Intt 442
Intt 442
Intt 442
HORIZONTAL AGREEMENTS are those entered into by and between two (2) or more
competitors. For example, two (2) competing manufacturers could collude and agree to sell the
same product at the same price.
VERTICAL AGREEMENTS are those entered into by and between two (2) or more entities at
different levels of distribution or production chains such as those entered into by suppliers,
manufacturers, distributors, and retailers. Examples include distribution, agency, and franchising
agreements.
Article 101(1) TFEU inapplicable to certain (cooperation) agreements that fulfil conditions
under 101(3) TFEU (procompetitive effects): R&D, specialization, application of standards
Bid-Rigging — Parties participating in a tender process coordinate their bids, rather than submit
independent bid prices
Output-Limitations — Agreements which, among others, limit output or control production by
fixing production levels or setting quotas, or agreements which deal with structural overcapacity
or coordination of future investment plans.
Market-Sharing — Producers restrict their sales of goods and services to certain geographic
areas, developing local monopolies.
Generally speaking, a cartel is an association of businesses in the same industry colluding with
one another to susbtantially prevent, restrict, or lessen competition. Cartels and collusive
agreements as described above are illegal. They result in anti-competitive practices like price-
fixing and market-sharing, which, in turn, reduce output and raise prices.
Antitrust rules prohibit agreements between market operators that would restrict competition,
and the abuse of dominance. European Antitrust policy is developed from two central rules set
out in the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union:
Article 101 of the Treaty prohibits agreements between two or more independent market
operators, which restrict competition
The most flagrant example of illegal conduct infringing Article 101 is the creation of a cartel
between competitors, which may involve price-fixing and/or market sharing.
Article 102 of the Treaty prohibits firms that hold a dominant position on a given market to abuse
that position, for example by charging unfair prices, by limiting production, or by refusing to
innovate to the prejudice of consumers.
The Commission is empowered by the Treaty to apply these rules and has a number of
investigative powers to that end (e.g. inspections at business and non-business premises,
written requests for information, etc.). The Commission may also impose fines on undertakings
which violate the European Antitrust rules. The main rules on procedures are set out in Council
Regulation (EC) 1/2003.
Cartels are generally highly secretive and hard to detect. The Commission’s leniency
programme encourages companies to hand over inside evidence of cartels in exchange for
immunity for fines or a substantial reduction of fines. The first company in any cartel to apply for
leniency, may receive full immunity, if the information it provides is sufficient for the Commission
to start an investigation. The Commission also carries out its own investigations to detect
cartels.
Individuals may report any inside knowledge or suspicion of a cartel to the Commission through
the "whistleblower" tool.
Cartel participants can settle their case by acknowledging their involvement in the cartel and
thereby receiving a 10% reduction in any eventual fine. The settlement procedure brings
efficiencies for the Commission and the parties by reducing the time of the investigations, a
limited access to file procedure and shorter final decisions.
In cartel cases, the Commission or the parties may propose a settlement. The Commission may
reject the settlement route for cases that are not suitable. In settlement cases, the parties
acknowledge upfront their participation in the cartel, resulting in a speedier procedure and an up
to 10% reduction in the fines. The Commission presents parties with the evidence and notifies
them of its conclusions as to duration, seriousness, liability and likely fine. The parties must
make an oral or written submission acknowledging their liability and stating that they accept the
Commission's statement of objections. The settlement procedure allows the Commission to
adopt a faster, more streamlined decision and to allocate resources to other cases.
https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_20_1774
The Guidelines make clear that any information exchange with the objective of restricting
competition in the market will be considered a restriction of competition, regardless of its actual
effect on the market. Accordingly, if the aim of the exchange of information is to fix prices,
quantities or other terms of trade, it would be considered and treated as cartel activity
regardless of whether such information exchange has an actual effect on the market. In other
words, once the Board establishes that the exchange of information is a restriction of
competition by object, it is no longer required to analyse the effect of such exchange. The
exchange of strategic information such as future prices or sales amounts generally fall under
this category and would typically be treated as cartel activity.
