become a crucial
element in the international segmentation of production process. Late-comers generally specialize in the
assembly of final products, the most labor-intensive segment of production, while more advanced countries
Trade in intermediate goods implies specific gains as imports of intermediate products increase the number of
varieties of inputs available to the producers. More variety upstream increases the efficiency in the use of
resources. Moreover trade in intermediate goods is an important channel of the transmission of technology
(Coe & Helpman, 1995; Coe, Helpman & Hoffmaister, 1995; Keller, 2001 and 2002). For emerging economies,
imports of components for assembly may become the easiest way to acquire high-technology. It makes it
possible for them to enter new production lines characterized by strong global demand growth and potential
productivity gains.
However, the benefits that low-wage countries derive from their participation in international production sharing
may be smaller than suggested by trade figures. The gains may be unequally spread between the firms involved
in the value-added chain. Also, taking part in the labor-intensive stages of production does not automatically
lead to the technological spillovers needed to move up the production chain and to ensure a sustainable trajectory
of economic development (UNCTAD, 1999 and 2002; Kaplinsky & Morrus, 2002; OECD, 1999).
China provides a case study which highlights how a latecomer can enter globalization and carve out its place in
the international division of labor. This case further illustrates how the splitting-up the value-added chain
-6-
between different locations (countries) and the development of firms’ cross-border production networks is
driving the process of industrial growth and integration in Asia (UNCTAD, 1996 and 2002; Borrus,
Ernst & Haggard, 2000). Since the mid eighties China has been involved in international production sharing
with Asian economies, as firms from Hong-Kong, Taiwan and from other Asian countries have relocated their
labor intensive industries on the mainland (Naughton, 1997; Lyons & Nee, 1994). The rapid expansion of
China’s foreign trade has been closely associated with an on-going reorganization of production in Asia. The
benefits China has derived from the becoming a production base for Asian industrial firms include a rapid rise in
exports which has contributed to economic growth, the development of an electrical and electronic industry
based on foreign technology, an accelerated economic growth of Southern coastal provinces and especially of
Guangdong province (Lardy, 2002; Wu, 1999; Naughton, 1997;; Lyons & Nee, 1994, Vogel 1989). However,
the positive effects of outward-oriented foreign direct investment on China’s domestic industry should not be
overestimated. Processing activities have been strongly stimulated by a preferential trade regime which has
benefited mainly to foreign invested enterprises, while domestic enterprises have not been in position to take
advantage of the concessional programs. This dualistic trade policy has created an institutional separation
between the domestic and the export sector and has diverted trade away from state-owned enterprises and toward
foreign joint-ventures; it has also led to an over-concentration of China’s foreign trade in some provinces
(Guangdong and Fujian) (Naughton, 1996). Moreover, processing activities out carried out by foreign affiliates
remained concentrated in low value-added production, making use of the China’s unlimited supply of low-cost
labor; they have had few backward and forward linkages (Zhang,1999; Sung, 2000, Wu, 1999); they involved
limited transfer of high technology (Naugthton, 1997; Huchet, 1997); the gains from foreign trade were much
smaller than suggested by the figures, since exports had a high import content, and since transfer pricing reduced
government fiscal revenue as well as local partners operating profits (Breslin, 1999; Sun, 1998; Sung, 2000).
The present paper provides evidence that at the end of the nineties, China’s foreign trade is still highly dualistic.
Processing trade and ordinary trade display quite different sectoral and geographic patterns. Processing trade has
been the engine of the outstanding rise and rapid upgrading of China’s foreign trade but domestic firms’ foreign
trade is still lagging behind, suggesting that the highly internationalized and competitive sector has not
significantly helped the modernization of the rest of the economy. China’s entry in the WTO is an important
step towards the unification of the foreign trade regime as it will enlarge the access of domestic firms to foreign
technology. At the same time, trade liberalization is likely to strengthen China’s specialization in labor-intensive
products.
-7-
Trade policy is an important factor determining a country’s involvement in the international splitting-up of the
value-added chain. Tariff structure may affect the degree of effective protection of the different sectors. It has
been shown that tariff exemptions and reductions on imported inputs increase the effective protection enjoyed by
the assembly activities using these inputs, as it reduces their costs of production (Grubel & Johnson, 1971).
China provides an outstanding case of such policy. Since the mid-eighties, the Chinese authorities have used
different instruments to promote exports, including duty exemptions granted to imports to be processed and re-
exported (Lardy, 2002; Ianchovichina, Martin & Fukase, 2000; Naughton 1996). These tariff exemptions have
resulted in a highly segmented trade regime. Basically, two broad regimes are distinguished: 1) processing trade,
which encompasses imports to be processed for exports and the corresponding exports; 2) ordinary trade, which
encompasses exports mainly based on local inputs, and imports aimed at the domestic market and subject to
normal tariff rates. Other trade regimes are less important and include imports of goods as equity investment in
3
joint-ventures, border trade, compensation trade, etc .
Although China reduced its average customs tariff from 41% in 1992 to 16.8% in 1998-2001, the advantage
derived from tariff exemptions has remained significant and this selective trade policy has proved very
successful in creating export-oriented industries based on imported inputs. The large gap between nominal tariff
rates and collected tariff rates provides evidence of the extensive use of tariff exemptions (see Appendix A).
China’s foreign trade expansion has relied mainly on processing operations (Table 1). As early as 1992,
processed exports made up 46% of total exports. This share rose to 55% in 1996 and has represented more than
half of China’s exports since then. During the Asian crisis (1998-1999), exports of processed goods performed
better than other categories of exports, and this resilience can be explained by their high import content which
makes them less vulnerable to the effects of a real appreciation of the exchange rate (Dées & Lemoine, 1999).
Correspondingly, imports for processing have increased rapidly since 1992 and their share in total imports rose
from less than 40% to almost 50% to 1997-1998. Since 1998 they have lagged behind ordinary imports, which
registered a strong rise partly due to the anti-smuggling measures implemented by the government but also to an
actual growth in imports driven by the rapid decline in the level of tariff rates in the late nineties. However, even
4
now, ordinary imports account for less than half of total imports . The last category (“other imports”) includes
The geographic distribution of China’s trade flows differs depending on customs regimes. Asian countries’
exports to China depend heavily on processing trade (Table 2). In 1999, Asia was by far the major source of
inputs for China’s processing industries. Japan and the NIEs provided more than two-thirds of these imports.
