13913-Article Text-10661-1-10-20150624

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 23

Canadian Journal of Political and Social Theory / Revue Canadienne de theorie

politique et rociale, Vol. 6, Nos . 1-2 (Hiver/Printemps, 1982) .

THE INNIS TRADITION


IN CANADIAN POLITICAL ECONOMY

Mel Watkins

Although the name of Harold Innis is not a household word in Canada, it


should be. He is without doubt the most distinguished social scientist and
historian, and one of the most distinguished intellectuals that Canada has ever
produced. Successively he wrote pioneering works in Canadian history and in
the history of civilizations, held together by the common thread of an intense,
passionate concern for scholarship and for the future of his country ; indeed, for
Western civilization itself. As an economic historian or economist, writing on
Canada, he was the central figure in creating an indigenous Canadian approach to
political economy that transcended economic history and economics to embrace
history, political science, sociology and anthropology. Yet the legacy of this "old
political economy" has been in recent years to facilitate the emergence of a "new
political economy", a new synthesis . That, at least, is what this paper will argue . I
In the process it will seek to answer a number of questions : What was the nature
of the old synthesis formed under Innis? How was its formation possible? Why
did it fall by the wayside? Why is it now being revived? Why, in terms of creative
work, is the new political economy mostly of a left - even Marxist -
persuasion, though Innis was certainly not a Marxist and was very much opposed
to the politics of his left-leaning colleagues?
Central to my argument, following the historian of science, Thomas Kuhn,z is
the power of paradigms to set the questions and to constrain the methods by
which answers can be sought to a limited list of questions ; that is, the powerful
manner in which the disciplines discipline. The phenomenon was familiar to
Innis, who opposed monopolies of knowledge and schools . The practitioners of a
discipline, as monopolists, set up barriers to the entry of dissenting ideas and so
generally impose their will with the consequence, at first evident to the student
but soon forgotten, that university departments are as much suppressors of
creative thought as they can be its supporters, places of unfreedom as much as
places of freedom. In Innis' arresting use of the language of orthodox economic
theory to expose the reality of its practice: "Imperfect competition between
economic theories hampers the advance of freedom of thought ."3 Intellectual
modes ofproduction are, in turn, related to real modes of production, so that the
dialectic of paradigm change must be related not only to matters internal to the
paradigm, following Kuhn, but also to the material reality . Concretely, we must
be concerned not only with the hegemonic nature of the paradigm (in our case
with the politics of economics) but also with the effect of the economy on
economics, including economic history : Carl Berger's history of Canadian
history4 might thus be better seen as notes toward an economic history of
Canadian economic history. As Innis put it: "We need a sociology or a philosophy

12
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

of the social sciences and particularly of economics, an economic history of


knowledge or an economic history of economic history" .5 Following Innis, the
recognition of the narrowness of the margin for intellectual manouevre, or for
creative freedom, can help us understand the bias of a discipline, and so
overcome it .
Now Innis was an economic historian which means, in the North American
tradition then as now, an economist who works on matters historical . The Innis
tradition in economic history can properly be said to be embodied in the so-called
staples approach, both in the concrete sense of the study of the great staple trades
and industries and in the methodological sense that the study of staple activity
broadly conceived was a unifying theme for the general historical experience at
the periphery . In a paper written on the occasion of the quarter-century since
Innis' death, the economic historian Hugh Aitken reminds us of "the golden age
of Canadian economic history that accompanied the statement and elaboration of
the staple theme", but he is critical of its legacy :

The fact of the matter is that, in Canadian economic history,_


Innis still dominates the field . . . Elsewhere [meaning the
United States], the last decade and a half in economic history
has been one of the most exciting periods ever experienced in
the history of the profession . Not so in Canada . . . [A]
reconstruction of the standard interpretation of Canadian
economic history is still a long way off . That standard
interpretation, enshrined in monographs and textbooks, is an
interpretation of the Innis model . It is no compliment to
Canadian scholarship that now twenty-five years after his
death, it still monopolizes the field .

