2014 Understanding Us Innovation System
2014 Understanding Us Innovation System
2014 Understanding Us Innovation System
net/publication/321790571
CITATIONS READS
40 4,592
1 author:
Rob Atkinson
information Technology and Innovation Foundation
92 PUBLICATIONS 1,751 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Rob Atkinson on 14 January 2019.
Indeed, as Christopher Freeman defined it, a national innovation system is “the network of
institutions in the public and private sectors whose activities and interactions initiate,
import, modify and diffuse new technologies.” 1 Innovation systems matter because a
nation’s innovation success depends on its national innovation system working effectively
and synergistically.
This report first briefly describes the historical evolution of the U.S. national innovation
system. It then describes the broad elements of the national innovation system organized
An effective trade, tax and regulatory environment features a competitive and open trade
regime, including serious efforts by government to protect its businesses against foreign
mercantilist practices; support for competitive markets such that new entrants, including
those introducing new business models, can flourish; processes by which it’s easy to launch
new businesses and to bring innovations to market; transparency and the rule of law; a
reasonable business tax burden, especially on innovation-based and globally traded firms; a
strong and well-functioning patent system and protection of intellectual property;
regulatory requirements on businesses that are, to the extent possible, based on consistent,
transparent, and performance-based standards; limited regulations on the digital economy;
limited regulations on labor markets and firm closures and downsizing; a balanced
approach to competition policy; and government procurement based on performance
standards as well as open and fair competition. To be sure, a good regulatory climate does
not mean simply the absence of regulations. As we saw with the recent financial crisis, the
right kinds of regulations are critical to ensuring that markets work and innovation
flourishes. But nations need a regulatory climate that supports rather than blocks
innovators and that creates the conditions to spur ever more innovation and market entry,
while at the same time providing more regulatory flexibility and efficiency for industries in
traded sectors.
The final leg of the innovation triangle is a sophisticated and strong innovation policy
system. While markets are key to innovation, without effective innovation policy, markets
will underperform. 2 An innovation policy system includes: generous support for public
investments in innovation infrastructure (including science, technology, and technology
This is not to say that policy did not play a role. In the early half of the nineteenth century,
government support for canals, railroads, and other “internal improvements” helped create
larger markets. In the 1860s the federal government created the system of research-based
land grant colleges through the Morrill Act. Funding for agricultural research helped power
agricultural productivity, which freed up tens of millions of farm workers to power
America’s growing factories and helped create larger markets for industrial producers. In
addition, since the founding of the Republic, the federal government had a robust patent
system embedded in the Constitution. Moreover, policy to spur competition—through the
Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 and the Clayton Antitrust Act of 1914—was used to ensure
that firms had the incentive to continue to innovate. And as Charles Morris’s The Dawn of
Innovation: The First American Industrial Revolution showed, wars (including the War of
1812, the Civil War and WWI) energized government-funded technology and industrial
This changed dramatically after WWII with the emergence of a more science-based system
of innovation (inspired in part by Vannevar Bush, director of the U.S. Office of Scientific
Research and Development during WWII) which would become dominated by large firms
and the federal government. The establishment—initially in the Great Depression and
then after the war—of large, centralized corporate R&D laboratories helped drive
innovation in an array of industries, including electronics, pharmaceuticals and aerospace.
On top of this, the massive federal support for science and technology in WWII helped
develop the “arsenal of democracy” that the Allies used to beat back the Axis powers threat.
This strong federal role continued after the war, with substantial funding of a system of
national laboratories and significantly increased funding of research universities. Federal
funding of research helped drive innovation and played a key role in enabling U.S.
leadership in a host of industries, from software, hardware, aviation, and biotechnology.
For the most part this research was funded through mission-based agencies seeking to
accomplish a particular federal mission (e.g., defense, health, energy) and through a system
of peer-reviewed basic research funding at universities.
In fact, the explicit promotion of innovation and productivity as an economic goal was
largely ignored and even rejected through most of the post-war period. To be sure there
were occasional efforts during the Kennedy, Johnson, and Nixon administrations, but these
were small scale and largely short-lived. The first major post-war federal effort to explicitly
support industrial innovation was made by the Kennedy administration in 1963 with its
proposal for a Civilian Industrial Technology Program (CITP). The administration
proposed CITP to help balance the overriding focus of federal R&D on defense and space
exploration, both of which had increased as the United States sought to counter the Soviet
Union in the Cold War. 5 The CITP program was to provide funding to universities to do
research helping innovation in sectors thought to help society, such as coal production,
housing, and textiles. But despite the administration’s efforts to launch the program,
Congress did not approve it, in part because of industry opposition that feared disruptive
technologies. For example, the cement industry opposed the program because it feared that
innovation in housing technology might reduce the need for cement in construction.
