S332A315FR en
S332A315FR en
S332A315FR en
AND
THE REAL ECONOMY
ISSUES AND CASE STUDIES
IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES
editors:
Yilm az Akyüz
Giinther Held
Inscription N9 88.481
Printed in Chile
INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................. 11
Yilmaz Akyüz
Giinther Held
Introduction 13
relation between the two. Financial liberalization often gives rise to deepening,
but the latter is not always associated with a better use of resources since,
inter alia, it tends to increase financial instability and fragility which, in
turn, underminebothproductive and allocative efficiency. Prudentialregulations,
while necessary, may not always be sufficient to prevent instability, particularly
in developing countries, where financial liberalization often leads to escalation
of interest rates and excessive risk taking. It may be necessary not only
to act directly on the asset portfolios of banks but also to use interest
ceilings. Efficiency also depends on the way finance is organized, since
it influences the degree of risk, uncertainty and instability. The German-
Japanese system of bank-based finance tends to be more stable and efficient
than the Anglo-American system of capital-market-based finance, provided
that the required fiscal and monetary discipline and prudential regulations
are in place. Financial instability may be increased, and efficiency reduced,
also by excessive financial openness. The speculative element that dominates
international capital flows is capable of generating gyrations in exchange
rates, giving rise to considerable uncertainty regarding prospective investment
yields with respect of traded goods. This can be particularly damaging at
a time when developing countries place greater reliance on trade as an
engine of growth.
Amsden discusses the rationale for government intervention in financial
markets in late industrializers and the factors that account for successful
intervention in the Republic of Korea and Taiwan Province of China. Challenging
the conventional wisdom that latecomers industrialize by "getting prices
right" on the basis of low wages that procure them a comparative advantage
in labor-intensive industries, she argues that low productivity even in such
industries cannot always be offset by low wages because of political and
social constraints. Nor does foreign capital help to overcome the productivity
drawback: foreign capital typically lags behind, rather than leads, industrial
development. Thus, late industrialization involves a process of using subsidies
to "get prices wrong" so as to overcome the productivity handicap. What
distinguishes the countries that are successfully "sneaking up" to the world
technological frontier from those that are "stumbling back" or "staying behind"
is not less State intervention but rather a different set of principles governing
subsidy allocation. While subsidies in the slow-growing late industrializers
have tended to be allocated according to the principle of "giveaway", in
Introduction 15
can work efficiently provided that there are adequate linkages, but these
are missing in SSA. Liberalization per se cannot overcome the impediments
to mobilization of resources arising from market segmentation; nor is the
capital market a panacea. More active policies would be needed to ease
the constraints facing banks in financial intermediation and to reduce financial
dualism.
Hanna begins by examining the theoretical links between finance, savings
and economic growth. He then focuses on the financial and real effects
of the financial reforms in Indonesia, which began with the removal of
ceilings on interest rates and credit expansion, followed by the lowering
of barriers to entry and the reduction of the direct role of the Central
Bank in credit allocation. Liberalization led to a large and sustained increase
in financial depth and breadth in the economy. Econometric work on real
private savings shows that they were not hampered by increases in financial
savings, independently of effects stemming from higher income, lower inflation
and real interest rates. The maturity of bank loans also extended over the
period of the reforms, better meshing with the investment needs of the
economy. Cost efficiency improved as well, with a reduction in overheads;
spreads between deposit and lending rates came down at all banks and
m oved closer to each other at different types of banks. However, given
the difficulties in allocating credit because of informational and incentive
problems, efficiency gains were more elusive. The author concludes that
financial reforms have been successful in Indonesia despite several factors
that differ from the standard prescription. First, the capital account was
open at the time of reforms, and second, reform began at a time of important
macroeconomic adjustment.
Uthoff examines the role of financial markets and pension funds
management, and their regulation and supervision, in the context of current
pension-system reforms in Latin American and Caribbean countries. Reforms
today seek to achieve better pension benefits without generating financial
and actuarial deficits, higher returns from portfolio investment of pension
funds, and increased savings and the development of capital markets. Pension-
system reforms require taking basic decisions regarding (i) the structure
of financing (ii) the structure of administration; and (iii) the relation between
contributions and benefits. One major concern of every reform taking place
in the region has been the proper protection and capitalization of reserve
Introduction 17
pension funds. One of the reforms which has attracted wide attention was
implemented in Chile in the early 1980s. It replaced a pay-as-you-go and
publically-administered system with one based on individual capitalization,
predefined contributions and benefits and private administration of funds.
The author emphasizes the following aspects with a view to providing good
pension benefits: (i) the role of the State in closely regulating and supervising
the portfolio allocation of pension funds, and in the provision of clear,
timely and simple information to affiliates regarding their individual accounts;
(ii) an efficient administration of reserve funds geared capitalizing them
at real annual rates of return of at least 5 per cent on average, based
on contributions equal to 10 per cent of a person's lifetime earnings profile;
(iii) the preclusion of oligopolistic behavior on the part of pension-funds,
and (iv) the provision of subsidies for participants unable to obtain minimum
pension benefits on the basis of their own contributions. The system's success
also depends on fiscal and monetary discipline.
Held looks at the outcome of different financial-policy experiences in
Latin American and Caribbean countries in the last two decades on the
basis of institutional arrangements of bank regulation and supervision. He
argues that the emergence of bank solvency problems in a sample of nine
countries in the region shares the common condition of severe flaws in
prudential regulation and supervision. These flaws have quite commonly
led to financial crises under financial liberalization, but they have also
engendered solvency problems under financial repression. Since prudential
regulation and supervision were not in place while credit allocation, interest
rates and other financial variables were liberalized, these experiences could
be better described as uncontrolled financial policies rather than financial
liberalization. In many of the countries studied, highly unstable macroeconomic
conditions were also responsible for severe solvency problems. The author
concludes that of the countries in the sample, only the Chilean and perhaps
the Costa-Rican experiences after the mid-1980s may be regarded as a fair
testing ground for the effects of financial liberalization on savings and exports.
Yilmaz A kyiiz
Giinther Held
Yilmaz Akyüz1
1 I have greatly benefited from comments and suggestions made by various people, including
the participants of a workshop on Financial Globalization and Systemic Risk at the Center
on International Economic Relations, University of Campinas, Sao Paulo, 15-16 June 1992;
the participants of an ECLAC/UNU-WIDER/UNCTAD seminar on Savings and Financial
Policy Issues in African, Asian, Latin American and Caribbean Countries, ECLAC, Santiago,
5-6 October 1992, particularly Carlos Massad and Gunther Held; and my colleagues in
UNCTAD, Shahen Abrahamian, Andrew Comford, Detlef Kotte and Cem Somel. The
examination of financial efficiency in terms of various concepts of risk in section 5 owes a
great deal to discussions with Jan Kregel. None of the persons mentioned are, of course,
responsible for any errors. The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect
the views of UNCTAD, and the designations and terminology used are those of the author.
CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION .............................................................................................. 23
VIII. CONCLUSIONS.................................................................................................. 60
REFERENCES............................................................................................................... 63
Financial liberalization: the key issues 23
INTRODUCTION
One o f the most contentious issues in financial policy is the effect o f interest
rates on savings. There can be little doubt that short-term, temporary swings
in interest rates have little effect on private savings behaviour since that
is largely governed by expectations and plans regarding current and future
incomes and expenditures: they alter the level of savings primarily by affect
ing the levels of investment and income. However, when there is a rise
in interest rates that is expected to be permanent (for instance, because
it is the result of a change in the underlying philosophy in the determination
of interest rates), will consumer behaviour remain the same, or will the
propensity to save rise? The orthodox theory expects the latter to occur,
and thus argues that removing "financial repression" will have a strong,
positive effect on savings (Shaw, 1973, p. 73).
Empirical studies of savings behaviour typically do not distinguish
permanent from temporary changes in interest rates. Recent evidence on
savings behaviour in a number of developing countries that changed their
interest-rate policy regimes shows no simple relation between interest rates
and private savings. This is true for a wide range of countries in Asia
and the Middle East (Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Sri Lanka, Republic
of Korea and Turkey -Cho and Khatkhate, 1989; Amsden and Euh, 1990;
Lim, 1991; Akyüz, 1990), Africa (Ghana, Kenya, Malawi, United Republic
of Tanzania and Zambia- Nissanke, 1990), and Latin America (Massad and
Eyzaguirre, 1990) that undertook financial liberalization, albeit to different
Financial liberalization: the key issues 25
ratio rose in the 1980s in the United States -something which is at the
heart of the current debt-deflation process (UNCTAD 1991, part two, chaps.
I-II; 1992, part two, chap. E). An inverse correlation between household
borrowing and savings ratios has also been observed in most other OECD
countries since the early and mid-1980s (Blundell-Wignall and Browne, 1991).
• Even if financial liberalization and higher interest rates do not lower
personal savings, they can reduce total private savings and aggregate domes
tic savings by redistributing income away from debtors -a category which
typically includes corporations and the government. In many developing
countries undistributed corporate profits are an important part of private
savings and the most important source of business investment. Generally,
the savings rate is higher than for households: corporate retentions are high,
ranging between 60 to 80 per cent of after-tax profits, because ownership
is usually concentrated in the hands of families and there is no outside
pressure to pay out dividends (Honohan and Atiyas, 1989; Akyüz, 1991).
The redistribution of income from corporations to households through higher
interest rates can thus reduce total private savings even if it raises household
savings. In developing countries this effect can be particularly strong because
firms operate with high leverage, loan maturities are short and corporate
debt usually carries variable rates. Thus, a rise in interest rates not only
raises the cost of new borrowing but also the cost of servicing existing
debt. Evidence from the studies already mentioned suggests that in a num
ber of countries (e.g. Philippines, Turkey, Yugoslavia), sharp increases in
interest rates were a major factor in the collapse of corporate profits and
savings that took place particularly in the early phases of financial libera
lization.
Such adverse effects are especially marked when interest rates are freed
under rapid inflation. There is widespread agreement that financial liberali
zation undertaken in an unstable environment may make things worse, and
that such reforms should be undertaken only after macroeconomic balances
are attained (World Bank 1989; Edwards, 1989). Nevertheless, many countries
have resorted to liberalization as part of shock therapy against stagflation.
Thus, interest rate increases are not a reliable instrument for raising
domestic savings, but can damage macroeconomic stability and investment.
The crucial question is how to design interest rate policies compatible with
sustained stability and growth.
Financial liberalization: the key issues 27
corporate sector and the government) save as well as invest, while surplus
sectors (households) invest as well as save. Thus, redistribution of savings
and investment among sectors can, by changing sectoral surpluses and defi
cits, result in financial deepening without any change in aggregate savings
and investment - for instance, as already noted, when higher interest rates
redistribute income and savings from debtors to creditors. Even when this
does not alter the volume o f aggregate savings (i.e. lower savings of debtors
are compensated by higher savings of creditors), it increases deficits and
surpluses and, hence, the amount of financial intermediation. Indeed, finan
cial intermediation can increase while aggregate savings and investment
fall (Akyüz, 1991). This can happen even under the orthodox assumptions
that saving rates are positively related to the interest rate and that savings
determine investment and growth (Molho, 1986, p. 112).
In such cases financial deepening is a symptom of a deterioration
of the finances of the corporate and public sectors, reflecting an accumula
tion of debt in order to finance the increased interest bill rather than new
investment. Financial deepening driven by such Ponzi financing has been
observed in a number of countries (e.g. Turkey, Yugoslavia and New Zea
land) where financial liberalization redistributed income in favour of cre
ditors and encouraged distress borrowing.
Similarly financial deepening can be the result of a redistribution of
a given volume of aggregate investment, when, for instance, higher inte
rest rates induce households to reduce investment in housing and shift
to bank deposits. Then, the increase in the household surplus and in the
volume of deposits represents a decline in household investment, not a
rise in savings.
Financial liberalization often raises holdings of both financial assets
and liabilities by firms and individuals at any given level of income, investment
and savings. This tendency to borrow in order to purchase assets is driven
by the increased scope for capital gains generated by financial liberaliza
tion. Liberalization increases the instability of interest rates and asset prices,
thereby raising prospects for quick profits through speculation on changes
in the market valuation of financial assets. It also allows greater freedom
for banks and other financial institutions to lend to finance activities unrela
ted to production and investment, and to firms and individuals to issue
debt in order to finance speculation. These can generate considerable fi-
F inancial liberalization: the key issues 29
nandal activity unrelated to the real economy, and lead to financial dee
pening -as in the United States in recent years through leverage takeovers,
mergers, acquisitions and so on (UNCTAD, 1992, part two, chap. II).
Deepening can also result from the impact of changes in interest rates
on the form in which savings are held. Indeed, one of the main reasons
why savings do not in practice strongly respond to increases in real interest
rates is the existence of a range of assets with different degrees of protection
against inflation; returns on such assets also influence savings decisions.
The greater the influence of interest rates on the allocation of savings among
alternative assets, the smaller the influence on the volume of savings.
Whether shifts of savings into financial assets improve the use of resour
ces depends on where they come from and how efficiently the financial
system is operating. Clearly, a switch from commodity holdings can improve
the use to which savings are put. But, contrary to widespread perception,
there is very little evidence of extensive commodity holding in developing
countries as a form of savings. Such holdings entail substantial storage and
transaction costs, making their own real rate of return typically negative.
Moreover, there is considerable uncertainty regarding the movement of pri
ces of individual commodities even when the general price level is rising
rapidly. These factors, together with the existence of more liquid, less costly
inflation hedges (such as foreign currency or gold) reduce the demand for
commodities as a store of value. The large commodity holdings that exist
in African countries typically reflect the nature of production and non
monetization of the rural economy. Consequently, increases in deposit rates
are often unable to induce liquidation of commodity stocks (Aryeetey et
al., 1990; Mwega, 1990; Nissanke, 1990).
An increase in domestic interest rates can induce a shift from foreign
currency holdings to domestic assets, and repatriation of flight capital. Many
governments, however, have found it necessary to legalize foreign currency
holdings and introduce foreign currency deposits for residents and to offer
very high interest rates in order to attract foreign currency holdings to
the banking system. Certainly, in both cases the portfolio shifts can increase
the resources available for investment and deepen finance. However, as
discussed in section VII, capital flows and dollarization resulting from such
policies often prove troublesome for macroeconomic stability, investment
and competitiveness.
30 Y ilmaz A kyüz
Freeing interest rates in the formal sector can also trigger a shift away
from informal markets. However, the scope of such shifts may be limited
since the reason for informal markets is not always interest rate controls
and credit rationing. They often provide services to small and medium pro
ducers w ho do not have access to bank credits. Since financial liberalization
does not always improve their access to banks, informal markets continue
to operate after the deregulation of interest rates. As savings placed in
the informal sector assure these producers some access to credit, they are
not always willing to shift to banks when deposit rates are raised (Chipeta,
1990; Aryeteey et al., 1990; Mwega, 1990). On the other hand, when funds
are shifted to banks, the cost of finance for informal market borrowers
can rise considerably. Moreover, such shifts can result in financial "sha
llowing" because informal markets provide more financial intermediation
due to the absence of liquidity and reserve requirements (Wijnbergen, 1983;
Owen and Solis-Fallas, 1989).
It can thus be concluded that financial deepening brought about by
liberalization is not necessarily associated with a higher level a n d /or better
use of savings. Indeed, the empirical evidence does not support the claim
that financial deepening is associated with faster growth (Dombusch and
Reynoso, 1989). The degree of financial deepening is therefore not a good
measure of the contribution of finance to growth and development.
The relevant issue in financial reform is efficiency rather than deepen
ing. There are various concepts of efficiency of financial markets and insti
tutions (Tobin, 1984), but from the point of view of the role of finance
in economic growth and development, the conventional notions of allo
cative and productive (i.e. cost) efficiency are the most relevant ones.
1. Market failure
2. Successful intervention
3. Measuring efficiency
(e.g. the Southern Cone countries, Indonesia, the Philippines, Turkey and
Yugoslavia) indicates that deregulation of interest rates and elimination of
restrictions on financial activities have almost always been followed by in
creases in the proportion of non-performing loans in bank portfolios and
in bank failures. Again, resort to liberalization to cure instability and stagna
tion has often played an important role. These, together with external shocks,
had already greatly weakened the balance sheets of the corporate sector
and financial institutions. Deregulation of interest rates, often accompanied
by monetary tightening, further disrupted the financial position of the highly-
leveraged corporate sector, leading to increased loan default rates and even
tually to bank failures.
the borrower. Second, there is the risk of involuntary default arising from
imperfect foresight, i.e. from uncertainties over factors outside the control
of the borrower which affect profitability. This risk, called the borrower's
risk or the pure risk, is inherent in all investment decisions and cannot
be eliminated. However, it can be reduced by access of the borrower to
better information and stabler economic conditions. The pure risk is closely
related to allocative efficiency. When finance is not efficiently allocated, the
probability of involuntary default increases. This raises the lender's risk and
the cost of finance: allocative inefficiency thus aggravates cost inefficiency.
The lender also runs a risk regarding the capital value of his assets
due to uncertainties over future interest rates and asset prices (as well as
the price level). The capital-value uncertainty increases with the volatility
of asset prices and interest rates, as well as with the increased frequency
of bank failures. These raise liquidity preference and lower the demand
for capital-uncertain assets, thereby shortening the maturities of financial
assets and pushing up interest rates, especially long-term. The degree of
productive efficiency of the financial system therefore depends in part on
its ability to attain stability and reduce capital-value uncertainty.
The search for greater allocative efficiency through financial libera
lization can greatly reduce the productive efficiency of the financial system
by giving rise to increased financial instability and raising the cost of finan
ce to investors. This is a systemic influence, quite independent of any rise
in interest rates that may result from eliminating ceilings. Indeed, the fi
nancial instability and bank failures stemming from financial liberalization
in the major industrial countries, especially the United States, in the 1980s
played a major role in considerably raising long-term interest rates and
reducing their sensitivity to changes in short-term rates (Akyüz, 1992, pp.
59-60).
2. Intermediation margin
1. Risk-taking by banks
16). Since higher interest rates tend to reduce the average quality of loans
through adverse selection (lending to high-risk borrowers willing to pay
high interest rates) and moral hazard (inducing "good" borrowers to invest
in riskier projects), the expected rate of return net of default will decline
once the loan rate has reached a certain level. This implies that even in
the absence of prudential regulations, there will be limits to price compe
tition and risk-taking in the banking sector.
However, self-restraint cannot always be relied on to prevent financial
instability, particularly in developing countries. Banks tend to engage in
speculative financing and excessive risk-taking provided that failure does
not have serious consequences for their shareholders and managers. This
happens when they can easily acquire deposit insurance, enjoy implicit or
explicit guarantees for bail-out and have easy access to the lender-of-last-
resort facility, and when sanctions and penalties for failing bank managers
are inadequate. This is often the case in developing countries where govern
ments are often all too ready to rescue banks in trouble. The moral hazard
that results is made worse by the existence of deposit insurance schemes
designed to give protection to depositors and attract funds into banks. Banks
often have to pay very little for the insurance coverage while having all
the incentives to raise deposit rates tomobilize funds to invest in high-
return, high-risk, and often speculative projects.
Furthermore, in developing countries large non-finandal corporations
are often able to exert strong influence over banks, causing bank lending
to be concentrated on a small number of firms, at the cost of increasing
their own vulnerability. Corporate distress borrowing and Ponzi financing
tend to be much more common in developing countries, and these become
particularly visible and problematic during episodes of financial .liberali
zation. The intense competition that banks in many developing countries
face from unregulated financial markets can also lead to higher interest
rates and greater risk-taking.
2. Prudential regulations
Evidence from both developed and developing countries shows that a ju
dicious combination of effective prudential and protective regulations is
necessary to prevent financial instability. In many developing countries,
F inancial liberalization: the key issues 39
with the collapse of the S&Ls with an estimated cost of about $200 billion,
and was replaced by the debt-deflation process already mentioned.
Stricter capital adequacy requirements of the type recently introduced
by BIS (UNCTAD, 1992, part two, Annex I) could have helped to slow
down this process but would probably not have prevented it. As there
was simultaneously a speculative bubble in the stock-market, banks would
have had no difficulty in raising capital on very favourable terms to cover
their high-risk investment, but would have remained exposed to risks on
both sides of their balance sheets. Indeed, this is exactly what happened
in Japan where banks can account as capital almost half of accrued but
unrealized capital gains on equities and use them to offset potential loan
losses. As the stock-market was rising rapidly in the 1980s, banks counted
on these gains instead of setting aside reserves against potential losses on
high-risk, property-related lending. The subsequent decline in stock prices,
together with the fall in property prices, thus created difficulties for banks
from both sides of their balance sheets.
There are also other instances of boom and bust where rapid expan
sion of some banks through high-risk, high-return lending increased their
stock prices sharply and allowed them to raise capital at costs lower than
the prudent banks. "In such cases neither public scrutiny of bank balan
ce sheets, nor capital ratios would have prevented the propagation of the
crisis" (Kregel, 1993, p. 10).
3. Interest ceilings
growth period" (Kato et al., 1993, p. 122), and have not yet been abolished
totally. Again, the recent legislation in the United States regarding the de
pository institutions (the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improve
ment Act of 1991, Jones and King, 1992) stipulates mandatory restrictions
on deposit interest rates for undercapitalized banks in the context of capital-
based policy of prompt corrective action. Since undercapitalization is wides
pread among banks in developing countries, the scope for the application
of such restrictions must be much greater.
Regulation of short-term interest rates through intervention in inter
bank markets is also essential for attaining greater financial stability and
preventing frequent bank failures, particularly when there is considerable
maturity mismatching between banks' assets and liabilities. Under such con
ditions, large swings in interest rates can create serious dilemmas for banks.
If banks respond to an unexpected increase in market interest rates by
raising deposit rates, their profits can be sharply reduced and their solvency
threatened. If they do not, or if they are prevented from doing so by deposit
ceilings, they may suffer a considerable deposit drain. Banks can respond
to increased swings in short-term rates with variable-rate loans or by shor
tening the maturities of their assets, as they have indeed done in many coun
tries, but when done on a laige enough scale this simply transfers the interest
rate risk onto the borrower and replaces it with greater credit risk.