Referring to "developments in Canadian economic history over the last decade


and a half - or rather, the relative lack of developments", he says "The strength
of the Innis tradition may be one explanation ."'
Aitken's evidence for "exciting" developments in the U .S . is the emergence of
the "new economic history" or cliometrics, forgetting Herbert Heaton's 1954
warning (significantly in the Canadian Journal of Economics and Political
Science) that :

The American cult of quantities is no mere turning tide . It is a


tidal wave, on which Clio's little craft seems likely to be sunk by
the swarms of vessels manned by statisticians, econometricians,
and macro-economists . . . . 7
MEL WATKINS

The new economic history now has a track record and not all observers are as
impressed as Aitken . Paul Davenport observes that "the 'new' economic
historians tend to take the position that if a technique is acceptable to the
theorists it is acceptable for economic history." "The new economic history," he
writes, "is sometimes described as 'the application of economic theory to
economic history' ; far too often it becomes . . .'the application of history to
economic history." And the economic theory at issue is, of course, neo-classical
theory. Ian Parker observes that since World War II:

Within economics .. .the gap between mainstream economic


theory and economic history widened, despite Innis' argument
that 'Any substantial progress in economic theory must come
from a closer synthesis between economic history and
economic theory' and despite (and on occasion because of)
recent attempts to apply simple neo-classical 'cliometric'
models directly to the explanation of complex historical
situations.9

The American economic historian Donald McCloskey says the theory in question
is "especially the theory of price" and insists (properly) that it, and not counting,
is "the defining skill of cliometricians, as of other economists." He recognizes
that "the cliometric school is characteristically American" and, in a
characteristically American way, writes "the frontier of cliometrics is the wide
world beyond America ."'°
Predictably the technique has, in fact, spread to Canada, where it has been in
part devoted to testing the staple theory . In a review of that literature I wrote that

to the extent it poses real questions it has upheld the validity of


the staples approach - though making little or no
contribution to our theoretical understanding. The staple
theory has survived the worst onslaughts of Americanization
and for that reason alone must be as hardy and genuinely
Canadian."

Aitken is excessively critical of the lack of developments in Canadian economic


history while exaggerating the strength of the Innis tradition, at least in the
sense of a holistic approach .
Only three years after Aitken, a new Canadian economic history textbook
appeared (Canada : an Economic History by Marr and Patterson 11) which was
largely successful in blending the best, or less fanatical, of the new economic
history with some of the insights of both the old and the new political economy.

14
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

A new textbook was possible precisely because, as Kenneth Norrie put it in a


review: "There has been an explosion ofresearch activity in the field over the last
quarter century, from perspectives as diverse as cliometrics to the new political
economy." But, as Norrie also points out, the limitations of a text reflect those
of existing research . The Marr and Patterson book is "an economic history of
Canada ." It is not based on "a broader synthesis of economic with social and
political history" because, writes Norrie, himself of the new economic history
persuasion, "so few of us are ourselves involved in such broad interdisciplinary
work." 1 3
Norrie is here alluding to the nature of the paradigm, and there are deeper
flaws in Aitken's argument that result from the superficiality of his analysis of
economics as a paradigm and economic history as a field within that paragidm .
Traditionally, economic history had been critical of economic theory and, to a
considerable extent, prepared to generate its own analytical frameworks, loosely
related to the prevailing body of theory . As well, under Innis, economic history
was central to economics itself, and had, in turn, been the core for the broader
synthesis that constituted the old political economy. Beginning in the'30s with
Keynes, and greatly intensifying during the war and postwar period, economics
became obsessed with the immediate and the short-run, and hence became
ahistorical, falling victim to quantification and the reification of technique . In the
United States, the new economics, or the so-called neo-classical synthesis,
destroyed the surviving remnants of the institutionalism of Veblen and
Commons; in Canada, it destroyed the Innis school as a dominant influence in
economics and as the unifying theme for political economy. Innis survived within
Canadian economic history because the new economics sees economic history
essentially as a ghetto, and because those of the Innis tradition, particularly at
Toronto under the influence of V.W. Bladen and W.T. Easterbrook, were able to
resist the inroads of the new economic history. In terms of influence over the
profession, the successor to Innis was to be Harry Johnson located outside
Canada at the University ofChicago and the London School of Economics and, as
a happy prisoner of the orthodox paradigm, wholly committed to the
obliteration of borders as impediments to the free movements of goods, capital
and ideas .
Berger argues that Innis foresaw his fate and, in effect in his later work
deserting the paradigm of economics, contributed to it:

Innis sensed that excessive specialization in economics, its


presentist tendencies, and the desire for disciplinary autonomy
implied a breakup of the political-economy tradition that had
underlain his economic history of Canada.. .. The staple thesis
linked the history of Creighton, the sociology of Clark, and the
political economy of Innis . The common approach was
weakened in the forties ; there were complaints about the
subordination of political science to political economy...

15
MEL WATKINS

Changing fashions in economics also foreshadowed a very


different style.. ..Innis's speculations on communications were
partly responses to the conditions that were leading to a
splintering of the'social sciences' . Ironically, they were also his
contribution to the dissolution of the political-economy
tradition. 14

It is difficult, however, to see how he could have avoided being read out of the
paradigm, for quantification and Keynesianism represented everything he was
opposed to as an economist . And in practice, Keynesianism - in the sense of
state activity to facilitate economic growth so as to maintain full employment -
was to mean for Canada in the postwar period a continuing if not increasing
commitment to the export of staple products developed by and for foreign
capital, that is, economicgrowth at the expense of deepening dependency . Daniel
Drache has argued that there are (even within the liberal paradigm) two versions
of the staple theory : Innis' dependency model and W.A. Mackintosh's
growth-mode1 ;15 Keyensianism was grafted onto the latter, not the former,
version of the staple theory . 16 Hence the influence of Keynes worked to erode the
influence of Innis - though Innis' suspiciousness of Keynesianism, given his
position within the profession with respect to academic appointments in
Canada, tended to weaken Keynesianism in Canada.
The prima causa of the fate of .Innis, and hence of Canadian political eco-
nomy, lies with the nature of mainstream orthodox economics from the late
'30s onward, its monolithic character and the arrogance of its practitioners, and
their intolerance of dissent. At the same time, however, some blame must be
attached to those whom Drache calls "the launderers" of Innis ." It is, after all, in
the nature of colonialism that at least some of the colonials are complicit ; the
essence of this comprador intellectual role (as we shall see below) consisted of
rejecting the dependency-model of the early Innis and the anti-American
imperialism of the later Innis.
The power of the neo-classical paradigm to kill reflects, of course, less its
external verities as theory and more its deadly consequences as ideology,
intensifying yet more powerful realities of global Realpolitik in the era of the
waxing of the American empire. As I have argued elsewhere,

Innis was able to exploit the already established bias toward


economic history at Toronto, the peculiar weakness of
economics generally as a discipline in the 1920s - its sterility
between Marshall and Keynes .. . - and the momentary
freedom as Canada moved from the British to the American
empire . Briefly, novelty was possible.'$
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

But the rise of the Toronto school was only followed by its fall as Canada
inexorably shifted into the American empire . The era of the Cold War saw the
Americanization of the social sciences as an aspect of the Americanization of
everything, and the destuction of a unified political economy appropriate to a
hinterland status . Canada became, for Canadian social scientists, a "miniature
replica" of the U.S., a "peaceable kingdom," America in slow motion with less of
both the good and the bad . Economics, with its pretensions to fine-tuning the
economy, became relevant with a vengeance when secular prosperity was
thought to have been "built-in". Canadian economics became a branch plant of
U.S. economics and, increasingly, of the Friedmanite orthodoxy of the University
of Chicago. The subtlety and sophistication of Innisian political economy was
replaced by the simplicity and banality of the dfctrines of free trade and
competition, notwithstanding the evident imperfections of competition that
inhered in the now-ascendant, transnational corporations . '.'The success of
laissez-faire has been paid for by the exploited areas of which we are one"
(Innis) . 1 9 "By the nineteen-fifties Innis and those who would have seen the
matter as he did were swamped by both the soft money Keynesian group and the
continentalist free traders" (Neill) .z°
The department of political economy at the University of Toronto, once
chaired with such distinction by Innis, grew quantitatively but, depending on
one's point of view, not necessarily qualitatively . Sociology broke away and its
assertion of discipline autonomy was followed, to some extent unavoidably, by
pervasive Americanization. Economics and political science held together, but in
the face of rising opposition from the economists that seems certain to triumph
shortly. (In any event, they already operate as if they were separate departments
and political economy as such is hardly taught .) The economists devote
themselves to redefining political economy, on the one hand, by reducing politics
to the narrowest margins of economic self-interest (for example, politicians
exchanging policies for votes ; nationalism reduced to a "taste for nationalism",
the better to vilify it)" and, on the other hand, by equating political economy
with the study of public policy. As the undergraduate Political Economy Course
Union recently pointed out : "It is presently possible for a student to gain a
four-year specialist degree in Economics at U. of T. without ever having read a
word of Harold Innis ." The university honoured Innis by naming a new college
after him, but I am told that the opening line of the Innis College song is, "Who
the hell was Harold Innis?"
If I have dwelt on economics particularly at the University of Toronto, it is
because there is the situation I know best, not because I think that situation is
unique. Nationally, the old Canadian Political Science Association combining
economists and political scientists split in 1967 ; significantly, when a Political
Economy section was created in 1976, it was not within the Canadian Economics
Association (CEA) but rather the successor Canadian Political Science
Association (CPSA). There is now more economic history, at least in the sense
that Innis would have understood, to be found at the meetings of the CPSA than
the CEA ; the same is true with respect to the Canadian Historial Association and