Exchanges of information may also lead to infringement of competition laws where the
objective is not to restrict competition. In this case, the actual and potential effects on
competition of such an exchange must be analysed on a case-by-case basis. As a first
step, the characteristics of the market as well as the nature of the information
exchanged must be assessed. Secondly, it is necessary to analyse whether the pro-
competitive benefits of the information exchange (if any) outweigh the anti-competitive
effects.
The Guidelines list five main market characteristics that increase the likelihood of
information exchanges resulting in a collusive outcome:
Transparent
Information exchanges may increase market transparency. The more transparent the
market in terms of prices, costs, volume, demand, output, etc., the more likely that
exchanges of information may result in the restriction of competition.
Concentrated
The fewer the number of competitors in a market, the more likely that information
exchanges will have restrictive effects.
Stable
Information exchanges may decrease volatility in a market. It is easier to collude in a
stable market in terms of demand, supply, market share, number of competitors, etc.
Therefore, the more stable the market, the more likely that information exchanges
will restrict competition.
Symmetric
Companies with similar cost structures, market shares, product range, capacities, etc.
are more likely to end up with a collusive outcome through the exchange of
information.
Non- Complex
It is harder to restrict competition through information exchanges in complex markets
covering a number of differentiated products.
Information exchanges
• Direct – indirect (trade associations, market research organization etc)
•
Characteristics of information:
The Guidelines lists the following factors that affect the assessment of whether
information exchanged is likely to raise competition law concerns:
Market Coverage
Information exchanges covering a substantial portion of the market are more likely to
raise competition law concerns.
Aggregated / Individualized
The exchange of genuinely aggregated data, which would make identification of the
individual data of a particular company difficult, is not likely to have restrictive effects.
Age of Data
The older the data, the less likely it is to have restrictive effects. Exchange of
historic data is unlikely to be problematic; however, there is no threshold to determine
how dated the data must be in order to be considered historic. This would require case-
by-case analysis. On the other hand, the exchange of current and especially future data
is generally considered problematic.
Frequency of Exchange
Frequent exchanges of information are more likely to lead to concerns compared to
infrequent exchanges; however, it should be noted that even one single exchange of
information may be considered restrictive.
Public / Non- public Information
The exchange of genuinely public information, described in the Guidelines as
information that is equally accessible to all competitors and customers in terms of
cost of access, is unlikely to restrict competition. A distinction should be made
between genuinely public information and publicly available information, the exchange
of which may give rise to a collusive outcome. The cost of collecting such data is an
important factor in the analysis and should be assessed on a case-by-case basis.
In cases where it has been established that the exchange of information is likely to have
restrictive effects due to market characteristics and the nature of information
exchanged, the next step would be to determine whether there are any pro-competitive
effects of the exchange and, if so, whether such pro-competitive effects outweigh the
restrictive effects of the exchange. In order to do so, based on Article 5 of the Law on
the Protection of Competition No. 4054, companies must show: (i) gains in efficiency, (ii)
consumer benefits arising from such efficiencies, (iii) that competition is not eliminated
in a significant part of the market and (iv) that competition is not restricted more than
necessary to achieve such efficiencies and consumer benefits.
Production agreements
Purchasing agreements
● joint purchase of products – alliance, association of undertakings
● aim at the creation of buying power which can lead to lower prices or better-
quality products
● Restrictive effects due to the buying power of parties
● Foreclosure of competing purchasers
● Market power
● restrict competition by object if they serve as a tool to engage in a disguised
cartel
Commercialization agreements
Standardization agreements
Information that has been put in the public domain for legitimate reasons – and
therefore has become readily accessible (in terms of access costs) to all competitors
and customers251 – is usually not commercially sensitive.
This may be the case, for example, where the information is exchanged in a less
aggregated or more granular form, or the information is exchanged more frequently than
it is made publicly available, or when comments are attached to the information that
may signal to competitors the desired joint action to undertake. In that case, the
information exchange may restrict competition within the meaning of Article 101(1)
An online platform can also act as a hub where it facilitates, coordinates or enforces
information exchanges between business users of the platform, for example, to secure
certain margins or price levels. Platforms may also be used to impose technical
measures which prevent platform users from offering lower prices or other advantages
to final customers.
