Published Remittanceand Exchangerates
Published Remittanceand Exchangerates
Published Remittanceand Exchangerates
net/publication/354688506
CITATIONS READS
5 237
1 author:
Seyedsoroosh Azizi
Purdue University Northwest
14 PUBLICATIONS 357 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Seyedsoroosh Azizi on 05 October 2021.
SEYEDSOROOSH AZIZI
Purdue University Northwest
Hammond, IN, USA
[email protected]
This study investigates the impacts of workers’ remittances on real exchange rates and net
export by using data for 101 developing countries from 1990 to 2015. One challenge in
addressing the impacts of remittances on real exchange rates is the endogeneity of
remittances. To address the endogeneity of remittances, we estimate bilateral remittances
and use them to create weighted indicators of remittance-sending countries. These weighted
indicators are used as instruments for remittance inflow to remittance-receiving countries.
Results obtained in this study indicate that remittances lead to real exchange rates appre-
ciation and net export reduction in remittance-receiving countries.
Keywords: Migration; remittances; real exchange rates; net export; Dutch disease.
1. Introduction
Between 1990 and 2015, the number of individuals living outside their countries of
birth grew from 153 million people to 244 million people, which corresponds to
2.87% of the world population in the year 1990 and 3.32% of the world population
in the year 2015 (United Nations). The total amount of remittances has risen from
$68 billion in 1990 to $553 billion in 2015. The average amount of money each
migrant remitted (in 2011 constant dollars) has risen from $688 in 1990 to $2,128
in 2015 (the World Bank, United Nations, author’s calculations).
Although remittances helped the remittance-receiving countries in many ways,
namely in the form of poverty and inequality reduction and enhanced human capital
and financial development, there are some undesirable consequences as well. For
example, remittances might reduce labor supply, deteriorate governance and insti-
tution, and appreciate real exchange rate and hence weaken the tradable sector of the
economy in remittance-receiving countries. The focus of this paper is the latter
concern: whether remittances appreciate remittance-receiving currencies and reduce
net export? In order to investigate the impact of remittances on real exchange rates
and net export, we use data for 101 developing countries from 1990 to 2015.
2150006-1
S. Azizi
In the past few years, many researchers have examined the relationship between
remittances, exchange rates, and Dutch disease. Dutch disease is the loss of
competitiveness of the nonresource tradable sector (export sector) due to an
appreciation of the exchange rate after a substantial inflow of resources from one
particular sector (remittances, in the case of this paper). The primary barrier in
investigating this topic is the endogeneity of remittances. Remittances are en-
dogenous to exchange rates. Reverse causality and measurement error are among
the sources of endogeneity.
To address the endogeneity of remittances, this research uses a novel instru-
mental variable (IV) approach by incorporating three economic indicators of the
remittance-sending countries as instruments: per capita Gross National Income
(GNI), unemployment rate, and real interest rate. Since each remittance-receiving
country has many countries as the sources of remittances, building the instruments
requires knowing the bilateral remittances to calculate the weighted average
indicators of the remittance-sending countries. Because bilateral remittances are
not generally available, we estimate them and use them as weights to build the
instruments. This estimation strategy allows utilizing three valid and strong
instruments, which are related to remittance-sending countries, to investigate the
impacts of workers’ remittances on exchange rates and net exports in remittance-
receiving countries. The results obtained in this paper indicate that remittances
appreciate real exchange rates and reduce net exports in remittance-receiving
countries.
The rest of the paper is arranged as follows. The literature review is provided in
Sec. 2. Section 3 discusses the data used in this paper. Section 4 is devoted to the
econometric model. Section 5 discusses the endogeneity problem and instrumental
variables. Section 6 presents empirical results, and Sec. 7 provides conclusions.
2. Literature Review
This surge in the value of remittances has attracted the attention of many
researchers. During recent years, different aspects of remittances have been under
the scrutiny of researchers. Some of the aspects of remittances that have been
investigated vigorously are motivations behind remittances (El-Sakka and
McNabb, 1999; Carling, 2008; Azizi, 2017, 2019, 2021); remittances and uncer-
tainty (Khanal and Todorova, 2019); remittances and human capital as most
researchers have found remittances increase human capital in remittance-receiving
countries (Calero et al., 2009; Azizi, 2018; Howard and Stanley, 2017); remit-
tances and poverty as most researchers have found remittances reduce poverty in
remittance-receiving countries (Adams and Page, 2005; Azizi, 2019, 2021);
remittances and inequality (Giannetti et al., 2009) remittances and growth (Konte,
2150006-2
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
2150006-3
S. Azizi
disease effect. They also investigate the short-run relationship between remittances
and exchange rates using a panel vector error correction model and confirm that
remittances appreciate exchange rates.
Although almost all studies have found that remittances appreciate real ex-
change rates in remittance-receiving countries, the following studies concluded that
real exchange rates appreciation only happens in some countries.
Barajas et al. (2011) find regional differences in the impacts of remittances on
real exchange rates. The Middle East–North African countries are most likely to
experience the conventional upward effect of rising remittance inflows on the real
exchange rate, and Asian countries less likely to do so. Beja Jr (2011) finds that
Dutch disease caused by international remittances afflicts the middle-income
countries but not the upper income and low-income countries. Alonso Gonzalez
and Sovilla (2014) find that remittances cause the Dutch disease and they propose
demand policies combined with central bank purchases of foreign currency in the
foreign exchange market to neutralize the negative impact of remittances on ex-
change rates.
Many studies have addressed the impacts of remittances on real exchange rates
and exports in a single country. All of these studies have concluded that remit-
tances cause real exchange rates appreciation in the remittance-receiving country.
We review some of these studies.
Using data for the Philippines, Mandelman (2013) estimates a general equi-
librium model for a small open economy and concludes the equilibrium level of the
real exchange rate appreciates upon a steady increase (trend growth) in remittances.
Sapkota (2013) investigates impacts of remittances on Nepal’s economy and
concludes although, remittances have reduced poverty and inequality, however,
remittances have also contributed to the Dutch disease effect and real exchange rate
appreciation. Using Bayesian methods and Salvadorian data, Acosta et al. (2009b)
develop and estimate a general equilibrium model of a small open economy and
conclude that an increase in remittances causes Dutch disease effects. Bourdet and
Falck (2006) find that the inflow of remittances to Cape Verde has an appreciating
effect on the real exchange rate and contributes to deteriorated competitiveness.
Makhlouf and Mughal (2013) focus on Pakistan and conclude that while aggregate
remittances and the remittances from the Persian Gulf contribute to the Dutch
disease in Pakistan, those from North America and Europe do not. Vargas-Silva
(2009) finds that remittances appreciate the Mexican peso and therefore, may
impact the competitiveness of the tradable sector negatively. Using Johansen
Cointegration and Vector Error Correction Model and annual data from 1971 to
2008, Chowdhury and Rabbi (2014) conclude that the influx of remittances sig-
nificantly appreciates the real exchange rate and deteriorates the external trade
competitiveness of Bangladesh.
2150006-4
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
3. Data
This study examines 101 developing (poor and middle-income) countries.1 The
annual data has a time span of 1990 to 2015. All dollar values in this paper are
constant 2011 US dollars.
Data on remittances come from the International Monetary Fund (IMF), which
has defined remittances as the sum of two components: personal transfers
(workers’ remittances) and compensation of employees. The World Bank has
adopted the same definition. In this study, we only focus on workers’ remittances.
Remittances are divided by remittance-receiving countries’ populations and con-
verted in constant 2011 US dollars. The income variable in Eq. (1) is per capita
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in constant 2011 US dollars adjusted for pur-
chasing power parity (PPP).
In this paper, we investigate the impacts of remittances on real exchange rates
and net export. Real exchange rate is defined as exchange rates adjusted for in-
flation. Net export is defined as export minus import. This study uses three
2150006-5
S. Azizi
4. Econometric Model
We use a panel of 101 developing countries to analyze how workers’ remittances
affect real exchange rates and net export. The relationship that we estimate can be
written as
Eit ¼ β0 þ β1 Rit þ β2 Iit þ X it0 γ þ δi þ eit ð1Þ
for i ¼ 1, . . . , N and t ¼ 1, . . . , Ti where E is real exchange rate or net export in
country i at time t, β0 is the intercept, Rit is the per capita remittances received by
country i at year t, Iit is the mean per capita income of country i at year t, Xit is a
vector of other variables that potentially affect Eit . More specifically, Xit includes
the ratio of broad money to GDP, the ratio of government expenditures to GDP, and
the ratio of trade openness (defined as sum of export and import) to GDP. δi is
country dummy and eit is the error term. All variables, except net export, are in
logarithm.
When Eit is the real exchange rate for country i at time t, it is defined as
PUS, t
Eit ¼ eit , ð2Þ
Pit
where eit and pit are the nominal exchange rates (units of home country currency
per US dollar: e.g. 10 pesos/dollar) and the Price Index of country i at year t,
2150006-6
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
2150006-7
S. Azizi
Notes: The dependent variable in the first stage regression is per capita remittances.
***Significant at 1% level.
**Significant at 5% level.
*Significant at 10% level.
positive, the parameter estimates for the impact of unemployment rate and real
interest rates in remittance-sending countries on remittances are significant and
negative.
The IMF provides workers’ remittances data annually. Unfortunately, the
IMF does not provide bilateral remittance data. Bilateral remittance means how
much money a remittance-receiving country receives from each specific re-
mittance-sending country. Therefore, although we know how much remittance
each remittance-receiving country receives in any year in total, we do not know
how much of the received remittances comes from a specific remittance-sending
country.
The main challenge in constructing instruments is that each remittance-
receiving country has more than one remittance-sending country. Therefore, rather
than per capita GNI, unemployment rate, and real interest rate in the remittance-
sending country, weighted average of the remittance-sending countries’ indicators
should be used as instruments. For remittance-receiving country i, in year t, the
2150006-8
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
2 Ratha and Shaw (2007) propose a method of “Calculating weights based on migrant stocks, per capita income in
the destination countries, and per capita income in the source countries”.
The average remittance sent by a migrant from host country j to home country i (rij ) is modeled as a function of the
per capita income of the home country and the host country.
(
Yi if Yj < Y i ,
rij ¼ f (Y i Yj ) ¼
Y i þ (Yj Y i ) β otherwise,
where Yj is the average per capita GNI of host country j, Y i is the per capita GNI of the migrant’s home country,
and β is a parameter between 0 and 1. The amount sent by an average migrant is assumed to be at least as much as
the per capita income of the home country, even when the individual migrates to a lower-income country. The
rationale is that the migration occurs in the expectation of earning a higher level of income for the dependent
household than what the migrant would earn in her home country. To estimate bilateral remittances for all
countries, they use the average β (equal to 0.75) for the top 20 remittance-receiving countries. Then, for each home
country i, rij is used to build weights for each host country j as
rij Mij
Wij ¼ P 214 :
j¼1 rij Mij
2150006-9
S. Azizi
where Y it is one of the following variables: weighted average per capita GNI,
unemployment rate, and real interest rate of the remittance-sending countries. wjit
is the weight as defined by Eq. (2) and Yjt is one of the following: per capita
GNI, unemployment rate, or real interest rate of the remittance-sending country j
at year t.
Two main concerns of using instrumental variables method, to address the
problem of endogeneity, are validity and strength of the instruments. The reason
that in this paper bilateral remittances are estimated, and economic variables re-
lated to remittance-sending countries are used is to guarantee the validity of the
instruments. More specifically, selecting economic variables from remittance-
sending countries, rather than from remittance-receiving countries, as instruments
is to ensure the validity of instruments. The other concern about the instruments is
whether they are strong or not. The whole process of estimating bilateral remit-
tances and use them as the weights of remittance-sending countries is to ensure that
instruments are strong. To investigate the strength of the instruments, first stage
regressions are examined. The results of the first stage regressions are provided in
Table 2. Note that F-statistics for weak instruments is 78, which indicates the
instruments are very strong.
6. Results
In all regressions, the results of the IV approach are reported alongside the results
of the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) model and Fixed Effect (FE) model. FE and
OLS models are similar in all aspects except one. Unlike the OLS model, the FE
model includes country-specific effects and addresses time-invariant cross-country
effects. However, both OLS and FE results are inconsistent and biased. They are
presented in this paper for comparison purposes. To address both endogeneity and
time-invariant cross-country effects simultaneously, all IV estimates also include
country-specific effects. The estimates for the impacts of remittances on real ex-
change rates are presented in Table 3.
In the first regression (columns (1a), (1b), and (1c)), the ratio of broad money to
GDP, the ratio of government expenditures to GDP, and the ratio of trade openness
(defined as sum of export and import) to GDP are used as explanatory variables
alongside per capita remittances and per capita GDP. The control variables are
some of the most common variables in the literature. For example, look at Lartey
et al. (2012). Both OLS and FE models underestimate the impacts of remittances
on real exchange rates and the effect captured by the IV is larger (in magnitude)
than the effects captured by the OLS or the FE. The results of IV regression
suggest that, on average, a 10% increase in per capita remittances will lead to a
1.4% appreciation in real exchange rates. In OLS model the R-squared is 0.19 but
2150006-10
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
Notes: HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include country dummies.
***Significant at 1% level.
**Significant at 5% level.
*Significant at 10% level.
in FE and IV-FE models R-squared is 0.94. This means country-specific effects can
explain 75% of changes in real exchange rates and by far is the most important
factor.
Since the ratio of government expenditures to GDP per capita is not significant
in the first regression, we dropped it from the regression. In the second regression
(columns (2a), (2b), and (2c)), assuming that estimates from the IV model are
closest to the true values of parameters, both OLS and FE models underestimate
the magnitude impacts of remittances on real exchange rates. Once again, the
results of IV regression provided in column (2c) suggest that remittances cause
currency appreciation.
The fact that the parameter estimates for remittances are negative and statisti-
cally significant across both regressions and three models (OLS, FE, and IV-FE)
shows that the results are robust and we can conclude that a rise in remittances will
cause a currency appreciation in remittance-receiving countries. The estimates for
the impacts of remittances on net export are presented in Table 4.
The same explanatory variables are used in Tables 3 and 4. After instrumenting
for the endogeneity of remittances and controlling for country-fixed effects, results
provided in columns (1c) and (2c) of Table 4 indicate that remittances reduce the
net export of remittance-receiving countries. However, note that all explanatory
2150006-11
S. Azizi
Notes: HAC standard errors are in parentheses. FE and IV models include country dummies.
***Significant at 1% level.
**Significant at 5% level.
*Significant at 10% level.
variables are in logarithm but net export is not used in logarithm (since for many
countries net export is negative, we did not use the logarithm). Therefore, based on
column (2c) of Table 4 a 100% increase in remittance per capita leads to 4%
decrease in net exports. The negative and statistically significant parameter esti-
mates for remittances across both regressions and three models indicate that the
results are robust and we can conclude that a rise in remittances will cause a fall in
net export in remittance-receiving countries.
7. Conclusion
The total amount of remittances has risen from $68 billion in 1990 to $553 billion
in 2015. Although receiving remittances help many developing countries to reduce
poverty and increase human capital and financial development, remittances might
damage remittance-receiving countries as well. This paper investigates the impacts
of workers’ remittances on real exchange rates and net export. The dataset that is
used in this paper includes 101 developing countries from 1990 to 2015.
One challenge in addressing the impacts of remittances on real exchange rates is
the endogeneity of remittances. Not only remittances impact real exchange rates,
but also migrants might increase or decrease the amount of money that they remit
in response to rise or fall in exchange rates. To address the endogeneity of
2150006-12
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
2150006-13
S. Azizi
and they will boost production and export in the long run. However, channeling
remittances toward investment and encouraging migrants and their families to not
spend their money on consumption might be hard or impossible if they are in
immediate need of remittances and in case that survival of the families depends on
remittances.
Appendix A
2150006-14
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
References
Acosta, PA, NR Baerg and FS Mandelman (2009a). Financial development, remittances,
and real exchange rate appreciation. Economic Review, 94, 1–12.
Acosta, PA, EK Lartey and FS Mandelman (2009b). Remittances and the Dutch disease.
Journal of International Economics, 79(1), 102–116.
Adams Jr RH and J Page (2005). Do international migration and remittances reduce
poverty in developing countries? World Development, 33(10), 1645–1669.
Adeniyi, O, K Ajide and ID Raheem (2019). Remittances and output growth volatility in
developing countries: Does financial development dampen or magnify the effects?
Empirical Economics, 56(3), 865–882.
Airola, J (2008). Labor supply in response to remittance income: The case of Mexico. The
Journal of Developing Areas, 41, 69–78.
Alonso Gonzalez, LA and B Sovilla (2014). A Kaleckian model for understanding and
responding to the economic policy challenges of remittances. International Review of
Applied Economics, 28(6), 832–848.
Amuedo-Dorantes, C and S Pozo (2004). Workers’ remittances and the real exchange rate:
A paradox of gifts. World Development, 32(8), 1407–1417.
Azizi, S (2017). Altruism: Primary motivation of remittances. Applied Economics Letters,
24(17), 1218–1221.
Azizi, S (2018). The impacts of workers’ remittances on human capital and labor supply in
developing countries. Economic Modelling, 75, 377–396.
Azizi, S (2019). Why do migrants remit? The World Economy, 42(2), 429–452.
Azizi, S (2020). Impacts of remittances on financial development. Journal of Economic
Studies, 47(3), 467–477.
Azizi, S (2021). The impacts of workers’ remittances on poverty and inequality in de-
veloping countries. Empirical Economics, 60(2), 969–991.
Ball, CP, C Lopez and J Reyes (2013). Remittances, inflation and exchange rate regimes in
small open economies. The World Economy, 36(4), 487–507.
Barajas, A, R Chami, D Hakura, P Montiel and T Tressel (2011). Workers’ remittances and
the equilibrium real exchange rate: Theory and evidence [with comment]. Economia, 11
(2), 45–99.
Beja, Jr., EL (2011). Do international remittances cause Dutch disease? Migration Letters,
8(2), 132–140.
Bettin, G and A Zazzaro (2012). Remittances and financial development: Substitutes or
complements in economic growth? Bulletin of Economic Research, 64(4), 509–536.
Bourdet, Y and H Falck (2006). Emigrants’ remittances and Dutch disease in Cape Verde.
International Economic Journal, 20(3), 267–284.
2150006-15
S. Azizi
Calero, C, AS Bedi and R Sparrow (2009). Remittances, liquidity constraints and human
capital investments in Ecuador. World Development, 37(6), 1143–1154.
Carling, J (2008). The determinants of migrant remittances. Oxford Review of Economic
Policy, 24(3), 581–598.
Chowdhury, MB and F Rabbi (2014). Workers’ remittances and Dutch disease in Ban-
gladesh. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 23(4), 455–475.
Correia, L and P Martins (2019). Has the sovereign debt crisis changed the cyclicality of
Portuguese remittances? International Review of Applied Economics, 33(3), 453–472.
Deonanan, R, B Ramkissoon, D Ramkissoon and R Hosein (2020). Disentangling the
relationship between remittances and financial development: Evidence from Jamaica.
International Review of Applied Economics, 34(2), 193–216.
El-Sakka, MI and R McNabb (1999). The macroeconomic determinants of emigrant
remittances. World Development, 27(8), 1493–1502.
Faini, R (1994). Workers remittances and the real exchange rate. Journal of Population
Economics, 7(2), 235–245.
Freund, C and N Spatafora (2008). Remittances, transaction costs, and informality. Journal
of Development Economics, 86(2), 356–366.
Giannetti, M, D Federici and M Raitano (2009). Migrant remittances and inequality in
Central–Eastern Europe. International Review of Applied Economics, 23(3), 289–307.
Hassan, GM and MJ Holmes (2013). Remittances and the real effective exchange rate.
Applied Economics, 45(35), 4959–4970.
Howard, LL and DL Stanley (2017). Remittances channels and the physical growth of
Honduran children. International Review of Applied Economics, 31(3), 376–397.
Kakhkharov, J and N Rohde (2018). Remittances and financial development in transition
economies. Empirical Economics, 1–33.
Khanal, K and Z Todorova (2019). Remittances and households in the age of neoliberal
uncertainty. Journal of Economic Issues, 53(2), 515–522.
Konte, M (2018). Do remittances not promote growth? A finite mixture-of-regressions
approach. Empirical Economics, 54(2), 747–782.
Lartey, EK, FS Mandelman and PA Acosta (2012). Remittances, exchange rate regimes and the
Dutch disease: A panel data analysis. Review of International Economics, 20(2), 377–395.
Lopez, H, M Bussolo and L Molina (2007). Remittances and the real exchange rate. World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 4213.
Makhlouf, F and MY Mughal (2013). Remittances, Dutch disease, and competitiveness:
A Bayesian analysis. Journal of Economic Development, 38(2), 67–97.
Mandelman, FS (2013). Monetary and exchange rate policy under remittance fluctuations.
Journal of Development Economics, 102, 128–147.
Mughal, M and F Makhlouf (2013). Labour effects of foreign and domestic remittances–
evidence from Pakistan. International Review of Applied Economics, 27(6), 798–821.
Ratha D and Shaw W (2007). South-South migration and remittances. World Bank Pub-
lications (No. 102).
Sapkota, C (2013). Remittances in Nepal: Boon or bane? The Journal of Development
Studies, 49(10), 1316–1331.
2150006-16
Impacts of Remittances on Exchange Rates
Vargas-Silva, C (2009). The tale of three amigos: Remittances, exchange rates, and money
demand in Mexico. Review of Development Economics, 13(1), 1–14.
Yang, D (2008). International migration, remittances and household investment: Evidence
from Philippine migrants’ exchange rate shocks. The Economic Journal, 118(528), 591–
630.
2150006-17
Copyright of Global Economy Journal is the property of World Scientific Publishing
Company and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv
without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print,
download, or email articles for individual use.