Lake AnarchyHierarchyVariety 1996
Lake AnarchyHierarchyVariety 1996
Lake AnarchyHierarchyVariety 1996
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
, The MIT Press , Cambridge University Press and University of Wisconsin Press are
collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to International Organization
Following World War II, the United States entered into an alliance with the
countries of Western Europe. At the same time, the Soviet Union created an
informal empire in Eastern Europe. America's alliances were anarchic in
character. While each partner agreed explicitly and implicitly to defend the
others, all retained substantial discretion over the implementation of this
agreement. The Soviet Union's informal empire was more hierarchic. Not only
were the parties committed to mutual defense but the Soviet Union intruded
deeply into the internal political, economic, and social affairs of its partners in
order to enforce their allegiance.
Realism cannot explain this difference in relations. Two countries occupying
similar positions within the international system should adopt similar strategies
for building power or security. The nature of the political regimes in the two
superpowers provides at best only a partial explanation. Regime type cannot
explain Soviet restraint in areas it might have dominated, such as Finland or
Yugoslavia, or American informal imperialism in the Caribbean and Central
America.' Nor are ideological or cultural approaches-whether primordial,
instrumental, or constructivist in nature-particularly promising alternatives.
Earlier versions of the essay were presented at the annual meeting of the American Political
Science Association, Chicago, 3-6 September 1992, and in seminars at Indiana, Princeton, and
Columbia Universities; the University of California, Berkeley, Los Angeles, Santa Barbara, and
San Diego; and the University of Chicago. Numerous colleagues have provided many helpful
suggestions and criticisms. I would like to acknowledge the especially important guidance of Jeff
Frieden, Joanne Gowa, Robert Keohane, Wendy Lake, John Odell, Robert Pahre, Paul
Papayoanou, Robert Powell, Beth Yarbrough, and several anonymous reviewers. Ellen Comisso,
Matthew Evangelista, Peter Gourevitch, Jack Snyder, and Celeste Wallander were kind enough to
comment on the penultimate draft on short notice. Scott Bruckner, Risa Brooks, Kathleen
Hancock, and Adam Stulberg provided research assistance. This research has been supported by
the Academic Senates of the University of California at Los Angeles (UCLA) and at San Diego
(UCSD), the Center for International Relations and the Office of International Studies and
Overseas Programs at UCLA, and the Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation at UCSD.
1. On the essential similarity between relations in the Soviet and U.S. spheres of influence, see
Triska 1986.
Grand strategy has been the topic of considerable scholarly debate. Defined by
Barry Posen as "a state's theory about how it can best 'cause' security for
itself," the subject is, appropriately, nearly synonymous with the study and
practice of international relations.4 As a field, we have made substantial
progress in understanding the sources and variations of grand strategy.5
2. For an example from economics, see Williamson 1985. For a review of the economic
literature, see Eggertsson 1990. For an application to American politics, see Weingast and
Marshall 1988. Robert Keohane was the first to employ this approach in international relations; see
Keohane 1983 and 1984. For applications, see Frieden 1994 and Simmons 1993. For a view from
two economists who speak directly to the concerns of international relations, see Yarbrough and
Yarbourgh 1992.
3. This metaphor has been employed with great effect in economic history. See Lane 1979 and
North 1981.
4. The quotation is from Posen 1984, 13.
5. For reviews, see Walt 1991; and Nye and Lynn-Jones 1988.
Nonetheless, two related problems remain. While these problems are natural
consequences of the magnitude of the subject and will not be remedied fully
here, they continue to limit further progress.
First, while scholars have given much attention to the many techniques for
causing security, they typically fail to consider adequately the alternatives
available to states. In other words, the range of possible variation in strategy-
the dependent variable-commonly is abridged.6 For example, scholars focus
on alliances or empires but fail to ask how, in what ways, and to what extent
these relationships are substitutes for one another.7 When states choose to seek
empire, for instance, they are simultaneously choosing not to form an alliance.
The net benefits of imperialism by themselves do not explain action; rather, it is
the net benefits of the alternatives relative to one another that drive state
choice. Any full explanation of grand strategy must therefore compare all
alternatives.8
Second, analysts continue to work within what Benjamin Most and Harvey
Starr describe as separate "islands" of theory and fail to appreciate or build
upon common political problems and independent variables.9 This is true even
in the comparatively well-developed literatures on alliance formation and
imperialism. The standard international relations texts, for instance, nearly
always discuss alliances and empires in separate chapters and often in very
different theoretical contexts: the first tend to be covered under the headings of
realism, systems-level theories, or the balance of power; the second under
Marxism, unit-level theories, or North-South relations. Yet in practice, all
states are concerned with problems of aggregating and pooling resources-
building power-and coping with opportunism by their partners-restraining
self-seeking actions. These practical problems are also central independent
variables in our theories of international politics, even if they are often implicit.
Without seeking to minimize differences in the research agendas that have
grown up around these and other topics, I want to suggest that a theoretical
core does exist-a core that informs the theory discussed in the remainder of
this article.
The current literature on alliance formation is dominated by a "capability
aggregation" model. As Bruce Russett and Harvey Starr write in their widely
used text, "Throughout history the main reason states have entered into
6. Among the best recent efforts to elucidate the full range of strategies are Friedberg 1988;
Snyder 1991; and Morrow 1993. Emerson Niou and Peter Ordeshook ask similar questions, but
take a different approach than discussed here. See Niou and Ordeshook 1994.