It should be kept in mind that control over interest rates through
ceilings and intervention does not eliminate the need for certain types of
prudential regulations to reduce financial fragility, i.e. vulnerability to de
fault in the corporate and household sectors (Minsky, 1982, 1986; Davis,
1993). This is particularly true in developing countries where the level of
economic activity is much more variable. When activity is buoyant, banks
tend to lend increasingly against assets which carry considerable capital
risk, including not only illiquid assets such as property but also securities;
they also expand consumer credits and invest directly in securities and
property. But when the expansion comes to an end and incomes and asset
prices start to fall, the quality of bank assets can deteriorate rapidly, and
even set off a debt-deflation process and credit crunch. Reducing the fragi
lity of the financial system thus calls for prudential regulations designed
to prevent excessive investment and lending with considerable capital risk
arising from their susceptibility to changes in the pace of economic activity.
42 Y ilmaz A kyüz
The discussions above suggest that the efficiency of the financial system
crucially depends on the way it is organized, because that influences the
nature and the degree of risk, uncertainty and instability. On the other
hand, the experience of industrial countries shows that there is no single
way of organizing finance. Consequently, an important issue in financial
reform in developing (and Eastern European) countries is what types of
financial institutions and markets need to be promoted.
2 The description of various systems here draws largely on Corbett and Mayer (1991), Kregel
(1991) and Somel (1992). For a summary account of the structural aspects of these systems,
see also Davis (1993, pp. 23-26). We do not examine here how these different systems
evolved, but there can be little doubt that government policies and regulations played a
major role.
F inancial liberalization: the key issues 43
sehold financial wealth tends to be held in banks rather than direct secu
rities, and bank credits account for a larger proportion of external financ
ing of corporate investment.
There are certainly a number of variants combining elements of both
systems. In the United Kingdom, commercial banks do not have much con
trol over corporations, but there is no legal separation between commercial
and investment banking. In Japan, commercial banks hold corporate equi
ties but are prevented from playing a major role in the underwriting of
corporate securities. Individual ownership of stocks is much smaller than
ownership by financial and non-finandal corporations, and corporate equi
ty is controlled through interlocking shareholding within industrial groups
where banks play a central role. Banks also control other financial insti
tutions (e.g. pension funds) that invest in equity. Lending by banks and
insurance and pension funds usually takes place within the same groups
and involves purchase of company bonds as well as loans. In Japan, bank
credits have played a much more important role in financing business growth
than in the other countries discussed here, although recently there has been
a shift to securities markets.
financial discipline over firms through shareholder action and the threat
of being taken over by other firms.
While there are often serious problems and weaknesses with a bank-
oriented system in developing countries, the benefits claimed for a market-
oriented system are unsubstantiated. It is often overlooked that the finan
cial systems in Germany and Japan have not only proved to be remar
kably stable, but also in the major respects discussed in sections El and
IV are more efficient than the Anglo-American system. Historically, finan
cial asset prices and interest rates in Germany and Japan have been less
volatile than in the United States, bank deposits more stable, and financial
disruptions and bank failures less frequent. Moreover, the cost of finance
to industry has been much lower in Germany and, more particularly, in
Japan. Evidence suggests that high capital costs have contributed to de
clining competitiveness in both industry and international banking in the
United States. Lower capital costs and a more predictable supply of fi
nance appear to have enabled Japanese firms to undertake longer-term pro
jects, including investment in research and development, whereas United
States firms have been deterred (McCauley and Zimmer, 1989; Poterba, 1991;
Zimmer and McCauley, 1991)3.
One of the main reasons for the greater stability and efficiency of
the financial systems in Germany and Japan is their ability to overcome
the dilemma posed by m odem capital markets. As noted by Keynes (1936,
chap. 12), m odem capital markets reconcile the social need for investment
with the preference of individual investors for liquidity. This is a necessity
since "if individual purchases of investment were rendered illiquid, this
might seriously impede new investment". However, while secondary mar
kets in securities accord savers liquidity, they also open up prospects for
speculation whereby most of the players "are, in fact, largely concerned,
not with making superior long-term forecasts of the probable yield of an
investment over its whole life, but with foreseeing changes in the conven
3 In conformity with contemporary trends and in response to outside pressure, Japan has
been undergoing a transition towards a market-based and open financial system, which is
not easy to reconcile with the policy of cheap finance. There have been severe fluctuations in
share prices, interest and exchange rates, and a tendency for the cost of finance to rise
(Martin, 1992).
F inancial liberalization: the key issues 45
tional basis of valuation a short time ahead of the general public". Thus,
these markets tend to operate like "casinos" where players speculate on
the speculations of other players.
The pattern of shareholding and ownership that characterizes the
German and the Japanese systems has allowed them largely to overcome
this dilemma. The fact that banks and business groups with a long-term
stake in the corporations hold the controlling interest means not only that
secondary markets tend to be less active and volatile, but also that the
managers do not need to pay much attention to how the market values
their assets from day to day, and can concentrate instead on the long term.
This also helps reduce liquidity preference and short-termism on the part
of individual investors and portfolio managers.
The bank-oriented system can exert a different and more efficient fi
nancial discipline over enterprises than the market-oriented system. Banks
in Germany and Japan (and banking groups) are often in a position to
monitor the performance of management by direct access to information
through their close and long-term relations with firms as shareholders and
creditors, and to intervene when needed in order to prevent failure. By
contrast, in the Anglo-American system of fragmented shareholding, indi
vidual investors have neither the means nor the incentive to monitor and
control corporate management. In extreme cases, market discipline is exer
cised through hostile takeovers, but these are often disruptive and waste
ful. More important, since markets tend to value the enterprise largely on
the basis of short-term financial performance, the takeover threat creates
pressures and incentives for the management to think short-term.
Furthermore, the internal capital market organized within banks and
firms connected by cross shareholding also improves enterprise performan
ce by reducing the borrower's risk by permitting economies of scale in
collecting, processing, evaluating and disseminating information. For the sa
me reason, there is less credit rationing in a bank-based system (Fama,
1985; Driscoll, 1991). Such a system also makes it possible to reduce consi
derably the lender's risk and the rate of interest, since it gives deposit
holders the liquidity they seek with a smaller risk of capital uncertainty
by pooling and institutionalizing the risk associated with individual invest
ment projects, and by reducing erroneous investment decisions.
A financial system with a close interface between banks and corpora
46 Y ilmaz A kyüz
While reform efforts need to concentrate in these areas, it is also true that
capital markets are a reality in a number of countries and they also need
to be improved. While most developing countries regulate primary issues
and stipulate a number of conditions regarding their size, maturity and
redemption and disclosure of information, there is very little effective con
48 Y ilmaz A kyüz
trol over secondary markets. Irregularities such as insider trading and fraud
are widespread and administrative capacity to undertake effective super
vision weak.
Stock prices in many of the so-called emerging markets have been
extremely erratic and subject to very large swings. By removing credit cons
traints, financial liberalization has often triggered an increase in speculative
activity by institutions and individuals. In many such countries, increased
speculative activity in the secondary market caused stock prices to rise be
fore 1987 even faster than in most of the world's major stock-markets, and
to fall, again far more than elsewhere, after October 1987 (Singh, 1992).
Most of these markets have again shown large swings over the last few
years.
Since the size of these markets is relatively small, the direct effects
of sharp falls in stock prices on the economy are negligible. However, the
state of expectations in the equities market influences the exchange rate
and capital flows since, as discussed in the next section, these markets
are open to foreigners an d/or provide alternative investment for holders
of foreign currency assets. Greater stability is thus essential to prevent
destabilizing feedbacks between equity and currency markets.
One way of reducing volatility is through the so-called "circuit bra-
kers" introduced in the United States after the October 1987 crash (Kupiec,
1991). These consist of predetermined price floors: when prices fall to the
floor, trading is suspended for a predetermined period. Such measures can
be particularly helpful in reducing intra-day bandwagon-type declines in
stock prices. Another is through the financial transactions tax long advocated
by Keynes (1936, pp. 160-161). Such a tax may help reduce speculative
instability by deterring short-term trading, improve the efficiency of the
stock-market and lengthen the time horizon of corporate managers (Stiglitz,
1989b; Summers and Summers, 1989).
Public or semi-public agencies with large holdings of securities can
also play an important role in bringing greater stability to stock prices.
For instance, in Turkey the agency dealing with privatization has operated
both as a buyer and a seller in the market for the shares of privatized
public companies, exerting a significant influence on prices, even though
its objective has not been to stabilize the market. Institutional investors
and particularly provident funds can both provide the Japanese/German
Financial uberauzation : the key issues 49
type of shareholding and control over enterprises, and help to attain grea
ter stability.
rates; nor has the link between the levels of savings and investment in
individual countries been considerably weakened (UNCTAD, 1987; Kasman
and Pigott, 1988; McCauley and Zimmer, 1989; Akyüz, 1992). The main
reason is that most international financial transactions are portfolio deci
sions, largely by rentiers, rather than business decisions by entrepreneurs.
The bulk of capital movements is motivated primarily by the prospect of
short-term capital gains, rather than by real investment opportunities and
considerations of long-term risk and return. The speculative element is ca
pable of generating gyrations in exchange rates and financial asset prices
by causing sudden reversals in capital flows for reasons unrelated to policies
an d /or the underlying fundamentals. Rather than penalizing inappropriate
policies, capital flows can help to sustain them, as has been the case in
recent years in the United States and Italy where inflows have helped to
run chronic fiscal deficits.
Thus, financial openness tends to create systemic problems regardless
of the order in which various markets are liberalized and distortions re
moved. The exposure to short-term, speculative capital flows is much grea
ter for developing than for developed countries because their instability
provides greater opportunities for quick, windfall profits on short-term capital
movements while their ability to influence capital flows through monetary
policy is much more limited.
While internal financial liberalization strengthens the link between in
flation and interest rates, external financial liberalization (unlike trade
liberalization) weakens that between inflation and the exchange rate, bringing
the latter under the domination of capital flows instead of trade balances
and the relative purchasing power of currencies: inflation differentials are
more readily reflected in nominal interest rate differentials than in the mo
vement of the nominal exchange rate. Thus, although short-term capital
inflows motivated by the lure of quick, windfall profits are often associated
with positive real interest rate differentials in favour of the recipient, such
a differential is neither necessary nor sufficient in all cases. Capital inflows
usually occur in response to a nominal interest rate differential that mar
kets do not expect to be fully matched by a nominal exchange rate depre
ciation. Such differentials often emerge when domestic inflation is much
higher than abroad and domestic financial markets have been liberalized.
Since in many developing countries inflation rates close to those prevailing
Financial liberalization: the key issues 53
in the major OECD countries are very difficult to attain, the scope for big
arbitrage opportunities to emerge is much greater. Similarly, an expectation
that equity prices will rise faster than domestic currency depreciation can
prompt an inflow of capital. Both types of expectation can be self-fulfilling
since the inflow of funds, if large enough, can itself maintain the value
of the currency and boost equity prices.
Such inflows are typically initially a response to a favourable shift
in market sentiment regarding the recipient country. This shift may result
from external causes such as a sudden rise in export prices, or from internal
ones such as reduced inflation, better growth prospects, and greater politi
cal stability and confidence in the government's policies. After the initial
shift in market sentiment, a bandwagon develops and creates a speculative
bubble where people are lending or investing simply because everybody
else is doing so. The boom does not necessarily peter out smoothly: a re
cently liberalized, well-performing economy can suddenly find favour with
foreign capital of all sorts, but if things go wrong for some reason, the
capital can disappear just as rapidly. When the bubble bursts and the cu
rrency comes under pressure, even a very large positive real interest rate
differential may be unable to check the capital outflow.
That was the story of the liberalization episodes in the Southern Cone in
Latin America in the 1970s, when high domestic interest rates, overvalued
exchange rates, freedom to borrow abroad and plentiful international li
quidity combined to induce capital inflows. But there are strong signs that
a similar process is again under way in a number of Latin American coun
tries. It is estimated that the region as a whole received about US$40 billion
in 1991, three times the level of 1990, the main recipients being Mexico,
Brazil, Argentina, Venezuela and Chile. Not all the capital inflows have
been for short-term uses, but much of them do appear to have been, particu
larly in Argentina and Brazil (Griffith-Jones et al, 1992, tables 4 and 5;
UNCTAD 1992, part two, Annex A). In the majority of these countries capital
inflows continued at an accelerated pace in 1992. In Chile where "the mone
tary authorities adopted a cautious approach based on the assumption that
the oversupply of foreign exchange was only temporary and was due to
54 Y ilmaz A kyüz
the unusually high price of copper and the low international interest ra
tes" (ECLAC 1991, p. 41), short-term capital inflows slowed down conside
rably in 1992 thanks to various measures designed to reduce the arbitrage
margin.
What is remarkable about recent capital inflows to Latin America is
not only that the recipient countries are in very different positions com
pared to the 1970s, but that they differ widely among themselves with
respect to inflation, fiscal posture, and exchange rate and trade policies.
Argentina, Chile and Mexico have liberal trade regimes whereas Brazil has
tight controls. While Brazil has had a large fiscal deficit and very high
inflation, others, particularly Chile and Mexico, have had balanced budgets
or fiscal surpluses, and moderate inflation. Capital has been attracted by
a combination of currency appreciation and high real interest rates in Chile,
Mexico and particularly Argentina (and also a booming stock-market in
the latter two), but not in Brazil where the underlying factor has been
very high real interest rates (about 4 to 5 per cent per month). Currency
appreciation is due to exchange rate policy in Argentina (which uses the
exchange rate as a nominal anchor to reduce inflation), but not in Chile
and Mexico where it is market-generated. It has led to a considerable dete
rioration of the trade balance, especially in Argentina and Mexico.
The ideal response to such capital inflows is a corresponding increase
in domestic investment in traded goods sectors. This not only prevents
a sharp appreciation of the currency by raising capital goods imports, but
can also enhance export capacity- something that may be needed especially
when capital flows dry up or are reversed. But higher investment is not
always possible when domestic interest rates are prohibitive and long-term
investment with funds borrowed abroad at lower rates carries considerable
exchange rate risk. In other words the high interest rates an d /or currency
appreciation that attract short-term capital also deter investment. In Latin
America, capital inflows resulted in a sharp swing in the transfer of resources
abroad by about 4 per cent of the region's GDP during 1990-1991, but
investment remained depressed: in Brazil and Argentina the investment ratio
remained below the levels of the 1980s when these countries had been
making large transfers on debt servicing.
The problems of macroeconomic management in the face of a massive
capital inflow are well known. Sterilizing them by issuing domestic debt
Financial liberalization: the key issues 55
can impose a serious burden on the public sector, particularly when the
arbitrage margin is large. In Brazil, for instance, the cost of carrying the
extra US$5 billion of reserves purchased in this way amounted to about
US$2 billion during 1991-1992, adding considerably to domestic public debt
(UNCTAD, 1992, part two, Annex II; Junior, 1992). Furthermore, by incre
asing the stock of government debt, sterilization itself tends to raise domes
tic interest rates and, hence, the arbitrage margin. If, on the other hand,
the currency is allowed to appreciate, it can undermine the competitiveness
of the domestic industry, possibly eventually triggering a sharp reversal
in short-term capital flows.
only prick the speculative bubble in the stockmarket, but also lead to a
currency crisis. Recent evidence suggests that chaotic feedbacks between
financial and currency markets can easily develop: for instance, when the
bubble burst in the Tokyo stock exchange at the beginning of 1990, there
was a massive shift out of yen-denominated assets, causing also considera
ble drops in the government bond index and the currency (Akyüz, 1992).
domestic currency and foreign currency assets also tends to raise the cost
of finance because of the greater risk and uncertainty in developing coun
tries. The fact that most developing countries are economically and po
litically less stable than developed countries, with financial and legal sys
tems that are less able to ensure enforcement of contracts, increases the
hazards of financial investment. In a financially closed economy the safety
premium on foreign currency assets is counter-balanced by the high tran
saction costs of shifting into them, at least for most small savers, but fi
nancial openness reduces these costs considerably. Consequently, domestic
assets need to carry much higher rates of return than external assets. This
can reduce investment and impair competitiveness.
effects on capital flows seem to have been limited (Banco de Mexico, 1992,
p. 144).
Historical experience clearly shows that capital controls are no ans
wer when the underlying policies are not sustainable. For instance, mea
sures to control capital inflows are generally ineffective against capital flight
stemming from economic and political instability. Moreover, it is important
to bear in mind that capital controls are needed not in order to pursue
inappropriate policies and exchange rates, but to minimize the disruptive
effects of short-term capital flows and gain greater policy autonomy to attain
growth and stability.
VIII. CONCLUSIONS
REFERENCES
Alice H. Amsden
CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................................................... 73
VI. CONCLUSIONS.................................................................................................................... 88
ANNEX OF T A B L ES...................................................................................................................... 89
REFERENCES 99
E a st A s ia n f in a n c ia l m a r r é is : w h y s o m u c h (and f a ir l y e f f e c t iv e ). 73
INTRODUCTION
prises could and did leap-frog ahead of Britain in the most dynamic sectors
such as chemicals and steel because British firms could not establish impe
netrable international entry barriers in the nineteenth century.
By the twentieth century this strategy had become impractical for two
reasons. First, over time the gap between the most and least advanced
countries (or even the average developed and developing country) had grown
far greater. The distance to the world economic frontier, measured as the
ratio of GDP per capita of the most developed countries to the appropriate
comparison, ranged from only 1.8 to 3.3 for the average backward European
country at the end of the nineteenth century compared with 11.9 for the
average developing country after the Second World War and 25.7 for the
typical least developed country in the 1970s (Hikino and Amsden, 1993).
Second, with the rise of global enterprises possessing "organizational
capabilities" based on a core technology (Chandler, 1990), Gerschenkron's
idea of leaping to the world technological frontier was no longer feasible.
The institutionalization of R&D in such enterprises allowed them to erect
entry barriers around their proprietary technology, which kept newcomers
out. The only economy in the twentieth century to attempt to leap-frog
to the world technological frontier ended in failure, namely the former
USSR, which was Gerschenkron's primary concern.
Gerschenkron conceived domestic enterprises in Europe as the agents
of industrialization, but increasingly after the Second World War, the
multinational firm came to be viewed in certain development theories as
the agent capable of transferring technology to backward countries. By rais
ing productivity there, the multinational supposedly precluded the need
for government intervention. Whether in the role of exporter of labour-
intensive manufactures (as in Taiwan, Province of China, and Puerto Rico),
or developer of import substitution industries (as in Mexico and Brazil),
the multinational firm was credited with nudging backward countries closer
to world productivity standards.
Nevertheless, casting the multinational firm at the heart of the deve
lopment drama has proved to be problematic in practice. Few developing
countries after the Second World War have managed individually to attract
significant amounts of foreign investment. Even in those Asian countries
which the multinationals have patronized, investments from abroad have
been found to amount to only a small fraction of aggregate capital require
76 A uce H. A m sd e n
ments (Amsden, 1992). Foreign capital typically lags rather than leads indus
trial development and tends to flow to backward countries where industria
lization has already started, and only then accelerates it (Herman, 1991).
Moreover, simply because a foreign investor is a multinational firm no longer
necessarily implies that it operates at the world frontier. The production
and design problems that afflict it at home may merely be transferred abroad
-as in the case of the South American operations of some North American
automobile companies (Shapiro, forthcoming). Thus, the multinational firm
cannot be counted on automatically to overcome the diseconomies of back
wardness mentioned above.
In sum, conventional development theory recommends that latecomers
industrialize by "getting the prices right" (allowing supply and demand to
determine prices), and typically by using low wages to gain a comparative
advantage in labour-intensive industries. But, in fact, successful late
industrialization has been a process of using subsidies to lower production
costs, such as capital, to get the prices "wrong" (preventing market forces
from determining prices, such as interest rates) in order to overcome the
handicap of an absence of proprietary technology, the inability to leap
frog over more advanced countries, and the inadequacy of a low wage
advantage (Amsden, 1989; 1992). Therefore, a necessary condition for
industrializing in the twentieth century is systematic and well-coordinated
government intervention to promote manufacturing investment. As sugges
ted below, what seems to distinguish developing countries that are "sneak
ing up" to the world technological frontier from those that are "stumbling
back" (such as the Philippines and Argentina) or "staying behind" (say,
Bangladesh and Pakistan) is not less state intervention but rather a different
set of principles governing subsidy allocation.
The factors underlying the ability of the East Asian States to impose per
formance standards on business have operated at different layers of com
plexity.
80 A uce H. A m sd en
2 Sections 5(b)-6(c) rely heavily on Amsden and Euh (1990 and 1993).
3 Tokyo National University, Seoul National University and Taiwan National University (the
last tw o in emulation of the first), were all founded with the purpose of supplying educated
governm ent officials, all of whom had to pass a "high" civil service exam. In general, all
three East Asian countries have invested heavily in education, and this has undoubtedly
contributed to the efficiency of the bureaucracy.
82 A l ic e H . A m sd en
1. Interest rates
Whether before or after reform, Korea's Ministry of Finance (MOF) has had
as one of its objectives lowering the level of financial costs for an ever-
increasing circle of firms. One consideration that has guided the Ministry
of Finance is that low interest rates are necessary to stimulate investment,
while high interest rates are not as necessary to mobilize savings.
In December 1988 the monetary authorities became serious about re
form and, as part of a sweeping financial reform, deregulated interest rates
on bank loans and discounts, and on the rates of both short-term and long
term financial markets. After December 1988 the MOF was no longer em
powered to set ceilings on interest rates (which, in a repressed financial
market, had become actual rates) or to earmark subsidized credit for spe
cial borrowers.
A brief example suffices to substantiate the continuation of the MOF's
informal interventions. In May 1989, the interest rate in the secondary short
term government bond market (special law bonds), which is a close appro
ximation to a free market rate, was 18.9 percent. The loan interest rate
of commercial banks was only 12.5 percent. This represents a big gap bet
ween the two markets and is therefore evidence against the liberalization
of interest rates which, in theory, occurred from 5 December 1988 onwards.
The only interference by government in loan allocation in the Republic
of Korea that is supposed to continue to exist is in relation to small and
medium-sized firms: all financial institutions, even branches of foreign banks
operating in the Republic of Korea, are required to set aside a certain portion
of their loans for small and medium-sized enterprises, since even foreign
banks, which were always free to choose their clients, tended to slight such
firms in the past. In practice, the MOF determines to which firms financial
84 A l ic e H. A m sd en
porate bonds, introduced in 1972, have continued. Stocks have been divi
ded into two tiers, blue chips and more risky issues. A country-wide drive
has attempted to educate the ordinary investor. Measures have been con
sidered by the government to reduce insider trading and improve disclo
sure.
