Casson2007-Social Capita
Casson2007-Social Capita
Casson2007-Social Capita
bj
http://isb.sagepub.com
[DOI:10.1177/0266242607076524]
Vol 25(3): 220–244
M A R K C A S S O N a n d M A R I N A D E L L A G I U S TA
University of Reading, UK
220
221
222
223
224
225
Configuration of Networks
A significant feature of any network is its geography, and in particular the location of
hubs. Hubs are points at which an unusually large number of connections converge:
they act as consolidation centres and distribution centres for the traffic over the
226
227
228
Nature of Obligation
The definition of trust in terms of obligation raises the issue of why anyone would
accept an obligation in the first place. The simple answer is that they get something
in return. If they recognize an obligation to another party then the other party will
recognize a reciprocal obligation to them. This is the basis on which social groups
are formed. All the members of a group accept an obligation to respect the rights
of the other members in return for respect from others. Trust therefore normally
develops within the context of a social group.
Different types of social group emphasize different types of obligation.
Contractual Obligations
In business dealings, keeping promises is regarded as being of paramount import-
ance. A contract is a reciprocal set of promises in which the seller agrees to deliver
in return for the buyer agreeing to pay. An entrepreneur promises to repay a loan to
a bank; an employee promises to work hard and obey orders; a supplier promises
to deliver quality products on time, and so on. Defaulting on a contract is a very
serious matter.
Customary Obligations
When people do not have a contract, obligations may still apply. Customary obli-
gations allow people to behave towards each other in a predictable fashion even
though there has been no prior communication between them. People are expected to
reply to business correspondence, and to compromise in negotiations, even though
they have not specifically promised to do so. People therefore have a common obli-
gation to observe business customs although they have not made a contract. Indeed,
without respect for custom, contracts would be difficult to negotiate.
Considerate Obligations
Entrepreneurs may feel obliged to consider the wider implications of their actions.
They do not confine their obligations to respecting customs and honouring con-
tracts. The paternalistic employer, for example, accepts an obligation to care for his
workers, and even their dependents, in times of sickness or stress. A philanthropic
banker might extend a loan against his better judgement because if the borrower
went bankrupt many people would lose their jobs. Business people who accept
229
Philanthropic Obligations
Some entrepreneurs may even accept a duty to society that extends beyond the
parochial boundaries of their firm. They move beyond paternalism to philanthropy.
They sponsor hospitals or holiday homes for the use of everyone and not just
their own employees. In modern jargon, they take corporate social responsibility
seriously.
For any given type of obligation, trust is greater the larger the value of resources
involved. An individual who can be trusted to repay a debt of £1000 cannot neces-
sarily be trusted to repay a debt of £1m. When people commit themselves to honour-
ing obligations, there is an implicit restriction on the size of the obligation that they
are willing to accept. The significance of this restriction may not be appreciated
until unusual circumstances arise. People can often train themselves to be honest
in regular dealings but can be caught out by temptations they cannot resist when
they are confronted with a type of situation they have not encountered before. Thus
unanticipated circumstances are more likely than anticipated circumstances to
precipitate dishonest behaviour.
Opportunity Seeking
‘Opportunity seeking’ is mainly about gathering information. Coordination fail-
ures provide opportunities for entrepreneurs to correct them. In a simple case, an
entrepreneur might spot an opportunity for arbitrage – for example, a brownfield
industrial site that could be converted to residential use. The entrepreneur might
use networks to discover the existence of the site, to assess the potential local de-
mand for housing, and obtain an estimate of local construction costs. In practice, a
combination of direct personal observation, social networking, private publications
and official information sources will be used.