Hence, most Asian exports to China are not aimed at satisfying domestic demand but at supplying inputs for
processing industries. Their role in China’s foreign trade reflects the international splitting-up of the value-
added chain within the region, driven by the strategies of Asian firms which have relocated the final stages of
production to the Mainland. In this way, Asian countries have already taken advantage from China’s selective
trade liberalization, as the largest part of their exports is exempted from customs tariffs. The bias in favor of
processing is especially strong in China’s imports from Taiwan and Hong-Kong (the share of processing
reaching 75%).
In 1999, Japan was the first supplier of China’s imports for processing (25%), but the NIEs accounted for the
largest share of these imports (40%), with Taiwan being by far the most important supplier (20%), followed by
South Korea. Interestingly, Taiwan and Hong-Kong taken together had a larger portion in the supply chain than
By contrast, European and American firms contribute only marginally to the supply of goods for China’s
processing industries (they supplied respectively 5% and 7% of imports for processing in 1999). European and
American firms hold their strongest positions in China’s ordinary imports, showing that their strategy was aimed
at the domestic market: American firms and to a lesser extent, European firms, are also developing production
bases in China: in 1999, goods for processing accounted for 13% of China’s imports from the EU and for 25%
The geographic structure of processed exports shows that China has become an export platform for Asian
industries aimed at world markets. China’s processing trade records its largest surpluses with the US and
Europe, while it is almost balanced with Japan and runs a deficit with Taiwan and South Korea. The surplus
with Hong-Kong is due to transit trade, as most Chinese exports to Hong-Kong are ultimately directed to third
markets, mainly to the EU and the US (EC, 1997). Almost 85% of China’s exports to Hong-Kong are re-
exported, one fourth is directed to the EU and one third to the US. If the distortions associated with this transit
(indirect) trade were removed, the geographic asymmetry of China’s processing trade would be even more
5
pronounced and China’s trade surpluses with Europe and the US would be bigger than stated in Table 2 .
-9-
International production sharing between China and industrialized Asian economies began in textile and clothing
in the mid-eighties and was already well entrenched in this sector in the early nineties. At that time half of
China’s clothing exports came from processing activities (Table 4). This has allowed China to become the
world largest exporter of apparel. Afterwards, the relocation strategy of Asian firms has expanded in new
industrial sectors, mainly in electrical machinery, and they have transferred to China the segments of production
in which they were loosing their comparative advantage. NIE firms have followed the path that Japanese firms
had taken earlier. Already in 1993, electrical machinery was the most important category of products supplied
for processing by Japan to China. At that time, textile products were still the most important category supplied
by the NIEs, which have since considerably expanded their exports of electrical intermediate products (Table 3).
Almost three-fourth of China’s processed exports of apparel and half of processed exports of electrical products
The rapid expansion of China’s processing trade was thus associated with far-reaching changes in its commodity
composition. The relative decline of processing trade in textiles and apparel can be explained by the import
quotas applied by the developed economies, which constrain the market shares of the most competitive
exporters. The traditional sectors (apparel, leather and shoes) taken together accounted for more than 40% of
processed exports in 1993, and for only 26% in 1999. The composition of processed exports shifted towards
machinery and electrical machinery: the share of these two sectors taken together rose from 24% to almost 40%
Processing operations have contributed decisively to the overall diversification of China’s manufactured exports
from traditional sectors towards more technologically advanced products, with rapidly expanding world markets.
In 1999, four-fifths of China’s total exports of machinery, electrical machinery, other transportation equipment
and precision instruments, depended on processing activities. In these sectors, China does not master the entire
production processes, but has established its specialization in the final, labor intensive stages of production.
The traditional sectors (textiles and apparel, leather and shoes), which lagged behind the average export
performance, are characterized by a below-average dependence on processing activities. However, some sectors
registered a rapid increase in their exports, despite a relatively low dependence on processing activities: this is
Foreign affiliates play an important and growing part in China’s foreign trade. In 2001, they accounted for 50%
of total exports (20% in 1992) and for 52% of total imports (32% in 1992). In fact they are responsible for most
of the expansion of China’s processing activities and they held a dominant share (more than 70%) in these
activities in 2001. They have played an outstanding role in China’s processing trade with Asian countries (Table
5). Most Asian firms which have transferred assembly operations in China have chosen to establish affiliates,
instead of contractual relationships with Chinese firms for out-processing. Moreover, to carry out these
processing activities, they have tended to establish wholly foreign affiliates, more than equity joint-ventures. In
2001, wholly foreign affiliates accounted for about 55% of processing operations by foreign invested enterprises
established in China (the proportion was less than 40% in 1995). A large portion of China’s trade thus
corresponds to intra-firm trade between parent firms in Asian countries and their affiliates in the Mainland. In
sectors such as machinery and electrical machinery, foreign affiliates account for more than three-quarters of
processed exports, and for more four-fifths of corresponding imports, providing evidence of the importance of
the cross-border production networks in explaining China’s competitiveness in these sectors. It also highlights
the role of China in the international reorganization of production, which has taken place in these industries
authorities in order to attract export-oriented joint-ventures. But these SEZ have progressively lost their
advantage, as their prices and production costs increased relatively fast, and as several other zones have been
created opened in coastal provinces, in which FDI also benefited from preferential tax treatment (Economic and
Technical Development Zones). Moreover, as tariff exemptions for processing activities did not depend on the
location of the enterprise, China has created “a kind of gigantic export processing zone, defined not
geographically but by the juridical status of the enterprises involved” (Naughton, 1996). In 2002 the four SEZ
were responsible for about one tenth of foreign affiliates’ foreign trade.
Coastal area received the overwhelming share of overall FDI (more than 80%) and almost all export-oriented-
FDI: in 2002, 97% of exports by foreign affiliates came from coastal provinces, 40% from Guangdong, and 24%
come from Shanghai and its neighbor province of Jiangsu taken together. The geographic location of export-
oriented FDI has shifted slowly northward, away from Guangdong province and in favor of the major industrial
- 11 -
centers, with better endowments in qualified labor. This evolution may be part and parcel of a technological
The analysis of China’s foreign trade by stage of production makes it possible to understand how its
are split up into two different categories: semi-finished products and parts & components, 3) final goods, which
are split up into two different categories: consumption goods and capital goods.