Second, stock market institutions themselves have been strengthened,
partly in anticipation of the opening of the Republic of Korea's capital m ar
ket to foreign investors and securities companies. The MOF allowed Korean
securities companies to increase their paid-in capital by a multiple of 7
in a four-year period. An attempt has also been made to increase participa
tion on the KSE of institutional investors by allowing non-bank financial
institutions to hold securities in their portfolios. The ownership structures
of life insurance companies and securities dealers themselves have been
amended to encompass ownership of corporate equities and bonds. At the
end of 1990, institutional investors accounted for 46 per cent of outstanding
shares, a lower proportion than in most advanced countries but a far higher
one than five years earlier (Securities Supervisory Board, 1992).
Third, to spread "people's capitalism", the government allowed 5 per
cent of a company's new issues of stocks or debentures to be reserved
for its employees for sale at par rather than market value. Directors and
executives were not allowed to be included in the scheme. Some finance
companies were successful in establishing such a programme, and since
they had a relatively high level of paid-in capital and few employees, the
gains to any individual employee sometimes reached US$20,000. This sti
mulated demands by workers in other companies for the establishment of
similar schemes, demands that were sometimes supported by strikes. By
1990 Employee Stock Ownership Associations covered some 945,600 wor
kers in 784 companies. The total number of shareholders was roughly 10.4
million people out of a population of about 42 million.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
Table 1
RATIO OF MANUFACTURING TO AGRICULTURAL NET PRODUCT
AND NET VALUE OF MANUFACTURING PER CAPITA,
LATIN AMERICA AND ASIA, L955
Latin America
Argentina 1.32 145
Brazil 0.72 50
Chile 1.35 75
Colombia 0.42 45
Mexico 1.00 60
Peru 0.52 25
Venezuela 1.43 95
Asia
India 0.30 7
Indonesia 0.20 10
Republic of Korea 0.20 8
Philippines 0.32 13
Thailand 0.28 10
Source: Alfred Maizels, Industrial G row th and W orld Trade, (Cambridge: At the Uni
versity Press, 1953), as cited in Christopher Freeman, "Catching up in world growth
and world trade," (mimeo), Science Policy Research Unit, Sussex University, Uni
ted Kingdom
92 A l i c e H. A m sd e n
Table 2
INCOME DISTRIBUTION (THE RATIO BY W HICH THE INCOME
OF THE TOP FIFTH OF THE POPULATION EXCEEDS THAT OF
THE BOTTOM FIFTH)
Table 3
DEPOSITS BY TYPES OF INSTITUTIONS
(end of year - billion won, %) (a)
Table 4
A COM PARISON OF INTEREST RATES IN
THE UNITED STATES AND KOREA
(1) Korean prim e rate 18.5 12.8 3.8 3.9 19.5 13.2 6.3
(2) US Prime Rate 15.3 15.8 11.0 9.5 8.8 10.5 6.5
(3) (l)/(2 ) (%) 120.9 81.0 34.5 41.0 221.0 125.7 96.9
(a) At the end of the year.
(b) Negative numbers indicate won depredation.
Source: The Bank of Korea, Monthy Bulletin (various issues), as cited in Amsden and Euh (1993).
E a st A s ia n f in a n c ia l m a r k e t s : w h y s o m u c h (and f a ir l y e f f b c t iv e ) . 95
Table 5
SOUTH KOREA’S FINANCIAL REFORMS
STOCK MARKET INDICATORS
(end of year -100 million won)
Tableó
SOUTH KOREA'S FINANCIAL REFORMS
SOURCES OF FUNDS BY THE CORPORATE SECTOR
(in percentage)
Table 7
TREND OF NOM INAL AND REAL INTEREST RATES
(in percentage) (a)
Table 8
GROW TH OF THE FINANCIAL SECTOR
(unit: %)
REFERENCES
Euh, Yoon-Dae and James Baker (1990). The Korean Banking System and Foreign
Influence. London: Routledge.
Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective (Cam
bridge, Ma.: Harvard University Press).
Goodrich, Carter (ed.) (1967). The Government and the Economy: 1783-1861
(Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill Co., Inc.).
Haggard, Stephan (1990). Pathways From the Periphery: The Politics of Growth
in Newly Industrializing Countries (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press).
Han, Dae-Woo (1988). "Liberalization of interest rates in Korea: its impact
and policy issues", Monthly Economic Review (in Korean), 397 (December):
1- 21 .
Hanson, J. and C. Neal (1984). "A review of interest rate policies in selected
developing countries" (mimeo), (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, Finan
cial Unit, Industrial Department (Sept.)).
Herman, B. (1991). "International finance of developing Asia and the Paci
fic in the 1990s" (mimeo), Department of International Economic and
Social Affairs, United Nations, New York.
Hikino, Takashi and Alice H. Amsden (1993). "Staying behind, stumbling
back, sneaking up, soaring ahead: Late industrialization in historical
perspective", in William J. Baumol, Richard R. Nelson, and Edward
N. Wolff (eds.), Convergence in Productivity, With Some International
Comparisons and Historical Examples (New York: Oxford University Press).
Hughes, Jonathan R.T. (1991). The Governmental Habit Redux: Economic Con
trols From Colonial Times to the Present (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton Univer
sity Press).
Khatkhate, Deena R. (1988). "Assessing the impact of interest rates in less
developed countries", World Development, 16 (May): 577-588.
Lively, Robert (1955). "The American system: A review article", Business
History Review, 29:81-97.
Maddison, A. (1989). The World Economy in the 20th Century (Paris: Develop
m ent Centre Studies, OECD).
Nye, John V. (1991). "The myth of free trade Britain and fortress France:
Tariffs and trade in the nineteenth century", journal of Economic Histo
ry, 51:
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (1990).
Industrial Policy in OECD Countries: Annual Review (Paris: OECD).
E a s t A s ia n f in a n c ia l m a r k e t s : w h y s o m u c h (and f a ir l y e f f e c t iv e ). 101
Machiko Nissanke
CONTENTS
REFERENCES.................................................................................................................................. 145
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l ic y is s u e s in S ub- S a h a r a n A f r ic a 107
INTRODUCTION
It has been increasingly recognized in recent years that the financial system
and its intermediation function could play a vital role in economic deve
lopment by effectively mobilizing and allocating resources and facilitating
transformation and distribution of risks and maturities among savers and
investors (World Bank 1989).
The Structural Adjustment Programmes (SAPs) in Sub-Saharan Africa
adopted by m any countries in response to the worsening economic crisis
of the 1980s have placed high priority on financial sector reform. Financial
liberalization policy, based largely on the arguments advanced by the Me
Kinnon-Shaw school1, has been implemented subsequently in these countries
as part of economic reform packages. Special Financial Sector Adjustment
loans (FINSAP loans) have been taken up to uphold reform measures and
to restructure and strengthen distressed financial systems in several coun
tries (e. g. Ghana, Tanzania and Uganda). However, the FINSAP has focused
mainly on putting distressed formal institutions on a sound financial foot
ing through restructuring and refinancing of balance sheets. Emphasis is
placed on prudence, an improved regulatory environment and supervision
of the banks' operations. However, these reform measures, together with
the financial liberalization policy, have at best had limited impact on econo
mic development so far.
1 See, Mckinnon (1973), Shaw (1973) and Fry (1982, 1988). For a critical literature survey of
this school, see Nissanke (1991).
108 M a c h ik o N is s a n k e
2 See, for example, Cho and Khatkhate (1989), Corbo and DeMelo (1985,1987) and the W orld
Bank (1989).
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l ic y is s u e s in S ub-S aharan A f r ic a 109
First, a critical difference in the size, form and pattern of savings be
tween rural and urban households may be noted. Rural households tend
to have higher average and marginal propensities to save. Voluntary savings
capacities in rural areas may be substantial, with far more liquidity than
is usually assumed. Though liquidity generated does not necessarily consti
tute a surplus as such3, the agricultural production cycle and the seasonal
and highly variable income creates an absolute need for savings. The pa
tterns are distinctly "short-run", governed by the seasonality of agricultu
ral production and that of liquidity flows of rural household income.
Secondly, to the extent that rural households dominate the household
sector, financial savings have a modest share in total household savings.
According to the theory, non-financial forms of asset-holding as stores of
value indicate large-scale 'efficiency loss' to the economy, where the finan
cial system can potentially perform an efficient intermediation function. Un
productive commodity holdings could entail substantial storage and tran
saction costs. In the countries studied, the insignificant share of financial
assets in total savings undoubtedly also reflects the insufficient degree of
monetization of the economy at large. Indeed, a reverse process of de
monetization has taken place in the countries where economic conditions
had deteriorated sharply in the 1980s4. The asset composition of household
savings is generally determined by the nature of the economic activities
which a particular household is engaged in as well as the degree of liqui
dity, risk, return structure of different assets and their storage and trans
portation costs. In this latter sense, it is also affected by the perception
of the households as to their liquidity constraints and the ease with which
they can switch between different sets of assets.
The third characteristic of household savings to note is that the finan
cial savings of the household sector are small in size per unit of transaction
and short-term in frequency. As noted by Deaton (1989), savings by the
household sector in developing countries are of a "high frequency" natu
re, as opposed to the "low frequency" life-cycle savings in developed eco
3 As Von Pischke notes, low levels of surplus do not necessarily accompany low levels of
liquidity (Von Pischke (1991) p. 81).
4 For the degree of monetization and the factors explaining the process of de-monetization in
the sample countries, see Nissanke et. al. (op. cit.).
110 M a c h ik o N is s a n k e
and the growth of financial savings, on the other. Unless transactions costs
can be lowered and risks management improved, neither the expansion
of the number of branches, mobile facilities and specialized rural banks
nor interest rate adjustments will rectify the current inefficient and passive
attitude of banks towards savings mobilization in the household sector.
The persistent financial dualism between the formal and informal sec
tors and the limited progress in financial "widening"5 by the formal sector
can thus be attributed specifically to the incentive to interact of both bo
rrow ers/savers and lenders/intermediaries. As mentioned above, the lack
of access to credit facilities has hindered the majority of the population
in using the savings facilities of formal institutions. Our country studies
point to the critical importance of linking savings mobilization with credit
provision. There is also ample evidence that credit unrelated to savings
has undermined many targeted programmes (Adams et al. (1984), Seibel
(1989), Meyer (1989) among others).
At the same time, commercial banks, the dominant financial institu
tion in these countries, often do not have the incentive to actively mobilize
savings, due largely to the excess liquidity syndrome. Thus, one of the prime
factors explaining the relative size of the informal financial sector and its
vibrant presence within the household sector lies in the striking degree
of constrained behaviour of formal institutions. The characteristics of the
financial system will be examined below.
a) Informal finance
While many of the traditional forms of savings and informal financial ac
tivities have existed for a long time in these countries, a dynamism has
begun to gain momentum in recent years, as the formal sector has failed
to stimulate economic growth or respond to the need of real sector deve
lopment, in particular, that of the private sector. Rather financial distress
5 The process of financial widening can be viewed as extending the frontier/boundary between
formal and informal activities (Von Pischke (1991)).
112 M a c h ik o N iss a n k e
6 See Nissanke (1992a) for a fuller discussion of the brief description of the two phenomena
sum m arized here.
114 M a c h ik o N is s a n k e
7 Some commercial banks were established by expatriate banks primarily for financing external
-often colonial- trade in preindependence years and later nationalized to become majority-
govem m ent ow ned or rem ain foreign controlled. Others were newly established in the post-
independence era as publicly ow ned. Operational decisions of m ost of these banks are in
principle guided by commercial considerations, though they were often required to take on
a developm ental function in advancing loans to priority sectors. In contrast, banking
operations of some state-owned commercial banks have been governed prim arily by the
need to finance fiscal deficits and to cover operational loss of public enterprises and marketing
boards (eg. Tanzania and Uganda, see Collier and G unning (1991) for the Tanzanian case).
1 The term "excess liquidity" here refers to banks' voluntary hoardings of liquid assets as
opposed to "monetary overhang" when nonbank public accumulates liquidity as a result of
shortages in the goods markets. The former phenomenon becomes prevalent, when perceived
default risks increase and banks resort to a sharp retrenchm ent in lending, exacerbating the
recessionary tendencies resulting from reduced aggregate dem and. Caprio and H onohan
(1991) report that in the United States of America this was observed during the Great
Recession of the 1930s as well as in the "credit crunch" of 1990-1991. In the earlier episode,
the share of liquid assets in total deposits of the US banking institutions was reported to
have nearly doubled from 35 per cent in 1929-1930 to 65 per cent in 1935, then further to 70
per cent in 1940. The deep recession that seized major industrialized economies in 1992 has
also been characterized by debt deflation on a global scale, w here portfolios of banking
institutions have been rapidly deteriorating with increasing non-perform ing loans and
debtors-consumers have been m aking adjustm ents to their over-leveraged positions from
excess borrowing in the previous period (UNCTAD 1992).
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l ic y is s u e s in S ub- S a h a ran A fr ic a 115
9 N aturally Treasury Bills and Government Paper held as secondary reserves are not nearly
as liquid as cash prim ary reserves. Risk-adjusted returns on these holdings have been,
how ever, high enough to justify investm ent in them com pared to lending to activities
perceived to be highly risky, even when nominal returns on them were low. The recent
u p w ard adjustm ents of rates of returns on these paper as a part of financial liberalization
and monetary stabilization policies im plem ented in a num ber of con tries have m ade m ost of
lending operations unattractive to banks, except very low cost and highly rem unerative
lending (Nissanke 1992a).
116 M a c h ik o N is s a n k e
ratio maintained by the commercial banks has been far below those ob
served in the other case studies throughout the 1970s and 1980s, ranging
from 18 per cent in 1974 to 1975 and 1983 to 28 per cent in 1977 and
1986, with fluctuating margins from year to year. A preliminary analysis
of annual changes in the commercial bank liquidity ratio (Mwega 1991)
suggests that there are the considerable adjustment lags involved between
an increase in commercial banks deposit liabilities and their increased lend
ing to borrowers10. In contrast to the other three countries studied, excess
liquidity in Kenya is of more transitory nature. Nevertheless, the excess
in liquidity ratio has still averaged more than 5 per cent of deposit liabi
lities throughout the 1970s and 1980s, exceeding 10 per cent in some years.
The sheer scale and persistence of the syndrome in the other countries
studied (Ghana, Malawi and Zambia) points to the need for analytical ex
planations of the permanent components of excess liquidity. The nature
and scale of the phenomenon of excess liquidity in these three countries
are illustrated in the following statistics:
In Ghana, the required minimum reserve requirements have histo
rically been set very high (Fig. 2): over 80 per cent of deposits in 1979
and 1980. The statutory level had been gradually brought down to 40 per
cent in 1985. The actual reserves held in liquid assets by the banks were
over 70 per cent in 1980-1983, indicating the extreme degree of 'low lend
ing trap1 in those years. In 1988, the year when the liberalization policy
was already well in place, the commercial banks held about 15 per cent
of their total deposit liabilities as excess reserves. Of these, about 5 per
cent was held in cash (in addition to the statutory requirement for 20 per
cent cash reserves) and 10 per cent was in the form of government paper
(over and above the statutory requirement for 25 per cent secondary re
serves). This brought the share of liquid assets to 60 per cent of total de
posit liabilities for the entire banking system in that year. The level of
liquid assets actually held by the banks subsequently increased, reaching
over 65 per cent in March 1991, as shown in Fig. 3.
10 The Kenyan country study suggests that the commercial banks liquidity decisions are
influenced by several factors including the maximun lending rates, the structure of deposit
liabilities, the required minim um ratios, and the changes in the commercial banks m one
tary base.
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l o is s u e s in S ub- S ah a ran A fr ic a 117
n In the 1970s, the largest component of liquid assets was held in governm ent stocks rather
than in Treasury Bills.
12 During the 1980s, the major part of liquid assets was held as deposits at the central bank,
rather than in governm ent securities, as in the 1970s. Some of these deposits at the central
bank reflected the bank's liabilities for outstanding im port paym ents awaiting extemali-
zation because of inadequate foreign exchange.
13 It is reported that the trade liberalization measures taken in 1989 subsequently eased the
banks' excess liquidity problems to some extent.
14 For more detailed discussion of the two paradigms, see Section II below.
118 M a c h ik o N iss a n k e
scale entities have little chance of obtaining bank credit due to high tran
saction costs and perceived risks in dealing with them. High transactions
costs can prevent banks from undertaking adequate screening, monitoring
and credit-enforcement procedure against default risks. The perceived high
risks of lending make banks extremely risk-averse in extending credit to
small borrowers, particularly those without collateral assets.
Bankers often explain their overly conservative lending policy by cit
ing the absence of viable projects to which to lend. It can be argued that
it is not necessarily the absence of viable projects per se but the lack of
mechanisms by which risks and viability can be adequately assessed, and
new ventures selected, monitored and repayment enforced. The adoption
of liberalization policies have had limited impact on this component of ex
cess liquidity. While latent demand for credit by solvent borrowers may
remain unsatisfied, the banking sector accumulate excess liquidity, withdraw
ing support from productive investment. Excess liquidity can thus give rise
to 'a low lending trap' (Caprio and Honohan (1991)) and can impede the
emergence of vigorous entrepreneurship.
Several implications may be derived from the Excess Liquidity Syndrome:
First, faced with limited lending opportunities worthy deemed and
excess liquidity hoarding, the banks lack incentive to mobilize additional
savings. Banks have even regarded the shift to deposits with longer matu
rity as raising the average costs of keeping funds, given the absence of
good investment opportunities promising a high rate of return which could
justify the wide margin between deposit and lending rates to cover high
intermediation costs. Therefore, commercial banks in Malawi and Ghana, for
example, are reported to have been turning depositors away, in particular
discouraging them from opening accounts bearing high rates of intrest15.
15 The adoption of an interest rate liberalization policy has h ad very limited im pact on the
resolution of this phenom enon, even where higher financial savings at the formal financial
institutions followed, as illustrated by the reaction of M alawian banks to the upw ard
adjustm ents in interest rates in 1987-88 (Chipeta and M kandaw ire (1991a) and Nissanke
(1992a). The banks are, first of all, constrained to raise the lending rate because of the
adverse selection incentive and moral hazard effects (Stiglitz and Weiss (1981). Even if the
lending rate is raised to cover the intermediation cost after the u p w ard adjustm ent in the
deposit rate, the resulted reduction in dem and for loanable funds squeezes their profit
margin and m akes it expensive to keep interest-bearing deposits.
120 M a c h ik o N iss a n k e
16 Von Pischke (1991) argues, however, that the concept of credit needs and the perception of
unsatisfied credit dem and should not be adopted as a prime criterion for lending. In order
to achieve long-run viability and sustainability of financial institutions, he instead advoca
tes using the risk-adjusted debt capacity, which could dynamically evolve over time, as a
basis for credit policy.
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l ic y issu e s in S u b- S a h a r a n A f r ic a 121
17 W hen economies are narrowly based, credit risks are highly correlated across loans exten
ded for similar economic activities.
122 M a c h ik o N is s a n k e
rational liability. Yet, there are several examples of DFIs which have achie
ved better performance by adopting a more flexible, pragmatic and com
mercial approach, while at the same time managing to meet development
objectives. Good performers can be found not only in more dynamic Asian
economies but also in Sub-Saharan Africa (e.g. in Zimbabwe and Botswana).
The recommendation that DFIs should reorientate their priorities to
commercial goals, however, leaves open the critical question of how to reach
the social objectives of loan provisions to the priority sectors and meet
the credit need of micro enterprises and low-income people, thus follow
ing a broad-based and more equitable development path. Adams and his
associates (1984) suggest that policies affecting income levels through input
and output pricing policies are more appropriate in stimulating economic
development than special credit programmes.
However, serious reservations have been cast on the notion that cre
dit will "trickle down" to where it is needed through market forces and
without policy intervention. Can a viable alternative system to the conven
tional DFIs be created to ensure equitable development, through a combi
nation of financial institution-building, market deepening, linkage develop
m ent and new innovative schemes and instruments? The example of NGO
and donor involvement in innovative schemes suggests a possible way,
although it is impossible to deduce that these will proliferate to the point
where widespread self-sustained development is achieved unless it is foun
ded on active mobilization of local savings18.
The phenomena of excess liquidity and non-performing term loans
suggest that banking institutions taking the traditional approach have fai
led to make any significant inroads on expansion at the "frontier". Further
more, the co-existence of these two phenomena not only highlights a de
gree of fragmentation within the formal system, but also the serious mis
match of liquidity positions and the asset maturity structure of the sys
tem: While short-term money abounds in the form of excess liquidity in
one segment of the banking system, within the economy as a whole the
re is an endemic shortage of capital, particularly long-term loan provisions
18 For these "grassroots" banking programmes, m odelled largely on the Grameen Bank of
Bangladesh, see below.
124 M ach uco N is s a n k e
for productive investment and diversification. The formal system lacks the
abi-Hty to take on the risks associated with the maturity term transformation19.
The absence of functional inter-bank money and viable capital markets li
mits the ability of financial institutions to reduce or hedge against these
risks. Resources mobilized by financial institutions are used more by go
vernment and the public sector, with no real choices being made in terms
of risk assessment or prudent resource allocation to private users of credit.
The intermediation function of the formal system is thus seriously cir
cumscribed.
Meanwhile, dualism of the formal and informal sectors has been in
creasing and little progress has been made in financial widening by the
formal institutions in Sub-Saharan Africa in the last three decades. Any
practical long-term financial sector development policy for these economies
has to take into account predominant characteristics of their financial sys
tem and operations; namely, financial market fragmentation and pronounced
dualism between the formal and informal financial sectors. The next section,
explores theoretical explanations for this phenomenon.
The conventional theory of "financial dualism" suggests that the extent and
degree of segmentation of financial markets between formal and informal
sectors reflects the inherent dualism of economic and social structures,
rooted firmly in the population's traditional values and practice. It is sug
gested that as development proceeds, the informal sector would wither
away as it would be integrated into the formal system.
Empirical evidence emerging from developing countries indicates, ho
wever, that the actual process of interaction between the financial struc-
19 M any argue that this weakness in m aturity transformation and long-term loan provision
m ay not present a problem, so long as the formal banking institutions are able to supply
sufficient working capital, while retained profits and internally generated savings could be
used for term investm ent as Mckinnon's complementary hypothesis suggests. It should be
noted, however, the growth of enterprises may be slower if fixed investm ent is solely
dependent on retained earnings.