Two years later the Johnson administration was able to get a redesigned effort through
Congress, but only after making a number of changes. The new program, the State
Technical Services program, was to fund university-based technology extension centers in
the states that would work with small and mid-sized companies to help them better utilize
new technologies. But despite the program’s success, the Nixon administration eliminated
it, largely on the grounds that this was an inappropriate federal intervention into the
economy. However, the Nixon administration proposed its own initiative, the new
Technology Opportunities Program, again to support technology in solving pressing social
challenges, like developing high-speed rail and curing certain medical diseases. But again the
program was not funded by Congress.
This system began to gradually change in the late 1970s with the emergence of
competitiveness challenges from nations like Japan and Germany. It was with the election of
President Jimmy Carter in 1976 that the federal government began to focus in a more
serious way on the promotion of technology, innovation, and competitiveness. The
motivation for this was the major recession of 1974 (the worst since the Great Depression),
the shift in the U.S. balance of trade from one of surplus to one of deficit, and the growing
recognition that nations like France, Germany, and Japan now posed a serious
competitiveness challenge to U.S. industry.
Attempts by the federal These efforts were followed up by efforts by Congress and the Reagan and Bush I
government to explicitly administrations. Indeed, policymakers responded with a host of major policy innovations,
support commercial including passage of the Stevenson-Wydler Act, the Bayh-Dole Act, the National
innovation were at best Technology Transfer Act, and the Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act. They created
a long list of alphabet soup programs to boost innovation, including SBIR (Small Business
made in fits and starts Innovation Research), NTIS (National Technical Information Service—expanded), SBIC
and never really got off (Small Business Investment Company—reformed), MEP (Manufacturing Extension
the ground. Partnership), and CRADAs (cooperative research and development agreements). They put
in place the R&D tax credit and lowered capital gains and corporate tax rates. They created
a host of new collaborative research ventures, including SEMATECH, the National
Science Foundation (NSF) Science and Technology Centers and Engineering Research
Centers, and the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST) Advanced
Technology Program. And they put in place the Baldridge Quality Award and the National
Technology Medal.
Moreover, it wasn’t just Washington that acted. Most of the 50 states transformed their
practice of economic development to at least include the practice of technology-led
economic development. Many realized that R&D and innovation were drivers of the New
Economy, and that state economies prosper when they maintain a healthy research base
closely linked to commercialization of technology. For example, under the leadership of
Governor Richard Thornburgh, Pennsylvania established the Ben Franklin Partnership
Program that provides matching grants primarily to small and medium-sized firms to work
collaboratively with Pennsylvania universities.
But by the time Bill Clinton was elected in 1992, America’s competitiveness challenge
appeared to be receding. Japan was beginning to face its own problems, in part stemming
from the popping of its property bubble and increasing value of the yen. And Europe was
preoccupied with its internal market integration efforts. Moreover, with the rise of Silicon
Valley as a technology powerhouse and the rise of the Internet revolution and companies
Soon after, information technology entered into a new phase, with more powerful
microprocessors, the wide-scale deployment of fast broadband telecommunications
networks, and the rise of Web 2.0 social network platforms. As a result, it became clear to
many policymakers that IT (or ICT) was now a key driver of growth and competitiveness,
and that effective economic policy now had to get IT policy right.
Toward that end, the Bush II administration and Congress undertook a number of
initiatives. Building on the Clinton administration’s Internet Governance Principles which
argued that government should take a light touch toward regulating the Internet, the Bush
administration took a number of steps to spur IT innovation, including deregulating
broadband telecommunications (now that most American homes had access to at least two
broadband “pipes” – cable and DSL), freeing up radio spectrum for wireless broadband,
taking a light touch with respect to regulating online privacy, and using IT to transform
government itself (e-government).
But while IT was thriving, U.S. industrial competitiveness was not. The United States lost
over one third of its manufacturing jobs in the 2000s, with the majority lost due to falling
international competitiveness, not superior productivity. 6 The United States went from
running a trade surplus in high-technology products in 2000 to around a 100 billion dollar
deficit a decade later. The Great Recession, both a result of this loss of competitiveness and a
cause of further industrial decline, may represent a watershed moment in U.S. history, one
that represented the high-water mark of U.S. industrial leadership. But that will likely
depend on the nature of the national policy responses over the next decade.
In any case, the state of U.S. industrial innovation and competiveness has gained renewed
attention after the losses of the 2000s, the Great Recession and the emergence of robust new
technological competitors, including, but not limited to China. Because of this, the Obama
administration has proposed a number of initiatives, including the establishment of a
National Network of Manufacturing Innovation (three centers have already been
announced); an expansion in the research and experimentation (R&D) tax credit; increased
funding for science agencies (including NSF, NIST, and DOE [Department of Energy]);
policies to expand the number of STEM graduates; patent reform; and increased efforts to
limit unfair foreign “innovation mercantilist” policies, among others. Congress has also
introduced a variety of similar measures. However, partisan differences fueled in part by a
growing populism from the right and the left (anti-government for the former; anti-
corporate for the latter) coupled with a large federal budget deficit and a political
unwillingness to raise taxes on individuals or cut entitlements, has meant that progress to
shore up the weaknesses in the U.S. innovation system has been extremely limited.
Business Environment
The business environment consists of three broad factors: market and firm structure and
behavior, the system for financing business, and related social and cultural factors affecting
how business operates.
Managerial Talent
When it comes to managerial talent it appears that the United States is the world leader
and this factor has played a role in explaining past U.S. innovation leadership. As professor
John Van Reenan and colleagues have shown, “when it comes to overall management,
American firms outperform all others.” 7 In part this comes from environmental factors that
There are three elements force better management: more competition and more flexible labor markets. But it may
of a national innovation also come from the fact that the United States developed the discipline of management (in
system: the business the 1950s) and perfected it through its extensive system of business schools at universities.
environment, the Time Horizon and Risk Appetite of Firms
regulatory environment Despite the high quality of many U.S. managers, they increasingly find themselves in firms
and the innovation policy buffeted by pressures for short-term performance, which in turn reduces their ability to
invest for the long-term. For example, in a 2004 survey of more than four hundred U.S.
environment.
executives, over 80 percent indicated that they would decrease discretionary spending on
areas such as R&D, advertising, maintenance, and hiring in order to meet short-term
earnings targets, and more than 50 percent said they would delay new projects, even if it
meant sacrifices in value creation. 8 This focus on maximizing short-term returns means
that companies are effective in reducing waste and pulling the plug on poor investments.
But at the same time, this pressure to achieve short-term profits all too often has meant
sacrificing long-term investment, which is the majority of investment in innovation. As the
Business Roundtable, the leading trade association for large American businesses, reported,
“the obsession with short-term results by investors, asset management firms, and corporate
managers collectively leads to the unintended consequences of destroying long-term value,
decreasing market efficiency, reducing investment returns, and impeding efforts to
strengthen corporate governance.” 9
ICT Adoption
U.S. firms are among the world leaders in adoption of information and communications
technologies (e.g., hardware and software). U.S. firms invest more as a share of sales and of
overall capital investment in hardware, software, and telecommunications than almost any
other nation. For example, these investments are almost twice as high as Korean
investments. And as Van Reenan and Bloom have found, not only do U.S. firms invest
more, but U.S. firms appear to get more benefit out of IT investment than many other
countries’ firms. In part this is because U.S. firms are more willing to use IT to
fundamentally restructure production processes. 10
Some state governments have also established programs to help with venture funding,
particularly to smaller and earlier stage startups. Some have also created angel capital
networks to help private funders better coordinate their efforts and find deals. And the
federal government, through the Small Business Administration’s Small Business
Investment Company, provides capital subsidies to some private sector venture firms, while
the Small Business Innovation Research (SBIR) program provides modest research grants
to small firms.
Government financing for firms is quite limited. Existing firms can raise additional money
on highly traded and liquid equities markets. And corporate debt, either through bonds or
loans, is widely available. At the federal level, the Small Business Administration provides
some direct and indirect lending for small firms, but this is not targeted to innovation-
based firms or firms in traded sectors. And many state governments provide modest
financing for industrial expansion and early stage firms.
Cultural Factors
As scholars such as Francis Fukuyama, Raquel Fernandez, Lawrence Harrison, and Samuel
Huntington have shown, cultural factors such as trust, group orientation, and risk taking
have impacts on innovation and growth. 13
Collaborative Culture
While innovation is about competition, it’s also about “coopetition” and cooperation—in
other words, groups working together to drive innovation. This has become more
important to enabling innovation, especially as innovation has become more challenging
with more organizations embracing open innovation. As Fred Block found, the nature of
the U.S. innovation system has changed dramatically over the course of the last 40 years. 21
Regulatory Environment
Regardless, compared to other nations, the U.S. NIS erects relatively few barriers to entry
for firms to break into existing markets, thus ensuring robust competition and the constant
threat of “Schumpeterian” creative destruction. We have seen this in industries as diverse as
financial services, energy production, and transportation. In addition, the U.S. system
attempts to create a level playing field with e-commerce competitors, enabling new entrants
to disrupt existing markets and business for the advantage of the consumer. However, that
may be changing as entrenched interests in industries such as real estate, car sales, taxi
services, hotels, legal services, and others seek to use laws and regulations to limit
competition.
Combine this change in
attitude with a very large Regulatory System for Entrepreneurship
national debt, and it Academic research shows that delays caused by entry regulations are associated with lower
rates of firm entry. 25 The United States ranks relatively high on the World Bank index of
becomes increasingly
ease of starting a business, but not as high as some nations like Canada, which has made
difficult for federal this a top priority. 26 Moreover, it is not only relatively easy to start a new business, but it is
elected officials to ask also easy to close one or lay off workers, at least in the non-unionized, non-governmental
American voters to pay share of the economy. 27 The latter is important, for if entrepreneurs cannot easily close or
more to support expanded downsize businesses and if investors cannot obtain reasonable capital recovery rates, the
incentives for entrepreneurship are reduced. 28
financial support for
innovation. Role and Form of Regulation
The U.S. system of regulations, many of which affect innovation, begins with Congress
passing legislation and sometimes requiring executive branch agencies to promulgate
regulations. These agencies go through an extensive public notice and comment period in
which individuals and organizations can submit written comments that the agencies are
required to review. In addition, the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA)
within the White House Office of Management and Budget also conducts cost-benefit
reviews of some proposed regulations, particularly those with high expected costs. To the
extent that OIRA finds a “significant” federal regulation inconsistent with its cost-benefit
analysis, it can return the regulation to the promulgating agency (which can then revise or
withdraw it). Although OIRA’s analysis does not always trump that of the agency, it does
dominate. And of course, if agencies do not change their regulatory decision, Congress can
also act and change the law. And this process is generally quite transparent. For example,
the Clinton administration inserted greater transparency into the OIRA review process by
requiring, inter alia, public disclosure of all communications between OIRA personnel and
individuals not employed by the executive branch.
While regulation is not always performance-based, in the last two decades there has been a
greater awareness among regulators of the importance of focusing regulations more on
However, it appears that the U.S. regulatory burden on innovation has grown over the last
decade, both in extent and orientation. As we see in areas like agricultural biotech and
privacy, the pressures for more regulation grow. Moreover, most regulatory agency budgets
have been cut or limited, making it harder for them to both modernize technologies and
processes and expand staff so that they can respond quickly to firms seeking regulatory
approval. We see this in areas as diverse as patent approvals, drug and medical device
approvals, and approvals of new airplanes.
Macroeconomic Environment
Macroeconomic policies can provide an overall supportive policy for innovation. U.S.
macroeconomic policy has been predicated on monetary stability, focused on limiting
inflation. Some have argued that in its efforts to limit inflation the Federal Reserve Board
has placed too little relative emphasis on full employment, especially since the late 1970s.
And while the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act was the exception, U.S.
macroeconomic policy relies principally on monetary policy, rather than fiscal policy, to
adjust cyclical growth rates. In addition, because of the overriding focus on consumer as
opposed to producer welfare, as well as a belief that markets should determine prices, U.S.
policy toward its currency (and that of other nations) is largely non-interventionist, and to
the extent that it is interventionist, it is to defend a strong dollar (which helps consumers
but hurts most producers, especially in traded sectors).
Tax Policy
While the prevailing view toward U.S. tax policy is that it should be neutral vis-à-vis
various economic activities, the reality is that it is somewhat interventionist, sometimes for
good policy reasons (e.g., the R&D tax credit, accelerated depreciation) and other times
because of special interest pressures for particular tax provisions. 29 But most policymakers
strive for a tax code that does not favor particular industries over others, even if this means
that some traded sectors exposed to international competition pay more than some non-
traded sectors. 30 Moreover, the U.S. corporate tax rate is quite high (in both statutory and
effective terms). 31 In addition, the U.S. R&D tax credit is relatively anemic compared to
other nations, ranking just twenty-seventh in R&D tax generosity. 32 And the United States
Trade Policy
The United States’ approach to trade policy is based on the belief that nations have
revealed comparative advantage and that an open and market-based trading system enables
nations to achieve that advantage to the benefit of its consumers. This has led the United
States to focus mostly on signing new trade agreements. However, in recent years, there has
been a growing focus on trade enforcement (including the establishment of an Interagency
Trade Enforcement Center) based on the belief that the benefits from trade will be less if
other nations are not playing by the rules developed by the World Trade Organization.
Nevertheless, funding for trade enforcement efforts is relatively anemic, with the Office of
the United States Trade Representative (USTR), Department of Commerce’s International
Trade Administration (ITA), and State Department trade efforts significantly under-
funded.
When it comes to trade promotion, the United States does very little compared to other
Most policymakers strive nations. Funding authority for the Ex-Im Bank is limited compared to many other
for a tax code that does nations. 33 Funding for foreign direct investment (FDI) attraction is also a fraction of what
not favor particular other nations invest. However, the Obama administration has made some efforts in these
areas, including establishment of the Select USA organization.
industries over others,
even if this means that Intellectual Property
some traded sectors The U.S. system of intellectual property protection has its roots in the U.S. Constitution,
exposed to international which gave Congress the powers to promote “the progress of science and useful arts” by
providing inventors with the limited but exclusive right to their discoveries. This applies to
competition pay more
copyrights and patents, with trademarks similarly protected by Congress under the
than some non-traded Commerce Clause (Article I, Section 8, Clause 3). The view then, as well as now, is that
sectors. without reasonable protection for their IP, inventors and creators (e.g., individuals or
companies) would innovate and create less. Patents and trademarks are governed by the
U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) in the Department of Commerce. Copyright is
governed by the Librarian of Congress. And of course, Congress writes the laws under
which these agencies must function, and mostly objective courts can rule on their decisions.
While there is some disagreement within the United States over exactly how strong IP
protection should be, the differences are largely at the margin (with some arguing for
slightly stronger protection and some for slightly weaker), or over particular issues
regarding implementation (e.g., the debate over the proposed Stop Online Privacy Act
[SOPA] legislation regarding how to identify and limit access to foreign infringing
websites). Part of this overall debate has stemmed from the fact that there is some evidence
that during the late 1990s and early 2000s the U.S. Patent and Trademark office was
perhaps too liberal in issuing patents, in part from a large patent backlog and from the
development of novel applications (e.g., business methods patents). However, after recent
passage of patent legislation that allowed an increased budget for the PTO, some of these
problems appear to have receded. However, there is a still a challenge from what some refer
to as “patent trolls,” a pejorative term used for a person or company that enforces its
Standards
The U.S. commercial standards system (as opposed to standards for health, safety, and the
environment) is characterized by a voluntary, consensus-based global system. By and large,
the government itself does not get involved in picking particular industry standards. For
example, in the dispute between HD and Blu-ray high-definition video players, the
government did not pick a standard, rather letting cooperation and competition between
industry and the emergence of consumer choice determine the winning standard. These
standards processes are coordinated by industry trade associations and by the American
National Standards Institute (ANSI). ANSI facilitates the development of American
National Standards (ANS) by accrediting the procedures of standards developing
organizations (SDOs). These groups work cooperatively to develop voluntary national
consensus standards. American National Standards are usually referred to as “open”
standards. In this sense, “open” refers to a collaborative, balanced, and consensus-based
approval process. The content of these standards may relate to products, processes, services,
Relative to private sector systems, or personnel. ANSI has served in its capacity as administrator and coordinator of
R&D funding trends, the United States private sector voluntary standardization system for more than 90 years.
federal support for R&D Initially funded by five engineering societies and three government agencies, the ANSI
has fallen substantially as remains a private, nonprofit membership organization supported by a diverse constituency
of private and public sector organizations. ANSI and other SDOs also work at a global level
a share of GDP from its
with their counterparts around the world to develop voluntary, consensus-based global
high levels in the 1960s standards. While the National Institute of Standards and Technology (NIST) is a federal
laboratory, its work largely involves metrology (measurement), not private sector standard
setting.
Relative to private sector R&D funding trends, federal support for R&D has fallen
substantially as a share of GDP from its high levels in the 1960s (during the Cold War and
the race to the moon). There have been occasional efforts to increase funding. In the late
Federal Labs
The United States funds a system of between 80 to 100 government research laboratories
(some are government operated, while some are private contractor operated). The largest
labs are funded by the departments of Defense, Energy, and Health. For the most part,
research is funded to help agencies better achieve mission goals. 37 While not part of the
National Labs system, the Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency (DARPA) and
Advanced Research Projects Agency-Energy (ARPA-E) have also played an important role
in the development of cutting-edge technologies initially designed to support core agency
missions (e.g., defense or energy efficiency) that over time have yielded substantial
technology spinoffs to the U.S. and global economy (e.g., the Internet, lasers, etc.).
University Research
University research is supported through a number of agencies, including DOD
(Department of Defense), DOE, and NIH, to help them achieve mission goals. However,
the National Science Foundation funds university research largely unrelated to agency
mission goals. While the system is based on the conception of the linear model of research
(first proposed by White House science advisor Vannevar Bush in the post-war period and
based on the notion that funding for investigator-directed basic research will lead to
valuable outcomes automatically), some argue that federal funding for university research
should take a more explicit account of the needs of the commercial economy and promote
tech transfer. However, in part because of cuts at the state government level and more
recently federal funding cuts, university R&D levels relative to GDP in the United States
lag behind many nations. 38
All of these measures are largely technology and firm agnostic, supporting innovation itself
(e.g., the R&D credit). However, the federal government has supported some industry-
specific efforts related to industry R&D. For example, SEMATECH and the StarNet
program have supported advanced R&D in the semiconductor industry. 39 The latter
program with industry and government funds a number of university research centers
focused on advanced semiconductor research.
Innovation Clusters
The concept of innovation clusters has been long understood by regional planners
(harkening back to “Marshallian” manufacturing learning districts in the early 1900s).
However, it was not until Harvard Business School Professor Michael Porter popularized
On a per-GDP basis, the notion of clusters in the 1990s that many governments in the United States began to
Korea invests 89 times focus more explicitly on spurring innovation clusters. Of course, the emergence of a few
high-profile clusters such as Silicon Valley and North Carolina’s Research Triangle Park
more than the United
(RTP) lent credibility to the notion that innovation clusters can power innovation and
States on industrially- growth. Despite this, the federal government has played little explicit role in the
oriented research, development of innovation clusters. To be sure, funding from the federal government
Germany 43 times more, (especially DOD in Silicon Valley and Boston’s Route 128 and NIH in RTP) has played a
key role in the development of some U.S. innovation clusters. But explicit innovation
and Japan 15 times more
cluster policies have been the province of states and sub-state regions, in part because these
units of governments are “closer to the ground” and have a better sense of which clusters
are important. Toward that end, many U.S. states have innovation cluster programs and
policies. 44
With regard to exporting technology, there are few limits on exporting U.S. commercial
technologies to other nations, unless those technologies have potential benefits for current
or potential military adversaries. As a result, the Department of Commerce’s Bureau of
Industry and Security oversees the transfer of certain sensitive U.S. technologies to some
foreign nations. But again, the number of technologies covered is relatively small.
Moreover, in the past decade there has been increasing pressure from industry and others
to reduce the restrictions in order to boost U.S. innovation competitiveness, in addition to
the U.S. government.
Education/Training (K-12)
The United States’s K-12 education system is largely operated at the state and local level,
with thousands of local school districts. Unlike many other nations, the United States has
not established federal control of the K-12 system. However, the development by the states
(and supported by the federal government) of the new “Common Core” standard is a move
in that direction.
One feature of the U.S. K-12 system that is different from that of many other nations is the
increased diversity of kinds of schools. Since the 1980s, the growth of “charter” schools
(publically funded, but privately operated) has been significant, with many of the charters
focusing on unique pedagogical approaches. In addition, the United States has a higher
share of students in private (religious and non-denominational) schools than most other
nations. Finally, despite the relatively mediocre test scores, the U.S. K-12 education system
does appear to do a better job than many national education systems in encouraging
independence and creative thinking among students. In many schools students are
encouraged to not just engage in rote learning (e.g., “drill and kill”) but in more creative
activities and independent thinking. This appears to play a supportive role in U.S.
innovation and entrepreneurship. However, with the rise of the standards movement, such
activities may diminish, rather than flourish.
Higher Education
The American higher education system is diverse and distributed in nature. As described
above, states manage public universities and colleges while private universities are funded
though tuition and charitable donations. For private schools, some students can afford high
tuitions while others receive financial aid from the universities. Public state schools are
subsidized, but with the fiscal problems of state governments, tuition rates have increased
significantly as public funding has been cut. This is one reason why the United States has
fallen behind many other nations in higher education enrollment rates.
In addition, there is little national or state effort to guide students in their choice of what
they study. On the one hand this helps students choose majors in response to market
forces; it also means that there is an undersupply of graduates in science, technology,
Skill/Technical Training
In the United States, skills training is largely seen as a private sector responsibility. As such
there is no national system for employer-based skills training. In the old economy,
employers played a stronger role in skills training. Some industries and firms took the lead
with the establishment of training institutes and industry-wide apprenticeship programs.
But over the past three decades most of these efforts have ended as firms see such
investments in “public goods” as something they can no longer afford. As such, overall
private sector investment in skills training has declined by about one-third as a share of
GDP in the last decade. 48
To the extent that there is a federal role (through the Department of Labor), it is focused
largely on helping disadvantaged individuals obtain skills. However, the National Skill
Standards Act of 1994 created a National Skill Standards Board (NSSB) responsible for
supporting voluntary partnerships in each economic sector that would establish industry-
defined national standards leading to industry-recognized, nationally portable
certifications. The vision was that each industry would define and validate national
standards for the skills it was seeking and credential individuals against those skills. One
key reason for doing this was so that companies would have a better way to assess the skills
of prospective and current workers and so that workers would have a better way to identify
and gain the skills they needed to be successful. But the federal government failed to
provide matching funding to establish this standards-based system. Moreover, in the
2000s, the national sectoral approach was abandoned in favor of a regional approach.
However, a number of states have established skills training programs. For example,
Wisconsin and Georgia have strong youth apprenticeship programs. Some states and local
school districts have established career academies within high schools. Several have
established regional skills alliances—industry-led partnerships that address workforce needs
in a specific region and industry sector. For example, Michigan has provided competitively
awarded startup grants and technical assistance to 25 industry-led regional skills alliances.
Pennsylvania’s $15 million Industry Partnerships program brings together employers and
workers (or worker representatives, when appropriate) in the same industry cluster to
address overlapping human capital needs. Other states have established tax credits for
company investments in workforce development. California has a deduction for training
expenses if a company has spent a certain share of sales on training. Firms in Rhode Island
can deduct up to 50 percent of training costs on their corporate income taxes.
Moreover, a core component of the U.S. skills training system is the system of community
colleges the nation enjoys. The community college system is a critical partner in training
Immigration Policy
More than many nations, the United States has relied on high-skill immigration to support
its innovation system. This has paid off to date. At least seven studies have examined the
role of immigrants in launching new companies in the United States, and all conclude that
immigrants are key actors in this process, creating from 15 percent to 26 percent of new
companies in the U.S. high-tech sector over the past two decades. 49 Some U.S. states have
seen even greater beneficiaries: nearly 40 percent of the engineering and technology firms
founded in the U.S. states of California and New Jersey between 1995 and 2005 were
At least seven studies have founded by foreign born-immigrants. 50
examined the role of
immigrants in launching The United States has several systems to encourage high-skill immigration, including a
policy to provide permanent residence to some STEM workers and a temporary employer-
new companies in the
sponsored work visa system (H1b). However, there is a general recognition that the system
United States, and all needs serious reform, in part to make it easier for high-skill immigrants to gain a path to
conclude that immigrants citizenship. One reason for the relatively successful U.S. immigration system is that
are key actors in this immigrants are more easily assimilated into the society than they are in many other nations.
process. According to one study, the U.S. ranked ninth in terms of integration policies, and first in
terms of its strong anti-discrimination laws and protections. 51 The U.S. also ranked high
on the access to citizenship scale because it encourages newcomers to become citizens in
order to fully participate in American public life.
But there are a number of other factors where the U.S. position is clearly trending down,
especially in relation to other national innovation systems. These include funding support
for universities and federal labs and other innovation inputs as federal policymakers
continue their unwillingness to prioritize investment in the federal budget process. Indeed,
this is a component of a broader factor of the unwillingness of American society to invest in
the future and in collective goods. There is little evidence that American voters are willing
to sacrifice additional current income and consumption for investments in the future. At
the same time, this pressure for immediate gratification reflects itself in the investment
decisions by publically traded corporations. Again there is little evidence that the pressures
from equities markets for immediate returns will abate any time soon. Even more, there is a
disturbing turn to “neo-Ludditism” in America as so-called “public interest” groups, the
media, and an increasing share of the public adopt an anti-innovation attitude, whether it
relates to genetically modified organisms, the use of data, or automation. Given the
complicity of the media in this process, which increasingly adopts the view that “fear grabs
eyeballs,” the likelihood is that neo-Luddite, anti-progress forces will strengthen, not
weaken, making the overall innovation environment more problematic.
For similar reasons, reform of the regulatory system as it affects innovation is equally
problematic. Most Democrats look at any efforts here as an attempt to gut needed
protections and therefore view even simple common-sense reforms as opening up the
floodgates of deregulation. Moreover, most liberal Democrats believe that business,
especially large businesses, are regulated too lightly. At the same time, most Republicans are
reluctant to increase funding for regulatory agencies, believing that this will simply
empower them to regulate more, rather than regulate more smartly and expeditiously.
Finally, there are a number of areas where it is either unclear what the future trends are
likely to be or that depend on policy choices which are possible in this political
environment. For the former, one key factor is entrepreneurship and risk taking. While
there does not appear to be any appreciable diminution of the American entrepreneurial
spirit, there has been a significant decline in entrepreneurial activity, as Robert Litan has
shown. 53 It is not clear if this is a long-term, structural decline, or something that is a
response to overall U.S. competitiveness decline that would rebound if the right innovation
policies were put in place.
For the latter, there are a number of areas where policy may make a significant difference.
One is high-skill immigration. While there is a general bi-partisan consensus in favor of
liberalizing high-skill immigration, opposition from the left and the Tea Party right make
future progress problematic. 54 There are a number of other areas where there is reasonable
bi-partisan consensus for action, including STEM education, manufacturing technology
support programs (e.g., the Congressional RAMI legislation), FDI attraction programs
(e.g., Select USA), funding for technical skills training, and increased resources for trade
enforcement. But to date, Congress has been preoccupied with matters other than
In summary, as nations compete to win the global innovation race, some will sprint out
ahead, others will remain stuck in the middle of the pack, and still others will struggle to
get out of the starting gate. Nations face different challenges in the race. No nation has it
entirely right just yet, although a few come close. While some nations—such as Japan and
much of Europe—have strong innovation policy systems, many of them suffer from
The nation that can put limited regulatory and business environments. In contrast, the United States has reasonably
together all three sides of good business and regulatory environments (although as noted above, many important
the innovation success factors are trending downward), but a weak innovation policy environment. The nation
triangle most effectively is that can put together all three sides of the innovation success triangle most effectively is
likely to be the nation that wins the race and reaps the rewards in greater economic vitality
likely to be the nation
and prosperity. Thus, the challenge for the United States going forward is whether it can
that wins the race and make the needed changes to its innovation system to meet the new competition. Our
reaps the rewards in economic future will depend on the answer.
greater economic vitality
and prosperity.