Final goods represent by far the most important export category (63% of exports in 1999), in which consumer
goods still take an overwhelming share (47%), but capital goods are rising faster (up to 15% in 1999) (Table 7).
On the import side, intermediate products are heavily dominant, accounting for two-thirds of total imports;
semi-finished products make up the most important category (42% in 1999), but parts and components has
This rapid expansion of China’s trade in parts and components corresponds to a general trend in Asian trade.
Trade in components has been the most dynamic segment of East Asian trade since 1985, as a result of
production sharing in the region (Ng & Yeats, 1999). Like the other low-wage Asian economies (Indonesia,
Thailand, Malaysia) China has specialized in assembly operations (with a trade deficit in components), while
Japan and the NIEs have a comparative advantage in production of components (with a trade surplus in
components).
As China’s exports have a high import content, the analysis of its comparative advantages should not rely on its
sectoral export performance but should rather take into account its sectoral trade balance. For that reason we
used an indicator which measures the contribution of the different sectors and stages of production to China’s
overall trade balance.(see Appendix D). Table 8 shows that China still displays its major comparative
advantages (trade surpluses) in textiles, clothing, leather and shoes. In more technologically advanced sectors
(machinery and equipment, office machinery and computers, electrical machinery, radio and TV equipment,
instruments), there is a reversal of China’s comparative disadvantages along the production processes: it
switches from a relative deficit in parts and components to a surplus in consumption, and in some cases in capital
- 12 -
goods. This vertical specialization highlights the crucial role of international production sharing in explaining
goods represent 14% of its imports and 8 percent of its exports, on average in 1997-1999 (Table 9). These
shares are relatively high by international standards, since corresponding ratios for the EU show a high-tech
content of 9.5% in both exports and imports (Fontagné, Freudenberg and Ünal-Kesenci, 1999).
Parts and components constitute the main channel of China’s high-technology imports. In 1997-1999, 57% of its
high-tech imports were parts and components. Capital goods accounted for only one-third of high-tech imports.
On average, imported parts and components embody more high technology than other categories of imports
(almost 40% of component imports have a high technology content, while this is the case for only one third of
imported capital goods). This suggests that export-oriented, internationalized industries have a higher capacity
Since imported parts and components are used (at least partially) in export processing industries, China’s exports
are more technologically advanced than would be expected given its level of development. Another
consequence is that China’s high-tech exports and imports take place in the same sectors (with the exception of
chemicals) (Table 10). High-tech trade is heavily concentrated in two sectors: radio & TV equipment and office
machinery & computers. Traded goods in both sectors have an outstanding high-tech content: 64% of imports
and 52% of exports of radio & TV equipment are high-tech goods; 84% of imports and 78% of exports of office
machinery and computers are high-tech goods. This sectoral concentration of high-tech exports helps to explain
why industrialized Asian economies are concerned by the rapid technological catch-up of China’s exports and
The geographic pattern of China’s high-tech imports indicates that Asian countries are by far its most important
suppliers (accounting for 55% of the total), and that parts and components amount to more than three-quarters of
their high-tech supplies to China (Table 11). Production sharing with Asian countries thus plays a major role in
the technological upgrading of China’s foreign trade. While Japan is by far the largest supplier of high-tech
products to China (with 25% of its high-tech imports), Taiwan ranks second in Asia (with 12.5%).
- 13 -
Western Europe is the second most important source of high-tech products (almost one fourth of China’s high-
tech imports). In contrast with Asia, West European high-tech products are mostly capital goods. European
transfers of technology to China follow a more traditional pattern, as they are aimed at modernizing investment
capacity and not at re-exports. China’s imports of high-tech products from America are evenly distributed
between capital goods and parts & components. America ranks second as a market for Chinese high-tech goods
(taking one fourth of China’s exports), far ahead Western Europe (14%).
It is worth stressing that although the EU stands far behind Asia as a supplier of high-tech products to China, its
exports are, on average, more technology intensive than Asian exports. This is also the case of American exports
to China. High-tech products account for 20% of China’s total imports from the EU, 17% from America, against
12% from Asia (15% from Japan). Despite geographic distance, traditional complementarities between China
China’s specialization in assembly trade has considerably enhanced its capacity to export high-tech products.
The share of high-tech products in China’s exports may be misleading since it does not reflect the innovative
capacity of China’s manufacturing industry, but the high-technology embodied in these exports and produced in
advanced economies.
Obviously, the outward-oriented sector has provided China’s economy substantial gains, but its dynamic impact
on the technological upgrading of the domestic industrial capacities is less easy to assess.
The technological level of exports indicates that China has entered lines of production for goods which are
characterized by a fast growing world demand, as for the last 20 years, international trade in high-tech products
has increased faster than average. This specialization in sectors with fast growing demand has increased the
scope of exploiting increasing returns to scales. Moreover, these new sectors are also characterized by strong
potential for productivity gains, since a close relationship between the technology intensity of products and their
Outward-oriented industries, based on imported inputs and carried out by foreign firm affiliates, have been the
most dynamic part of China’s foreign trade in the nineties and have been responsible for a growing share of
China’s trade surplus. Their trade surplus jumped from two and half billion dollars in 1994 to 36 billion in 2001
(the corresponding figures China’s overall trade surplus were six and 22 billion dollars). These industries have
- 14 -
also had positive effects on the domestic economy, by increasing job opportunities, improving labor training and
skills, rising income. There is no precise data which indicate the role played by these outward-oriented
industries in China’s economy, but their role can be estimated in looking at the activities of Hong-Kong and
Taiwanese affiliates, which are strongly specialized in processing activities in the Mainland. In 1999, these
affiliates accounted for 3 to 5% of urban employees, were responsible for 12% of the industrial output of the
9
organized sector , and for 14% of the profits; they held 10% of the fixed assets and paid 10% of the VAT. In
Hong-Kong and Taiwanese affiliates, the labor and capital productivity was much higher than in the Chinese
firms, due to better production and management techniques and to economies of scale associated with large
foreign markets.