In opportunity seeking, much of the information gathered will be ‘spillover’ in-
formation acquired from people who cannot use the information themselves. The
entrepreneur is not looking for commercial secrets acquired by eavesdropping on
business rivals, but rather information obtained from non-competing sources that
is surplus to their requirements. Information about a prospective brownfield site
could come from a conversation with a manufacturer who is planning to close
230
Resource Acquisition
Once an opportunity has been identified, the entrepreneur must decide how best
to implement it. This will require mobilizing resources of labour and capital. At this
point trust becomes a major issue. The entrepreneur needs to trust the financier to
reach a quick decision and deliver the funds, and to trust employees to work hard
and remain loyal. Social networks help the entrepreneur to make contact with reli-
able people. He can meet suitable people face-to-face outside the formal environ-
ment of the office interview. He can compare the way they behave in a more relaxed
environment, and use this to predict how they might react to an unexpected problem.
Depending on the trust that develops, the entrepreneur may decide to make a deal
on the basis of a handshake, to make a deal on the basis of a formal contract, or not
to make any deal at all.
Trust is also important because of the confidentiality issue. The entrepreneur
requires at least a temporary monopoly of exploitation in order to recover the cost
he has sunk in seeking out the opportunity – including the time spent networking.
This monopoly would be undermined if a prospective financial backer or prospective
employee set up in competition with him. Fear of imitation means that the
entrepreneur cannot afford to disclose his opportunity to people he does not trust.
Meeting people socially allows him to assess how far these people are discreet.
The entrepreneur can also check out the people he meets with other members of
the network. He may be able to talk to customers of the bank from which he plans
to borrow, and to former employers of the people he plans to hire. It is therefore
useful if the network contains a mixture of people who have already made contracts
with each other and those who are about to do so. It is also useful if there are some
experienced people present – perhaps as chairmen or speakers – who can advise the
entrepreneur on the criteria he should use for assessing the most suitable business
partner.
A useful type of network for building trust is a church, charity, sports club or
hobby club. There is an opportunity for regular meetings, and for the discussion of
important issues that will reveal the fundamental values and beliefs of the person
231
Market Organization
‘Market organization’ is a key aspect of most large-scale entrepreneurial activity.
If the entrepreneurial opportunity relates to the innovation of a new product, or a
better or cheaper variant of an existing product, then the entrepreneur will need to
establish an organization to sell the product. Even if he simply sets up a wholesale
operation to hold a better range of stock, or a new retail operation to serve a grow-
ing residential area, he will need to invest in market organization. The entrepreneur
appropriates his reward by altering the network of trade in the product concerned.
He diverts trade away from existing channels into new channels that he has set up
for this purpose.
To implement the diversion of trade the entrepreneur needs to win customer
support. In terms of social networks, he needs to encourage potential buyers to join
his customer club. To attract interest he must advertise his product and display it at
a convenient location – typically close to existing outlets where his target customers
normally go shopping. He lures them with introductory offers and then locks them
in, as far as he can, through a loyalty scheme.
Innovative entrepreneurs marketing consumer products will join the established
agglomerations at major retail centres. By locating next to established rivals, they
can intercept customers before they make their usual purchases. If successful, they
will take market share from their rivals and may even drive some of them out of
business; but they may in turn be replaced by other innovators following in their
footsteps. In this way agglomerations renew themselves by attracting successive
waves of innovators.
Innovation, therefore, alters the configuration of trade in markets. The geography
of trade may be unaffected, in the sense that agglomerations at strategic centres such
as river estuaries and the feet of mountain passes continue to be the major hubs, but
the control of trade will change. New firms, created by innovative entrepreneurs,
and dealing in novel products, now own the products from the point at which they
leave the factory (or before) to the point at which they are placed in the customers’
hands. Entrepreneurship, therefore, provides a dynamic to networks – it exploits
networks to discover and implement opportunities, but the implementation of the
opportunities feeds back to change the network structures on which the next gen-
eration of entrepreneurs depends.
This discussion suggests that each stage of entrepreneurship benefits from mem-
bership of a particular type of network.
232
Schematic Summary
Because networks are inherently complex, it is useful to employ a schematic approach
to summarize the arguments. Figures 3 to 6 use an information systems approach to
represent the various links in a network. They develop the symbolism of the preceding
figures, which in turn followed the conventions established in previous applications
(in particular Casson, 1997).