7. See Walt 1987; and Doyle 1986.
8. David Baldwin suggests that international political economists may not be sufficiently
attentive to this fundamental tenet of rational choice theory either. See Baldwin 1985, 8-18 and
29-40. Much of the work on trade policy, for instance, has proceeded without sufficient reference
to exchange rate manipulation as an alternative to tariff protection. For a typical example of this
failing, see Lake 1988.
9. Most and Starr 1984. See also Siverson and Starr 1991.
alliances has been the desire for the aggregation of power. "10 In this model,
states form alliances primarily to counter common threats larger than each
individually.
Within this model, the costs of alliances-and the reasons why states
sometimes eschew foreign entanglements-are understood to be reduced
autonomy and freedom of action. Glenn Snyder has explicated these costs
more fully. In the "alliance dilemma," he writes, states may be "abandoned,"
defined broadly to include both free riding on the efforts of others and shirking
on agreements, and "entrapped," or embroiled in conflicts they might
otherwise avoid. More recently, Thomas Christensen and Jack Snyder have
termed these respective costs "buck passing" and "chain ganging."'1
The literature on imperialism, on the other hand, has long been rent by three
competing perspectives: metrocentric theory focuses on dispositional features
of imperial states, systemic theory highlights competition between the great
powers, and pericentric theory emphasizes conditions in peripheral states and
territories. In several recent studies, scholars have succeeded in integrating
these approaches into a consistent and powerful explanation of imperialism.12
With obvious differences, metrocentric and systemic theories of imperialism
share with theories of alliance formation an emphasis on capability aggrega-
tion. At the most basic level, both hypothesize that states form empires to
capture important resources-raw materials, manpower, markets, strategic
locations-otherwise unavailable to groups at home or the polity in general.
Although many theories of imperialism emphasize the domestic implications of
expansion, explanations of alliance formation and imperialism share a common
focus on capability aggregation.
More than the other approaches, pericentric theories attempt to explain the
form of imperialism and in turn focus on opportunism. Following the
pioneering work of John Gallagher and Ronald Robinson, such theories
hypothesize that dominant states prefer informal empire when possible but
create formal empires when local elites are either unwilling or unable to
provide acceptable domestic political orders; in other words, formal empires
are created when local rulers possess different policy preferences or lack the
ability to carry out the interests of dominant states.13 Whether emphasizing
intent or ability, the failure to comply with or carry out the desires of the core
10. Russett and Starr 1989, 91 (emphasis original). For reviews of the voluminous literature on
alliances, see the essays collected in Friedman, Bladen, and Rosen 1970; and in Holsti, Hopmann,
and Sullivan 1973. Another explanation of alliance formation focuses on national attributes, such
as ideology or regime type. For that view, see Barnett and Levy 1991; David 1991; and Siverson and
Emmons 1991. The historical literature also points to the desire to control partners as a motivation
for alliances, but this empirical insight has not been incorporated into the theoretical literature; see
Schroeder 1976. For an alternative approach, see Morrow 1991.
11. See Snyder 1984 and 1990; and Christensen and Snyder 1990.
12. See Doyle 1986; Smith 1981; and Cain and Hopkins 1993. The labels for the three theories
are from Doyle 1986, 22-30.
13. Gallagher and Robinson 1953. On the ensuing debate, see Louis 1976.
Security, the starting point for any discussion of grand strategy, is too often
undefined, and when it is defined, it is usually tailored either to the specifics of
time and place or the idiosyncratic preferences of the author.16 I define security
here as the ability to consume, invest, or otherwise use national wealth as a
polity sees fit. In other words, a country is secure to the extent that its wealth
cannot be coerced or otherwise extorted from it. It follows from this definition
that a polity will be concerned with two essential national freedoms: the
freedom to possess wealth, traditionally associated with the territorial integrity
of the nation-state, and the freedom to choose its own form of rule, embodied
in constitutional independence and a defining characteristic of sovereignty.'7
Central to the latter freedom is the country's ability to decide autonomously
how to accumulate and use its wealth, which requires that the collective choice
mechanism be free from foreign control. So defined, security is aspired to
rather than realized; it is a continuous rather than a dichotomous variable. A
country is more secure the lower the probability that other states can seize or
constrain effectively the disposition of its wealth.
Security is a complex phenomenon, dependent upon a state's assessment of
the likely behavior of another. The behavior of the threatening state is in turn a
function of its intentions and military capabilities, which for simplicity are
assumed to be exogenous throughout this essay (see below), and the first state's
own defense efforts and security relations, which it can alter in response to
changing preferences or circumstances. A state's defense effort is influenced by
many factors, including threats from others, the aggregated preferences and
risk propensities of its constituents, and the costs of producing defense relative
to other goods in the economy. These factors are captured in the traditional
guns or butter trade-off, which reflects the willingness of the polity to trade
other valued goods for increased defense effort and, in turn, security.
When confronted by a common threat, a state and its partner may choose to
pool their resources, abilities, and efforts with one another in what I call here a
security relation.18 Security relations can take a variety of forms and can vary by
dyad. The dyadic nature of these relations is particularly important. Each state
has many potential partners, and there are many degrees of hierarchy within
each possible relationship (see below). Accordingly, relations can differ across dyads,
taking one form with one partner and another with its neighbor, depending on
circumstances. In the early postwar period, for example, the United States entered
into an alliance with Australia and New Zealand but, in the same general region,
expanded its imperial outpost in Guam to include all of Micronesia.