Turning to the impact of overall foreign direct investment (FDI) in China (including FDI from industrialized
countries which has been more oriented towards the domestic market), its effect on the restructuring of China’s
manufacturing industry has been outstanding. In 1999, foreign affiliates were responsible for 28% of China’s
industrial output. In electronic and telecommunication equipment, they have now a dominant share (70% of
output) (see Appendix B). International comparisons of productivity show that China’s level of productivity in
manufacturing is very low, but suggests that the sectors in which foreign affiliates’ contribution to output is high,
tend to have an above average performance (leather and shoes, electrical equipment) (Szirmai, Ren & Bai,
2002).
The positive effect of foreign direct investment on growth and productivity can thus hardly be contested, but
apart from the impact linked to the presence of high-performing foreign affiliates, the spill-over effects on
Chinese producers are less easy to assess. There is some evidence that outward-oriented industries have
developed rapidly without having a decisive effect on the technological capacities and export competitiveness of
(wholly-) Chinese firms. The local content of processed exports and the evolution of domestic exports tend to
indicate that there are limited linkages between the outward-oriented sector and the rest of the economy.
The ratio of exports after processing to imports for processing steadily increased from 1.2 in 1994 to almost 1.5
in 1998-2001. This means that the local content of processed exports rose from 20% in 1992 to more than 30%
in 2000. Several factors explain this evolution. First, the share of profit margins and/or wage costs may have
increased more rapidly than costs of imported inputs, especially due to the real appreciation of the Yuan in 1998-
1999. Second, the value-added realized in China has also increased as a result of the growing integration of the
production process in the Mainland: the value-added chain now includes more stages of production and related
- 15 -
services (packaging, marketing) which were previously carried elsewhere, especially in Hong-Kong. Moreover,
as the local content is higher in the sector of machinery and electrical machinery (40%) than in textiles-clothing
industry (30%), the shift which took place in processing activities towards the former sectors tended to increase
However, a study of the electric appliances and electronics industry provides evidence that the increased local
content is due to the rapid escalation of transactions among foreign affiliates located in China (Maruya, 2000). It
shows that the increased integration of production in the Mainland has been mainly due to foreign affiliates
which have been switching from imported parts and materials towards procurements from other foreign
affiliates. Procurements from Chinese companies have remained low. The increased local content is generated
by trade flows within clusters of foreign affiliates, located in Guangdong province, but does not reflect the
upgrading of Chinese firms’ production capacities. The overwhelming share taken by foreign affiliates in
processing trade (which rose from 56% in 1994 to 72% in 2001) tends to confirm that this is a general
phenomenon.
Other reasons may explain the weak linkages between the outward oriented sectors and the domestic-based
exports: the higher quality of imported intermediates, the tighter delivery schedules of foreign suppliers, the
difficult access of foreign firms to local primary products (agricultural goods and raw materials).
From 1992 to 2001, “ordinary” exports lagged behind processed exports. The former increased by 11% a year
and the latter by 15% a year. Moreover the commodity structure of ordinary exports recorded relatively limited
changes during the nineties. Apparel still remained by far the most important sector, followed by chemical
products and raw agricultural products. In these sectors, more than half of China’s exports in 1999 relied on
“ordinary” trade. Although ordinary exports of machinery and electrical machinery increased they remained
It can be argued that the tariff exemptions granted to imports of intermediate products for processing industries
have led to a relative discrimination against industries involved in ordinary trade, or producing mainly for the
domestic market. In contrast to processing activities which benefited from “effective protection” (as tariff
exemptions correspond to an indirect subsidy), ordinary exports were affected by the level of tariffs on imported
inputs. At the same time, tariff exemptions on imports for processing may have had a negative impact on the
- 16 -
local production of intermediate goods, thus limiting the backward linkages of processing activities (Zhang,
1999).
Ordinary trade is mostly carried out by wholly-Chinese firms. In 1999, they were responsible for the
overwhelming share (84%) of ordinary exports, and these account for almost two thirds of their total exports.
Chinese firms’ heavy reliance on this slow-growing trade segments may partly explain their poor export
performance. Chinese firms’ exports increased at the rate of only 6% a year from 1992 to 2001, compared to
25% for foreign affiliates. In fact, even in ordinary trade they have lost ground to foreign firms (Chinese firms
accounted for 94% of ordinary exports in 1994 and for 76% in 2002). Moreover, they also have failed to keep
pace with the expansion of processing activities; though domestic firms could benefit from the same tariff
exemptions as foreign affiliates for these activities, most of them had no direct trading rights, and this has
hampered their involvement in the international segmentation of production processes (Naughton, 1996). Their
contribution to processed exports fell sharply between 1994 and 2001 (from 45% to 28%).
The analysis of China’s exports by trade regime, by type of firms and by sector shows that Chinese firms and
foreign affiliates tend to be positioned in different product markets, which correspond to their respective reliance
on local versus imported inputs (Table 13). Chinese firms’ exports rely mainly on ordinary exports of garment,
textile and chemicals which are integrated in domestic production chains; while foreign affiliates’ exports are
concentrated in processed exports of machinery and electrical machinery, which result from international
production sharing. The dualism of China’s foreign trade regime has led to relatively weak linkages between the
Finally, the outstanding part taken by foreign affiliates in China’s foreign trade reflects the weakness of the local
private sector. It has been convincingly argued by Huang (2003), that the development of private firms in China
has been severely constrained by legal discrimination and limited access to bank credit, and that foreign
investors have been a substitute for them. Foreign investors have taken advantage from the restraints put on the
development of a strong local private sector. Moreover, in order to avoid the discriminations against private
enterprises and to benefit from preferential treatment given to foreign investment, Chinese firms have been
induced to create joint ventures with foreign partners, or to set-up fake foreign affiliates, using Hong-Kong as a
China’s foreign trade has remained highly dualistic at the eve of its entry in WTO. Competitive industries,
dominated by foreign affiliates and integrated in the international segmentation of production processes, coexist
with a traditional export sector, dominated by wholly-Chinese firms, which are lagging behind. Linkages
between the two sectors seem to be rather weak, as shown by their growth rates and their commodity
composition (Table 13 above). The circuits of high-tech exports and imports, directly associated with China’s
participation in the international segmentation of production processes, have provided rather limited spillovers to
This situation suggests that the technological upgrading of China’s foreign trade has had limited effects outside
firms involved in processing activities. While its specialization in assembly trade has enabled China to
incorporate high-tech products in its production for exports, the dissemination of foreign technology into the rest
of China’s industrial capacities has been slow. The fact that most processing trade is carried out by foreign
affiliates, and not by Chinese firms, may have contributed to this situation. These findings tends to confirm the
conclusions of previous studies (Zhang, 1999; Sung 2000; Wu, 1999; Naugthton, 1997; Breslin, 1999; Sun
1998).
