002 MRK Pwr.... 1 Removed
002 MRK Pwr.... 1 Removed
002 MRK Pwr.... 1 Removed
Small-scale
Industrialisation
Small Industry
Rationale for Supporting Small-scale Enterprises
THE arguments advanced in the literature for promotion of small-
scale enterprises involve both certain desirable characteristics of such
enterprises and also a common belief that under normal market
conditions many such enterprises would not be able to survive in the
economy. A list of desirable characteristics of such enterprises include,
i n t e r a l i a , higher labour intensity and related positive income
distribution effects, their potential for balanced regional development
through greater decentralisation, their contribution to the promotion of
entrepreneurship, their flexibility in operation, and their ability to
export. If these positive characteristics are seen to be important and if
there is reason to believe that market failures inhibit the growth of small-
scale enterprises then it would be appropriate to frame policies that
attack these market imperfections.
however, that the higher wages facing large firms can generally be
compensated by higher efficiency of the workforce so that the wage
cost difference per efficiency unit of labour is much less than the
observed difference in the prices of capital. Thus, it can be argued
that distortions in the capital market are much more important than
those in the labour market. Large firms are able to compensate the
higher wages through higher efficiency, but small firms are not able
to compensate for the high cost of capital through higher efficiency
of the capital used. Similarly in the land market small enterprises
could face greater regulatory hurdles in achieving appropriate access
to land.
In his study Rakesh Mohan has argued that this support structure
may have reflected well the needs of the 1950s, 1960s and 1970s. The
argument is that these policies have now become obsolete and are now
likely to be harmful to the development of small-scale industries and of
industrial development in general. There has been vast growth of small
units over the years. Thus, the governmental structure for technical
support of small-scale industries has become both obsolete and
inadequate. There is now much greater availability of private sector
business and technological support service which should be fostered.
Second with the opening of the economy the reservation policy has
become counter productive. Third, the fiscal concessions can also be
Small-scale Industrialisation 401
operating so as to discourage growth into large units. Thus, it is argued
that a whole new approach for supporting small-scale industries has to
be adopted in India to serve the changing needs of the new open
economy.
STATEMENT
Investment Ceilings for Small-scale Industry (December 1999)
In recent years, with the opening of Indian trade almost 75 per cent
of all reserved items are now already importable with the removal of
quantitative restrictions (QRs) in the last few years. India is also
committed to remove the remaining QRs by April 2001. We, therefore,
now have a curious situation that the reserved items can be produced
by large foreign enterprises and imported into India whereas Indian large
enterprises are not allowed to produce the same items! Even this change
in the external environment has so far not persuaded the authorities to
change this policy of small-scale industry reservation.
404 Indian Economy: Performance and Polities
It is possible that the damage caused by such policies was not very
high in the 1970s, when competition in exports of low technology
products was not as high as it is now. Furthermore, changing industry
structure and demand patterns in the developed world now place a much
higher premium on both product quality and service quality with the
inexorably rising incomes there. The average quality demanded for
products such as clothing, footwear, toys and sports equipment and the
like is getting higher and higher. Furthermore, the integration of
information technology in even these industries also requires greater
investment and greater labour sophistication. Such products are no longer
seen as free standing products but are increasingly becoming parts of long
value chains with the share of value added in plain manufacturing perhaps
falling. Higher quality requires high level designing upstream even for
simple products. Downstream marketing involves linkages with large
organisations which buy such products in bulk. Small enterprises
sandwiched between such high level organisations find it increasingly
difficult to operate and be competitive. Thus, apart from the loss that India
has suffered over the last 2-3 decades it is likely that the future scenario
will become even more difficult for Indian small enterprises to survive,
particularly in the reserved sector. Another issue of note is the prospective
dismantling of the Multi-Fibre Agreement. Paradoxically, although it may
have seemed that textile quotas were inhibiting Indian exports, it is likely
that we were actually protected through the MFA mechanism. This is
shown in Somnath Chatterjee and Rakesh Mohan (1993) who documented
406 Indian Economy; Performance and Policiej
the fact that Indian clothing exports went primarily to quota countries
and were almost absent in the markets of non-quota countries. Thus, the
removal of small-scale reservation is especially necessary in the items
affected by the removal of MFA.