Security relations vary along a continuum defined by the degree of hierarchy
between the two parties (see Figure 1).19 The degree of hierarchy is in turn
17. James 1986. Today, as factors of production become more mobile internationally, the
traditional concern with territorial integrity may be less central; see Rosecrance 1986.
18. States also possess the option of unilateralism, in which they choose not to pool resources
and efforts in the joint production of security. Prior to 1945, this was the prevailing policy of the
United States, and it is the principal alternative to alliances today. In addition to the expected costs
of opportunism and governance costs, the choice between unilateralism and the "relational"
alternatives discussed in this article is also influenced by scale economies in producing security.
More specifically, the analysis must expand to include the division of labor between the parties, the
technology of production, and positive externalities in the unilateral and relational alternatives.
For reasons of space, I do not develop this additional dimension of policy or set of causal variables
in this article. As scale economies are important only for the choice between unilateralism and the
optimal relationship between parties defined below, the analysis presented here stands on its own.
For a full treatment, however, see Lake forthcoming. I also do not address alternatives to
balancing, such as appeasement or detente with threatening states.
19. Although relationships may be hierarchic, the international system remains anarchic. See
Waltz 1979.
Anarchy Hierarchy
20. Surprisingly, economists typically fail to define hierarchy in a formal way. The definition
used here follows most closely from Grossman and Hart 1986.
21. Williamson 1985, 20.
22. One of the best, if dated, sources on relational forms is Willoughby and Fenwick [1919] 1974.
23. Compare the discussion of the United States in Waltz 1967 with that of hierarchy in Waltz
1979.
for firms, this implies profit maximization and for states (under assumptions to
be discussed shortly), cost minimization. At a general level, this implication-
while clearly artificial-is nonetheless plausible. When decision makers are
perfect agents for their principals, whether these be shareholders in a firm or
voters in a democracy, they have no incentive to conduct relations in ways that
intentionally waste resources. Yet at this level, the implication is also a virtual
truism, as it is relatively easy to concoct post hoc stories about why any observed
relationship is efficient for the parties involved; indeed, this is perhaps the most
common criticism of the approach. The true test of a theory of relational
contracting comes from specifying more concretely the range of alternatives
and the determinants of efficiency-issues scholars continue to debate, thus
yielding multiple theories united by a common approach.
Below, I develop a theory of relational contracting tailored to international
security affairs. As we shall see, the optimal relationship is principally a
function of the expected costs of opportunism, which decline with relational
hierarchy, and the governance costs of creating and maintaining the relation-
ship, which increase with hierarchy.
In the following theory, I make several assumptions, which I will note here
but not defend at length. First, actors are rational, but information is costly and
therefore limited. The first part of this assumption is common but frequently
criticized in theories of international politics. By rationality, I mean simply that
actors possess transitive preferences and act purposively. While states may
know their own defense effort with certainty, they can observe features of their
environment-including their partner's defense effort-only at some cost. Due
to diminishing marginal returns, states never acquire complete or perfect
information about their partners. Rather, they estimate probabilities of certain
behaviors and update their beliefs as they receive new information. In short,
states are Bayesian decision makers and choose relations on the basis of
expected utility calculations.28
Second, security is a single dimension of policy; the relevant "selectorate"
(whether voters or Politburo members) possess single-peaked preferences; and
the government is a perfect agent for its selectorate. These are the familiar
conditions behind the median voter theorem, applied here more generally to a
wider variety of domestic choice mechanisms.29 This assumption produces a
highly stylized view of domestic politics in which policy always reflects the
position of the median selector and allows us to treat states as unitary actors. In
28. For an introduction to Bayesian decision making in a fully strategic setting, see Morrow
1994, 161-87.
29. For a good introduction to public choice models, see Schwartz 1987. For applications of the
concept of selectorate to nondemocratic polities, see Roeder 1993, 24-27; and Shirk 1993, 71-72.
For a related approach, see Achen 1988.
making this assumption, I do not intend to imply that domestic politics are
unimportant. Rather, I want to focus attention on relations between rather
than within states. I have addressed some consequences of relaxing this
assumption elsewhere.30
Third, states do not possess preferences over particular relations; that is, the
selectorate does not innately prefer alliances or imperialism but values these
alternatives only as instruments toward some other, unspecified but valued
ends. States may be expansionary or status quo powers, power-seeking or
wealth-seeking; this assumption merely restricts states from having preferences
for or against particular instruments of policy. Like the second, this assumption
is often violated in reality, but its effect is to concentrate our attention on the
environment of states rather than their dispositions. Whether environmental
theories, such as this, or dispositional theories prove more useful is an
empirical question not addressed here.
Together, these first three assumptions imply that states choose the
relationship that minimizes their costs of producing a desired level of security.
By so choosing, states and their selectorates maximize their utility by conserv-
ing resources that can then be used to obtain other valued ends.