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l ic y iss u e s in S ub- S a h a ran A fr ic a 125
ture and real sector development is more intricate than this simple view
suggests. In some dynamic economies of Asia, integration of the financial
system has indeed taken place; the intermediation efficiency of the sys
tem as a whole has increased over time. Neverhteless, a heterogenous and
dynamic informal financial sector continues to exist. Indeed the formal and
informal sectors form a continuum of the integrated and well-functioning
financial system, with specialization in financial services by each sector
(Biggs 1991, Ghate 1990).
In contrast, in other developing countries, where economic performan
ce has been poor or stagnant, financial dualism appears to have deepened
over time; the two sectors persistently form almost discrete financial en
claves with little interaction between them. In such circumstances, market
segmentation can be detrimental to efficient functioning of the financial
system. A theoretical explanation is required to understand this phenome
non20.
The 'financial repression' hypothesis attributes the prime cause for the
dualism and fragmentation to repressive financial policies. With selective
or sectoral credit policies, a segmented and fragmented credit market emer
ges in which some borrowers obtain (rationed) credits at highly negative
real interest rates, while non-favoured borrowers m ust seek funds in ex
pensive and unreliable informal credit markets21.
In contrast, the imperfect information paradigm (Stiglits and Weiss
(1981), Stiglitz (1989)) explains the fragmentation of financial markets in
terms of the nature of credit transactions. According to this paradigm, in
the presence of imperfect information and costly contract enforcement,
market failures result from adverse selection and incentive effects and moral
hazard, which undermine the operation of financial markets. As the interest
rate charged increases, borrowers with worthwhile investments may be
discouraged from seeking loans and the 'quality' of the mix of applicants
changes adversely. Further, borrowers have an incentive to adopt projects
that promise higher returns but with greater risks; this increases the pro
20 Explanations for market segmentation are not necessarily limited to the two hypotheses
discussed below, nor are these m utually exclusive competing hypotheses. Both Hypotheses
may well be valid in combination, as suggested by Roemer and Jones (1991), (see below).
21 See Nissanke (1991) for a critical review of this thesis.
126 M a c h ik o N is s a n k e
bability of defaults. There is also a moral hazard with high interest rates,
when applicants borrow to pay interest on previous loans or simply to
stave off bankruptcy rather than to invest or to finance working capital.
With these possibilities, lenders may choose not to raise interest rate
to clear the market, when faced with excess demand for loans, since the
lenders' expected return on a loan could deteriorate as the interest rate
increases. Instead, they opt to select borrowers by adopting their own ra
tioning procedure. Thus, the interest rate has generally to take on an addi
tional function of regulating the risk composition of the portfolio of finan
cial intermediaries; it then often fails to perform its market clearing role;
hence market equilibrium is frequently characterized by credit rationing,
even in the absence of credit controls and direct credit allocation. In such
a case, by this paradigm, free markets do not ensure Pareto efficient allo
cation, nor do policies that move the economy closer to free market so
lutions enhance welfare.
While these features are universally applicable to all credit transac
tions, the problems arising therefrom are likely to be most pronounced in
low-income countries, where the economy-wide information flows are ex
tremely limited, access to information asymmetric and information gather
ing extremely costly. Where there is a generally low level of income and
asset accumulation, with widespread poverty and highly skewed income
and asset distribution, strict collateral requirement restricts access to credit;
moreover the applicability of various colla teral-substitutes, such as reputa
tion and group responsibility, cannot be well tested. There is limited scope
for legal enforcement owing to the inadequate infrastructure of legal ins
titutions.
With these deficiencies in markets and market-support infrastructure,
the transaction costs for financial intermediaries -which in addition must
minimize depositors' risks- are prohibitively high. As discussed above, banks
tend to become overly conservative and risk-averse in extending loans to
non-established borrowers. This sets economic constraints on the growth
of the formal financial institutions in these countries, unless there is some
impetus to break through the stalemate. If the formal institutions are push
ed against these operational constraints, their commercial viability is threa
tened. It is this particular aspect of credit transactions that largely explains
both the failure of the subsidized credit programmes administered through
S a v in g s a n d f in a n c ia l p o l ic y is s u e s in S ub- S a h a r a n A f r ic a 127
formal institutions to reach the targeted group and the high loan concen
tration in the relatively well-off groups which have collateral or reputa
tion at their disposal.
The recent study by Hoff and Stiglitz (1990) advances an explanation
for the extreme segmentation of markets in terms of asymmetric access
to information on borrowers and the differences in costs of screening, mo
nitoring and contract enforcement across lenders. The formal institutions,
even those specifically established for this purpose, faced with high tran
saction costs, ration out smaller borrowers, farmers and the poor, so as
to safeguard their operational viability. The unsatisfied demand for credit
of those left out by the formal sector is satisfied by heterogenous informal
lenders. Informal lenders have access at reasonable costs to local informa
tion on their borrowers with whom they have social interpersonal rela
tions, thus reducing screening and monitoring costs. Furthermore, tangible
assets are not necessarily the only form of collateral since informal len
ders are flexible in using other available m eans/forms for collateral subs
titute. They could, for example, rely on interlinked credit contracts with
other markets (land, labour and product), social group pressures and per
sonal knowledge of borrowers for their risk management and assessment
of debt capacity. Their service is far more flexible in loan terms and speed
compared with formal institutions. Hence, informal lenders have sizeable
comparative advantages over the formal lenders in engaging in small-scale
credit transactions because of their lower transaction costs and different
ways of handling risk. Informal associations and agents have a competitive
edge in small and short-term deposit mobilization. The result is market
segmentation and there is no automatic mechanism to integrate these seg
mented markets.
In examining the applicability of these two hypotheses explaining mar
ket segmentation by formal and informal sectors in Sub-Saharan Africa,
one can note an interesting conceptual distinction made by Roemer and
Jones (1991) between 'fragmented market’ and 'parallel market'; parallel mar
kets arise principally to evade government controls and regulations; mar
kets can be fragmented owing to some inherent characteristics of particular
market operations, even in the absence of government controls. They sug
gest that "credit markets in developing countries display characteristics of
both parallelism and fragmentation" (p. 8).
128 M achiko N issanke
22 Qiandavakar (1985) address the issue of the impact of the large presence of the informal
financial sector on the efficacy of monetary control.
132 M achiko N issanke
sector (the curb market) as "an efficient adjunct to regulated credit institu
tions". Secondly, the informal lenders have been adaptive to develop new
and innovative instruments for risky projects, and hence, they have ex
tended loans to borrowers without demanding real assets as collateral.
Furthermore, while the financial market exhibited a clear dualism into for
mal and informal segments, demarcated for borrowers depending on the
size of their activities, formal credits were available indirectly to smaller
borrowers through an extensive subcontracting system. Larger firms offered
on-lending facilities such as trade credit or suppliers credit to their sub
contractors and suppliers, acting as "de-facto intermediaries". The use of
"market interlinkage" and "credit layering" has been instrumental to their
success and supportive to industrial growth.
In other Asian countries, "interlinking" of contracts across financial,
trade and production transactions and "credit layering" have been used by
informal lenders for risk management in rural areas, wherever informal
sectors do perform an intermediation role effectively. These techniques help
to improve information gathering and contract enforcement. Yotopoulos and
Floro (op. cit. 1991) report that the informal lending operations with two-
tier credit layering, involving traders-lenders (commodity-based) and far-
mers-lenders (land-based), are extensively used in the rural Philippines.
These experiences in Asia suggest that market segmentation may not
be necessarily a sign of inefficiency, or a cause of inefficient intermediation.
Market segmentation, however, constitutes a problem when there is total
lack of communication or links between the different segments, constraining
severely the transmission of price and policy signals across the system.
This points to one key condition for a segmented system to work efficiently;
namely, there must be linkages, indirect if not direct, between segments.
In low-income African economies, this condition appears to be absent
or under-developed. Fig. 6. illustrates the flow of funds (savings and credit)
among different economic agents and sectors in these economies. Following
the conventional classification adopted in the literature on "dualism", econo
mic activities (the real sector) and financial services ( the financial sector)
are sub-grouped into the formal (modern) and the informal (traditional)
sectors.
The formal financial institutions predominantly provide services to
established large-scale "formal" sector activities, many of which, (in parti
Savings and financial policy issues in S ub-S aharan A frica 133
cular, State-owned) have had very low returns and shown poor financial
performance. The fiscal record of the governments -beneficiaries of most
of the credit from the central banks and whose papers other formal insti
tutions have largely invested in- has been generally dismal, exposed to
large external and internal shocks. The performance of many formal ins
titutions has been correspondingly poor. Past attempts to provide credit
and loans to the small-scale sectors, through the DFIs and the targeted
credit schemes, have largely failed, as little attention was given to the build
up of viable financial institutions (Meyer, 1989, 1991). Thus, the formal fi
nancial sector has suffered from a legacy of either conservatism or finan
cial distress. There is at present very little financial flow to the small-scale
sector from formal financial institutions (diagonal flows from the upper-
left box to the lower-right one in Fig. 6).
The financial needs of 'peripheral' activities of micro enterprises, SMEs
and small-scale farmers -upon whom the livelihood of a majority of the
population is dependent- are met by heterogenous informal financial orga
nizations and agents. Multifarious informal financial activities have deve
loped a dynamism of their own, demonstrating flexibility and adaptability
to the needs of local communities in which they operate. However, infor
mal financial arrangements are usually organized in a confined local vici
nity; hence their intermediation function is often constrained by their limi
ted scale of contacts, subject to highly seasonal funds and highly covariant
risks affecting the whole local community.
Consequently, markets and financial flows are largely segmented.
Critically, horizontal linkages are weak in both financial and real activities:
linkages between the formal and informal financial sectors (between the
two upper boxes in Fig. 6) are insubstantial. Since backward -and forward-
linkages of economic activities also tend to be weak (between the lower
boxes), formal credit fails to reach smaller borrowers through indirect rou
tes such as "credit layering" or subcontracting systems. Thus there is little
effective linkage whereby information and funds can flow between segments.
Presently, there is neither a dynamic market force for workable spe
cialization of financial intermediation by sector, nor policies to recognize
efficient functioning of the informal sector as intermediaries, i.e. those who
could sort borrowers according to 'information intensity' and credit risk.
There is no automatic mechanism to integrate the segmented markets into
134 M achiko N issanke
O)
T3
Sub-Saharan A frica
ZI
erg
co
O
<u
Oh
MALAWI
31
oq’
4*.
M achiko N issanke
Source: Reserve Bank of Malawi, Financial & Economic Review
ZAMBIA
Liquidity Ratio
cfi
<U
rÛ
(C
cn
0
Oh
01
T3
Fig. 6
FINANCIAL IN TERM EDIATION : FLOW OF SA V IN G S AND CREDIT
Financial flows (w eak:------------- , strong:-------------- )
REFERENCES
(*)The views expressed are the author's and not necessarily those of the World Bank. Inneke
Herawati provided indispensable word-processing support.
CONTENTS
I
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 153
INTRODUCTION
1 Van Wijnbergen (1983) and Taylor (1983) present an argument based on the efficiency of the
curb market and the effects of interest rates on the supply of goods (through the cost of
working capital) whereby freeing interest rates may not lead to growth. These arguments
turn on empirical magnitudes that need to be evaluated for each case. Other prominent
debates concern the timing and sequencing of financial reforms, the content of reforms and
the nature of financial-market supervision. See for example Edwards (1984), Caprio and
Atiyas (1992).
154 D onald P. H anna
1. Macroeconomic Background
2 For an excellent overview of the Indonesian economy, with a focus on international debt,
see Woo and Nasution (1989).
T he I ndonesian experience with financial - sector reform 155
or at a mild deficit. Oil revenues from the State-owned oil monopoly, Per-
tamina, also accounted for as much as 70 per cent of budgetary revenues,
keeping the domestic tax effort low. A period of hyperinflation in the mid-
1960s had led to the imposition of a policy that eschewed domestic-bond
financing of the government budget. The same concern over inflation led
to the adoption of an open capital account in 1970, whereby all movements
of capital by the non-finandal private sector into and out of the country
were completely unrestricted. Only banks and public enterprises faced
restrictions on the amount of foreign lending they could undertake. A debt
crisis in 1975 brought on by irresponsible borrowing by Pertamina led to
tight controls over public-enterprise borrowing and a strong desire by the
Indonesian government to limit its external debt burden. The crisis helped
Indonesia avoid the external debt build-ups that plagued many other middle-
and low-income oil producers in the late 1970s and early 1980s.
Government revenues were used throughout the 1970s to promote key
domestic industries, usually State-owned, behind a barrier of tariffs and
quantitative restrictions. Oil inflows created a Dutch disease problem during
the 1970s that Indonesia attempted to counter in 1978 by devaluating its
fixed exchange rate. Although non-oil exports initially responded positively
(Woo and Nasution, 1989), inflation in the intervening period, however,
led to continued appreciation of the rupiah.
Table 1
KEY M ACROECONOMIC IN DICA TO RS (a)
3. Financial Repression
(Table 4). Private banks, on the other hand, were not subject to interest-
rate controls, neither on deposits nor on loans. As a result, private banks
offered deposit rates two to three times higher than State banks.
Table 3
LIQ U ID ITY CREDITS
(billions of rupiahs; end of period)
State Banks
Liquidity Credit (LC) 3,876 6,426 9,176 13,873 10,807 12,048
L C /State Bank Credit 43.8 46.7 10.1 32.6 19.8 19.5
State Bank L C /A ll LC 92.2 93.6 89.0 79.5 82.7 87.5
Private National Banks
Liquidity Credit 208 298 753 2,602 1,693 1,280
LC Share (%) 15.4 9.1 9.2 11.5 4.8 3.0
LC/A11 Bank Credit 1.8 1.6 2.2 3.7 1.7 1.1
All Banks
Liquidity Credit 4,203 6,862 10,311 17,451 13,061 137,68
LC Share (%) 37.1 36.8 30.7 24.6 13.1 11.9
Source: Bank o f Indonesia.
Table 4
IN TEREST RATES A T COMMERCIAL BAN KS, 1982-91 (a)
(annual %)
Decem ber of 1982 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991
Table4 (Cont.)
D ecem ber of 1982 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991
late the domestic financial system from large foreign exchange inflows (the
main concern of policy makers during the period of oil wealth), since these
could not be transformed into credit.
Table 5
SECTORAL SHARES & GROW TH OF CREDIT AND GDP
(%)
Growth
1982 1988 1991 88-91
By 1982, the worsening price of oil and world-wide recession had under
mined Indonesia's balance of payments and fiscal balance, thus prompt
ing a series of macroeconomic adjustments. The current-account deficit had
reached 7.8 per cent of GDP, while oil-tax receipts had fallen 13 per cent
in real terms during the fiscal year (April to March).
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 163
One of the most important steps taken was a devaluation of the ru
piah by 38 per cent in March 1983, which brought the real exchange rate
back to its 1978 level, when the last devaluation had occurred. This was
undertaken to spur non-oil exports, which had responded well to the 1978
devaluation, and to increase rupiah revenues in the budget.
The devaluation was coupled with a series of fiscal adjustments to
make it stick. These involved cuts in current expenditures and reductions
in domestic subsidies to oil, public enterprises and food. This was reinfor
ced by delaying or cancelling dozens of large public-sector projects, includ
ing four multi-billion-dollar petrochemical projects planned by Pertamina.
Efforts at increasing domestic tax collections were also undertaken.
The fall in oil revenues played havoc with the old structure of the financial
system that had relied on significant recycling of the government's oil reve
nues through the banking system. Policy makers began to focus on the
need to promote the mobilization of domestic savings to maintain investment
in face of tightening external constraint. There was also growing concern
about the need to provide banks with more flexibility in the allocation
of credit, with the goal of increasing the efficiency of its use.
The reform process began in August 1982 as BI cut back on the provi
sion of directed credits for some low-priority sectors. This was followed
in June 1983 by more substantial reductions in the utilization of directed
credits to 14 "priority areas" and a hike in their interest rates to 12 per
cent. BI also moved to limit its direct credit to the public, relying instead
on refinancing. At the same time, the bank announced the elimination of
ceilings on lending rates at State banks, except for directed credits. Interest
rates on time deposits longer than six months were also freed3. Further
efforts to mobilize domestic funds included the authorization of bearer CDs
and the elimination of a 20 per cent withholding tax on domestic dollar
deposits. Finally, and most importantly, BI eliminated all credit ceilings.
3 This was followed several months later by the elimination of limits on six-month time
deposits, so that only savings deposits continued to have interest-rate ceilings.
164 D onald P. H an n a
The move to lower entry barriers was to take five years. In the intervening
time Indonesia's external environment improved in 1984-85 and then worse
ned considerably, with the 1986 plunge of the price of oil and the appre
ciation of the yen both pushing the current account into the red. As in
1983, the Indonesian authorities responded with a combination of exchange-
rate and fiscal policies to restore the balance of payments. Real current
government expenditures were cut through a salary freeze, subsidies were
reduced and capital spending slowed. Another sharp devaluation was
announced in September 1986, lowering the value of the rupiah by 50 per
cent. In response to the stabilization program, Indonesia was also able to
step up its aid program, with large amounts of balance-of-payments support
coming from the World Bank, the Asian Development Bank and Japan.
Unlike the 1983 crisis, this time stabilization efforts were coupled with
trade-reform measures. This began in 1985 with a reduction in the dispersion
of tariff rates. A duty-drawback system for exports was revamped in May
1986. More reforms accompanied the 1986 devaluation, setting a pattern
of replacing non-tariff barriers with tariffs which were subsequently lowe
red. In an effort to attract foreign investment, licensing requirements were
simplified in 1987. By 1991, a series of almost annual trade-reform packages
had succeeded in sharply lowering export bias and variance in the trade
regime and broadening the scope and ease of foreign direct investment.
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 165
in. The new capital requirements forced greater levels of equity for banks4.
Insurance company soundness was improved by the imposition of solvency
requirements.
Having dealt with banking, the next reform package (PAKDES, in
December 1988), focused on stimulating the capital market and other fi
nancial institutions. The government issued new regulations covering the
establishment of multi-finance companies empowered to engage in leasing,
factoring, venture capital, credit-card operations and consumer credit. The
same activities were made available to banks. Another set of regulations
came out governing securities trading, including prohibitions against in
sider trading. A major limitation to the stock market was eliminated when
domestic deposits were subjected to a 15 per cent withholding tax, the
same tax levied on dividend payments. New regulations also opened the
market to foreign investors.
PAKMAR, the March 1989 package, was aimed at refining the pru
dential regulations first announced in October 1988. It contained a series
of decrees clarifying, among other matters, the development and control
of NBFIs, lending limits, joint-venture bank capital ownership and bank
mergers, the definition of bank capital, reserve requirements and bank
investment in stocks. The long-standing absolute limit on external borrow
ing was replaced with restrictions on the net open position of banks in
foreign exchange (25 per cent of equity). Furthermore, the requirement of
prior BI approval of off-shore lending was eliminated. This allowed banks
to borrow off-shore more freely so long as they lent domestically in foreign
exchange or otherwise covered their position, thereby further freeing up
the capital account.
PAKJAN, announced in January 1990, took on the directed credit pro
grams that had continued to exercise a large though diminishing role in
the banking system despite initial efforts to curtail them in 1983 (Table
3). This time priority programs were limited to four activities (mainly fi
nance for small farmers and foodstuffs). One important sector excluded
from directed credit was export finance. Interest rates were moved closer
4 This equity cushion was quickly erased when lending expanded (to be discussed in the next
section).
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 167
to the market level and the portion of credit available for refinancing was
lessened. Mandatory, subsidized credit insurance was abolished. All these
measures were additional incentives for originating banks to more carefu
lly select and monitor their borrowers. As a political compromise, the eli
mination of directed credit programs for small businesses was replaced by
a requirement that 20 per cent of a bank's loans be made to small bo
rrowers.
PAKFEB, the latest set of reforms, and announced in March 1991,
returned once again to prudential regulations. New professional standards
were set for bank directors. Loan-loss provisioning standards were over
hauled, now involving a financial analysis of customers rather than simply
a check of whether their payments were current. A new, more quantita
tive evaluation of bank soundness, based on capital, asset quality, mana
gement, equity and liquidity, was implemented. Finally, banks were obli
ged to adopt the risk-based capital adequacy standards (as stated in the
Basel Agreement) by the end of 1993 (subsequently extended to the end
of 1994).
These important reforms were followed by several important new
pieces of basic legislation covering banks, pension funds and insurance
companies, all issued in February and March of 1992. Immediately before
hand, a regulation establishing the operating rules for closed-end mutual
funds was also handed down. The Banking Law is particularly important
since it eliminates any legal distinction between private and State banks
or between NBFIs and commercial banks. The former must now choose
between operating as a security house or a bank. New, stiffer penalties
for fraud are included in the law, along with a provision for the partial
privatization of State banks.
3. Summary of Reforms
agriculture. Competition between State and private banks and between banks
and other financial intermediaries was stymied by high entry barriers and
the ceiling on credit expansion at all banks. Nonetheless, the open capital
account put limits on Indonesia's ability to manipulate domestic interest
rates by offering larger depositors and borrowers an off-shore option. The
financing of fiscal deficits through foreign borrowing put a cap on expen
ditures that helped contain inflation and domestic demand.
The pressures of adjusting to external shocks, chiefly the oil-price de
clines of the 1980s, and concerns over the implications of pervasive controls
of credit, led to the 1983 reforms which removed all credit controls and
freed interest rates on all but directed credits. The latter were streamlined
but continued to play an important role in the system until their reform
in early 1990. The second stage of reforms, begun in 1988, tackled the high
entry barriers to banking and attempted to foster competition between banks
and other financial intermediaries. This was followed in 1991 by strengthen
ing of prudential regulation, a process that had first begun with some re
forms in 1989.
Despite this generally market-based reform, there are still some areas
of finance where the market is not given full play. As mentioned above,
the most important is the ruling requiring banks to lend 20 per cent of
their portfolio to small customers. For foreign and joint-venture banks this
rule has been replaced with a requirement that 50 per cent of all lending
be to exporters. The reinstitution of quantitative limits on bank external
borrowing in November 1991 also limits the openness of the capital account.
diation. We now review how the financial system has reacted in three key
areas: (a) financial deepening and interest rates (b) transforming the ma
turity of savings to match tire needs of investment projects, and (c) the
efficiency of intermediation.
Following reform, the financial system has deepened and broadened. Re
form led to a rapid expansion of financial assets within the economy after
credit and interest rates ceilings were eliminated in 1983 (Table 2). Overall
financial asset growth in real terms more than doubled (to 13.2 per cent)
between 1982 and 1988 compared to its rate between 1978 and 1982. Private
foreign-exchange bank growth was the strongest in banking, surpassed on
ly by leasing, which had a much smaller asset base. Private banks were
particularly successful in attracting time deposits from private individuals
and firms, despite a narrowing of their interest spread over State banks
as the latter responded to their new freedom by boosting rates 6 to 8 per
centage points (Table 4). This move narrowed the differential from 8.5 per
centage points on 3-month time deposits in 1982 to 2.6 percentage points
in 1983. The differential fell to less than 2 percentage points by 1985 and
is currently closer to one percentage point. Initial gains in deposits at pri
vate banks were also made despite restrictions on the number and location
of private bank offices. Insurance companies, public enterprises and govern
ment accounts all continued to be dominated by State banks, chiefly be
cause of legal and regulatory restrictions. The freedom to set interest rates
did allow State commercial banks to boost real growth to almost 12 per
cent, after a real growth of less than 2 per cent earlier on. Interestingly,
despite the initial attempts to curtail directed credits, BI's assets expanded
at close to 11.8 per cent real per annum between 1982 and 1988, compared
to only 1.4 per cent between 1978 and 1982. This growth did not slow
down until 1988-1991.
After the lowering of entry barriers in 1988, growth expanded further,
helped by a sharp increase in the number of firms. Assets at deposit mo
ney banks grew by nearly 20 per cent in real terms between 1988 and
1991, pushed by private foreign-exchange and non-foreign-exchange banks,
whose asset growth was 41 per cent and 35 per cent, respectively. On
170 D onald P. H anna
the deposit side of the balance sheet, private banks in only two years have
increased their share of deposits to over 40 per cent, while that of State
banks has fallen to below 50 per cent. Part of this increase is due to the
success of private banks in attracting savings accounts. Nominal growth
of savings accounts has exceeded 40 per cent since 1988.
Overall financial savings increased dramatically as a result of the 1983
and 1988 reform measures. M2 to GDP ratios increased sharply between
1982 and 1991, after an increase in the previous nine years of only 4 per
cent (Table 6). The bulk of this improvement came because of an expan
sion of quasi-money -time and savings deposit- that went mostly to pri
vate banks after the interest rate deregulation of 1983 (for time deposits)
and 1988 (for savings deposits). The link between this dramatic jump in
financial savings and domestic savings relative to national accounts is ex
plored below. In the meantime, however, it is important to note that an
important, though unknown, amount of the increase in M2 to GDP was
due to the movement of deposits out of Singapore and other off-shore
markets and into Indonesia.
An interesting impact of the reforms is evident in the figures on Ml
to GDP, where M l is composed of currency, C, and demand deposits, DD
(Table 8). As Chant and Pangestu (1992) have pointed out, the 1983 re
forms had little effect on the M l/G D P ratio, with the ratio actually falling
in 1983 and 1984. This pattern is consistent with Ml being held chiefly
for transactions and therefore only marginally affected by the higher ra
tes available on quasi-money. The 1983 increase in interest rates did lower
demand for M l relative to income somewhat, as people turned to the more
remunerative quasi-money. After the 1988 reforms, which allowed greater
branching and improved service, including interest on demand deposits,
there has been a discrete jump in the M l/G D P ratio. The effect of higher
interest rates on demand deposits is also visible in the stagnant share of
currency to GDP and the increase in DD/GDP.
Looking at the allocation of credit across institutions shows a diffe
rent pattern from that noted earlier for deposits. State banks actually ex
panded their share of total credits between 1982 and 1988 from 61.7 per
cent to 65.1 per cent. The maintenance of State bank dominance in credit
provision was due in large part to the continued importance of liquidity
credits funneled principally through State banks (Table 3) and to the decli-
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 171
ne in direct lending by BI, whose share fell from 26 per cent in 1982 to
only 4 per cent in 1988. Because of the withdrawal of BI from direct credit
creation, private banks also expanded their share of credit, which surged
from 9 per cent to 23 per cent.
Lower entry barriers created a stampede of new firms into financial
services. In banking, more than 75 new banks were opened between 1988
and 1991 (Table 2). Not only new banks, but the number of branches sur
ged as well, an increase of more than 1100 to 3700 between 1988 and 1991.
The PAKDES reforms initially sparked the equity market, leading to the
licensing of over 200 stock-brokerage firms. The market itself finally be
gan providing equity finance to complement greater amounts of debt fi
nance, though this slowed down in 1990 with the rise in domestic interest
rates and institutional growing pains (see discussion below).
Tableó
M ONETARY AGGREGATES IN GDP, 1978-1991
(%)
Not only has overall asset growth been strong, but the number of
products available to savers and borrowers has multiplied and service im
proved. Some of the fastest growth, for example, has occurred in leasing
and other newer financial activities. In banking, the range of attractive sa
vings current and time deposit accounts widened. Home mortgages and
172 D onald P. H an n a
b) Maturity structure
Table 7
COM M ERCIAL BAN K M A TU RITY STRUCTURE
(billions of rupiahs; end of period)
Bank Credits
< 3 months 1,829 1,991 2,354 3,495 3,957 1.5
3-6 months 1,787 3,443 5,392 5,057 5,726 4.5
6 months-1 year 4,438 11,237 18,866 43,753 49,539 9.0
1-3 years 1,604 2,092 3,731 8,778 9,938 24.0
> 3 years 3,944 8,974 14,825 29,904 33,859 60.0
unclassified 105 56 105 191 218 1.5
Total 13,707 27,793 45,273 91,178 103,237
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 173
Table 7 (Cont.)
Average Maturity
(mths) (a) 23.8 25.5 26.0 26.3 26.6
Bank Funds
Demand Deposits 6,031 8,157 10,350 19,254 22,013 1.0
Savings Deposits 584 1,387 2,174 9,662 10,595 1.0
Total Rupiah Time
Deposit 4,441 10,393 19,622 38,789 40,559
< 3 months 934 1,280 3,895 11,899 11,802 1.5
3-6 months 605 1,448 4,133 5,886 9,160 2.0
6 months-1 year 843 1,767 2,719 5,958 8358 9.0
1-3 years 1,948 5,898 8,350 13,910 9323 15.0
unclassified 111 132 525 1,136 1,716 1.5
Total All Deposits (b) 11,056 19,937 32,146 67,705 73,167
Average Maturity
(mths) (a) 5.8 8.6 7.8 73 5.1
(a) Calculated by weighting th e share of each m aturity in total credit (deposits) by the assumed matu
rity weight (the last colum n of the table).
(b) This total does not include FX tim e deposits.
Source: Bank o f Indonesia and author's calculations.
Tobin (1984) divides banking efficiency into three categories. The most
straightforward is cost efficiency: Do banks intermediate funds at the lowest
possible cost for a given level of risk? This entails looking at overhead
costs and, more generally, at the spread between borrowing and lending.
The second measure of efficiency, allocative efficiency, tries to incorporate
whether borrowers receive credit at a price commensurate with their risk.
Alternatively, it can be thought of as how successful the financial system
is in equalizing the marginal return on investment across the economy.
The measure of efficiency disregards the cost and risk of credit to focus
on liquidity. Since banks will necessarily have some maturity mismatch on
their balance sheet, prudent management requires keeping enough liqui
dity on hand to meet unexpected demands for cash. This last item can
be seen as a way of verifying that cost efficiency has not been achieved
174 D onald P. H an n a
through increasing risk. In general one could extend the analysis to other
sorts of risks (foreign-exchange, interest-rate, etc.). We will now examine
these different measures of efficiency.
i. Cost Efficiency
Indonesian banks have become more cost efficient since 1983. Non-interest
operating expenses (NIOE), chiefly wages, rents and office supplies, have
fallen sharply as a share of average total assets (Table S f. For all banks
in 1982 NIOE chewed up 4.26 per cent of average assets while accounting
for an exorbitant 7.11 per cent in non-foreign exchange banks. Interestingly,
State banks showed lower overhead costs than private banks, implying that,
though overstaffed, State bank wage levels were quite low. By 1988 NIOE
figures had fallen to 3.23 per cent overall, a decline of 24 per cent, with
private banks successfully bringing their overheads in line with those of
State banks. As the 1988 reforms took hold, NIOE initially fell further as
competitive pressures began to build. By 1990, however, the costs of a ra
pidly expanding branch network and higher wage rates for skilled staff
pushed up NIOE at all but the foreign banks6. With the slowdown in this
network expansion, banks, faced with lower asset growth and higher loan
losses (see below), have responded by once again reducing overhead, most
noticeably at State banks.
5 The figures in Table 8 are based on unaudited balance-sheet and income statements collected
by the Bank of Indonesia.
6 Note that foreign banks were still subject to limits on branches and had traditionally had
higher wage bills because of more extensive use of expatriate staff.
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 175
Table 8
CO ST EFFICIENCY FOR BANKS
(% of average total assets)
Table 9
BANK C O STS AND M A RGIN S
(% of average total assets)
Interest Income
State Banks 1.42 9.57 10.48 11.25 13.57
Private FX Banks 1.59 15.82 14.32 16.48 20.59
Private Non-FX Banks 0.91 16.92 14.81 19.56 25.13
Foreign Banks 4.45 11.71 12.05 12.52 12.99
All Banks 1.60 11.17 11.60 13.18 16.03
Interest Expense
State Banks 4.12 7.40 7.77 8.08 11.43
Private FX Banks 7.95 11.90 10.81 12.49 16.14
Private Non-FX Banks 9.74 12.64 11.49 15.03 20.09
Foreign Banks 9.15 7.57 7.97 6.95 7.83
All Banks 4.82 8.25 8.83 9.29 12.60
Net Operating Margin
State Banks 2.55 2.45 2.63 2.84 1.31
Private FX Banks 4.00 2.89 2.37 2.26 2.24
Private Non-FX Banks 3.67 1.78 1.37 1.93 1.87
Foreign Banks 4.51 3.70 3.64 3.98 4.53
All Banks 2.99 2.64 2.57 2.91 1.98
Pre-Tax Return on Assets
State Banks 2.40 1.40 1.55 1.78 0.31
Private FX Banks 3.60 1.93 1.68 1.39 1.24
Private Non-FX Banks 3.08 1.29 0.78 0.97 0.91
Foreign Banks 4.32 1.78 2.80 3.02 3.39
All Banks 2.81 1.68 1.67 1.99 0.97
Return on Equity
State Banks 67.31 44.54 47.34 65.59 16.16
Private FX Banks 32.89 29.65 18.43 15.07 12.63
Private Non-FX Banks 18.34 15.51 7.02 5.97 5.37
Foreign Banks 119.90 48.77 18.59 17.33 25.26
All Banks 45.97 29.93 24.82 28.21 16.65
mine loan rates, but also the elimination of credit ceilings which allowed
State and other banks to move more assets into loans. State bank inte
rest expense, however, does not increase nearly as much as interest inco
me -only 3.3 percentage points, as compared to 8.2 percentage points. This
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 177
increase is smaller than that of private foreign exchange banks which were
the State banks' closest rivals. The lower increase may be due to the con
tinued presence of public-enterprise deposits in State banks, as well as the
continued access of State banks to refinancing from BI. Another part of
the difference is explained by the implicit government guarantee that State
banks enjoy.
Lower interest costs at State banks did not translate into lower interest
margins at these banks because of low loan income, which between 1982
and 1988 reflected the continued importance of liquidity credits (Table 3).
The 1983 reforms did, however, lead to sharply higher interest margins
at all banks, going from 2 per cent to 4 per cent by 1988, somewhat exceed
ing the 3.5 per cent interest margins earned by US banks in 19887. Such
margins were negative at all banks in 1982, while the figure for private
non-foreign exchange was -8.8 per cent! This is only an accounting ploy,
however, since gross operating margins were all quite high in 1982, made
possible because income was being recorded from fees, rather than from
interest. It is a mystery as to why, without restrictions on interest rates,
private and foreign banks would resort to this subterfuge.
Reductions in NIOE between 1982 and 1988 allowed net operating
margins to fall less than gross margins for all types of banks. The opening
of new private banks pushed down margins at these banks, especially in
1991 when they approached international levels. State bank net operating
margins were steady, however, until 1991 when, in the wake of reductions
in refinancing and the loss of public-enterprise deposits, interest expenses
grew 2.5 percentage points. All domestic bank returns on assets also declined
between 1988 and 1991, chiefly as a result of higher provision expenses.
This was particularly true for state banks where the combination of higher
interest and provision expenses reduced profits to only 0.1 per cent of assets.
Meanwhile, foreign banks, helped by low deposit costs and high income
from foreign exchange trading, have been able to hold pre-tax profits at
levels two to three times those of domestic banks.
Overall, the examination of ex post margins shows a banking sys
tem that has significantly reduced its spread as measured by net operat-
ing margin, chiefly through a reduction in fees and overhead that has out
stripped increases in the interest margin. Pre-tax returns on assets are
approaching levels seen in recent years in the US.
One of the central aims of financial deregulation was to improve the allo
cative efficiency of the banking system by eliminating ceilings on credit
and interest rates while limiting directed credits. These moves were designed
to allow resources to be directed to high-return sectors of the economy,
at prices that reflected the risk inherent in those sectors. As w e have seen,
the reforms were associated with lower costs of intermediation and greater
credit flows. But was the credit better allocated? To assess the effects of
the reforms in this area we look first at the sectoral allocation of credit,
and then at the results of a firm level study, following this with an analysis
of changes in the riskiness of bank lending.
The overall allocation of credit was not greatly affected by the 1983
reforms (Table 5), though the pattern has roughly followed changes in GDP.
In part this may have been due to the continued importance of liquidity
credits within overall credit until very recently. Trade continued to receive
about 30 per cent of all credit between 1982 and 1988. Manufacturing's
share of credit rose to almost one-third at the expense of lending to mining.
These changes mirrored movements in value added over the period, with
the manufacturing share in GDP increasing and the mining share falling.
Since 1988 credit growth has accelerated most rapidly in services and
"other" two areas that have not seen a corresponding increase in value
added. This is due to expanding home mortgages, car loans and other consu
mer finance. Part of the increase in 1990 was in response to the govern
ment decree mandating that 20 per cent of a bank's portfolio be lent to
small borrowers. Most consumer loans satisfy the government's criteria. Cri
tics have charged that this consumer and property-development lending
has spurred conspicuous consumption and unhealthy increases in land pri
ces. Experiences in other countries would support the view that lending
to consumers and for commercial real estate is riskier than lending to other
sectors. Indeed, the 1990/91 tight money policy, instituted in part to slow
overall credit growth, took the steam out of the property market and led
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 179
Altering bank cost of funds and thereby bank profitability has had pro
found effects on banks loan pricing, as can be seen in Table 9. Both these
changes should lead, a priori, to an improvement in banks' management
of default risk. Offsetting this, though, is the pressure on banks to build
market share by aggressively expanding their lending portfolios at the cost
of underpricing loans. While this has happened at some banks, margins
in general do not seem to support this conclusion. However the sheer speed
of the growth in credit of some 50 per cent per annum between 1988 and
1991 must have led to a weakening of credit quality8.
Determining which effect has predominated as regards pricing and
allocative efficiency is highly speculative. An answer requires a judgement
about changes in the level of risk in bank portfolios and the adequacy
of measures to cover that risk. One approach to this question is to look
at how loan-loss reserves and provision expenses have behaved over recent
years (Table 10). This approach, however, requires caution for several rea
sons. First, BI portfolio examinations have traditionally focused only on
the status of interest payments and collateral in classifying loans and deter
mining reserve adequacy. Hence, the level of reserves needs not reflect the
underlying financial strength of borrowers. Commercial-bank criteria have
generally been stricter in classifying their portfolios. However, accounting
standards as to when to declare a loan non-performing and how much
to provision were not tightened until 1991 with a two-year phase-in. The
standard for the treatment of accrued income when a loan becomes non
performing was not implemented until early 1991. Prior to that, interest
payments, for example, could be capitalized so that a loan would appear
current although a borrower had made no payments and could conceiva
bly be bankrupt9. Analysis is further complicated by the nature of a great
part of bank lending. Firms generally receive lines of credit that are rolled
over, the so-called "evergreen" loans. If the line is large enough, a company
can easily keep current by simply drawing down the line to meet debt
service. In a period like 1988-90, when aggregate credit growth exceeded
the interest rate for the system on the whole, no one paid off any debt
but instead simply borrowed more. Furthermore, the fastest rise in credit
came in 1989 and 1990 as the overall economy grew at over 7 per cent.
Such strong growth can reduce company loan defaults until economic
growth slows, making it appear that current levels of reserves are adequate,
based on recent experience, but potentially inadequate in the future. Indeed,
as growth slowed in 1991 and 1992 problem loans increased as a share
of bank portfolios. Finally, tax laws limit loan-loss reserve deductibility to
3 per cent of loans for private banks and 6 per cent for State banks, limit
ing banks' interest in exceeding these levels. All of these factors combine
to make drawing conclusions about default risk from loan-loss reserves
tentative.
Table 10
LOAN L O SS RESERVES AND PRO V ISIO N S (%)
With these caveats in mind, the figures in Table 10 show that loan-
loss reserves at all banks rose as a share of loans between 1982 and 1988,
fell in 1989, and since then have increased to levels higher than in 1982.
Provision expenses at state banks measured as a share of the interest mar
gin show a similar pattern since 1988. This fall and subsequent rise in
loan loss reserves is just the opposite of the pattern of credit growth shown
in Table 2. Taken at face value it implies that banks, particularly State
banks, have experienced a deterioration in credit quality during the last
two years. So long as external factors have not dramatically affected the
conditions of borrowers between 1982 and now, this would imply that allo
cative efficiency has worsened, at least since 1990.
One striking feature of the figures on loan-loss reserves and provision
expenses is the sharp difference between the levels at State and private
banks. In 1991, State banks recorded almost four times the loan-loss reser
ves of private banks, and were placing almost half their (smaller) interest
margin into those reserves. Part of this discrepancy reflects sounder port
folios at private banks whose portfolio decisions were more often guided
by profitability. However, the level of reserves at private banks is barely
over the minimum of 1 per cent set by the Bank of Indonesia. For this
low level to be prudent, almost the entire private bank loan portfolio would
need to be sound! The low level of reserves, then, must also reflect attempts
by private banks to bolster profits by foregoing needed provision expenses.
Unfortunately the data do not allow us to compare the size of these unco
vered losses today versus the pre-reform period. One can simply note that
reserves are marginally higher today than in 1982, when the economy was
slowing down sharply, so that the problem may have diminished since
1982.
Harris, et al. (1992) tackle the question of allocative efficiency from a diffe
rent angle, focusing on whether the financial reforms led to a equalization
of the marginal efficiency of investment across different firms. This mea
sure of efficiency has shortcomings since it is an equilibrium concept, while
changes in returns in different sectors due to changing technology, prices,
etc. could alter returns unexpectedly. Using plant level data from a sample
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 183
of about 200 manufacturing firms they find that there was a more efficient
allocation of credit between 1984 and 1988; small and large firms, which
show the highest increases in the productivity of capital and a convergen
ce to the absolute levels of medium-sized firms, increased their access to
credit in the wake of the reforms. Unfortunately, the analysis by Harris,
et al. does not include post-1988 data. Since this is the period when banks
showed increasing loan-loss reserves, it will be important to engage in fur
ther analysis before forming a definitive opinion on the implications of
the financial reform for allocative efficiency.
10 See section C for a fuller discussion of the need for improved risk management and
supervision.
184 D onald P. H an n a
11 One might argue that foreign-exchange deposits are not sufficiently large in a domestic
financial system for their price to be a good reflection of their true value. In Indonesia these
deposits have made up 10-20 per cent of time deposits and 5-10 per cent of demand depo
sits since 1982.
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 185
rest-rate risk, maturity and liquidity risk, as well as the risk of managing
new operations12. Figures for 1982-1988 (Table 4) show that the first stage
of reforms lowered the spread, though the negative number in 1985 pro
bably reflects transaction costs and a relatively thin market. The spread
widened in 1986-1988 as the economy went through macroeconomic ad
justment. In the aftermath of the 1988 reforms, however, the spread again
fell. This decline was accompanied by large increases in capital inflow,
chiefly external borrowing. Nonetheless from 1989 on, the figures show a
steady rise in the difference between on-shore and off-shore dollar depo
sits. Thus, the market believes that risks have increased since 1989.
Summing up the evidence on efficiency and risk, the 1983 reforms have
certainly lowered intermediation margins and fostered credit expansion,
much of it going to profitable firms, including small firms that were pre
viously rationed. Increased lending to consumers, higher provisioning and
higher market perception of financial risk, however, point to a growing
risk in the financial system since 1988 as both the number of banks and
credit growth have surged.
G edit allocation is closely related to the quality and quantity of infor
mation available in the market and the options available to bankers should
a borrower default. Weak accounting standards and a scarcity of practicing
public accountants, lack of registration of collateral and strict banking se
crecy laws all limit the quantity and quality of information available. Ina
dequate bankruptcy laws limit the ability of banks to act against delinquent
debtors. Although steps have been taken to shore up these weaknesses,
their existence makes it easier to understand why financial reforms would
be less effective in improving the efficiency of credit allocation than in
increasing the quantity.
A strong supervisory agency can help to ensure a sounder allocation
of credit by limiting the actions of banks that engage in risky activities,
knowingly or not. As we have noted, Indonesia moved to improve pru-
a) Savings
Sparking savings, particularly by the private sector, was one of the avo
wed goals of financial reform in Indonesia. In judging whether this goal
was achieved we first look at data from the Indonesian flow of funds and
then estimate a private consumption function for Indonesia, focusing on
the effects of financial savings on domestic savings.
The Indonesian flow of funds, available from 1984-89, provides infor
mation on savings and investment from various sectors of the economy,
including firms, households and the government (Table 11). The figures
on domestic savings rates show an 8.5 per cent increase, from 26.4 per
cent to 34.9 per cent of GDP, between 1984 and 198913. This is casual evi
dence of a positive correlation between savings and financial reform. Closer
examination of the figures shows that 7.7 per cent of the increase comes
from private firms which doubled their savings rates. None of the other
sectors show rates of increase anywhere near that size. Private firm savings,
however, include the residual left from adjusting the other sectors savings
rates to the aggregate level taken from the standard national accounts. This
number is probably overestimated for three reasons: first, because the size
of the change is not reflected in other sectors, particularly households; se
13 The figures on savings and investment used in this section rely on official estimates. Other
estimates, prepared by the World Bank, show a similar pattern of savings and investment
but at much lower shares in GDP (see Table 1 for the World Bank estimates).