Consider an entrepreneur who believes that there may be an opportunity to
enter an established market with a new product. The initial state of the market is
represented in Figure 3. Upstream from the entrepreneur’s proposed point of entry
are suppliers, represented by the top row of circles, whose capacity is currently
devoted to meeting the needs of established intermediaries, while downstream are
potential customers for the product, represented by the bottom row of circles. The
precise nature of the suppliers and customers depends on the stage of production
at which entry is contemplated. To fix ideas, it is assumed that the suppliers provide
either finished products that the entrepreneur sells on through a wholesale or retail
operation, or components that the entrepreneur converts into finished product.
At the outset the entrepreneur faces two established rivals that divide the market
between them; these firms intermediate between the suppliers and the customers, and
are therefore positioned in the middle row of the figure. Two of the suppliers work
for one of the intermediators and two for the other. The physical pattern of trade is
233
Suppliers
Market-making
entrepreneurs
Customers
Figure 3.
illustrated by the lines and arrows, which show product flowing from the suppliers
to the intermediators, and from the intermediators to the customers.
Each intermediator has many customers. They serve two separate segments of
the market that initially do not overlap. However, some customers in each segment
may be prepared to switch to the new product. Each customer base therefore contains
two groups, one of which may be prepared to switch (represented by the two circles
in the middle of the diagram) and one of which is not (represented by the circles at
the left-hand and right-hand sides of the diagram).
To identify such an opportunity and confirm its existence the entrepreneur needs
to make contact with suppliers and customers to discover whether they would indeed
be willing to switch. He needs to talk to dissatisfied customers of the established
firms who constitute the group that may be prepared to switch. He also needs to talk
to suppliers that either have excess capacity or are dissatisfied with the terms they
receive from the established intermediators who buy from them. Both customers
and suppliers have an incentive to negotiate once he has made contact with them.
He also needs to obtain information about the established intermediators, but
since they will be unwilling to talk to a potential rival he must simply observe their
activities instead.
The entry strategy is summarized schematically in Figure 4. The entrant is rep-
resented by the shaded circle in the centre of the middle row. His information re-
quirements are represented by the thin black lines. He needs to carry out market
research through dialogue with representative customers who may be prepared to
switch. He also needs to talk to representative suppliers to assess the terms on
which they would be willing to supply. Dialogue involves two-way flow of infor-
mation and is indicated by arrows that point in both directions. Observation of
established rivals, by contrast, involves a one-way flow of information from the
rival to the entrepreneur, and so a single arrow is shown.
The entrepreneur may find it difficult to make direct contact with suppliers and
customers. A social network can provide him with the opportunity he requires. He
may be able to attend a trade fair at which he can meet suppliers, while if the po-
tential customers are local businesses he may be able to meet them through the
Chamber of Commerce or Rotary Club. If there is a shortage of suitable networks,
then government-sponsored events may help.
234
Suppliers
Market-making
entrepreneurs
Customers
Figure 4.
Leaders of
social groups
Supplier contact-broker
and reputation-broker
Suppliers
Market-making
entrepreneurs
Customers
Customer
contact-broker
Figure 5.
235
Leaders of
social groups
Suppliers
Market-making
entrepreneurs
Customers
Figure 6.
236
237
Policy Interventions
The argument that networks promote economic performance is often used to just-
ify political interventions that subsidize networking. Most developed economies
now promote entrepreneurial networks through fostering partnerships between
academic institutions, businesses, venture capitalists and government. It is, how-
ever, quite difficult to appraise policy interventions based on ‘soft’ activities such
as networking. Performance measurement indicators can be used to estimate the
impacts of policies on the productivity and profitability of supported firms, relative
to the public expenditure involved. But it is an ‘act of faith’ to interpret the meas-
ured outcomes as pure ‘networking’ effects.
The analysis of social capital developed in this article suggests an alternative
approach to evaluation, in which impact of policy is measured by the increase in
the value of social capital attributable to government support. An initial estimate
is obtained by interviewing the participants in the networking activity. The social
interactions between members of the network are then mapped out using the
schematic technique set out earlier. The mapping is used to assess how far the ef-
fects identified by participants can be safely attributed to the network investments
funded by government.