The technological dualism which characterizes China’s industrial capacity explains the apparent contradiction
between two ways of assessing China’s capabilities. On the one hand, most experts stress that China’s
technological capabilities are still weak and that its technological dependence on imports has tended to increase
(Dahlman & Aubert, 2001; OECD, 2002). On the other hand, there are fears in many Asian industrialized
countries (Japan, Taiwan) of a too-rapid technological catch up of China, associated with the hollowing out of
their own industries. These countries are concerned by the rapid upgrading of China’s manufacturing exports
(especially in the electronics sector) driven by the progressive relocation of their high technology segments of
production in this country. This would accelerate the trend towards de-industrialization in the most advanced
economies in East Asia, and foster the switch of their economic structures towards services, an evolution that has
Indeed, for late-comers, importing foreign technology is a short-cut to modernization and it makes it possible to
save resources (as long as imports are cheaper than domestic innovation). However, this leads to an ever-
increasing dependency if the dissemination of foreign technology remains insufficient and if the country’s
innovative capacity is not enhanced. China’s technological catching up will depend on its own capacity to
- 18 -
launch a sustained effort to improve the diffusion of technology in its economy and to strengthen its own
In general terms, the R&D effort slowed down in China in the mid-1990s, and has only recovered since 1997.
R&D spending as a share of GDP remains low by international standards, representing 0.8% of GDP in 1999,
compared to 2.5% in South Korea, and 2.05% in Taiwan. Chinese firms spend many more resources importing
foreign technologies than financing their own research and development. Moreover licensing of foreign
technology, which is supposed to be more efficient for technology diffusion than imports, represents relatively
limited spending: less than 0.5% of merchandise imports in China’s case, against 0.7% for India, 2.2% for South
WTO accession may contribute to reducing the technological dualism of China’s industry, in providing domestic
firms with enlarged access to foreign equipment and technology. The reduction in tariffs and non-tariff barriers
will alleviate the distortions existing between the different customs regimes. Hence, Chinese firms producing for
the domestic market will suffer less discrimination compared to foreign affiliates carrying out processing
activities. More generally, this should help Chinese firms to improve their competitiveness in world as well as in
10
domestic markets . Lower tariff rates will trigger Chinese imports of both capital goods and consumer goods.
The expected rise in imports of investment goods aimed at the domestic market should provide Chinese firms
with more high-technology. For Chinese domestic-based firms, trade liberalization is thus a double-edge sword:
they will face increased competition from imported goods, and at the same time will have better access to foreign
technology and equipment, which up to now has been mostly imported by the “internationalized” sector. The
modernization process which up to now seems to have been concentrated in the outward-oriented industries
The institutional separation between domestic and foreign firms will also be reduced as the existing limitations
on foreign trade rights will be phased out (in 2004). Up to now, the ordinary import regime has included strong
limitations and most imports for the domestic market have to be channeled through foreign trade corporations.
Some production enterprises have been allowed to import but only for their own needs. Chinese firms’ ability to
export has thus been hampered by their restricted access to imports. As a consequence of WTO accession, all
firms will have the right to directly export, import and sell products in the domestic market and this is likely
increase the export potential of domestic firms. It will also let private Chinese firms develop export-import
The decision, still under consideration by the Chinese authorities, to phase out the preferential tax treatment
benefiting foreign affiliates would be another step towards leveling the playing field for domestic and foreign
firms.
A major effect of WTO accession on China’s economy will be to foster the expansion of the textiles and clothing
industry. First, trade liberalization will strengthen China’s specialization in the sectors in which it has a
comparative advantage, namely labor intensive industries. Second, the phasing out of MFA quotas by 2005 will
enable China to enlarge its world market share. Studies simulating the impact of WTO accession on China’s
economic structure indicate that it would enlarge the share of textile and clothing industries in industrial output,
employment, exports and imports (Li & Zhai, 2002; Ianchovichina & Martin, 2001; OECD, 2002). This
evolution would slow-down or reverse the structural changes which have taken place in China’s industry since
the mid-1980s in favor of electrical and electronic industries, transport equipment and against textiles. The
accelerated expansion of labor-intensive industries will help contain the rise of unemployment which has
become the most serious problem of China’s economy since the end of the 1990s, as the reform of the state-
owned sector, aimed at increasing its productivity, has resulted in massive lay-off. In the next ten years,
unemployment will remain a major challenge for China’s economic policy, due to demographic trends which are
raising the working age population by 1% a year (10 million people per year), as well as due to the labor surplus
in agriculture which is estimated at around 120 to 140 million people. The service sector, which is less exposed
to international competition, will absorb an increased proportion of the labor force. Manufacturing industry
7 CONCLUSION
This in-depth analysis of China’s foreign trade has amply shown that China’s outstanding performance in world
markets during the 1990s can be traced back to its involvement in the international segmentation of production
processes, which has been deliberately encouraged by a selective trade policy granting preferential tariff
treatment to assembly. The final stages of production of matured Asian economies have migrated to China,
boosting its export capacities. Its vertical specialization has enabled China to rapidly diversify its exports, and
especially to build up its strengths in the electrical machinery sector. The study points out that this specialization
has driven the technological upgrading of China’s foreign trade, since imported parts and components have
constituted an important channel of technology transfers. It provides evidence that this strategy has led to the
building-up of highly internationalized and competitive industries, but has not helped the upgrading of the
- 20 -
traditional exporting sector, based on domestic inputs, which has lagged behind. These findings tend to confirm
the conclusions put forwards in several studies (Zhang,1999; Sung, 2000, Wu, 1999; Naugthton, 1997; Breslin,
The paper argues that trade and investment liberalization associated with WTO accession will alleviate the
institutional dualism of China’s foreign trade. This will make it possible for the modernization process, which
has up to now been concentrated in export-oriented industries, to spread more widely to the rest of the economy.