Fourth, the threats faced by dyads are exogenous. Positing exogenous threats
is an analytic convenience that produces a point of entry into the ongoing cycle
of action and reaction in international politics. Phrased differently, the theory
begins with the existence of a security threat from a third party and seeks to
explain how the members of a dyad choose a particular response. As noted
above, the threat from others is a complex phenomenon, driven by the third
party's goals and risk propensities, the state's own goals, the security dilemma,
and many other factors. Without explaining where threats originate, it is
nonetheless appropriate to ask how others respond.
Finally, when members of a dyad would otherwise choose different relations,
the stronger of the two parties prevails by coercing the weaker party into
accepting its preferred alternative. The current theory is decision theoretic
rather than game theoretic in construction. In essence, states are understood as
playing against "nature" when in fact they are interacting with other strategic
actors. This construction is problematic when coupled with the assumption of
costly information, as there is then no guarantee that actors will share identical
estimates of the probability distributions of the variables in the model-
although over time we may expect these estimates to converge. As a result,
states in the same dyad may choose different relations, a problem that arises in
the real world as what I have above called out-of-equilibrium behavior. This
assumption is, admittedly, rather severe-especially in dyads where the actors
are of relatively equal strength and, if locked in a coercive struggle, might
logically become caught in an infinite spiral. It is less problematic in the
unequal dyads, such as those between the superpowers and their respective
partners, that motivate this article; in very practical ways, the superpowers were
relationship "makers" and others relationship "takers." Recognizing that this
is an important limitation, I nonetheless offer the current theory for consider-
ation and, in the spirit of ongoing debate, invite readers to challenge, extend,
and possibly refine its logic.
Opportunism
33. This is also known as the asset's quasi-rent; see Klein, Crawford, and Alchian 1978. The
more specialized the asset, the greater are its quasi-rents. Asset specificity can also be understood
to affect the transactions costs of changing relations.
integrated the amalgamated territories, the smaller the probability that the
subordinate partner will act opportunistically.
The expected cost of opportunism is a function of its actual cost, if it occurs,
and its probability. Expected costs can be absorbed directly by the state; here,
the state simply accepts some opportunism by its partner as a necessary evil.
Conversely, the state can deploy some of its own resources as a hedge against
possible opportunism. Even when a partner has agreed to help protect it, for
instance, the state may maintain redundant forces for fear that the partner will
not produce the promised benefits. The state may also forgo the most efficient
technology-or continue to use a less efficient technology in some portion of its
forces-for fear that its partner will renege on necessary basing rights or other
matters. Or, the state may waive some degree of specialization for fear that the
other will not live up to the terms of the agreement. Hedging is a form of
insurance against opportunism. Like actual opportunism, it is costly to the
state.
In principle, the expected costs of opportunism can be measured by the
resources necessary to hedge completely against this possibility, given existing
information. This conversion provides a useful metric and allows us to map the
resources required to produce a constant level of security onto the degree of
relational hierarchy, creating an "isosecurity" contour that reflects the change
in costs as a function of the probability of opportunism. This is illustrated in the
O contour in Figure 2. The shape of the contour reflects the probability that the
partner will act opportunistically. Following from the arguments above, it is
negatively sloped throughout. The more effectively hierarchical governance
structures control opportunism, the steeper the contour will be. The height of
the contour in turn is positively related to the state's opportunity costs; O'
represents either an exogenous increase in the state's opportunity cost or,
comparatively, another dyad with higher costs of opportunism.
All other things considered, states should prefer to bind their partners in
more hierarchic relations. The fewer the residual rights of control retained by
the partner, the lower the potential for opportunism and thus the expected
costs. The specific relationship chosen, however, also depends upon gover-
nance costs.
Governance costs
Costs
G'
E3 El E2
Anarchy Hierarchy
(alliance) (empire)
FIGURE 2. Optimal se
opportunism (0) and govemance costs (G)
are subject to increasing control by the dominant state and, thus, are less
valuable to the subordinate. As the subordinate party's residual control
recedes, incentives in other areas of economic and political life are also
distorted. By definition, as residual rights decline, the dominant state exercises
control over a greater range of behavior and, by implication, directs resources
to uses the subordinate party would not choose on its own. As the residual
rights of control shift from one party to the other, distortions in the subordinate
member multiply.34
These distortions-both in the production of security and other areas-can,
in part, be corrected by additional contractual provisions that mandate certain
specified actions by the subordinate party. When states adopt this contractual
solution, however, the dominant state must employ additional resources to
monitor and safeguard the new provisions. As the distortions increase with
relational hierarchy, the resources employed by and therefore the costs to the
dominant state must increase as well.
Contracting cannot remove distortions entirely. Monitoring and safeguard-
ing additional areas of behavior are subject to diminishing marginal returns. It
is also efficient to shift the locus of residual control from one party to the other
precisely when it is difficult to specify future contingencies; as a result, it is very
costly to safeguard against all possible distortions. Because of its inherent and
uncorrectable distortions, increasing hierarchy-ceteris paribus-reduces the
welfare of the subordinate party. To gain the subordinate party's willing
consent to a hierarchic relationship, the welfare losses created by these
distortions must be compensated by some transfer or side-payment from the
dominant state-increasing costs to the latter. As the subordinate partner's
residual control declines and the distortions increase, so must the compensa-
tion package offered by the dominant state.