S m a l l a n d T i n y E n t e r p r i s e s
The primary objective of the NSEP as mentioned under the above
head, is to impart "more vitality and growth impetus". In as-much-as
408 Indian Economy: Performance and Policia
Village Industries
Although the objectives and policy measures for village industries
are presented separately for handlooms, handicrafts and other village
industries, there is a lot that is common for them in the NSEP as regards
both objectives and measures. To avoid repetition, it may therefore be
best to examine first the proposals of the NSEP for these industries
together and then draw attention to their special features individually.
410 Indian Economy: Performance and Policies
TABLE - 19.1
Performance of Micro and Small-scale Enterprises
Year No. of units (lakh) Production (Rs. crore)
Employ-
ment Exports
Regd. Unregd. Total (at current (at constant (in (Rs.
prices) prices) lakh) crore)
2002-03 15.91 93.58 109.49 3,11,993 2,10,636 260.21 86,013
(4.1) (10.5) (7.7) (4.4) (20.7)
2003-04 16.97 96.98 113.95 3,57,733 2,28,730 271.42 97,644
(4.1) (14.7) (8.6) (4.3) (13.5)
2004-05 17.53 101.06 118.59 4,18,263 2,51,511 282,57 1,24,417
(4.1) (16.9) (10.0) (4.1) (27.4)
2005-06 18.71 104.71 123.42 4,76,201 2,77,668 294.91 N.A.
(4.1) (13.9) (10.4) (4.4)
The Approach Paper to the 11th Plan states there is need to change
the approach from emphasis on loosely targeted subsidies to creating
an enabling environment. A cluster approach can help increase viability
by providing these units with infrastructure, information, credit, and
support services of better quality at lower costs, while also promoting
their capacity for effective management of their own collectives. The
11th Five Year Plan should restrict subsidies to those needed to create
a level playing field and to reflect the costs or benefits to others in the
society. It should incentivize innovation and creativity. It should remove
all entry barriers and mitigate business risks for start-ups, the latter,
inter-alia, through a large number of well-managed business incubators
in the identified thrust areas of manufacturing. It should provide
infrastructure and liberate MSEs from the inspector raj. Further, in order
to improve the competitiveness of these micro, small and medium
enterprises, schemes for establishment of mini tool rooms, setting up
design clinics, providing marketing support, sensitization to IPR
requirements and tools, adoption of lean manufacturing practices, wider
use of IT tools, etc., should be evolved on a PPP basis. Brand building
can be used as an effective strategy to promote their products in national
and international markets.
Introduction
THE growth-augmenting role of external trade and foreign capital
flows has assumed critical importance in India in recent years. The
overall shift in the policy stance in India from export pessimism and
foreign exchange conservation to one that assigns an important role to
export of goods and services in the growth process has primarily been
guided by the perception that an open trade regime could offer a
dynamic vehicle for attaining higher economic growth.
I
FOREIGN CAPITAL VERSUS EXPORT-LED GROWTH
GDP, that would tantamount to no role for net external financing as the
country must necessarily save more than it can invest, leading to net
capital outflows. The underlying assumption behind this assessment is
that an export-led growth strategy can stimulate growth only by
generating a surplus in the external goods and services account. The
actual external resource transfer process and the stages over which the
importance of each form of transfer changes can explain how a
developing country could simultaneously benefit from both export-led
and capital-flow-induced growth strategies.