However, WTO accession also provides China with the opportunity to expand its textile productions and
exports, thus strengthening its specialization in labor intensive industries, which will help contain the rise of
unemployment. China’s manufacturing industry is thus bound to keep a relatively high degree of technological
dualism. Due to its huge size, China can avoid a narrowly defined specialization and combine comparative
advantages in labor-intensive goods with strengths in high-tech and skill- intensive industries brought in by FDI.
In this context, what is crucial for China’s catch-up process is the development of a strong domestic sector of
competitive firms, which are able to assimilate and disseminate foreign technologies and to create their own
innovative capacities. This is what is at stake in the current effort to rationalize and privatize the state-owned
enterprises. This also makes it necessary to reform the financial system to allow for the expansion of the new
private sector.
NOTES
1. Note that the notions “horizontal” and “vertical” have a different meaning when they refer to product
differentiation: the former concerns similar products, i.e. different varieties, and the latter different qualities.
2. The term “intermediate good” is used for any manufactured goods which are reintroduced into the
3. Trade figures corresponding to these different trade segments are available since 1992. Within each
category it is possible to identify the respective contributions of domestic (wholly Chinese) firms and of the
4. Of course, there is a fraudulent use of import duty exemptions. Goods embodying duty free imports are
sold on the domestic market, as well as parts and components imported on a duty free basis.
5. It is estimated that about 60% of China’s recorded surplus with Hong-Kong (which amounted to 30 billion
US dollars in 1999) stemmed from its trade with the EU and the US. The adjusted figure for China’s surplus
with the EU would be 13 billion US dollars (instead of 4.8 billion); and with the US it would be 32 billion US
- 21 -
dollars (instead of 22 billion). For the methodology, see European Commission (1997); Feenstra, Hai,
7. According to a classification based on the United Nations’ Broad Economic Categories (see Appendix C,
Table 17).
9. Excluding small firms, which represent 40% of the total industrial output.
10. Of course, “successful stories” show that several Chinese firms have been able to take leading positions in
competitive markets but these cases seem to be more the exceptions than the rule.
REFERENCES
Akamatsu, K. (1961). A theory of unbalanced growth in the world economy, Weltwirtschafliches Archiv, 86,
196-215.
Bernard, M., & Ravenhil, J. (1995). Beyond product cycles and flying geese. Regionalization, hierarchy, and
Borrus, M., Ernst, D., & Haggard, S. (2000). International production networks in Asia: rivalry or riches?,
Breslin S. (1999). The politics of Chinese trade and Asian financial crisis: questioning the wisdom of export-led
Coe, D. T., & Helpman, E. (1995). International R&D spillovers, European Economic Review, 39(5), 859-887.
Coe D. T., Helpman, E., & Hoffmaister, A. W. (1995). North-South R&D spillovers, NBER Working Paper,
5048.
Dahlman, C. J., & Aubert, J. E. (2001). China and the knowledge economy. Seizing the 21st Century,
Dées, S., & Lemoine, F. (1999). The devaluation of the Yuan: a little impatience may ruin a great project, La
EC (1997). Comparison of bilateral trade statistics of China and the European Union: discrepancies and
underlying factors, a joint study by the European Commission, the CESD, the Customs General
Administration of the PRC and the International Trade Center UNCTAD/WTO, 4 November, Geneva.
ESCAP UN (1991). Industrial restructuring in Asia and the Pacific, March, Bangkok, United Nations.
- 22 -
Feenstra, R. C., Hai, W., Woo, W. T., & Yao S. (1999). Discrepancies in international data: an application to
Fontagné, L., Freudenberg, M. & Ünal-Kesenci, D. (1999). Trade in technology and quality ladders: where do
561-582.
Guerrieri, P. (2000). International competitiveness, regional integration, and corporate strategies in the East
Asian electronic industry, in Borrus, M., Ernst, D., & Haggard, S. (Eds.), International production
Huang, Y. (2003). Selling China. Foreign direct investment during the reform era, Cambridge University Press.
Huchet, J. F. (1997). The China circle and technological development in the Chinese electronic industry, in
Naughton, B. (Ed.), The China circle: economic and technology in the PRC, Taiwan and Hong-Kong,
Ianchovichina, E., & Martin, W. (2001). Trade liberalization in China’s accession to WTO, Journal of
Ianchovichina E., Martin, W., & Fukase, E. (2000). Comparative study of trade liberalization regimes: the
Case of China’s Accession to the WTO, paper prepared for the Annual Conference of Global Economic
Kaplinsky, R., & Morrus, D. (2002). Globalization of product markets and immisering growth: lessons from the
Keller, W. (2002). Trade and the transmission of technology, Journal of Economic Growth, 7, 5-21.
Keller, W. (2001). The geography and channels of diffusion at the world’s technology frontier, NBER Working
Kojima, K. (2000). The flying gees model of Asian economic development: origin, theoretical extensions, and
Lafay, G. (1994). The measurement of revealed comparative advantages, in Dagenais M. G. & Muet P. A.
Lardy, N. (2002). Integration China into the global economy, Washington, D.C., Brookings Institution Press,
- 23 -
Li, S., & Zhai, F. (2002). China’s WTO accession and its implications for regional economies, Economie
Lyons, P., & Nee V. (Eds.) (1994). The economic transformation of South China, New York, East Asia Program
Cornell University.
Maruya T. (2000). The electric appliance and electronics industry clusters in China: present status and future
Naughton, B. (1996). China’s emergence and prospects as a trading nation, Brookings Paper on Economic
Activity, 2, 273-344.
Naughton, B. (1997). The China circle: economic and technology in the PRC, Taiwan and Hong-Kong,
Ng, F., & Yeats A. (1999). Production sharing in East Asia: who does what, for whom and why?, The World
OECD (1999). Foreign direct investment and recovery in South East Asia, OECD Proceedings, Paris.
OECD (2002). China in the world economy - The Domestic Policy Challenge, Paris.
Sun, H. (1998). Foreign investment and economic development in China:1979-1996, Aldershot. Brookfield,
Sung, Y. W. (2000). Costs and benefits of exports-oriented foreign investment: the case of China, Asian
Szirmai, A., Ren, R., & Bai, M. (2002). How productive is Chinese manufacturing? Comparative labor
productivity in Chinese manufacturing, 1980-1999, paper prepared for the 27th General Conference of The
International Association for Research in Income and Wealth, Stockholm, Sweden, August 18-24.
UNCTAD (1996). Trade and development report 1996, New York and Geneva, United Nations.