34. This argument has a direct analog in the case of private firms; see Grossman and Hart 1986.
35. On opportunism by hierarchical authorities, see Dow 1987.
36. Safeguards render the dominant state's commitment not to exploit the subordinate partner
credible. On the problem of credible commitments in international relations, see Powell 1990;
Bueno de Mesquita and Lalman 1992; Fearon 1992; Papayoanou 1992; and Cowhey 1993. James
Fearon focuses on precisely the problem here-that after consolidation the weaker party will
become even weaker-and finds that under a wide range of circumstances the weaker side will
choose to fight rather than accept an incredible agreement. See Fearon 1993.
37. Safeguards may also create maladaption costs, which arise when circumstances change and
render existing contracts less appropriate. See Williamson 1985, 21; and North 1990.
direct military action, but it holds equally for other sanctions, such as trade
embargoes (which, if effective, reduce the sanctioning country's terms of
trade). States will choose between contracting and coercion according to their
relative costs. Countries that possess a comparative advantage in coercion-
whether from sheer size, military prowess, resource endowments, or whatever-
will tend to rely upon this instrument. Coercion does appear to be the more
cost-effective and, at least for hierarchic relations, the more frequently used
instrument. The process of consolidating political authority into larger territo-
rial units, the state-building process that produced the modern nation-states in
today's developed world, frequently was violent.38 Likewise, the threat of
coercion by technologically superior European states was key to the process of
empire building in the periphery of the global system.
As with the other governance costs, the costs of creating and maintaining a
relationship through coercion typically increase with hierarchy. The more
hierarchic the imposed relationship, the smaller the subordinate actor's rights
of residual control, and therefore the more it can be expected to resist its loss of
freedom both at the outset and throughout the course of the relationship. The
greater the resistance, the greater the coercion necessary to support a given
relationship.
Thus, the governance costs of acquiring control over others and maintaining
a relationship either by contract or coercion increase as relations move from
anarchy to hierarchy. As Figure 2 illustrates, defined in terms of the resources
used in correcting and compensating distortions, safeguarding against the
potential for exploitation by the dominant state, and coercing the subordinate
party, these costs aggregate into a positively sloped governance schedule (G). I
assume here that such costs rise at an increasing rate and that each move
toward hierarchy becomes progressively more expensive to the dominant state.
The absolute quantity of resources devoted to governance determines the
height of the G schedule. Its shape is derived from the relative costs of
alternative governance structures.
Optimal relations
The expected costs of opportunism vary over time and across countries
depending upon the opportunity costs of the state and its partners. They also
vary across alternative relations, declining with hierarchy. Governance costs
vary across time and space as well, depending upon the ease of safeguarding
against and coercing partners. These costs rise with the degree of relational
hierarchy, deterring states from imperialism.
Together, the expected costs of opportunism and governance determine the
optimal relationship between a state and its partner.39 For any dyad, this
dyad allow third parties to update their prior beliefs about the expected costs of opportunism or
governance of their relations with the members of that dyad, and scale economies in governance
costs, which may promote multilateral relationships. For reasons of space, these extensions of the
basic model are not developed here. See Lake forthcoming.
coerce their partners. In the end, states weigh the efficacy of hierarchy agai
increasing governance costs when choosing their security relations.
Superpower strategies
Assessing the theory developed above faces three major hurdles. First, the
independent variables are not easy to operationalize. The expected costs of
opportunism and governance costs both are difficult to measure precisely; in
turn, we lack systematic data. This same problem also has bedeviled tests of
relational contracting theories in economics. Direct tests of the theory based on
good proxies for these variables will be nearly impossible for the foreseeable
future.
Second, and relatedly, both variables actually are defined as probability
distributions: states do not know the expected costs of opportunism or
governance costs with certainty but base their decisions on some set of prior
beliefs that they update as they receive new information. The probabilistic
nature of the variables makes definition and measurement difficult. Case
selection, then, is extremely consequential. For example, focusing on promi-
nent historical events-especially noteworthy policy failures where the strate-
gies employed performed far under expectations-risks limiting analysis to
cases with extreme values for one or both variables. Deterrence failures
resulting from buck passing or entrapments from chain ganging, often
described as pathologies resulting from dysfunctional political or cognitive
biases, may simply be the result of unfortunate events drawn from the
"unlucky" tails of the probability distributions.40 Fortunately, the dyadic nature
of the present theory multiplies the number of possible cases.
Third, and most important, we can observe the relationship chosen within a
dyad, but we cannot observe the relationships not chosen and the costs and
benefits associated with those counterfactuals.41 In other words, we can
observe, presumably, the intersection of the isosecurity and governance cost
contours, but we cannot observe directly the height and shape of the curves
themselves. Yet these unobservable relationships are central to the theory and,
as argued above, structure the choice of relations by states.
All three of these problems are quite common in the social sciences but
typically are glossed over; they certainly are not unique to the current theory.
Given these problems, one appropriate research strategy is to use historical
episodes in which there were relatively clear differences in the independent
variables to compare the static predictions of the theory. Through such cases,
we can observe the direction of the independent variables and predict the
In 1948, the United States began negotiations with Britain (and Canada)
over what would eventually become NATO. The treaty was signed in April
1949 and ratified three months later. Although the Korean War heightened
America's commitment to Europe, deepened its involvement, and institutional-
ized the alliance, the basic direction of U.S. foreign policy already had been
determined prior to June 1950. Article 5, the core of the treaty, simply states
that "the Parties agree that an armed attack against one or more of them in
42. For an extended treatment of the U.S. case and more complete citations, see Lake
forthcoming, chapt. 4. For the Soviet case, the single best source remains Brzezinski 1967. Other
noteworthy studies include Holden 1989; Jones 1990; Mastny 1979; and Ulam 1974.