T he I ndonesian experience wrm financial- sector reform 187
cond, because the aggregate rate of investment, 37 per cent, is one of the
highest in the world; and, third, because inventories make up nearly 10
per cent of the aggregate investment number.
Even if the aggregate domestic savings figures are correct, they only
show a coincidence between financial reforms and increases in savings. To
get a better understanding, we estimated a private consumption function
that controls for other effects. Private consumption was chosen rather than
private savings to reduce the impact of measurement errors on the esti
mation, while taking advantage of the accounting identity that links pri
vate disposable income, consumption and savings. Private, rather than gross
domestic savings, was estimated because of the independence of public sa
vings and financial reform14.
Table 11
STRUCTURE OF SECTORAL G R O SS SA V IN G, 1984-1989
(% of GDP)
14 One could argue that a substantial reform which increased demand for M l would increase
government seignorage and, ceteris paribus, increase public savings. As we have seen above,
M l/G D P did increase after 1988. Nonetheless, treating expenditures or tax revenues as
given is not realistic since they are both instruments of fiscal policy and therefore their
movements will reflect both policy changes and exogenous factors.
188 D onald P. H an n a
15 For reviews of savings in developing countries see Schmidt-Hebbel and Webb (1992), Deaton
(1989) and Fry (1988).
T he I ndonesian experience with financial- sector reform 189
savings reduces domestic savings since the former do not solely finance
additional investment.
Finally and most importantly for this paper, the amount of financial
wealth has been posited as a determinant of private savings. The argument
is that greater levels of financial wealth imply fewer liquidity constraints
on borrowers and therefore higher consumption levels. Note that this pre
mise runs opposite to the usual argument that financial reform, by increas
ing interest rates, will increase savings.
Using the independent variables just discussed -permanent income,
liquidity, foreign and public savings, the real interest rate and inflation-
we estimated a private consumption function using annual data from 1970
through 1991. The data were taken from a database maintained by BI. All
variables were logs of current values, except for the real interest rate and
foreign savings, the latter appearing as a share of private disposable in
come. Permanent income was calculated as a three-year moving average
of private disposable income (Schmidt-Hebbel and Webb, 1992). Public sa
vings were taken from national accounts and exclude public enterprises.
The real interest rate was calculated using the three-month average time
deposit rate and actual consumer price inflation for the year in question.
The results of the least squares regression of private consumption on
the five variables and a constant shown in Table 12 show an excellent
fit and no sign of first-order autocorrelation. Since several variables were
not stationary, an Engle-Granger test for unit roots in the estimated equa
tion was done using the first difference of private consumption. As expected,
the sign of logged private consumption was negative. However, due to
a fairly small sample size the non-stationary hypothesis cannot be rejec
ted. There is a large and significant correlation between private consumption
and permanent income, with an elasticity of .93, very dose to the theoretical
life-cyde value of one. Government savings come in with a unexpectedly
positive and significant sign. This could be the result of the high correlation
between oil prices and government savings, meaning that higher savings
did not result from increased taxes with their contractionary effect on pri
vate consumption, but rather from additional income from abroad. This
conjecture is consistent with the negative, though insignificant, coeffident
on the foreign saving rate. The real interest rate and inflation have negative
and insignificant coeffidents.
190 D o n a ld P . H anna
Table 12
DETERMINANTS OF PRIVATE CONSUMPTION, 1970-1991
b) Investment
Most prescriptions for financial reform call for stable macroeconomic con
ditions on the eve of financial reform (e.g. Caprio and Atiyàs, 1992). Prefe
rence is generally given to opening the financial system after the current
account and before the capital account (Hanson, 1992), and the references
dted therein). The Indonesian experience with finandal reform shows that
within limits neither a stable economy nor a dosed capital account is ne
cessary for successful finandal reform. As was discussed in section II, In
donesia in 1983 was in the midst of a serious stabilization program to
adjust to the effects of deteriorating external conditions. Inflation, though
relatively low at just over 10 per cent, was accelerating. A yawning current
account defidt of 7.4 per cent of GDP needed to be financed. The capital
account had been open for over a decade, while a web of trade and invest
ment regulations restricted the current account. Nonetheless, the freeing of
interest rates and elimination of credit ceilings successfully boosted finan
cial and domestic savings.
Rather than condudve external conditions, the Indonesia experience
spotlights the need for macroeconomic management that recognizes and
adjusts to the constraints imposed by the external environment and the
government's own budget limitations. Adjustment to the external environ
ment was the thrust of the 1982-83 stabilization program with its major
devaluation and extensive fiscal adjustment. The fiscal balance moved from
a deficit of 24 per cent of GDP in 1983 to a surplus of 1.4 per cent. Deva
luation provided the real depreciation needed to reach external balance,
while fiscal adjustment made the real depreciation stick. In these efforts,
the open capital account and the government's commitment to avoid fi
nancing the fiscal deficit from domestic sources played a critical role in
conditioning the response of the economy. Commitment to the open capi
tal account with a quasi-fixed exchange rate meant that attempts to soften
the external blow by loose monetary policy would lead to capital outflows
T h e I n d o n e s ia n e x p e r ie n c e w it h f in a n c ia l - s e c t o r r e fo r m 193
IV. CONCLUSIONS
risk all point to increasing risk since 1988. Given the difficulties in allo
cating credit because of information and incentive problems, it is not
surprising that efficiency gains are more elusive. These information and
incentive problems highlight the need for improvements in the legal ac
counting and prudential systems that support efficient financial systems.
Indonesia's reform efforts were generally successful despite several
factors that differed from standard prescriptions. First, Indonesia's capital
account was open at the time of reforms; second, reform began in a time
of serious macroeconomic adjustment. Indonesia's experience highlights the
need for macroeconomic management that recognizes the limitations im
posed by the external budget constraint and that of the government rather
than macroeconomic stability per se, and responds quickly to those cons
traints. Indeed the open capital account aided macroeconomic management
by providing quick feed-back when domestic policies moved out of line
and limiting the inflationary consequences of excessive demand stimulus.
The absence of domestic finance for fiscal deficits removed an important
source of pressure on domestic financial markets. Quick response to exter
nal imbalance, backed by strong fiscal adjustment, aided the successful re
forms in 1983. Overly stimulatory monetary policy, and a private-sector
savings-investment gap which was not sufficiently offset by fiscal policy,
exacerbated the credit expansion of 1989-90. Furthermore, the slow respon
se of fiscal policy put more of the burden of adjustment on monetary po
licy, keeping interest rates high and thereby prolonging the problem of
non-performing loans within the banking system. Adroit macroeconomic
management can thus promote successful financial reform even in periods
of macroeconomic adjustment with a economy open to speculative capital
flows.
196 D on a ld P . H a n n a
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Ahmed, Sadiq and Basant K. Kapur (1990), How Indonesia's Monetary Po
licy Affects Key Variables, Policy, Research and External Affairs Papers,
WPS 349, World Bank.
Balino, Tomas J.T. and V. Sundararajan (1986). "Financial Reform in Indone
sia" in H.S. Cheng, Financial Policy and Reform in Pacific Basin Coun
tries, Singapore: Oxford University Press.
Barro, Robert (1988), "Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?", Journal of Po
litical Economy, Vol. 82.
Bemanke, Ben S. and Mark Gertler (1986). Agency Costs, Collateral and Bu
siness Fluctuations, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Pa
per #2015, September.
Caprio, Gerard (1992), Policy Uncertainty, Information Asymmetries, and Fi
nancial Intermediation, Country Economics Department, World Bank, Po
licy Research Working Paper, WPS 853.
Caprio, Gerard and Izak Atiyas (1992), "Policy Issues in Reforming Finance:
Lessons and Strategies," The Economic Development Institute (EDI)
World Bank.
Caprio, Gerard et al. (1990), "Research Proposal: The Impact of Financial
Reform", Financial Policy and Systems Division, Country Economics
Department, World Bank.
Center for Strategic and International Studies (1990), Survey of Recent De
velopments, Jakarta: CSIS, September.
Chant, John F. and Mari Pangestu (1992). "An Assessment o f Financial Re
form in Indonesia: 1983-1990," World Bank, Washington.
(1988), 'The Analysis of Efficiency of Indonesia Banking", mimeo.
Cheng, Hang-Sheng (1986), Financial Policy and Reform in Pacific Basin Coun
tries, Lexington, Lexington Books, Mass.
Cole, David C. and Betty F. Slade (1990), "Financial Development in Indo
nesia," Economic and Development Institute, W orld Bank.
de Juan, Aristóbulo (1987), "From Good Bankers to Bad Bankers: Ineffec
tive Supervision and Management Deterioration as Major elements in
Banking Crises," Country Economic Department, World Bank.
Deaton, Angus (1989), "Saving in Developing Countries: Theory and Re
T h e I n d o n e s ia n e x p e r ie n c e w it h f in a n c ia l - s e c t o r r e fo r m 197
Andras W. U th ofP
1 This paper is based on national case studies carried out under ECLAC/UNDP projects
RLA/90/001 and RLA/192/003, "Finandal Policies for Development". These case studies
have been published by ECLAC in separate edited volumes (Uthoff and Szalachman, 1991
and 1993 (forthcoming), and Iglesias and Acuña, 1991).
2 The author wishes to thank Gunther Held for his comments on an earlier draft of this paper.
The author has also benefited from comments received at different ECLAC seminars.
3 The views expressed in this study, which has been reproduced without formal editing by
ECLAC, are those of its author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the organizations.
CONTENTS
V. CONCLUSIONS................................................................................................................... 237
P e n s io n s y s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n a n d . 205
INTRODUCTION
5 See ECLAC, 1992, "Pension Systems in Latin America: Diagnosis and Reform Alternatives".
Case Studies in Latin America and the Caribbean. Conclusions and Recommendations.
Santiago, 3-5 December 1990 and 22-23 August 1991. ECLAC, Santiago de Chile, September
1992.
P e n sio n sy s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 207
month for the number of years given in each column (30, 35, 40 and 45),
with contributions capitalized at the real rates of returns given in each
row (-5, -3, 0, 3, 5).
The amount of savings obtained after this person retires (Part 1 of
the Table), and its equivalent in pensionable years with a pension equal
to constant real salary (100 pesos) (part 2 of the Table), indicates that un
less real capitalization rates are set at around 5 per cent, the system will
provide pension benefits far below the average real level of earnings (given
the 10 per cent contribution rate). Thus, with low capitalization rates the
system would need higher contribution rates to achieve the goal of pension
benefits equal to the earnings of the last working years, an d /or the exten
sion of the working lifespan (increased retirement age). Quite to the con
trary, higher capitalization rates would allow for better pension benefits
a n d /or extension of life expectancy at the age of retirement (earlier reti
rement), a n d /or lower contribution rates.
Returns on systems based on capitalization schemes depend on the
composition of the investment portfolio of the funds and capital-market
performance. In turn, returns on simple pay-as-you-go schemes are set equal
to the rate of change of real wages plus that of the number of contribu
tors minus the rate of growth of life expectancy at the age of retire
ment. Systems combining both schemes have a return which results from
a weighted average of the two above.
Table 1
SIMULATION OF INDIVIDUAL PENSION BENEFITS:
IMPORTANCE OF CAPITALIZATION IN DEALING
WITH SHORT-SIGHTED ATTITUDESf*)
Table 1 (Conl.)
Despite the original design, pension systems have been merged with
other social-security contingency systems (e.g., job-related accidents and
professional sickness, non-job-related accidents and non-professional health
and maternity care and leave for the working mother, maternity and health
care for dependents, dependent allowances, national health systems or pu
blic health programmes). It has been very common practice, on the basis
of arguments in favour of redistributing income by creating a social-securi
ty net, to use pension system reserve funds to expand the population and
contingency coverage under social security. This practice has been mentio
ned as one of the main factors contributing to the financial and actuarial
deficits of the pension system. Use of reserve funds to cover temporary
fiscal deficits, which are not repaid by the State, and use of funds for
social-security purposes other than defined pensions, have been justified
on the grounds of improving equity and the result of joint management
of all social security schemes (Uthoff and Szalachman, 1991 and 1993)7.
7 See for details, Uthoff, Andras and Raquel Szalachman 1991 Sistemas de Pensiones en
America Latina. Diagnóstico y alternativas de reforma. Costa Rica, Ecuador, Uruguay,
Venezuela. CEPAL, Proyecto Regional Políticas Financieras para el Desarrollo. Santiago de
Chile, and Uthoff Andras and Raquel Szalachman 1993 Sistemas de Pensiones en América
Latina. Diagnóstico y alternativas de reforma. Volumen 2. Bolivia, Brazil, Guatemala,
México, Colombia. CEPAL, Proyecto Regional Políticas Financieras para el Desarrollo.
Santiago de Chile.
210 A n d r a s W. U t h o f f
8 See CEPAL, 1990 Transformación productiva con equidad. La tarea prioritaria del desa
rrollo de América Latina y el Caribe en la década del noventa. Naciones Unidas, Santiago
de Chile.
P e n s io n s y s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 211
Table 2
PROBLEMS AND POSSIBLE REFORMS IN PAY-AS-YOU-GO SYSTEM
To improve collection Evasion and/or delays To create incentives Creation of unique list
of funds in payment of social for punctual payment of contributors and
security taxes, debt of social security con dependen ts;creation of
from the state as an tribution taxes, to crea individual accounts;
employer, lack of con te mechanisms to ne inspection of payments
tributions from inde gotiate employer debt. and indexed instru
pendent workers. ments to charge real
interestrates to debtors
to the system; indexed
government bonds;
simplification of pro
cedures.
Investment of reserve Low returns on re Regulation and super Creation of regulation
funds serve fund investment vision of investment and supervisory insti
portfolio; use of funds portfolio; development tution; risk classifica
for other government of capital markets; se tion commission; fi
executed programmes; paration of govern nancial interm edia
lack of indexed ins ment programme ad tion; periodic and pu
truments to cope with ministration. blic balances of social
inflation. security accounts; se
paration of fiscal ac
counts by social secu
rity and other govern
ment programmes.
Solidarity and wider Systems cover only a Development of mixed Use of funds in indivi
population coverage. small share of the la systems with a basic dual accounts as co
bour force and its de minimum pension and llateral for access to
pendents; there are supplements based on personal credits; stan
large population individual savings ef dardized minimum
groups facing income forts; development of pension; self-financing
restrictions. incentives to promote of additional pension
212 A n d r a s W. U t h o f f
Table 2 (Cont.)
To make pension be- Individual pension be- Relate pensions to mi- Age at retirement and
nefits bear relation to nefits bear no relation nimums determined pension benefit s
contributions. to changes in life-time by law and comple- according toabalanced
contributions; exis- ment them with addi- formula taking into
tence of non-eligible tional benefits accord- account life expectancy
beneficiaries; indexa- ing to life-time addi- at retirement and pre-
tion of pension be- tional voluntary con- vious contributions;
nefits which bear no tributions and their flexibilization of age at
relation to indexation capitalization. retirement on the basis
of financing sources of of adjustment of pen-
the system. sion to similar formula
as above; implement a
basic minimum pen
sion anda self-financed
supplement; develop
ment of life insurance
schemes; development
of indexed instruments
to be used in the ope
ration of the system;
regulation and super
vision of eligible de
pendents; elimination
ofprivilegesbearingno
relation to contribu
tions.
9 For details see Augusto Iglesias and Rodrigo Acuña, 1991. Sistema de Pensiones en Amé
rica Latina. Chile: Experiencia con un Régimen de Capitalización 1981-1991. CEPAL. Pro
yecto Políticas Financieras para el Desarrollo. Santiago, Octubre 1991.
10 For details see Ayala, Ulpiano 1992 Un Sistema Pensionai de Capitalización Individual pa
ra Colombia. Documento para el Proyecto Regional CEPAL/PNUD "Políticas Financieras
para el Desarrollo". CEPAL, Santiago, Chile Noviembre de 1992. And also Schulthess, Wal
ter, 1992 "Sistema Nacional de Previsión Social de la Argentina y Propuesta de Reforma"
Documento para el Seminario Regulación y Supervisión de la Banca" y "Reforma al Sistema
de Pensiones y Ahorro Institucional" en América Latina. CEPAL, Santiago de Chile,
Noviembre 1992.
11 Camargo, J. M. 1991, Pensión Funds in Brazil. Paper prepared for the Seminar on "Pension
Systems in Latin America: Diagnosis and Reform Alternatives" ECLAC Joint ECLAC/UNDP
Regional Project" Financial Policies for Development. Santiago de Chile.
214 A n d ras W . U th o ff
12 For further details see, William Me. Greevey. Social Security in Latin America. Issues and
Options for the World Bank World Bank Discussion Papers 110. The World Bank,
Washington D.C. November 1990 and Carmelo Mesa-Lago 1991. "Social Security and Eco
nomic Adjustment-Restructuring in Latin America and the Caribbean. A Study for the
International Labour Office. University of Pittsburgh, December 1991.
P e n s io n s y s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in -L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 215
system financially and actuarially sound and separated from other govern
ment redistributive programmes. The conditions to achieve this goal are
given in the next section.
Table 3
EARNINGS PROFILES AND SIMULATIONS. SIMULATIONS OF CONDITIONS
TO ACHIEVE UNIVERSAL PENSION EQUAL TO PER CAPITA GDP
Parameters Simulations
Wage
GDP Share of earnings Contrib. Years needed
per capita population % Rate to achieve si
(approx. 1990) 65+ GDP milar pension
(US$ of 1980) (%) (%) (%)
Latin America 1,872 4.7 - - -
nings in real terms, less the rate of increase in life expectancy at the age
of retirement (e.g., 65 for males and 60 for females)13. That is why actua
rial studies of such systems often recommend, as some of the suggestions
in Table 2 do, either increasing contribution rates, reducing pension bene
fits (both in terms of coverage and the level of the benefit), increasing
the age at retirement, or a combination of all three.
These parameters are particularly relevant to Latin America and the
Caribbean. Demographic transition varies both between and within countries
according to the socio-economic level, affecting basic demographic para
meters which in turn influence pension system performance. On the average,
in 1950 the total population of the region (some 89 million) grew at a
rate above that of the 15 to 64 age group (the potential labour force parti
cipants). Statistics showed 78 persons at passive ages (below 15 and above
65 years old) per 100 persons at active ages. These elderly (above 65) repre
sented only 8 per cent of the total passive population, or one elderly per
son per 17 persons at active ages. From 1960 onwards, the total fertility
rate in Latin America declined sharply and the trends in the above indica
tors changed dramatically. In 1990, the total population was estimated at
260 million, more than triple the 1950 figures. The dependency ratio fell
to 69 persons at passive ages per 100 persons at active ages (after rising
to a maximum of 87 in 1970). One out of eight passive persons is elderly
and there are less than 13 persons at working ages per each person over
65 (CELADE, 1990)14.
These characteristics are far less important in terms of ageing than
has been the case in Western Europe. In that region, those aged 60 and
above currently represent 20 per cent of the total population and two-thirds
of the total passive population (Chesnais, 1989)15. However, as a distinctive
feature of Latin America, ageing is taking place together with relatively
high population growth rates in all age groups: those in need of education,
13 Larrain, Felipe and Gert Wagner 1982 Previsión Social, Algunas Consideraciones. Instituto
de Economía, Universidad Católica de Chile, Documento de Trabajo N2 84.
14 For further details, see CELADE, 1990 America Latina. Proyecciones de Población. Boletín
Demográfico. Año XXII, Ns 45, Santiago de Chile.
15 See Chesnais, J. C. 1989 L'inversion de la pyramide des ages en Europe: perspectives et
problems. "Congres International de la Population, N2 3. New Delhi.
218 A ndras W . U th o ff
those in need of jobs, and those in need of pension benefits. This brings
us to the important issue of the allocation of investment resources for growth
with equity and environmental sustainability. The investment in human ca
pital throughout the different stages of a person's life becomes a crucial
element which also strongly encourages political pressures on the alloca
tion of pension system reserve funds.
Another important feature of the region is the extremely heteroge
neous nature of the relationship between potential contributors and bene
ficiaries within each system. This is the result of a highly segmented labour
market. The poorer segments do not participate in formal pension fund
systems but instead are organized through intrafamiliar solidarity schemes,
operating via extended families in which those in the labour force contri
bute with their income to satisfy the needs of all the young and the aged
and those of working age, although well below the standards of any rea
sonable poverty line. Elsewhere, workers employed in the modem sectors
contribute to compulsory public pay-as-you-go schemes, whereby those in
the labour force finance the pension benefits of the retired with the expec
tation that future generations will in turn pay for them. At present, some
formal-sector workers have access to private capitalization schemes, in which
each generation contributes savings and investment needed to supplement
its pension benefits. The coexistence of all these formal and informal pen
sion systems is the result of the structure of the labour market in Latin
America. It is hard to believe that population coverage of formal systems
will increase without radical changes in labour market structures an d/or
the creation of very particular and innovative incentives to join the formal
compulsory institutional schemes. None of these events is likely to take
place in the near future.
In fact, between 1950 and 1980 Latin America's share of m odem or
formal employment, to which an institution pension-fund scheme is more
suitable, increased by only 5 percentage points (from 52 to 57 per cent)
of the total labour force. The rest of the employed pertained to traditional
agricultural activities (self-employed, peasants and non-remunerated family
workers) or to informal non-agricultural activities an d /or domestic service,
where control of compliance with labour legislation and the collection of
compulsory taxes for social security purposes is more difficult. This posi
tive trend in formal/modern employment creation was halted during the
P e n s io n s y s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 219
16 For further details on these trends see PREALC, 1982 Mercado de Trabajo en cifras 1959-
1980 PREALC-OIT Santiago de Chile, and also PREALC, 1990 Empleo y equidad, el desafío
de los 90 PREALC-OIT Santiago de Chile.
17 See CEPAL, 1985. El desafío de la seguridad social en América Latina Estudios e informes
de la CEPAL, Santiago de Chile. ECLAC, 1989 The Elderly in Latin America: A strategic
Sector for Social Policy in the 1990s LC/R 833 December 1989, and Mesa-Lago 1990 La se
guridad social y el sector informal Investigaciones sobre empleo 32. PREALC, Santiago.
220 A ndras W . U th o ff
Table 4
ESTIMATED OLD-AGE PENSION BENEFITS:
ALTERNATIVE HYPOTHESES
(As percentage of net earnings from last 10 working years,)
For different initial net earnings brackets, Table 4 computes the pension
benefit an individual worker starting his/her working life at the age of
22 would receive had his/her net life earnings profile increased by 2 per
cent per annum in real terms up to age 50 and remained stable thereafter.