Information may also be exchanged indirectly via a shared optimisation algorithm which
takes commercial decisions based on commercially sensitive data feeds from
competitors.
the restrictive agreement must lead to economic benefits, such as improvements in the
production or distribution of products or the promotion of technical or economic
progress, i.e. efficiency gains;
the restrictions must be indispensable to the attainment of the efficiency gains;
consumers must receive a fair share of the resulting efficiency gains attained by
indispensable restrictions;
the agreement must offer the parties no possible elimination of competition in relation to
a substantial part of the products in question.
Where these four criteria are met, the efficiency gains generated by an agreement can
be considered to offset the restrictions of competition generated by it.
An information exchange may lead to efficiency gains, depending on the nature of the
information exchanged, the characteristics of the exchange and the structure of the
market.
Restrictions that go beyond what is necessary to achieve the efficiency gains generated
by an information exchange do not fulfil the conditions of Article 101(3).To fulfil the
condition of indispensability, the parties must be able to prove that the nature of the
information exchanged and the characteristics of the exchange are the least restrictive
means of generating the claimed efficiency gains. In particular, the exchange should not
involve information that goes beyond the variables that are relevant for the attainment of
the efficiency gains.
The lower the market power of the undertakings involved in the information exchange,
the more likely it is that the efficiency gains will be passed on to consumers to an extent
that outweighs the restrictive effects on competition.
The conditions of Article 101(3) cannot be met if the undertakings involved in the
information exchange are afforded the possibility of eliminating competition in respect of
a substantial part of the products concerned.
Block Exemption Regulations
The block exemption regulations issued pursuant to Article 101(3) TFEU specify the
conditions under which certain types of agreements are exempted from the prohibition
of restrictive agreements laid down in Article 101(1) TFEU.
The Horizontal Block Exemption Regulations are two Commission regulations that
define certain research and development and specialisation agreements that can be
considered more beneficial than harmful. Agreements that meet the conditions of these
regulations are therefore exempted from Article 101(1) of the Treaty.
Abuse of Dominance
Article 102 TFEU
Dominance → economic strength that enables undertakings to prevent effective competition from being
maintained in a relevant market, by affording it, its customers.
Dominance is not likely if below 40%
Dominance has been defined under Community law as a position of economic strength enjoyed
by an undertaking, which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on a
relevant market, by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of
its competitors, its customers and ultimately of consumers
• Competition constraints to be considered: existing suppliers, actual and potential
competitors, market position, strength of customers
The assessment of dominance will take into account the competitive structure of the market,
and in particular the following factors:
— constraints imposed by the existing supplies from, and the position on the market of,
actual competitors (the market position of the dominant undertaking and its
competitors),
— constraints imposed by the credible threat of future expansion by actual competitors or
entry by potential competitors (expansion and entry),
Consider:
A dominant undertaking may try to foreclose its competitors by tying or bundling. This
section sets out the circumstances which are most likely to prompt an intervention by the
Commission when assessing tying and bundling by dominant undertakings.
‘Tying’ usually refers to situations where customers that purchase one product (the tying
product) are required also to purchase another product from the dominant undertaking (the tied
product). Tying can take place on a technical or contractual basis (33). ‘Bundling’ usually refers
to the way products are offered and priced by the dominant undertaking. In the case of pure
bundling the products are only sold jointly in fixed proportions. In the case of mixed bundling,
often referred to as a multi-product rebate, the products are also made available separately, but
the sum of the prices when sold separately is higher than the bundled price.
two products are distinct if, in the absence of tying or bundling, a substantial number of
customers would purchase or would have purchased the tying product without also buying the
tied product from the same supplier, thereby allowing stand-alone production for both the tying
and the tied product
Predation
in line with its enforcement priorities, the Commission will generally intervene where there is
evidence showing that a dominant undertaking engages in predatory conduct by deliberately
incurring losses or foregoing profits in the short term (referred to hereafter as ‘sacrifice’), so as
to foreclose or be likely to foreclose one or more of its actual or potential competitors with a view
to strengthening or maintaining its market power, thereby causing consumer harm
The Commission will consider these practices as an enforcement priority if all the following
circumstances are present: