024 Article A001 en
024 Article A001 en
024 Article A001 en
in Developing Countries
A Conceptual Framework
5
Until now most studies that have analyzed the effect of stabilization policies
on output, prices, and the balance of payments in developing countries have not
included the interest rate as a possible transmission mechanism. The main reason
for this omission is that the experience with liberalized capital markets is still
relatively recent. A theoretical discussion, however, of the effects of a stabiliza-
tion program working through increases in real interest rates is contained in
Dornbusch (1982b).
where
i = the nominal rate of interest
rr = the real (ex ante) rate of interest
Tte = the expected rate of inflation.
The real interest rate in turn can be specified as
6
We are ignoring here, for example, the effects of taxation on the relation
between expected inflation and the nominal interest rate. On this topic see
Darby (1975), and Tanzi (1976).
7
Note that EMSt could also affect TT*. Furthermore, it is assumed here that
changes in < have no direct effects on rrt. On these types of effects, see Mundell
(1963).
Recent empirical studies on interest rate behavior in the United States in-
clude, among others, Fama (1975), Tanzi (1980), Makin (1982), and Melvin
(1983).
9
In this formulation the weights of the lag distribution are not assumed to
follow any specific pattern.
10
These would be the empirical representations of the rational expectations
model in which economic agents are assumed to take into account all available
information in forming their (conditional) expectations.
11
Note that equation (4) is only one of the alternative ways to specify excess
money supply, or monetary disequilibrium. For example, it can be postulated
that only money surprises will influence the real interest rate (Makin (1982)). In
such a case EMS would have to be replaced by some proxy of unanticipated
monetary changes in equation (2).
12
Of course, one could also introduce an "own" rate of return into the money
demand formulation. This would certainly be advisable when dealing with broad
definitions of money that include deposits paying positive rates of interest (see
Mathieson (1982, 1983)). Because we work with narrow money (currency plus
demand deposits) throughout, in our case this omission is obviously not serious,
since demand deposits typically are non-interest-bearing.
The workings of the model given by equations (3), (4), and (6)
can be conveniently described within the framework of Figure 1.
In the figure the initial equilibrium is point A, where the long-run
demand for real money balances is equal to the supply (EMS = 0),
the nominal interest rate is at its equilibrium level (p + ire), and
the actual stock of real money balances is equal to m0. Suppose
now that there is an increase in the supply of money from msQ to
m(. This would create an excess supply of real money balances
(EMS >0), and the nominal interest rate would fall below its
equilibrium value (say, to ^). The movement from A to B in
essence represents the short-run liquidity effect we referred to
earlier. B, however, is only a temporary equilibrium position
because in the next period the (unchanged) long-run demand for
money is less than the actual stock in the previous period,
m?+l<mt(=ms2}\ therefore, by equation (6) the actual stock of
real money balances would begin to decline. In Figure 1 the m 5
schedule would shift to the left until the actual money supply is
once again equal to equilibrium money demand, and conse-
quently the nominal interest rate would be given by p + rf.
Figure 1. Interest Rate Determination in a Closed Economy
Using equations (1), (5), and (7), we can derive the reduced-form
equation for the nominal interest rate:
14
From a methodological point of view, even if interest-parity arbitrage differ-
entials are white noise it is still possible that other variables, besides the world
interest rate and the expected rate of devaluation, will affect the domestic
interest rate. For this reason a more appropriate procedure is to test directly
whether other variables suggested by the theory have an effect on /,.
15
In a more recent study of Uruguay, Blejer and Gil Diaz (1985) found that
the risk premium was highly serially correlated.
16
During the period when the parity condition does not exactly hold there
would obviously be unexploited profit opportunities. The attempts by trans-
actors to take advantage of these opportunities would set in motion the very
forces that would bring about equality between domestic and foreign interest
rates (adjusted for expected exchange rate changes). How long this process takes
is an empirical question and would have to be estimated from the data.