Government interventions involving any kind of business support are typically
justified by appeal to market failure. In the absence of public subsidies, market fail-
ures may cause private firms to under-invest in networks, leading to a sub-optimal
level of communication within the economy. In this context, the ‘null hypothesis’
used in an evaluation is that the economy already supports an optimal number of
business networks, so that there is no need for any subsidy. Network affiliation is time
consuming, and a successful entrepreneur will be well aware that ‘time is money’.
As a result, it can be argued, encouraging business managers to network may sim-
ply mean that they spend too much time networking, and too little time attending
to their ordinary business affairs.
A straightforward argument for additional networks is that existing ones are
simply not good enough. The fact that there is a shortage of really effective networks
238
239
Conclusion
This article has examined in detail the key concepts of networks, trust and social
capital. Each of these concepts links in to a large literature that connects the
discussion of social capital to a bewildering variety of topics. Concepts such as
‘network’ and ‘trust’ have different meanings in different contexts, but equally, there
are certain core ideas that are independent of context. Connectivity, for example,
features in all the applications of these concepts.
This article has focused on the issue of building entrepreneurial networks that
will improve the performance of the economy. It has argued that different types of
social network are required for different purposes. Some types of networks are most
useful in the early stages of entrepreneurial activity and others at later stages.
Policy interventions need to be precisely targeted in order to maximize their im-
pact, but targeting cannot be effective if the underlying analysis is fuzzy. Effective
networks are created around reputable people. In the long run, reputable institu-
tions sustain their reputations through the calibre of the people they employ. It is
important that government does not overestimate its own reputation, and assume
that any network that it sponsors will ‘leverage’ its reputation successfully.
Government reputation, like any form of reputation, is specific, and ‘extending
the brand’ to encompass new forms of business support may take government into
areas where its reputation carries little weight. There are already many different
social groups that support business activity, either directly or indirectly, and it is pos-
sible that government might achieve better results by strengthening the activities
of these groups, rather than by subsidizing the establishment of new groups that
compete with them. Rigorous evaluation is needed to inform decisions on the ap-
propriate types of network to support.
240
References
Aldrich, H. E. (1987) ‘The Impact of Social Networks on Business Founding and Profit:
A Longitudinal Approach’, in Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research. Wellesley, MA:
Babson College.
Aldrich, H. E. and Zimmer, C. (1986) ‘Entrepreneurship through Social Networks’, in
D. L. Sexton and R. W. Wilson (eds) The Art and Science of Entrepreneurship, pp. 154–67.
Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
Andall, J. (2000) Gender, Migration and Domestic Service: The Politics of Black Women in
Italy. Aldershot: Ashgate.
Anderson, A. R. and Jack, S. L. (2002) ‘The Articulation of Social Capital in Entrepreneurial
Networks: A Glue or Lubricant?’, Entrepreneurship and Regional Development 14(3):
193–210.
Anderson, A. R. and Miller (2003) ‘Class Matters: Human and Social Capital in the Entre-
preneurial Process’, Journal of Socio-Economics 32: 17–36.
Basu, A. (2004) ‘Entrepreneurial Aspirations amongst Family Business Owners: An Analysis
of Ethnic Business Owners in the United Kingdom’, International Journal of Entre-
preneurial Behaviour and Research 10(1): 12–33.
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. (2002) ‘Social Capital and Community Governance’, Economic
Journal 112(483): F419–36.
Brown, J. S. and Duguid, P. (2002) ‘Local Knowledge: Innovation in the Network Age’,
Management Learning 33(4).
Bunting, M. (2004) Willing Slaves: How the Overwork Culture is Ruling Our Lives. London:
Harper Collins.
Burt, R. S. (1992) Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA:
Harvard University Press.
Casson, M. (1982) The Entrepreneur: An Economic Theory. Oxford: Martin Robertson.