II
across countries nor can large capital flows make any significant
difference to the growth rate that a country could achieve (Krugman,
1993). In the subsequent resurrection of the two-gap approach, the
emphasis was generally laid on the preconditions that could make
foreign capital more productive in developing countries. The important
preconditions comprised presence of surplus labour and excess productive
demand for foreign exchange. With the growing influence of the new
growth theories in the second half of the 1980s that recognised the effects
of positive externalities associated with capital accumulation on growth,
the role of foreign capital in the growth process assumed renewed
importance. In the endogenous growth framework, the sources of growth
attributed to capital flows comprise:
Portfolio Capital
Portfolio capital has emerged as the key channel for integrating
capital markets worldwide. For developing countries, the growth process
in the initial phase is often characterised by self-financed capital
investment, which is replaced gradually by bank-intermediated debt
finance and supplemented over time by both debt and equity from the
capital market. Portfolio capital flows can ease the constraint on growth
imposed by illiquid and small sized capital markets in the early and
intermediate stages of the growth process. Countries that reduced
barriers to portfolio flows exhibit significant improvements in the
functioning of their stock markets. Greater liquidity in the capital market
makes it possible to take up investment projects in developing countries
that require lumpy and long-term capital. Equity, unlike debt, allows a
permanent access to capital.
External Aid
The role of external aid in enhancing growth has waned in recent
years. In several developing countries, including India, public and
publicly guaranteed capital flows have been supplanted by a growing
recourse to private capital flows. In some countries, the problem of
Role of Foreign Capital 421
negative resource transfer associated with aid has emerged as an
additional balance of payments/growth constraint. Except for the poorest
countries and those with very limited access to commercial capital, a
general sense of aid fatigue has set in. Donors have also gradually de-
emphasised the role of aid in international economic relations resulting
in a significant decline in aid flows as percentage of GDP of the donors
since the 1960s.
External aid was initially equated with the need for resource transfer
to ease the financing constraint to growth. The major contradiction that
surfaced soon was that while the poorest countries had the greatest need
for external aid, their capacity to absorb foreign aid was highly
unsatisfactory. In the 1980s, structural reforms were seen as the key to
promote growth and the earlier project-linked aid strategy was
supplemented by non-project linked structural adjustment lending as an
additional instrument to augment growth. Lack of sound policy
environment in the aid receiving countries has operated as a major factor
in eroding aid effectiveness (World Bank, 1998). Despite the general
dissatisfaction with aid effectiveness, factors such as lower cost and
higher maturity of aid in relation to commercial loans has encouraged
many developing countries to maintain their access to aid flows.
III
A large part of the net capital flows to India in the capital account
is being offset by the debt servicing burden. As a consequence, net
resource transfers have fluctuated quite significantly in the 1990s,
turning negative in 1995-96.
Till the early 1980s, the capital account of the balance of payments
had essentially a financing function (Rangarajan, 1996). Nearly 80 per
cent of the financing requirement was met through external assistance,
Aid financed imports were both largely ineffectual in increasing the rate
of growth and were responsible for bloating the inefficient public sector
(Kamath, 1992). Due to the tied nature of bilateral aid, India had to
pay 20 to 30 per cent higher prices in relation to what it could have got
through international bidding (Riddell, 1987). The real resource transfer
424 Indian Economy: Performance and Policies
associated with aid to India, therefore, was much lower. There were
occasions "when India accepted bilateral aid almost reluctantly and
without enthusiasm because of the combination of low priority of the
project and the inflated price of the goods". The Report of the High
Level Committee on Balance of Payments (1993) identified a number
of factors constraining effective aid utilisation in India and underscored
the need to initiate urgent action on both reducing the overhang of
unutilised aid and according priority to externally aided projects in
terms of plan allocations and budgetary provisions. Net resource transfer
under aid to India, however, turned negative in the second half of the
1990s.
The need for supplementing debt capital with non-debt capital with
a clear prioritisation in favour of the latter has characterised the
government policy framework for capital flows in the 1990s. The High-
Level Committee on Balance of Payments recommended the need for
achieving this compositional shift. A major shift in the policy stance
occurred in 1991-92 with the liberalisation of norms for foreign direct
and portfolio investment in India.
There has been a paradigm shift in the policies on FDI right from
the early nineties with the adoption of the Industrial Policy Statement
of July 1991. One of the objectives of Industrial Policy Statement was
that "foreign investment and technology collaboration will be welcomed
to obtain higher technology, to increase exports and to expand the
production base". The Industrial Policy Statement of 1991 has followed
an 'open-door' policy on foreign investment and technology transfer.
The policy since then has been aimed at encouraging foreign investment
particularly in the core and infrastructure sectors. During the fourth
phase, favourable policy environment consisting of the liberalisation
policies on foreign investment, foreign technology collaboration, foreign
trade and foreign exchange, have been exerting positive influence on
foreign firms' decisions on investment and business operations in the
country.
During this period, the FERA, 1973 has been amended and
restrictions placed on foreign companies by the FERA have been lifted.
In 1999, FERA has been replaced with Foreign Exchange Management
Act. Government has permitted, except for a small negative list, access
to the automatic route for FDI. Hence, foreign investors only need to
inform the RBI within 30 days of bringing in their investment.
Companies with more than 40 per cent of foreign equity are now treated
on par with fully Indian owned companies. New sectors such as mining,
banking, telecommunications, highways, construction, airports, hotel
and tourism, courier service and management have been thrown open
for FDI. Even the defence industry sector is opened upto 100 per cent
for Indian private sector participation with 26 per cent FDI, subject to
licensing. (FDI is not permitted in the following industrial sectors:
i) arms and ammunition, ii) atomic energy, iii) railway transport, iv)
coal and lignite, and v) mining of iron, manganese, chrome, gypsum,
sulphur, gold, diamonds, copper and zinc). The liberal policies have
been accompanied by active courting of foreign investors at the highest
level. The international trade policy regime has been considerably
liberalised too with removal of quantitative restrictions lowering of peak
tariffs to 30 per cent and sharp pruning of negative list for imports. The
rupee was made convertible on current account and gradually to capital
account.
430 Indian Economy: Performance and Policies
EXHIBIT — 20.1
Thus, the ongoing measures taken since 1991 are focused towards
a virtual elimination of the both direct and indirect barriers to foreign
direct investment [indirect barriers in the form of investor protection,
differences in accounting standards, legal and regulatory structure]. In
short, the evolution of FDI policies in India are characterised by
receptive attitude till the mid-sixties to a policy of restrictions and
controls till 1980 and then to gradual liberalisation till 1990 and finally
to a policy of full-fledged liberalisation since 1991.
From a closer look at the data, one can identify two distinct phases
in the growth of FDI during the nineties. The four year period from 199.4
432 Indian Economy: Performance and Policies
On the other hand, during the next four year period from 1998 to
2001 (till October) there was a slow down in both number and amount
of approvals but growth of inflows and realisation rate was higher. During
this low growth phase, the yearly average number of approvals declined
to 1,998 from 2,205 during the high growth phase. Further, the average
annual growth of amount approved during this period was lower at 12
per cent as against 63 per cent during the previous phase. Though there
was a lower growth of approvals during this period, the actual inflow has
been higher in terms of absolute amount and realisation rate. Average
amount of inflow during this period was Rs.16,419 crore as against Rs.
9,231 crore during 1994 to 1997. Actual inflows as a per cent of amount
approved rose from 26 per cent to 56 per cent.
T AB L E - 20.2
Share of Different Approval Sources in Actual Flow of FDI
(Per Cent)
TABLE - 20.3
TABLE — 20.4
Impact of FDI
Impact of FDI can be felt on a number of areas and it varies
depending upon the nature of the projects and the degree of integration
with the rest of the economy.
IV
However, the foregoing reasoning still does not explain why foreign
investment does not come to use cheap labour and skills for export of
labour-intensive manufactures—as it has happened in China. We are
inclined to believe that the foreign investment policy lacks a clear focus.