17
It is, of course, assumed here that the degree of openness (v|/) is constant over
time. The implications of relaxing this assumption, and the possible procedures
for doing so, are considered in Section III.
18
Strictly speaking, in the shift from the closed economy to the open economy
case the demand for money function should be generalized to allow for foreign
interest rates, the expected change in the exchange rate, or both. A suggested
procedure for doing so is presented in Section III (under "Effects of Currency
Substitution").
19
Note that when 6 = 1 the lagged interest rate term would drop from the
specification, so that the equilibrium model is only a restricted version of this
formulation.
The model presented here has its limitations and can obviously
be expanded in several directions. In this section we briefly discuss
four possible extensions: (1) analysis of the determinants of real
interest rates in developing countries; (2) analysis of interest rate
behavior during the process of liberalization of the capital account
of the balance of payments; (3) explicit modeling of the expected
rate of devaluation in the context of interest rate behavior in open
developing countries; and (4) consideration of the effects of cur-
rency substitution. This list is by no means exhaustive; specifi-
cally, it does not incorporate various econometric issues that
could arise in estimating a model of interest rate determination.
Such issues would include, among others, simultaneity, specifica-
tion of the underlying dynamics, and the proper treatment of the
error structure. Here we focus on what we see as the principal
theoretical extensions.
30 Bleier and Gil Diaz (1985) specify a two-equation model for the real interest
rate and inflation. Their model, of course, can be used to determine the nominal
interest rate as well.
31
Note also that \|> would depend on the interest rate chosen. For different
interest rates one could easily have different values of i|i. We are indebted to
Michael Mussa for this point.
The last term in this modified equation would then capture the
effects of currency substitution.
This type of formulation would not be applicable in the extreme
cases of interest rate determination in completely closed and com-
pletely open economies. In a closed economy the variable e would
obviously not enter; in a fully open economy domestic monetary
disequilibrium (and thus the demand for money), with or without
currency substitution, does not matter. Equation (5 a) would cer-
tainly be relevant in the intermediate case, which of course does
correspond to the actual case in most developing countries.
IV. Conclusions
APPENDIX
This Appendix briefly gives the major sources of the country data and defines the
principal variables used in the model.
Colombia (1968-82)
The basic sources for the data were Montes and Candelo (1982); Direccion
Nacional de Planeacion (DNP); Direccion Administrativa Nacional de
Estadistica (DANE), Boletin Mensual de Estadistica (Bogota), various issues;
and International Financial Statistics (IPS), International Monetary Fund (Wash-
ington), various issues.
The definitions of the variables and specific sources are as follows:
e Percentage change in the official buying rate for export receipts and
capital inflows (Montes and Candelo (1982), and DNP)
i Domestic interest rate: for 1968-69, the average rate on mortgage bills,
for 1970-82, the effective annual yield on three-month certificados
de abono tributario, or tax certificates (Montes and Candelo (1982)
and DNP)
/* Three-month U.S. Treasury bill rate (IPS)
M Narrow (Ml) money balances: for 1968-80, data are from Montes and
Candelo (1982); for 1981-82, from DNP
P Consumer price index (DANE, Boletin Mensual de Estadistica)', TT is
defined as the percentage change in this index
y Quarterly real gross domestic product (GDP; Montes and Candelo
(1982)); updated through 1982.
Singapore (1976-83)
The sources of the data are IPS and the Monetary Authority of Singapore
(MAS), Monthly Bulletin (Singapore), various issues.
The definitions and specific sources are as follows:
e Three-month forward premium (MAS)
/ Three-month interbank rate (MAS)
/* Three-month Eurodollar rate (IPS)
M Narrow (Ml) money balances (IPS)
P Consumer price index (IPS); the variable IT is defined as the percent-
age change in this index
y Quarterly real GDP; the annual series were obtained from IPS and
interpolated to a quarterly basis using an index of manufacturing
production, also from IPS.
REFERENCES