UNCTAD (2002). Trade and development report 2002, New York and Geneva, United Nations.
UNCTAD (1999). World investment report: foreign direct investment and the challenge of development, New
Vogel, E. (1989). One step ahead in China. Guangdong under reform, Cambridge, Massachusetts. London,
Wu, Y. (Ed.) (1999). Foreign direct investment and economic growth in China, Cheltenham, UK. Northampton,
Zhang, X. (1999). Foreign investment policy. Contribution and performance, in Wu, Y. (Ed.), Foreign direct
investment and economic growth in China, Cheltenham, UK. Northampton, MA, USA. Edward Elgar.
TABLES
Table 2 Breakdown of China’s foreign trade by main partner and customs regime, 1999
World EU15 US Japan New industrialized economies
Total Hong- Singapore South Taiwan
Kong Korea
in %
Total imports 100 15 12 20 29 4 2 10 12
Ordinary imports 40 9 6 6 7 1 1 4 2
Imports for processing 44 2 3 11 19 3 1 6 9
Other imports 15 4 2 3 3 0 0 1 2
Total exports 100 16 22 17 27 19 2 4 2
Ordinary exports 41 7 6 7 9 6 1 2 1
Processed exports 57 8 15 10 17 12 2 2 1
Other exports 3 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0
billion US dollars
Total trade balance 29 5 22 -1 5 30 0 -9 -16
Ordinary trade 12 -2 1 3 7 11 0 -2 -1
Processing trade 37 13 25 0 2 19 1 -6 -12
Other regimes -20 -6 -3 -4 -4 1 -1 -1 -3
Source: General Administration of Customs of the P. R. China, China Custom Statistics, authors’ calculations.
- 25 -
Table 5. Foreign affiliates in China’s foreign trade with major partners, 1999
World EU-15 US Japan Hong- Singapore South Taiwan
Kong Korea
All export flows (in %) 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
a 45 42 54 55 49 55 44 50
FA total exports
a 38 36 48 43 42 50 36 42
FA processed exports
All import flows (in %) 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100
a 52 49 43 63 60 64 58 65
FA total imports
FA imports for processing 32 12 21 43 50 41 44 50
Trade balance
(in million US dollar)
Overall trade balance 29 232 4 760 22 469 -1 353 29 971 441 -9 419 -15 577
a 2 762 178 14 244 -3 754 13 893 -108 -6 524 -10 773
FA total trade balance
a 21 886 7 872 15 886 -386 11 915 570 -4 705 -8 164
FA processing trade balance
a
FA: Foreign Affiliates.
Source: General Administration of Customs of the P. R. China, China Custom Statistics, authors’ calculations.
- 26 -
a
Table 6. Contribution of foreign affiliates to China’s processing trade by sector , 1999 (in %)
Processed exports Imports for processing
Construction materials 78 84
Vehicles 76 84
Machinery 78 82
Electrical machinery 76 80
Metallic articles 60 79
Leather & shoes 70 78
Metallurgy 47 70
Chemical products 65 68
Precision instruments 69 68
Fiber, thread & cloth materials 66 67
Wood, paper & printed books 65 66
Garments 58 62
Food products 65 61
Raw agricultural products 60 58
Toys & various manufactured goods 53 47
Raw materials, mineral & oil 35 35
Other transportation equipment 48 32
All products 67 72
a
Sectors are ranked according to the share of foreign affiliates in imports.
Source: General Administration of Customs of the P. R. China, China Custom Statistics, authors’ calculations.
Table 9. China’s foreign trade by technology content and production stages (average 1997-99, in %)
Stages Imports Exports
High-tech Other High-tech Other
Primary goods 0 13 0 5
Semi-finished goods 1 40 1 21
Parts & components 8 12 3 6
Capital goods 5 10 3 7
Consumption 0 10 0 53
All stages 14 86 8 92
Source: United Nations, Comtrade database, authors’ calculations.
Table 10. Commodity breakdown of China’s exports and imports of high-tech products (average 1997-99, in %)
Nace Classification Imports Exports
24 Chemical products 5 19
28 Metal products, 1 0
29 Machinery & equipment n.e.c. 5 1
30 Office machinery & computers 17 25
31 Electrical machinery & apparatus n.e.c. 4 3
32 Radio, television & communication equipment 46 42
33 Precision & optical instruments, 9 9
35 Manufacture of other transport equipment 13 1
36 Total 100 100
Source: United Nations, Comtrade database, authors’ calculations.
- 28 -
Table 11. China’s trade in high technology products: breakdown by production stages and major zones
(average 1997-99, in %)
Asia Western America Others World
Europe
Imports Semi-finished products 4 1 1 0 6
Parts & components 42 6 8 1 57
Capital goods 9 16 11 1 37
Consumption goods 0 0 0 0 1
All Stages 55 23 20 2 100
Exports Semi-finished products 10 5 3 1 19
Parts & components 27 5 9 1 42
Capital goods 19 5 9 1 33
Consumption goods 2 1 2 0 5
All Stages 57 16 24 4 100
Source: United Nations, Comtrade database, authors’ calculations.
a
Table 12. China s’ ordinary exports, sectoral breakdown (in %)
Sectoral breakdown Share of Chinese firms
1993 1999 1999
100 100 84
Garments 20 20 90
Chemical products 10 12 87
Raw agricultural products 12 8 77
Fiber, thread & cloth materials 13 8 92
Metallurgy 4 7 87
Raw materials, mineral & oil 10 6 79
Electrical machinery 3 6 82
Wood, paper and printed books 5 5 73
Leather & shoes 4 5 88
Toys & various manufactured goods 3 5 87
Machinery 4 5 82
Food products 6 4 76
Construction materials 2 3 70
Metallic articles 2 2 86
Vehicles 1 1 85
Precision instruments 1 1 80
a
Sectors are ranked according to their share in ordinary exports, descending order.
Source: General Administration of Customs of the P. R. China, China Custom Statistics, authors’ calculations.
- 29 -
a
Table 13. China’s exports by custom regime and type of firm , 1999, (in % of total exports)
All Processed exports Ordinary exports
exports Foreign Chinese Foreign Chinese
firms firms firms firms
Total 100 38 19 6 34
Electrical machinery 17 11 3 0 2
Garments 15 4 3 1 7
Machinery 10 6 2 0 2
Chemical products 8 2 1 1 4
Leather & shoes 7 3 1 0 2
Toys & various manufactured goods 7 3 2 0 2
Fiber, thread & cloth materials 6 2 1 0 3
Metallurgy 5 1 1 0 2
Wood, paper and printed books 5 2 1 1 2
Raw agricultural products 4 0 0 1 2
Precision instruments 4 2 1 0 0
Raw materials, mineral and oil 3 0 0 1 2
Food products 3 0 0 0 1
Other transportation equipment 2 1 1 0 0
Construction materials 2 0 0 0 1
Metallic articles 1 0 0 0 1
Vehicles 1 1 0 0 1
a
Sectors are ranked according to their share in China's exports, descending order.
Source: General Administration of Customs of the P. R. China, China Customs Statistics, authors’ calculations.
- 30 -
APPENDIX A
Table 14. China’s nominal and collected tariff rates on manufactured products (in %)
1997 Tariff Rate
Nominal Collected
Processed food 23.2 3.7
Beverage 60.2 24.0
Tobacco 49.1 10.6
Textile 27.5 0.2
Apparel 41.8 0.7
Leather 35.5 0.3
Sawmills and furniture 14.4 2.5
Paper & printing 11.0 3.1
Social articles 3.1 1.0
Petroleum refining 8.7 4.8
Chemicals 10.8 3.0
Medicine 10.9 7.2
Chemical fibers 15.5 1.0
Rubber and plastics 19.8 2.0
Building materials 20.8 3.6
Primary iron and steel 8.1 2.0
Non-ferrous metals 7.1 0.9
Metal products 13.1 2.4
Machinery 13.7 4.2
Special equipment 14.1 2.6
Automobile 50.7 32.6
Other transport equipment 5.6 1.3
Electrical machinery 17.9 3.1
Electronics 11.8 2.1
Instruments 12.5 2.3
Other manufacturing 38.9 0.9
Manufacturing sector average 11.2 2.5
Source: Li & Zhai (2002).
- 31 -
APPENDIX B
a
Table 15. Foreign affiliate industrial output by sector in China, 2001 (in %)
Output by sector Share in sector output
Total industry 100.0 28.5
Electronic and telecommunications equipment 24.4 73.8
Transport equipment 7.4 30.9
Electric equipment and machinery 6.7 33.4
Chemical products 5.0 21.8
Textile industry 4.5 21.9
Garments & other fiber products 4.4 46.0
Metal products 3.7 35.7
Food processing 3.6 23.8
Plastic products 3.4 43.7
Leather, furs 3.1 54.5
Ordinary machinery 2.8 22.0
Nonmetal mineral products 2.8 19.1
Food manufacturing 2.4 40.3
Papermaking & paper products 2.1 31.6
Instruments, office machinery 2.0 58.3
Beverage manufacturing 2.0 29.9
Smelting & pressing of ferrous metals 1.7 8.1
Medical & pharmaceutical products 1.7 22.2
Petroleum & coke processing 1.5 9.1
Special purpose equipment 1.5 17.7
Cultural, educational & sports goods 1.5 60.0
Rubber products 1.1 34.8
Non ferrous metals 1.1 12.1
Printing & recording 0.9 33.5
Chemical fiber 0.8 22.1
Timber processing, 0.8 28.8
Petroleum & natural gas extraction 0.8 7.5
Furniture manufacturing 0.7 45.7
a
Sectors are ranked according to their share in foreign affiliate output.
Source: National Bureau of Statistics of China (2002).
- 32 -
The trade data used in this study come from two sources: China’s Customs Statistics and the Comtrade database
1) Trade data from China’s Customs statistics were available at the two-digit level of HS classification
(Harmonized Nomenclature). The 98 items have been grouped into 17 sectors (Table 16).
• Products have been reclassified by stage of production, using a correspondence table based on a revised
version of the Broad Economic Categories (BEC) of the United nations. The BEC has been elaborated by
the UN, and it was derived from the SITC, rev.3 (standard International Trade Classification). SITC items
are reclassified according to the principal use of products. More specifically, foreign trade data has been
reclassified into categories corresponding to the final or intermediate use of the products, in accordance with
the system of National Accounts. In this study, BEC categories have been reclassified as indicated in
Table 17.
- 33 -
by Fontagné, Freudenberg and Ünal-Kesenci (1999). The classification derives from a joint list elaborated
by the OECD and Eurostat. It includes 252 high-technology products identified at the six-digit level of the
HS classification. They belong to nine production sectors: 1) aeronautics, 2) office machinery and
Different types of indicator have been used for measuring revealed comparative advantages. The early attempts
to quantify revealed comparative advantages were based on export data. These ratios were in fact indexes of
“export specialisation” and failed to take into account imports while it has become more and more necessary to
incorporate imports in the measure of comparative advantage. As the international division of labour has
intensified, imports have become an important factor for explaining export performance.
The indicator which is used in this part of the paper to analyse the comparative advantages of China follows the
methodology designed at the CEPII for building the indicator of contribution to trade balance.
x − mik x − mi x + mik
CTB = ik − i x ik x1000 where i = country; k = branch; x = exports; m = imports.
( xi + mi ) ( xi + mi ) xi + mi
The first term measures the country’s trade balance for a given commodity weighted by the total trade of the
country.
- 34 -
Comparative advantage is a concept which refers to the structural characteristics of the national economies
(Lafay, 1994) so, the second term is meant to eliminate the effects of short-term fluctuations (trade deficits or
surplus), connected to macroeconomic factors. It measures the “expected” trade balance of the given
commodity, assuming that each commodity contributes to the overall trade balance in proportion of its weight in
total trade. The overall trade deficit is thus distributed among commodities according to their respective share in
total trade.
The indicator of contribution to trade balance thus compares the country’s actual trade balance for a given
commodity to the “expected” trade balance for this commodity. The difference between the actual trade balance
for a commodity and the “expected” trade balance for the same commodity measures its specific contribution to
the total trade balance. The contribution is positive when the actual trade surplus is larger than the expected
trade surplus and also when the relative trade deficit is smaller than the expected trade deficit. The indicator
highlights the relative strengths and weaknesses of individual sectors in the country’s trade. The commodity
contributions to the country’s trade balances may be added and the sum is zero, by definition.