The difference by gender is due to the earlier retirement of women (at
age 60) as compared to men (at age 65). This means that the former con
tribute during a shorter period and need pension benefits for a longer pe
riod (due to their greater life expectancy at the age of retirement). This
explains why the relation between the monthly pension benefit for w o
men, compared to the average last ten years net earnings, is significantly
below that for men. But the table also shows that fixed commissionsimple
mented to bear the cost of administrating individual accountsareregressi
ve, in the sense that they lead to lower returns for those in the lower
net earnings brackets.
P e n s io n sy s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 221
Three changes have been pointed out as the most important in order to
balance public-sector accounts: the financing of social-security system defi
cits, the autonomy and solvency of the Central Bank, and the elimination
and reduction of all quasi-fiscal deficits in the financial system.
In relation to the topic of this paper, the first change is straightforward.
222 A ndras W . U th o ff
A second set of conditions deals with reforms to the banking system (Held
and Szalachmann, 1991 and 1992, ECLAC, 1992)18. These can be presented
in two stages. First, macroeconomic adjustment needs to be complemented
by intermediation through the financial system in order to allow an efficient
allocation of resources. A precondition is the financial solvency of banks
and firms. Otherwise, financial liberalization and international competition
through gradual opening of the capital account may prove inimical to heal
thy development of the domestic financial sector. The steps taken to libera
lize the capital market in order to achieve monetary autonomy, free ca
pital flows and exchange rate management must start with a reasonably
solvent domestic banking system.
Regulatory structures through which the State may establish bank
and financial-institution "rules of the game" for deposits and loans is a
second stage. These include prudential regulation, to control banking risks,
financial insolvency and illiquidity; financial regulation, oriented towards
interest and exchange rates, currency denomination, instrument maturity
18 For further details on the regulation and supervision of banks and financial institutions, see
Held and Szalachman 1991, Regulación y Supervision de la Banca. Experiencias de América l a
tina y el Caribe. Argentina, Costa Rica, Chile, República Dominicana. CEPAL, PNUD. Proyecto
Regional Políticas Financieras para el Desarrollo, Santiago de Chile; also Held and Szalachman,
1992, Regulación y Supervisión de la Banca. Experiencias de América Latina y el Caribe. Volumen 2.
Guatemala, México, Paraguay, Perú, Venezuela. CEPAL, PNUD. Proyecto Regional Políticas
Financieras para el Desarrollo, Santiago de Chile, and ECLAC, 1992, "Regulation and Super
vision of Banks and Financial Institutions. Case Studies in Latin América and the Caribbean. Serie
Financiamiento del Desarrollo N2 8. Santiago dc Chile.
P e n s io n s y st e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 223
periods, and other conditions related to the price and value of both do
mestic and foreign assets and liabilities; and finally, organizational regu
lation, to seek bank and financial institutional operational efficiency
through economies of scale, the integration of economic activities and the
promotion of competition among financial institutions.
Supervision of banks and financial institutions entails verification of
compliance with the prudential, financial and organizational rules and
regulations which govern their activities as financial intermediaries. (See
the chapter by Held in this volume.)
Last but not least are the reforms needed to promote the development
of securities and insurance markets. Competition in these markets also re
quires three regulations: regulations for entry into the particular market;
prudential regulation for those operating in the market; and motivational
regulation for expanding the financial market.
Entrants into these markets must demonstrate financial solvency by
fulfilling legal and financial requirements as an intermediary, and provide
information about all financial instruments and conditions that will keep
the market transparent. This includes registration of instruments to be issued
and intermediated in the stock market, with the commitment to provide
public and periodical information on their financial status, and secondly,
registration of intermediaries in the stock market that will accept regula
tory norms and supervision of their activities by independent institutions
in order to maintain a minimum level of professional conduct, thus wa
rranting a competitive and equitative intermediation of securities.
Prudential regulation of these markets is mainly concerned with three
factors: market entry conditions -minimum capital and property require
ments; an investment insurance guarantee scheme; and portfolio quality
control standards and risk limitations. Two separate institutional develop
ments in this area are the Deposit or Custody of Securities and the Risk
Classification Commission. The first keeps track of all deposits, liquidations
and other transactions, in accounts which also perform multilateral elec
tronic balancing. The classification of risks is a service provided by spe
cialized agencies, in order to carry out ongoing evaluation of firms offering
224 A n d r a s W. U t h o f f
The reform in Chile has drawn a great deal of attention due to its radical
transition from a pay-as-you-go public system to an individual capitalization
scheme, and also due to its relative success during its first ten years. This
experience has been described in ECLAC's case study (Iglesias and Acuña,
1991) and elsewhere (Arrau, 1992; and Montt 1992)19.
19 An exhaustive description of the reform is given by Iglesias, Augusto and R. Acuña. 1991
Sistema de Pensiones en América Latina. Chile: Experiencia con un Régimen de Capitalización 1981-
1991. Proyecto Políticas Financieras para el Desarrollo, CEPAL/PNUD Santiago de Chile.
Summary reviews of the reform are given by Arrau, Patricio. 1992 El Nuevo Régimen previsio-
n d Chileno Seminario Internacional de Reformas al Régimen Pensionai, Bogota, Colombia,
Mayo 20-21 de 1992; and Montt, Diego, in The Chilean Private Pension Fund System Superinten
dencia de Administradoras de Fondos de Pensión-Chile presented at Workshop on "Emerging
Markets, Current Issues", Bolsa de Comercio de Buenos Aires, 23,24 November 1992.
P e n s io n s y s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 225
The system operates under very strict regulations which can be summari
zed as follows:
The effects of the pension system reform will now be analyzed in terms
of four important results: population coverage; level of pension benefits;
financial market developments; and national savings and investment.
In general, these types of evaluations are very hard to perform, largely
due to the difficulty in identifying the standard of comparison. If, as is
often done, the results of the new systems are compared to those of the
old system, this is said to be unfair since it is precisely due to its poor
P e n s io n sy s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 227
results that the latter is being replaced. If, quite to the contrary, the system
is assessed on absolute terms, then supporters claim unfairness because it
ignores the starting conditions. On the whole, as will be made clear, no
definite evaluations have been made, and further research is under way
on these matters.
Table 5
PRUDENTIAL REGULATION OF PENSION FUND INVESTMENTS:
CHILEAN LIMITS SET BY LAW ACCORDING TO INSTRUMENTS
1. Government instruments 45
(Treasury and Central Bank)
2. Mortgages 80
3. Long-term savings, other securities
from approved financial institutions 50
Short-term (less than one year) 30
4. Public and private sector bonds 50
5. Shares from other pension funds 20
6. Corporate shares
a. non-concentrated property 30
b. real state corporations 10
c. concentrated property 10
7. Shares of investment funds 10
8. Commerce 10
9. Finandal instruments from abroad 10(a)
(a) From O ctober 1996 onwards
Source: Iglesias y Acuña 1991, op. cit.
mal sectors who had not contributed to the old system were ineligible for
the main incentive, that being a compensation bonus.
As given in Table 6, population coverage measured by share of the
labour force shows that whereas affiliates have come to represent 86 per
cent of the labour force, those actually contributing to the system have
never increased above 55 per cent. The causes of this poor result should
be eliminated in order for coverage to increase. As mentioned before, this
responds to the labour market structure in Chile, still with a high share
of independent informal workers, together with a large incidence of p o
verty (Uthoff and Pollack 1990)20. Other authors have also mentioned that
the situation results from loss of jobs; lack of incentive for independent
workers to contribute; delays in contributions by employers; people for
merly in the labour force w ho are retired and do not qualify; and partici
pants in the old system (estimated below 10 per cent of the labour force)
(Arrau, op. cit.).
Tableó
POPULATION COVERAGE UNDER THE NEW PENSION SYSTEM
(as a porcentage of total labour force)
1981 39.0 - -
20 Uthoff, Andras and Molly Pollack. 1989. Poverty and the Labour Market: Greater Santiago, 1969-
85 in Rodgers Gerry, ed. Urban Poverty and the Labour Market. Access to Jobs and Incomes
in Asian and Latin American Cities. ILO, Geneva.
P e n s io n sy s t e m r e f o r m s a n d s a v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n a n d .. 229
It has not been possible to make a definite and general comparison bet
ween the amount of pension benefits received in the old and new system.
The problem lies in the difficulties in estimating the pension benefit after
full maturity of the new system. Such an exercise involves an estimate
of the expected active life-cycle income (which in turn requires assumptions
concerning labour productivity increases according to human capital en
dowments to estimate longitudinal earning profiles). It also involves an es
timate of returns during the capitalization period and standarization proce
dures with respect to age and life expectancy at retirement.
Table 7
FINANCING AND CHARACTERISTICS OF PENSIONS
Table 8 indicates the amount of the cumulated fund and its portfolio invest
ment composition. Only after 1985 were pension fund managers authori
zed to invest in the stock market. But it was not until 4 years later, in
1989, that these firms decided to go about it professionally. Between 1989
and 1992, the market value of common stock in pension fund portfolios
multiplied by 10, from US$ 350 to US$ 3.3 billion. A note of caution must
be sounded before extrapolating this behaviour. Again it is hard to isolate
the impact of the pension-fund purchasing power from that of at least three
other phenomena that can also help to explain the same figures: first, dur
ing the same period, capital flows from abroad increased significantly and
currency revalued in United States dollars by about 20 per cent; second,
Chile has witnessed seven years of strong economic growth that started
P e n s io n s y st e m r e f o r m s a n d sa v in g s in L a t in A m e r ic a n and. 231
in 1985, just when pension funds were authorized to invest in the stock
market, and has averaged above 6 per cent per year; and third, since 1985
the real average price index of shares (i.e., after allowing for inflation) has
recorded a 500 per cent increase, of which half occurred after 1989 (see
Table 9).
An important conclusion with respect to the relationship between pen-
sion-fund developments and financial market behavior is their contributions
to expanding the financial system. This is the result of a relatively young
system, which, together with the exponential accumulation of investment
income in the individual funds of those of contributing age, justifies a lar
ge share of resources to be intermediated in financial markets.
The last column in Table 8 contains one indicator of financial expan
sion in Chile. Pension funds as a percentage of GDP grew from less than
one per cent in 1981 to above 38 in 1992. Projections show that this share
will level out at above 100 per cent of GDP by the year 2020 and before
the system has completely matured.
The portfolio investment composition in Table 8 also shows extensive
diversification and changes as the result of very strict regulations which ha
ve subsequently been modified. Highly concentrated on bank deposits and
bonds (62 per cent) in the earlier stages, it is now more heavily weighted
toward Central Bank and Treasury bonds (37 per cent) and common stocks
(28 per cent).
Despite conservative regulations to avoid risks to institutional inves
tors, returns on these investments have averaged, during the first 12 years
of existence of the system, well above real interest rates in the financial
system for the same period (see Table 10). Nevertheless a note of caution
is also needed here. When analysing the results for 1992, one must obser
ve that returns in real terms have dropped to 4 per cent, which contrasts
with the excellent performance of Chile's economy during that same year,
considered to be the best in the last 30 years (CEPAL, 1992)21.
Table 8
PORTFOLIO COMPOSITION OF PENSION FUNDS IN % (CHILE)
Table 9
STOCK MARKET AND PENSION FUND PORTFOLIO
Table 10
PENSION FUNDS: CHILE
Real Rate of Return on Fund Investments (%)
This result, however, is not sustainable in the long run, as would seem from
the fact that for 1992 real returns on such investments fell to four per cent.
Table 11
SAVINGS AND INVESTMENT IN CHILE
(% of GDP)
creased quite significantly. The second is that despite the unusually high
public-sector savings figures for 1980-81, what really happened is that pu-
blic-sector savings capacity was affected, reverting to its more traditional
figures. This is^xiue l o large increases in social-security deficits resulting
from the transition from one^system to another. This deficit is estimated
to have reached close to 5 per cent of GDP during 1989-91.
Table 12
SOCIAL-SECURITY DEFICIT ASSOCIATED WITH REFORM
(% GDP)
Aside from the above issues related to the financial market, there still are
some challenges linked to its current structure and functioning. There are
also problems of a different nature.
236 A ndras W . U th o ff
b) Other challenges
V. CONCLUSIONS
* This paper draws heavily on country case studies undertaken for the joint ECLAC/UNDP
regional project on Financial Policies for Development.
** I would like to thank Luis F. Jiménez for his very helpful comments. However, responsibi
lity for this paper rests solely with the author.
CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION
Since the mid-1970s financial liberalization has been part of structural re
form in Latin American and Caribbean countries. Liberalization of bank
credit and of interest rates and related measures on funding and on the
structure of the banking system have characterized policy measures. Only
recently have security markets and stock exchanges in some of the more
developed countries of the region become important to financial develop
ment.
Solvency and efficiency are closely interrelated criteria of bank per
formance. A solvent bank is able to pay its deposits and other liabilities
without drawing on its capital or own funds1. Bank efficiency can be apprai
sed at two levels: operational efficiency in carrying out financial and servi
ces transactions at minimum cost, that is, at a minimum "spread" between
lending and deposit rates of interest; and allocational efficiency when mak
ing loans and granting credit to socially profitable projects. Allocational
efficiency includes operational or cost efficiency as well as the capacity of
banks to attract deposits and make loans at competitive interest rates2.
This paper seeks to highlight the factors which determined the out
come of financial liberalization experiences in Latin American and Caribbean
countries in the 1970s and 1980s. Emphasis is given to country cases where
these experiences led to solvency problems or severe financial crises.
The performance of banks as regards solvency and efficiency depends
mainly on the following:
a) Macroeconomic factors and policies determining output variability
growth and relative price changes. These factors affect the level and
variability of profit and income, i.e., the "first" loan repayment sour
ces of firms and households; they thus also affect risks of loss in
bank loan and asset portfolios.
b) Regulations and norms which set the "rules of the game” of banking
and the supervision of their compliance.
c) Internal bank management of loans, credit and financial investments
in terms of "safe and sound" portfolio practices.
Macroeconomic conditions and policies can have a major effect on
bank solvency and efficiency. Here, only a brief outline of such conditions
and policies will be provided as part of the environment in which finan
cial liberalization experiences took place. Bank management also ranks high
in determining bank performance. However, it will not be taken up except
for noting that loan, credit and financial-investment practices depend signi
ficantly on bank regulation and supervision.
The main issues of this paper refer to bank regulation and supervi
sion and their relations to liberalization and financial instability. The paper
consists of three sections. The first provides an account of the different
types of regulations which shape the framework of banking activities. It
deals with financial liberalization, prudential regulation and alternative
arrangements for controlling bank solvency. The second section looks at
the financial liberalization of the Chilean banking system. This experience
is of particular interest since it has gone full circle -from swift liberaliza
tion in the 1970s, to a heavy financial crisis at the beginning of the 1980s,
a far-reaching bank reform in the mid-1980s, and since then, to renewed
financial liberalization and proposed additional reforms to the banking
structure. The third section contains an overview of a large sample of fi
nancial liberalization experiences in Latin American and Caribbean countries
during the 1970s and 1980s which resulted in solvency problems and fi
nancial instability. This section seeks to highlight common factors behind
this outcome. The paper ends with a summary of conclusions.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y in . 247
1. Financial regulation
Norms seeking to control the flow and intermediation of funds are mainly
geared to price stability and efficient allocation of resources. The Central
Bank (or other financial regulator) may set norms on interest rates and
the exchange rate, taking into account macroeconomic conditions and the
competitiveness of domestic financial instruments (the latter should be able
to attract and keep funds denominated in domestic currency). It may also
regulate bank reserve requirements and foreign-capital flows to control the
growth of the supply of money, the channelling of credit in certain directions
(deemed socially profitable), and other aspects related to the pricing and
availability of financial resources.
Financial regulations may set interest rates a n d /or the exchange rate
too low, or below equilibrium levels. They may impose heavy reserve
requirements, low-yield public-sector financial investments and other "quasi
fiscal" burdens on banks, and put other restrictions on raising and allocat
ing funds, all of which reduce the real rate of growth and the real size
of funds in relation to GDP or other non-finandal magnitudes. According
to the financial liberalization approach, in this case, regulations cause fi
nancial "repression" and lead to a backward or "shallow" financial system,
represented typically by a few oligopolistic banks and a fragmented finan
cial system. Furthermore, in real terms, regulations on interest rates and
exchange rates would discourage savings and hence capital formation, ex
ports and the production of tradeables4.
3 E. Marshall, "El Banco Central como Regulador y Supervisor del Sistema Financiero", Reu
nión de Gobernadores de Bancos Centrales, Santiago, October 1991.
4 E. Shaw, Financial Deepening in Economic Development, (Oxford University Press, 1973).
248 G ü n th er H eld Y .
5 A low and controlled rate of inflation is an important condition of bank performance and
financial liberalization. High and variable inflation rates change relative prices and profits in
ways which are difficult to predict. They foster higher credit risks, higher interest rates and
a shortening of the period of financial transactions.
A public sector with a financial surplus is also important to bank performance and financial
liberalization. A frequent policy to provide resources to an inadequately funded public
sector involves imposing high reserve requirements and other "quasifiscal" charges on banks.
The latter increase the spread through higher lending or active rates of interest and lower
deposit or passive interest rates. Strong public finances therefore mean both lower interest
rates and a greater availability of funds to the banking system.
6 R. Me Kinnon, Money and Capital in Economic Development, Washington D.C., (The Brookings
Institution, 1973).
7 E. Shaw, op. cit., pp 3-14.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , u b e r a u z a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y i n ... 249
2. Organizational regulation
8 Cost efficiency translates into low spreads or margins between lending or active interest
rates and deposit or passive interest rates.
9 Universal banks are able to offer a full range of financial services.
10 Consider for instance a commercial bank which sets up a wholly owned mutual fund. If the
bank issues bonds which are bought up by the mutual fund at above market interest rates,
the profits of the bank will be lower and the profits of the mutual fund will be higher than
otherwise.
11 F. Morandé and J. M. Sánchez, "La Expansión del Giro Bancario Tradicional a los Negocios
No Bancarios", in La Banca Ante Nuevo Negocios y Mercados, (Santiago, Asociación de Bancos
e Instituciones Financieras de Chile, December 1992).
250 G ü n t h e r H e l d Y.
3. Prudential regulation
For the most part, prudential norms aim at preserving the solvency of
banks. The latter are financially fragile for two main reasons. First, a dis
tinctive feature of banks as firms is that payment of deposit or passive
interest rates and the stock value of deposits and liabilities are contracted
as fixed with the public, although lending or active interest rates and the
recovery of loans and financial investments (at currency denominations
which may partly differ from those pertaining to deposit and liabilities)
are subject to risk of loss, and are thus variable in nature. Second, the
financial structure of banks is highly leveraged12. Thus, the loss of a small
proportion of assets can wipe out all capital13 unless other of the bank's
own funds are at hand.
The (accounting) capital of banks represents an effective capital or
patrimony, provided all expected losses in assets (stemming from risk tak
ing) have been properly measured and fully provisioned (out of profits).
In this case, capital is an indicator of solvency and a measure of the abili
ty to withstand unexpected losses. As long as effective capital is positive,
a bank is able to pay all its deposits and liabilities out of its loans and
financial investments (without having to draw on its own funds)14. De Juan
has remarked that in the case of banks, insolvency invariably comes be
fore illiquidity (while in the case of firms located in the real sector, illi
quidity usually precedes insolvency)15. Thus non-payment of deposits and
other liabilities by a bank is a clear sign that it is fully insolvent.
12 The ratio of deposits and liabilities, or else their counterpart of loans and finandal invest
ments, usually exceeds capital by ten times or more.
13 If loans and finandal investments are equal to deposits and liabilities, this loss is equal to
the inverse of the leverage ratio.
14 Capital is the difference between correctly-valued assets and liabilities. If capital is positive,
assets exceed liabilities.
15 Banks are able to raise funds from the public and to sell finandal instruments out of thrir
portfolio to make cash. This allows them to meet their obligations though they may face
acute insolvency. See Aristóbulo de Juan, "From Good Bankers to Bad Bankers: "Ineffective
Supervision and Management Deterioration as Major Elements in Banking Crises", World
Bank, Washington, Country Economic Department, 1987, mimeo.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in st a b il it y in .. 251
The State can provide a guarantee on deposits to limit the risk of bank
runs. However, insolvency risks increase due to the fact that a State gua
rantee "distorts" the retum-risk relation by diminishing or eliminating the
risk of losses to depositors and by stimulating banks to take on larger
risks.
The return-risk relation calls for depositors and savers to make their
decisions considering both the deposit interest rates offered by banks and
the repayment prospects of their funds (as determined by the riskiness of
banks' asset portfolios). However, as State guarantee coverage expands, de
posit interest rates offered by banks have an increasingly greater influence
on savers' and depositors' decisions as to which bank to choose. Evidently,
252 G ün th er H eld Y .
when there is a full State guarantee on deposits there is no asset risk for
depositors; the only variable guiding depositors and savers is the level of
the interest rate offered by different banks. The State guarantee on de
posits also distorts the retum-risk relation in bank portfolio management.
A broad State guarantee allows banks to assume greater risks when mak
ing loans and financial investments without being exposed to deposit
withdrawals themselves. Banks are therefore tempted to relax their credit
and investment allocation processes. They are also able to enter more risky
market segments without having to increase their deposit interest rates. Thus
the larger the guarantee, the greater the probability that the Central Bank,
as "lender of last resort", will have to cover the deposits of insolvent banks
and assume bank losses.
A very important characteristic of the State guarantee on deposits is
that it can be explicit or implicit. In the first case, there are written norms
which set out the terms of the guarantee. In the second case, the public
clearly understands that the Central Bank (or other public sector institu
tion) will stand behind the deposits of insolvent banks. While the explicit
State guarantee may be partial (leaving an element of risk in savings and
deposit decisions), the implicit guarantee is distinguished by the fact that
depositors and savers behave as if their funds are fully protected (that
is, their decisions will depend only on the level of deposit interest rates
offered by banks)16.
b) Deposit insurance
16 Various factors can shape one's perception of an implicit State guarantee on deposits. The
following are all important; lack of bank liquidations in the past due to the rescue of banks
with solvency problems; the existence of public banks and large private banks in relation to
the size of the domestic credit market, and foreign banks, which depositors believe will not
be allowed to go under; introduction of a partial guarantee on certain deposits; and lack of
transparency of bank solvency. In the latter case, economic agents are unable to distinguish
among banks according to their risks. The State thus assumes somewhat of a moral duty to
protect the savings and deposits of banks which become insolvent.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y i n . 253
ing to the risk of banks losing their assets. However it is very difficult
to make practical use of this advantage. So far, measurement of the va
rious risks faced by banks does not rely on generally accepted procedures,
nor are accepted methods at hand to sum up these risks in an overall
index. For these reasons, insurance funds are generally built up on the
basis of uniform premiums charged on all banks, to cover listed deposits
up to certain amounts in cases of insolvency. Hus type of insurance has
similar effects as a partial guarantee on deposits17.