Costs Gus
GUSSR
OUSSR
------- ~ ?us
US USSR
Anarchy Hierarchy
(alliance) (empire)
Europe or North America shall be considered an attack against them all" and
calls upon each member to "assist the Party or Parties so attacked by taking
forthwith ... such action as it deems necessary, including the use of armed
force, to restore and maintain the security of the North Atlantic area." Article
3 specifies that the member states should engage in "continuous and effective
self-help and mutual aid."43 While based on mutual defense and assistance,
each state is free under the treaty to interpret circumstances and choose its
response according to its own designs. Each remains in control of its own policy
not only in all areas outside the alliance but in virtually all areas covered by the
agreement as well.
The Soviet Union's informal empire in Eastern Europe was more opaque.
While each state remained nominally sovereign, the Soviet Union exerted
control over significant areas of political, economic, and social activity in
Eastern Europe through two principal means. First, the Soviet Union imposed
Opportunism
Governance costs
The conduct of the war left the Soviet Union and United States with
dramatically different governance costs in their respective spheres in Europe.
The United States fought alongside its Western allies during the war and, with
the exception of its occupation zone in Germany, did not claim exclusive areas
of jurisdiction upon victory. To assert control over the areas it liberated would
have forced the United States either to forfeit the considerable gains it
acquired from pooling resources with its partners during the conflict or to tu
its war machine against its allies. The Soviet Union, conversely, fought by itself
on the eastern front. While they cooperated with local resistance groups, often
communist, Soviet troops liberated most areas from Axis control, directly
occupied them after the war, and-in the ensuing flux-ensured that commu-
nists and other pro-Soviet groups formed important parts of every postwar
government. As a result, the costs of establishing control over and coercing
their postwar partners were absorbed in the defeat of Germany. From the
perspective of postwar relations these costs were "sunk." In other words,
finding themselves in a dominant position in Eastern Europe at the close of the
war, past costs of coercing partners were not factors in the choice of future
relations. The costs that theoretically-and in the West, practically-impeded
the pursuit of hierarchy dropped out of the Soviet calculus. All the Soviets
needed to consider were the future costs of governing territories they already
effectively controlled.
The governance costs of maintaining hierarchic relations also differed
between the Soviet Union and the United States. For the United States, the
costs of an alliance were small but rose rapidly with relational hierarchy. In this
regard, the U.S. occupation of Germany provides a useful case through which
to probe the relevant counterfactual. Even though the defeat of Germany left
U.S. troops dominant in their zone and thus in a position similar to that of their
Soviet counterparts, the ongoing costs of the occupation were prohibitive,
suggesting that greater hierarchy elsewhere also would have been extremely
costly. The Germans were expected to pay all costs associated with the
occupation, and they bore a substantial burden during a period when many
were living below subsistence levels: between 1946 and 1950, for instance,
between 42 and 26 percent of all tax revenues collected in Germany were used
to pay for the occupation.49 Yet, the United States maintained that it was
spending far more than it received from Germany in reimbursements-and
may have been spending four times more for the occupation than the Germans
themselves. Even in 1946, during the initial, punitive peace phase when little
sympathy was shown the defeated Germans and before Marshall Plan and
other forms of aid began to flow to the war-devastated state, the occupation of
the then-consolidated Anglo-American zone was costing taxpayers in Britain
and the United States over $600 million per year.50
Closer to its occupied territories, less attentive to local needs, and more
willing to use coercion as a substitute for voluntary compliance, the costs to the
Soviet Union of its informal empire were relatively low in the early postwar
years-taking the form mostly of low paid occupation troops.5' Moreover, these
49. Grosser 1955, 90. See also Davidson 1961, 261, 265, and 297.
50. Botting 1985, 216 and 110.
51. For suggestive evidence that leaders within the Soviet Union considered the maintenance
costs of the informal empire and decided nonetheless to continue the relationship, see the growing
literature on the so-called Beria Affair, especially Richter 1993, in which the secret police chief
appears to have proposed loosening Soviet control over East Germany-possibly to the point of
allowing reunification.
52. The net extraction estimate is from Brzezinski 1967, 285-86. The debate over implicit price
subsidies is large; see Marrese and Vanous 1983; Marer 1984a; 1984b; van Brabant 1984; Crane
1986; and Poznanski 1988. On the politics of implicit trade subsidies, see Stone forthcoming. The
history of Soviet-East Europe economic relations is surveyed in Bunce 1985.
53. Brzezinski 1967, 122, 173, 459.
were sunk, the Soviet Union chose more hierarchic relations in Eastern
Europe. While the evidence is supportive, it provides only a preliminary and
tentative assessment of the theory. I have neither explicated fully the variables,
probed within-region variations, nor controlled for plausible rival hypotheses-
such as regime type. Even so, the broad fit provides a source of optimism for the
likely success of more extensive tests.
Conclusion
have all but disappeared from the field. With the current movement toward
political integration in Europe, and the ongoing dissolution of the Russian
empire, it is time that we reclaimed hierarchy as an interesting and variable
characteristic of international relations.