1. Christopher Freeman, Technology and Economic Performance: Lessons from Japan (London: Pinter, 1987).
2. Robert D. Atkinson, Stephen J. Ezell and Luke A. Stewart, “The Global Innovation Policy Index” (ITIF,
March 2012), 17,
http://www.kauffman.org/~/media/kauffman_org/research%20reports%20and%20covers/2012/03/globa
linnovationpolicyindex2012.
3. For some broader and deeper views, see Michael Lind, Land of Promise: An Economic History of the United
States (New York: HarperCollins, 2012), and Charles R. Morris, The Dawn of Innovation: The First
American Industrial Revolution (New York: PublicAffairs, 2012).
4. Alfred Chandler, The Visible Hand (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1977).
5. Robert D. Atkinson, “Innovation policy making in a federalist system: Lessons from the states for U.S.
federal innovation policy making,” Research Policy 20, no. 6 (December 1991): 559-577,
http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/B6V77-45D0R95-
43/2/2bb90d167270cfa32c758d21507349a1.
6. Robert D. Atkinson, Luke A. Stewart, Scott M. Andes, and Stephen J. Ezell, “Worse Than the Great
Depression: What Experts are Missing About American Manufacturing Decline” (ITIF, March 2012),
http://www2.itif.org/2012-american-manufacturing-decline.pdf.
7. Nicholas Bloom, Rebecca Homkes, Raffaella Sadun, and John Van Reenen, “Why American
Management Rules the World,” HBR Blog Network, June 13, 2011,
http://blogs.hbr.org/cs/2011/06/why_american_management_rules.html.
8. Dean Krehmeyer, Matthew Orsagh and Kurt Schacht, “Breaking the Short-Term Cycle: Discussion and
Recommendations on How Corporate Leaders, Asset Managers, Investors and Analysts Can Refocus on
Long-Term Value” (CFA Institute and Business Roundtable Institute for Corporate Ethics, 2006),
http://www.corporate-ethics.org/pdf/Short-termism_Report.pdf.
9. Ibid.
10. Ben Miller and Robert D. Atkinson, “Raising European Productivity Growth Through ICT” (ITIF, June
2014), http://www2.itif.org/2014-raising-eu-productivity-growth-ict.pdf.
11. Robert D. Atkinson and Adams Nager, The 2014 State New Economy Index (ITIF, June 2014),
http://www2.itif.org/2014-state-new-economy-index.pdf.
12. Chris O’Brien, “Where does WhatsApp acquisition rank in history of tech deals?,” Los Angeles Times,
February 20, 2014, http://www.latimes.com/business/technology/la-fi-tn-where-does-whatsapp-rank-in-
history-of-tech-deals-20140220-story.html.
13. See: Francis Fukuyama, The End of History and the Last Man (New York: Avon Books Inc, 1992);
Raquel Fernandez, “Does Culture Matter?,” in Handbook of Social Economics, by Jess Benhabib, Matthew
O. Jackson, and Alberto Bisin (North-Holland: Elsevier B.V., 2011), 481-510;
Lawrence Harrison and Samuel Huntington, Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress (New
York: Perseus Books Group, 2000).
14. Michael Porter, Competitive Advantage of Nations (New York: The Free Press, 1980).
15. For example, in the United States, rooms are larger, more likely to be air conditioned, and have better
quality beds. U.S. hotels are more likely to provide room service. They are also more likely to have
electronic keys.
16. Amar Bhidé, The Venturesome Economy: How Innovation Sustains Prosperity in a More Connected World
(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008).
17. Roxana Mihet, “Effects of Culture on Firm Risk-Taking: A Cross-Country and Cross-Industry Analysis”
(working paper, International Monetary Fund, August 2012),
http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12210.pdf .
18 Merritt Roe Smith, Does Technology Drive History? The Dilemma of Technological Determinism
(Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1996).
19 Quoted in Amy Sue Bix, Inventing Ourselves Out of Jobs?: America’s Debate over Technological
Unemployment, 1929-1981 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2000), 166.
20. Ben Miller and Robert D. Atkinson, “Are Robots Taking Our Jobs, or Making Them?” (ITIF,
September 2013), http://www2.itif.org/2013-are-robots-taking-jobs.pdf.
ABOUT ITIF
The Information Technology and Innovation Foundation (ITIF) is a Washington,
D.C.-based think tank at the cutting edge of designing innovation strategies and
technology policies to create economic opportunities and improve quality of life
in the United States and around the world. Founded in 2006, ITIF is a 501(c) 3
nonprofit, non-partisan organization that documents the beneficial role
technology plays in our lives and provides pragmatic ideas for improving
technology-driven productivity, boosting competitiveness, and meeting today’s
global challenges through innovation.