These norms seek to limit risks and control bank solvency mainly by re
lying on "self regulation" by market participants. They aim to encourage
bank directors and bank managers (in representation of shareholders) to
adopt "safe and sound" loan and financial investment portfolio policies and
decisions (taking on risks compatible with the high leverage of banks). At
the same time, they seek to encourage depositors to exert market disci
pline on banks by taking into account both deposit (or passive) interest
rates and the risk of loss of their funds at different banks when making
their decisions.
Table 1 shows the objectives and content of a typical set of pruden
tial norms intended for self-regulation of bank solvency. These norms
address the main factors acting in favour of the financial stability of banks
taking into account the macroeconomic external repercussions related to
bank solvency and insolvency.
First, strict norms for entering the banking system. These norms re
quire the "screening" of entrants and a barrier of minimum capital18.
Second, norms maintaining a solid capital base, net of expected risk
of loss, for established banks. Accordingly, solvency norms aim at:
• Limiting the risks which banks are able to take on when making
17 Depositors and savers tend to overvalue the deposit rate of interest banks in their decisions;
banks can allocate funds to more risky market segments without fearing a withdrawal of
deposits.
18 Entry conditions for solvency reasons may be more demanding than the barriers on account
of organizational regulations promoting competition.
254 G u n t h e r H e l d Y.
Table 1
PRUDENTIAL REGULATION OF BANK SOLVENCY
loans and financial investments, particularly credit risks (or the risk
of loan default), foreign-exchange risks (derived from lending or
investing in a currency denomination which differs from the one
pertaining to deposits and liabilities), and interest-rate risks (arising
from lending or investment at fixed interest rates at longer terms
than those for deposit and liabilities).
• An accurate measurement and full provisioning of all risks of loss
in the asset portfolio of banks, and the suspension of interest
accruals on high-risk loans.
• Building up the capital base of banks according to the risk profi
le of their loan and financial asset portfolio19.
The effectiveness of these norms in preserving the solvency of banks
depends significantly on the timely and periodic furnishing of reliable
information to depositors and the public concerning risk and capital in
dicators of banks, as well as how depositors and bank shareholders per
ceive their funds as being subject to losses depending on the riskiness of
bank assets.
Third, norms dealing systematically with financial instabilities of dif
ferent magnitudes, including timely recapitalization of banks with emer
ging solvency problems and orderly liquidation of insolvent banks. In the
latter case, norms must clearly indicate the precedence of payments of de
posits and liabilities out of the liquidation of assets, in favour of small-
scale savers and of the Central Bank as "lender of last resort".
4. Bank supervision
c) Bicontrolled banking
22 Free banking differs from non-regulated banking as regards solvency, in that the former is
not subject to financial and organizational norms nor to prudential norms.
23 Banks carrying larger risks in their asset portfolios will have to pay higher deposit rates of
interest.
24 In this arrangement prudential norms should be gauged taking into account the market dis-
258 G ü n t h e r H e l d Y.
Table 2
INSTITUTIONAL ARRANGEMENTS FOR BANK SOLVENCY REGULATION (a)
Solvency controls
Deposit Without solvency With prudential
Guarantee controls regulation controls
(a) Adapted from A. Feller, "Supervisión, Regulación y Riesgos Bancarios", Superintendencia de Bancos
e Instituciones Financieras, Información Financiera (Santiago, Chile, May 1985), pp. ix-xi.
d) Uncontrolled banking
dpline role of depositors and savers. Too rigorous norms can lead banks to adopt highly
conservative loan and financial policies, taking on less risks than are socially desirable.
Loans for small -and medium- scale firms, especially agents wishing to start an economic
activity, may get little credit since prudential norms may consider that they are too risky.
Thus bank solvency indicators may be very good, although the establishment may not
finance socially profitable investment projects.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in st a b il it y in . 259
excessive high risk credit due to the lack of "filters" or restrictions on de
mand for bank funds. At the level of firms and banks, this translates into
a significant number of high-risk projects, uncollectable loans and large ex
pected bank losses. The counterpart at the macroeconomic level is excessi
ve aggregate expenditure, high real interest rates (and inflationary pressu
re). This process can be accumulative as very high real interest rates drag
down solvent bank debtors25.
25 As Feller points out, there comes a point when the government perceives that the situation
is unsustainable. But at this stage, the restoration of solvency of both banks and debtors
invariably means large financial losses for the State. (A. Feller, 'Supervisión, Regulación y
Riesgo Bancario”, Información Financiera, Santiago, Superintendencia de Bancos e Institucio
nes Financieras, May 1985).
26 The setting of (nominal) interest rates and the rate of exchange in inflationary conditions
frequently led to negative real rates of interest and, most of the time, to a substantially
overvalued domestic currency. At the outset of liberalization policies in 1975-76, bank loans
averaged only 9.3 per cent of GDP, national savings 11.2 per cent of GDP (though 14 per
cent represented historical levels), and exports of goods and services 25.2 per cent of GDP
(though 20 per cent were closer to historical levels).
27 For short but forceful statement regarding the evaluation and changes in the economic
policy régime see S. de Castro, "Exposición sobre el Estado de la Hacienda Pública”, Boletín
Mensual, Banco Central de Chile, January 1978, and P. Barahona and M. Gómez, "Esfuerzos
de Estabilización en Chile", Boletín Mensual, Banco Central de Chile, October 1975.
260 G ü n t h e r H e ld Y.
Virtually all banks had also been taken over by the State in 1970-73. The
banking reform thus had two main components. First, financial liberaliza
tion of credit and interest rates and related measures concerning reserve
requirements, a broader funding base and access to foreign capital. Second,
organizational measures aimed at a private and competitive banking sys
tem and the first steps toward multibanking by authorizing banks to un
dertake longer term transactions and mortgage operations.
28 Financial establishments are unable to offer checking accounts and to finance foreign trade
transactions. They devote themselves mainly to financing household purchases of durable
consumer goods.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , u b e r a u z a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y in .. 261
could be indexed to the CPI after July 1976. Reserve requirements for sight
and time deposits were reduced starting in 1975 and 1976, and levelled
out at 10 per cent and 4 per cent respectively in 1980. Restrictions on the
acquirement of foreign debt by banks were gradually removed after De
cember 1977 and virtually abolished in April 1980. However, controls were
kept on outflows of capital. These were instrumental in maintaining foreign
funds in the banking system and in increasing the financing role of the
latter. In 1981 all loan and finandal-asset portfolio growth of the banking
system was due to foreign debt financing.
The financial liberalization measures were soon followed by abnor
mally high rates of growth of the banking system's loan (and finandal-
asset) portfolio and of interest-rate levels, as well as by extremely large
interest spreads29. Column 1, Table 3 shows these figures for 1978-80, four
years after financial liberalization got under way in order to dampen the
effects of inherited financial "repression" on the behaviour of banking va
riables. Loan (and finandal-asset) portfolios grew on the average at almost
40 per cent a year in real terms (equivalent to five times the GDP growth
rate), while average real rates of interest on the outstanding stock of loans
(and finandal assets) stood at around 20 per cent a year (equivalent to
two and a half times the GDP growth rate). Gross spreads were almost
10 per cent a year. They covered provisions and write offs of risk-prone
loans of 1.7 per cent a year (indicating an apparently sound portfolio growth),
and hefty administrative and other current expenses of 5.2 per cent a year
(suggesting operational ineffidendes). Gross spreads also provided for a
substantial profit rate of 22 per cent on capital (achieved with an average
asset ratio of nine). The above indicators reflected a booming banking sys
tem which looked profitable and safe.
Yet a solvency crisis of unexpected magnitude erupted in 1981, lead
ing to large-scale intervention of the banking system. Between 1981 and
1984 the Superintendency of Banks and Financial Institutions intervened
in fourteen private domestic banks, induding the two largest private banks
in 1983, and eight finandal establishments, out of twenty-six domestic pri-
29 On the behaviour of interest rates see R. Zahler "Las tasas de interés en Chile: 1975-82", El De
sarrollo Financiero de América Latina y el Caribe 1985, (Caracas, Instituto Interamericano de
Mercados de Capital, 1985).
262 G ü n th er H eld Y .
Table 3
CHILE
Bank Behaviour at the Peak of Financial Liberalization (1978-80) and after
the Recovery of Solvency and Prudential Regulation Reform (1986-91)
(in %, with the exception of the asset leverage ratio)
33 The minimum capital of banks went up from US$ 2.5 million to around US$ 10 million; that
of financial societies from US$ 0,4 million to around US$ 5 million. The financial crisis of the
early 1980s demonstrated the pitfalls of attempting to face solvency problems by merely
strengthening capital bases. The latter proved totally insufficient to cover accumulated losses.
266 G ü n th er H eld Y .
tutions, only 4 per cent were backed up by such goods at the end of
1985. Limits on individual credit were amply exceeded in the case of "re
lated" loans by lending to fictitious firms and other practices. It is estima
ted that up to 50 per cent of bad loans which banks undergoing inter
vention in 1981-83 sold to the Central Bank were "related" (and had vir
tually no collateral). Indirect evidence regarding interest capitalization and
the rolling over of overdue loans is provided by the fact that while loans
were growing at abnormal rates, interest-income accruals by banks were
very high; after they had sold their large stock of bad loans to the Central
Bank, both the growth rate of their loan portfolio and the lending rates
dropped sharply (see second and third column of Table 3).
Not until 1980 did the Superintendency of banks introduce a method
to classify loans according to risk categories. The public was evidently not
informed of expected losses; however, these losses led to intervention in
the banking system starting in 1981, in order to gauge the magnitude of
the recovery measures. Therefore, neither the Superintendency nor depo
sitors and shareholders had access to reliable information on portfolio qua
lity -and consequently on effective results and capital figures of bank and
financial establishments- in the course of financial liberalization. The high
profitability shown in column 1 of Table 3 was fictitious as it followed
mainly from accounting as income interest accruals on high-risk loans and
from insufficient provisioning of these risks.
p = 1 + f = 1 + fj + (1 - a)r (1)
Table 4 defines credit risk categories for the loan portfolio and an example
of credit risk assessment of two banks starting in May 1987. The lower
part of this table shows the "effective" capital position of the same two
banks also starting May 1987, when the above information was made pu
blic for the first time by the Superintendency of Banks. The capital p o
sition is shown by means of a coefficient where the numerator is "effec
tive" capital, the denominator accounting capital, and with the following
variables:
Table 4
CHILEAN PRUDENTIAL REGULATION BANK REFORM OF 1986 TRANSPARENCY
OF CREDIT RISK AND OF EFFECTIVE CAPITAL OF BANKING INSTITUTIONS
36 Thus, if ecc > 100 or if ecc < 100, effective capital exceeds or falls short of accounting capital
by the percentage difference to hundred.
270 G ünther H eld Y.
37 The precise percentage of capital at risk depends on the leverage ratio of the bank of
financial establishment. The higher the leverage ratio, the lower the admitted percentage of
capital at risk.
38 If this capital is not forthcoming or deemed insufficient by the Superintendency, the bank or
financial establishment in question is not permitted to expand its loan and financial-asset
portfolio, with the exception of the purchase of financial instruments issued by the Central
Bank.
39 Full insolvency is not defined, but banks and financial establishments assumed to incur
"severe solvency problems" run the risk of being liquidated if no corrective measures are
forthcoming. If the Superin tendency of Banks decides to liquidate, sight deposits and small
savings are protected by the State guarantee, while the Central Bank enjoys priority in
recovering both its loans to the affected financial establishment and its disbursements to
cover protected deposits.
B ank r é g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y i n .. 271
40 The Central Bank "suggested" short-term deposit interest rates between 1982-86, while the
financial crisis was overcome.
272 G ünther H eld Y.
which around 3 per cent is due to the pension-fund reform of 1981); exports
of goods and services reached a peak of 35 per cent GDP in 1990-92, backed
by record high real export rates of exchange in 1988-91; inflation has been
kept at nearly 20 per cent or less a year (in a highly indexed economy)41
and GDP has been expanding at above 6 per cent a year, both since 1986.
The "revival" of growth and the behaviour of financial and real variables,
quite akin to the results predicted by the financial liberalization approach,
merit close attention under this policy and relative to the interrelationship
among these variables42.
In the meantime, the highly successful bank reform of 1986 created
new issues. It only partially achieved the objective of establishing a regime
of "bicontrolled" banking as regards solvency. Although pension funds,
insurance companies and other institutional investors follow closely the sol
vency indicators of banking institutions shown in Table 4, there is evidence
that a large proportion of depositors still behave as if their funds were
fully protected by the State43. What was achieved may be closer to public-
sector-controlled banking. This has led to proposals which enlarge the role
of the private sector in evaluating the risk of the loan and financial-asset
portfolio pertaining to banking institutions, and which render the risk of
deposit capitalization and of deposit losses in cases of insolvency feasi
ble44. Rapid development of the capital market since the mid-1980s brought
about by the pension fund reform of 1981 has also led the banking sys
41 The CPI measured inflation was 27 per cent in 1990 but approached one digit rates at the
end of 1992.
42 While the real rate of exchange appears as essential in explaining the expansion of exports
and tradeables; it can be argued that a further fall in interest rates requires more national
savings (instead of attempting to rely on higher rates to incentívate household savings).
43 The following factors may have contributed to this result: the explicit guarantee on sight
deposits and on small scale deposits, the preponderant role of the Superintendency of Banks
in measuring risks and in controlling solvency, and the requisite that banks and financial
societies have to repurchase the bad loans which they sold to the Central Bank and are thus
hardly expected to break down.
44 Since Institutional investors keep themselves informed on the solvency position of banks
and financial societies, they will withdraw their deposits before the "capital at risk" of a
bank reaches the critical ratio of 60 per cent, that is, when deposit capitalization under a
creditors committee is to take place.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y in . 273
Argentina 1974-81 Credit and interest rate Fiscal imbalance and Severe shortco Large banking cri High real rates of
liberalization. high inflation. Stabiliza mings. ses. interest. Lagging
Early opening of capi tion based on the rate of rate of exchange.
tal account. exchange (1979-81).
Chile 1974-82 liberalization of credit Structural reforms. Stabi Severe shortco Generalized bank High real rates of
and interest rates. lization based on the rate mings. ing crises. interest. Lagging
of exchange (1978-1982). rate of exchange.
Uruguay 1974-82 Credit and interest rate Current account imba Severe shortco Large banking cri High real rates of
liberalization. lance. Stabilization based mings. ses. interest. Lagging
Early opening of capi on the rate of exchange rate of exchange.
tal account. (1979-1982).
Colombia 1979-82 Sectoral credit alloca Fairly stable macroeco Severe shortco Large banking cri Fragmented inte-
tions. nomic conditions. mings. ses. ' rest-rate structu
G ünther H eld Y.
re.
El Salvador 1980-89 Directed credit and set Large fiscal deficit. Infla Severe shortco Large banking cri Financial repres
ting of interest rates. tionary pressure. mings. ses. sion.
Table 5 (Cont.)
Bank
Out Come
regulation, liberalization
Key Prudential re
Country Period Financial regulation macroeconomic gulation and Stability of fi Financial
conditions supervision nancial system prices
Dominican 1982-90 Sectoral credit limits Fiscal imbalance. Grow Severe short Financial crises in Financial repres
Republic and setting of interest ing inflation. comings. non-regulated fi sion of regulated
rates. nancial sector. banks. High real
Hidden solvency rates of interest in
problems in regu non-regulated
and
lated banks!?). sector.
financial
Costa Rica 1983-87 Credit liberalization Stabilization and balance Important im Financial crises in High real rates of
and gradual deregula of payment adjustment. provements in non-regulated fi interest in non-re
instability
tion of interest rates. prudential regu nancial institu gulated financial
lation and su tions. sector.
pervision.
in ...
Bolivia 1985-90 Credit and interest-rate Stabilization and struc Severe Some insolvent Very high real
liberalization. tural reforms following shortcomings. banks. Weakened lending rates of
large fiscal deficits and solvency of bank interest.
hyperinflation. ing system.
Peru 1990-92 Credit and interest-rate Stabilization and struc Shortcomings in Solvency pro Slow decline of
liberalization. tural reforms, following provisions and blems in commer very high real
large fiscal deficits and recapitalization cial banking sec lending rates of
hyperinflation. norms. tor. Ínteres.
.
276 G u n t h e r H e l d Y.
47 V. Corbo, J. de Melo and J. Tybout, "What Went Wrong with the Recent Reforms in the
Southern Cone", Washington D.C., World Bank, 1985, Report DRD128.
48 Ibid.
49 A full State guarantee on deposits was reintroduced in Argentina in 1973. The guarantee on
deposits of firms became negotiable with the Central Bank in 1977. However, all deposits in
banks which had undergone intervention up to the beginning of 1982 were paid. The im
plicit State guarantee on deposits in Uruguay stemmed mainly from full payment of de
posits during the financial crisis of 1971.
50 A. Banda, "Regulación Bancaria, Crisis Financiera y Políticas Consecuentes. El Caso
Uruguayo", in G. Held and R. Szalachman eds., A horroyAsignacióndeRecursosFinancieros,
(Buenos Aires, GEL, 1990).
B ank r e g u l a t io n , u b e r a u z a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in st a b il it y i n . 277
tion, there were eight "official" banks, administered by the public sector,
as compared to three in 1982, and nine private banks as compared to sixteen
in 1982. By 1989, the former accounted for 70 per cent of the assets of
the banking system.54
The commercial banking system of El Salvador had accumulated losses
equivalent to 3.4 times its capital at the end of 1989. Overdue and refinanced
loans representing 39 per cent and 26 per cent of the loan portfolio signalled
further outstanding losses. Three factors are particularly noteworthy when
seking to explain the financial crises amidst a stagnant economic activity
and die severe political turbulence of the 1980s: public-sector interference
in the credit process, financial repression and shortcomings in the regula
tion and supervision of banks.55
The nationalization of commercial banks in March 1980 and a large
Central Government deficit (equivalent to 15 per cent of CDP in the mid-
1980s) facilitated financial repression and made bank credit prone to politi
cal influence and sectoral pressure groups. The Central Bank set both de
posit and lending rates of interest, and banks had to meet a reserve requi
rement of 20 per cent on deposits while investing 10 por cent of their
asset portfolios in low-yield public-sector financial instruments. In the 1980s,
yearly inflation rates averaging 20 per cent led to negative real deposit
interest of 6 per cent a year on average. While deposits stagnated, bank
credit dropped by 35 per cent in real terms between 1980-81 and 1988-89.
Public-sector and Central Bank authorities took on an increasing role
in the management of banks and the allocation of credit through appoint
ment of personnel and credit directives. Under such conditions, the bulk
of bank regulation and supervision fell to financial norms and their com
pliance. Prudential regulation and supervision were sidestepped. Individual
credit limits were bypassed, credit risks inadequately assessed, provisions
on risk-prone loans delayed, bad loans rolled over and overdue loans not
collected. Since deposits enjoyed an implicit State guarantee after the na
tionalization of banks, financial repression in El Salvador took place in a
ped. The real lending interest rates of banks went from around minus 80
per cent a year in 1984 (when interest rates were still set by the Central
Bank) to nearly 100 per cent in 1985, 70 per cent in 1986, 40 per cent
in 1987 and an average of 20 per cent in 1989-91. Though real lending
rates of interest have fallen, they have none the less remained at high
levels.
Solvency problems led to the closure of four banks in 1987. The very
high real interest rates and the changes in relative prices and sectoral
profitabilities brought about by rapid disinflation and the trade reform
loom large in this situation. Inadequate norms controlling credit risk, an
implicit State guarantee on deposits, and week supervision also played a
role. Since 1987, a number of measures have been taken to limit credit
concentration and related credit, increase provisions on risky credit, and
shore up supervision. Yet, overdue loans still stood at 14 per cent of the
loan portfolio of banks in 1989.67 The prevailing high real lending rates
of interest may thus partly reflect remaining high credit risks in bank
portfolios.
A handful of bank insolvencies in the first half of the 1980s alerted
public-sector financial authorities in Peru as to defective norms controlling
solvency and the risks stemming from an implicit State guarantee on de
posits. Accordingly, a number of measures considerably improved pruden
tial regulation in the second half of the 1980s. Credit classification to risk
categories and stricter limits on individual and related loans became offi
cial in 1989. The new banking law of 1991 expanded capital requirements,
introduced the sharing of information on debtors among banks, required
banks to provide the public with information regarding the quality of their
portfolios and capital positions, and empowered Supervisory authorities to
levy clearly defined sanctions. At the same time, the banking law of 1991
set up an explicit and compulsory deposit insurance fund. The fund gua
rantees bank deposits up to US$ 3,500 (at the rate of exchange prevail
ing in 1991) against a premium payable by banks. The latter are to be
differentiated according to the risk of their portfolios.68
interest rates in the 1980s did not cause financial problems in the regulated
banking system. It is also the only case where prudential regulation and
supervision had been substantialy improved.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
70 It is also important to make sure that banks are solvent at the outset of finandal liberali
zation.
B ank r e g u l a t io n , l ib e r a l iz a t io n a n d f in a n c ia l in s t a b il it y in . 287
banking controlled by the public sector (see Table 2), though some
countries have explicitly limited the guarantee or insurance on de
posits.
ANNEX
* The State Bank was not authorized to sell bad loans, but it did not require Central Bank
assistance to overcome its loan-portfolio probles.
290 G ü n th er H eld Y .
d = 1 /e (i + 1 + fj + g - a.r) (2)
where "a.r" stands for the proportion of interest accruals on loans paid
in cash and where non previously mentioned symbols mean:
Filling in the variables o f this equation with 1978-80 data on the bank
ing systems yields a rate of growth similar to that of the loan andfinan
cial asset portfolio of the banking system:
b A simple bank model is assumed where loans and financial assets are equal to deposits and
liabilities. See G. Held and R. Szalachman, Regulación y Supervisión de la Banca en la Expérien-
cia de Liberalización Financiera en Chile (1974-1988), (Santiago, ECLAC, 1989), Annex B.
NOTE ON THE AUTHORS