More generally, focusing on transactions rather than actors may even allow
international relationists to begin probing the rapidly changing patterns of
political authority within the present global system. The breakup of the postwar
communist empire, the formation of the European Union, and the rise of
global markets and firms are momentous events that are defining, for better or
worse, our new world order. Changing forms of relational contracting may well
be creating, in John Ruggie's words, a postmodern, multiperspectival world.56
But the concerns of international relations properly understood endure and are
shaping the actors now emerging on the world stage.
References
Eggertsson, Thrainn. 1990. Economic behavior and institutions. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Fearon, James D. 1992. Threats to use force: Costly signals and bargaining in international crises.
Ph.D. diss., University of California, Berkeley.
. 1993. Ethnic war as a commitment problem, University of Chicago. Photocopy.
Friedberg, Aaron L. 1988. The weary titan: Britain and the experience of relative decline, 1895-1905.
Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Frieden, Jeffry A. 1994. International investment and colonial control: A new interpretation.
Intemational Organization 48:559-93.
Friedman, Julian R., Christopher Bladen, and Steven Rosen, eds. 1970. Alliance in intemational
politics. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.
Gallagher, John, and Ronald Robinson. 1953. The imperialism of free trade. The Economic History
Review 2d ser., 6:1-15.
Grosser, Alfred. 1955. The colossus again: Westem Germany from defeat to rearmament. New York:
Frederick A. Praeger.
Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart. 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of
vertical and lateral integration. Joumal of Political Economy 94:691-719.
Holden, Gerard. 1989. The Warsaw pact: Soviet security and bloc politics. New York: Basil Blackwell.
Holsti, Ole R., P. Terrence Hopmann, and John D. Sullivan. 1973. Unity and disintegration in
intemational alliances: Comparative studies. New York: Wiley.
James, Alan. 1986. Sovereign statehood: The basis of intemational society. Boston: Unwin and
Hyman.
Jervis, Robert. 1983. Security regimes. In Intemational Regimes, edited by Stephen D. Krasner.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Jones, Robert A. 1990. The Soviet concept of "limited sovereignty" from Lenin to Gorbachev: The
Brezhnev doctrine. London: Macmillan.
Kaplan, Lawrence S. 1984. The United States and NATO: The formative years. Lexington: University
Press of Kentucky.
Keohane, Robert 0. 1983. The demand for international regimes. In International Regimes, edited
by Stephen D. Krasner. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
. 1984. After hegemony: Cooperation and discord in the world political economy. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
King, Gary, Robert 0. Keohane, and Sidney Verba. 1994. Designing social inquiry: Scientific
inference in qualitative research. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G. Crawford, and Armen A. Alchian. 1978. Vertical integration,
appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Joumal of Law and Economics
21: 297-326.
LaFeber, Walter. 1993. America, Russia, and the cold war, 1945-1992. 7th ed. New York:
McGraw-Hill.
Lake, David A. 1988. Power, protection, and free trade: Intemational sources of U.S. commercial
strategy, 1887-1939. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
. 1992. Powerful pacifists: Democratic states and war. American Political Science Review
86: 24-37.
. Forthcoming. Entangling relations: American foreign policy in its century.
Lane, Frederic C. 1979. Profits from power: Readings in protection rent and violence-controlling
enterprises. Albany: State University of New York Press.
Leffler, Melvyn P. 1992. A preponderance ofpower: National security, the Truman administration, and
the cold war. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press.
Lipson, Charles. 1994. Understanding international contracts: Building institutions and sustaining
agreements in an anarchic world. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American
Political Science Association, 1-4 September, New York.
. 1995. Techniques and problems of international contracting. Paper presented at the
annual meeting of the International Studies Association, 21-25 February, Chicago.
Louis, Wm. Roger, ed. 1976. Imperialism: The Robinson and Gallagher controversy. New York: New
Viewpoints.
Marer, Paul. 1984a. Intrabloc economic relations and prospects. In The Warsaw pact: Alliance in
transition, edited by David Holloway and Jane M. 0. Sharp. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University
Press.
. 1984b. The political economy of Soviet relations with Eastern Europe. In Soviet policy in
Eastem Europe, edited by Sarah Meiklejohn Terry. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.
Marrese, Michael, and Jan Vanous. 1983. Soviet subsidization of trade with Eastern Europe: A
Soviet perspective. Research series no. 52, Institute of International Studies, University of
California, Berkeley.
Martin, Lisa L. 1992. Coercive cooperation: Explaining multilateral economic sanctions. Princeton,
N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Mastny, Vojtech. 1979. Russia's road to the cold war: Diplomacy, warfare, and the politics of
communism, 1941-1945. New York: Columbia University Press.
Mearsheimer, John J. 1994-95. The false promise of international institutions. Intemational
Security 19:5-49.
Morrow, James D. 1991. Alliances and asymmetry: An alternative to the capability aggregation
model of alliances. American Joumal of Political Science 35:904-33.
. 1993. Arms versus allies: Trade-offs in the search for security. Intemational Organization
47: 207-33.
. 1994. Game theory for political scientists. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Most, Benjamin A., and Harvey Starr. 1984. International relations theory, foreign policy
substitutability, and "nice" laws. World Politics 36:383-406.