Unlike China, India has not invested in export infrastructure. In fact, as
is widely accepted now, the share of infrastructure in fixed capital
formation has declined sharply for nearly one and half decade now
(Nagaraj, 1997). Further, what is needed is perhaps not large investment
but suitable inducement to international marketers—trading houses and
retail chains—to set up purchase offices and testing facilities to tap the
potential of the domestic manufacturers. It is widely acknowledged that
China's export success largely lies in marrying its low cost
manufacturing capability in Town and Village Enterprises (TVEs) with
Hong Kong's highly developed trading houses and other long-
established commercial organisations catering to international trade.
While it is out of question for India to replicate the locational and
historical advantage of Hong Kong for China, investment in export
infrastructure in strategic locations and carefully tailored incentives to
international trading houses (and retailers) merit a serious consideration.
Similarly, such investments are perhaps equally necessary to tap the
440 Indian Economy: Performance and Policies
growing potential for using India's labour cost advantage for doing back
office jobs—business processes outsourcing—for international firms
(The Economist, May 5, 2001).
Realistically, what is it that India expects from foreign investment,
and how to secure it? In principle, openness to foreign investment
should be strategic, not passive (or unilateral). History does not seem
to support such an uncritical international integration as a proven route
to growth and efficiency. If the recent experience is any guide, foreign
capital is far from a major provider of external savings for rapid
industrialisation of any large economy. It can only supplement the
domestic resources, wherever they necessarily come bundled with
technology, and access to international production and distribution
networks. The terms of foreign investment will depend on the relative
bargaining power of the foreign firm vis a vis domestic firms, backed
- -
V
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
brand names), the bulk of them have—at least yet—largely been able
to withstand the competition by making large capital investment, and
in expanding distribution networks.
What should be done to increase foreign investment? It is popularly
believed that a more liberal policy regime, industrial labour market
reforms, and infrastructure investment are needed. While infrastructure
improvement surely merits a close attention, one is not so sure if the
extent of the reforms and the quantum of foreign investment inflow are
positively related. Moreover, there is little evidence that greater FDI
inflow ensures faster output and export growth. Such simplistic
associations, usually based on cross-country analysis, seem to have
support neither in principle nor in comparative experience.
TABLE — 21.2
Sectoral Shares in GDP in 2001, Global Averages
(Per cent of GDP)
Agriculture Industry Services
Source : World Bank's WDI, 2003, Table 4.2. Definition: Low income: per capita GDP<$745;
Lower middle-$746-2975; Upper middle-$2976-9205; and high->$9206.
How does the Indian experience fit in with this pattern? In the four
decade period, 1950-1990, agriculture's share in GDP declined by about
25 percentage points, while industry and services gained equally. The
share of industry has stabilised since 1990, and the entire subsequent
decline in the share of agriculture has been picked up by the services
sector. Thus, while over the four decades, 1950-1990, the services sector
gained a 13 per cent share, the gain in the 1990s alone was 8 percentage
points. Consequently, at current levels, India's services share of GDP
is higher than the average for other low income countries.
TABLE — 21.3
India, Sectoral Shares in GDP, 1950-2006
(Per cent of GDP)
Agriculture Industry Services
1950 58 15 28
1980 38 24 38 Stage I
1990 33 27 41
2000 24 27 49 Stage II
2003-04 22 26 53
2004-05(P) 20 26 54
2005-6(Q) 20 26 54
2006-07(R) 19 27 55
. g e l I N V N I M . 1 . . . 1 0 1 m a m ___
TABLE — 21.4
Comparison of the actual and the trend growth rates shows that
growth in several service sub-sectors accelerated sharply in the 1990s
(and 1980s for banking); indicating some sort of a structural break in
their growth series. According to Gordon and Gupta these activities are
fast growers. The remaining activities grew more or less at a trend rate,
these they call trend growers.
Fast Growers
Business services was the fastest growing sector in the 1990s, with
growth averaging nearly 20 per cent a year. Though disaggregated data