Casson, M. (1997) Information and Organization. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Casson, M. and Rose, M. (1997) ‘Introduction to the Special Issue on Institutions and the
Evolution of Modern Business’, Business History 39(4): 1–8.
Casson, M. and Della Giusta, M. (2006) ‘Economics of Trust’, in A. Zaheer and R. Bachmann
(eds) Handbook of Trust Research, pp. 332–54. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Coleman, J. S. (1988) ‘Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital’, American Journal of
Sociology 94(Supplement): 95–120.
Dasgupta, P. and Serageldin, I. (2001) Social Capital: A Multi-faceted Perspective. Washington,
DC: The World Bank.
Della Giusta, M. (1999) ‘A Model of Social Capital and Access to Productive Resources’,
Journal of International Development 11(1): 921–34.
Doreian, P. and Stokman, F. N. (1997) Evolution of Social Networks. Amsterdam: Gordon
and Breach.
Gambetta, D. (ed.) (1988) Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relationships. Oxford:
Blackwell.
Granovetter, M. (1985) ‘Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness’,
American Journal of Sociology 91(4): 481–510.
Haggett, P. and Chorley, R. J. (1969) Network Analysis in Geography. London: Arnold.
Hardin, R. (1993) ‘The Street-Level Epistemology of Trust’, Politics and Society 21(4):
505–29.
241
MARK CASSON is Professor of Economics and Director of the Centre for Institutional
Performance at the University of Reading. He is also Leverhulme Major Research Fellow
in the Economics of Social Networks, 2006–9. He is the general editor of The Oxford
Handbook of Entrepreneurship, 2006. Please address all correspondence to: Director,
Centre for Institutional Performance, University of Reading Business School, Whiteknights,
Reading, RG6 6AA, UK. [email: [email protected]]
242
Los gobiernos han invertido cuantiosas sumas en el desarrollo de redes empresariales locales
y regionales para mejorar el comportamiento y repunte de la economía . No obstante, hay
muchos tipos de redes, y las diferentes redes son apropiadas para diferentes fines. Algunos
tipos de redes son más útiles en las etapas iniciales de la actividad empresarial y otras más
adelante. Se necesitan definiciones bien formuladas para analizar el papel de las redes en
la generación de confianza interpersonal e interorganizativa y, por consiguiente, aumentar
las acciones del capital social. Las redes efectivas son normalmente gestionadas por agentes
fiduciarios acreditados que actúan de mediadores. La reputación del gobierno le permite jugar
un papel decisivo como agente fiduciario, pero se expone a perder su buena fama si extiende
sus actividades a esferas donde carece de competencia para intervenir con eficiencia.
Palabras clave: actuación del agente; empresario; red; obligación; capital social; confianza
243
Regierungen haben stark in den Aufbau von lokalen und regionalen unternehmerischen
Netzwerken investiert, um wirtschaftliche Leistung und Erneuerung zu unterstützen. Es
gibt jedoch viele Arten von Netzwerken, und die verschiedenen Arten von Netzwerken
dienen unterschiedlichen Zwecken. Einige Arten von Netzwerken sind sehr nützlich
am Anfang unternehmerischer Aktivitäten, andere zu späteren Zeitpunkten. Es bedarf
genauer Definitionen, um die Rolle von Netzwerken mit Bezug auf die Entstehung von
zwischenmenschlichem und zwischenbetrieblichem Vertrauen - und somit die Vermehrung
des Sozialkapitals - zu analysieren.
Effektive Netzwerke werden normalerweise von seriösen Vermittlern aufgebaut. Das Ansehen
einer Regierung teilt ihr eine wichtige Rolle als Vermittler zu, doch es besteht auch die
Gefahr, dass dieses Ansehen geschädigt werden könnte, wenn es seine Aktivitäten in Bereiche
ausweitet, in denen die Kompetenz zu effektivem Einschreiten nicht gegeben ist.
Schlüsselwörter: Vermittlerleistung; Unternehmer; Netzwerk; Obligation; Sozialkapital;
Vertrauen
244