Niou, Emerson M. S., and Peter C. Ordeshook. 1994. Alliances versus federations: An analysis with
military and economic capabilities distinguished. Durham, N.C.: Duke University, and Pasa-
dena: California Institute of Technology, respectively. Photocopy.
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and change in economic history. New York: W. W. Norton.
. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Nye, Joseph S., Jr., and Sean M. Lynn-Jones. 1988. International security studies: A report of a
conference on the state of the field. Intemational Security 12:5-27.
Papayoanou, Paul A. 1992. Economic interdependence and the balance of power: The strategy of
commitment and great power politics. Ph.D. diss., University of California, Los Angeles.
Posen, Barry R. 1984. The sources of military doctrine: France, Britain, and Germany between the
world wars. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Powell, Robert. 1990. Nuclear deterrence theory: The search for credibility. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Poznanski, Kazimiera Z. 1988. Opportunity cost in Soviet trade with Eastern Europe: Discussion of
methodology and new evidence. Soviet Studies 40:290-307.
Richter, James. 1993. Re-examining Soviet policy towards Germany in 1953. Europe-Asia Studies
45:671-91.
Roeder, Philip G. 1993. Red sunset: The failure of Soviet politics. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton
University Press.
. 1995. From hierarchy to hegemony: Patterns of security among the Soviet successor states.
In Regional orders: Building security in a new world, edited by David A. Lake and Patrick M.
Morgan, Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation, University of California, San Diego.
Typescript.
Rosecrance, Richard. 1986. The rise of the trading state: Commerce and conquest in the modem world.
New York: Basic Books.
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1983. Continuity and transformation in the world polity: Toward a neorealist
synthesis. World Politics 35:261-85.
. 1993. Territoriality and beyond: Problematizing modernity in international relations.
Intemational Organization 47:139-74.
Russett, Bruce, and Harvey Starr. 1989. World politics: The menu for choice. 3d ed. New York: W. H.
Freeman.
Schroeder, Paul W. 1976. Alliances, 1815-1945: Weapons of power and tools of management. In
Historical dimensions of national security problems, edited by Klaus Knorr. Lawrence: University
Press of Kansas.
Schwartz, Thomas. 1987. Votes, strategies, and institutions: An introduction to the theory of
collective choice. In Congress: Structure and policy, edited by Mathew D. McCubbins and Terry
Sullivan. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Shirk, Susan L. 1993. The political logic of economic reform in China. Berkeley: University of
California Press.
Simmons, Beth A. 1993. Why innovate? Founding the Bank for International Settlements. World
Politics 45:361-405.
Siverson, Randolph M., and Juliann Emmons. 1991. Birds of a feather: Democratic political
systems and alliance choices in the twentieth century. Joumal of Conflict Resolution 35:2
Siverson, Randolph M., and Harvey Starr. 1991. The diffusion of war: A study of opportunity and
willingness. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Smith, Tony. 1981. The pattem of imperialism: The United States, Great Britain, and the late-
industrializing world since 1815. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Snyder, Glenn H. 1984. The security dilemma in alliance politics. World Politics 36:461-95.
1990. Alliance theory: A neorealist first cut. Joumal of IntemationalAffairs 44:103-22.
Snyder, Jack. 1991. Myths of empire: Domestic politics and intemational ambition. Ithaca, N.Y.:
Cornell University Press.
Stein, Arthur A. 1990. Why nations cooperate: Circumstance and choice in intemational relations.
Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
Stone, Randall, forthcoming. Satellites and commissars: Strategy and conflict in the politics of
Soviet-bloc trade. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, capital, and European states, AD 990-1990. Cambridge, Mass.: Basil
Blackwell.
Triska, Jan F., ed. 1986. Dominant powers and subordinate states: The United States in Latin America
and the Soviet Union in Eastem Europe. Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press.
Ulam, Adam B. 1974. Expansion and coexistence: Soviet foreign policy, 1917-1973. 2d ed. New York:
Praeger.
van Brabant, Jozef M. 1984. The USSR and socialist economic integration: A comment. Soviet
Studies 36:127-38.
Wallander, Celeste A., and Robert 0. Keohane. 1995. An institutional approach to alliance theory.
Working paper 95-2, Center for International Affairs, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass.
Walt, Stephen M. 1987. The origins of alliances. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.
. 1991. The renaissance of security studies. Intemational Studies Quarterly 35:211-39.
Waltz, Kenneth. 1967. Foreign policy and domestic politics: The American and British experience.
Berkeley: University of California Institute of Governmental Studies Press.
. 1979. Theory of intemationalpolitics. Reading, Mass.: Addison Wesley.
Weingast, Barry R., and William J. Marshall. 1988. The industrial organization of Congress: Or,
why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets. Joumal of Political Economy
96: 132-63.
Wendt, Alexander. 1992. Anarchy is what states make of it: The social construction of power
politics. International Organization 46:391-425.
Williams, William Appleman. 1972. The tragedy ofAmerican diplomacy. 2d rev. ed. New York: Dell.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational
contracting. New York: Free Press.
Willoughby, W. W., and C. G. Fenwick. [1919] 1974. The inquiry handbooks, vol. 16. Wilmington,
Del. Reprint. Originally published as Types of restricted sovereignty and of colonial autonomy.
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Yarbrough, Beth V., and Robert M. Yarbrough. 1992. Cooperation and governance in intemational
trade: The strategic organizational approach. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.