17
MEL WATKINS

even the Canadian Sociology and Anthropology Association relative to the CEA .
Though this is what happened, it must be insisted that there is an important
sense in which it did not have to happen that way, namely, that neo-classical
theory could have incorporated Innis' staple economics . Innis, after all, was a
liberal, albeit a liberal with a difference.zz If he has been ignored, suppressed, and
laundered, it has happened more for ideological reasons than from theoretical
imperatives per se. The latter point is important not only in its own right but
because it is suggestive of developments that may in duecourse take place within
the beleaguered orthodox paradigm.
It seems to me that there are some ways in which the staple thesis could have
been seen as relevant to neo-classical theory . By 1963, the staple theory had been
restated as a theory of economic growth,z3 showing that Innis was respectable
within the orthodox paradigm ." Subsequent literature has been mostly devoted
to its quantitative testing (as noted) or to theoretical elaboration narrowly
focussed and taxonomic in character . 15 How might it have been effectively
'modernized'?
There could havebeen incorporated into the staple theory, as a resource-based
theory of growth, the importance of economic rents, as demonstrated by Eric
Kierans (and understood by Innis), and of policies directed toward further
processing of staples, that is, forward linkage or the "manufacturing condition"
as demonstrated by Aitken and H.V. Nelles .zb Thereby, the staple theory would
have been further elaborated as a theory of capital formation - the latter being a
central concern ofInnis and Kenneth Buckley .z1 The consideration of rents leads
to a concern with the loss thereof : their outward drain through foreign
ownership and the consequence, particularly at the regional level, for
underdevelopment ; alternatively, when the rents are retained but under foreign
control the power of foreign capital is entrenched. (Such considerations led, in
the real world, to the National Energy Program in 1980.) Attending to the
forward linkage potential of the new staple industries would have confronted the
reality of the power of the resource-based corporations to resist and subvert the
policies of hinterland governments (for example, Inco as documented by Nelles)
and the power of the American government with a tariff-structure favouring the
import of unprocessed resources. In effect, serious attention to these matters
would have confronted the economic historian with Canada's role as a resource
hinterland within the American empire, that is, with Canada's dependency, and
offered an alternative to the sterility of the new economic history. For the
orthodox paradigm, however, what could not be risked was the discovery of
neo-colonialism .
The rationale for extending the staple approach to allow for the institutional
fact of the transnational corporation transcends the matter of resource-
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

processing ; at issue is the larger reality of the emergent global economy and
polity . The task would have been facilitated by taking advantage of the American
literature on the rise of the giant corporation and its transnational spread (for
example, the work of Alfred Chandler and Mira Wilkins), 28 not to speak of the
American revisionist historians . Notwithstanding the failure to do so - except
by the historian Stephen Scheinberg - important work was done on foreign
ownership, albeit mostly on the contemporay phenomenon (by, for example,
Aitken himself, the early Stephen Hymer and Kari Levitt) and on Canadian
nationalism as a reaction to it by Abraham Rotstein building on Karl Polanyi . 29
Against this, and particularly the latter, the neo-classicists wheeled out their
heaviest cannon ; it all smacked of economic nationalism, dangerous nonsense by
second-rate Canadian academics in bed with second-rate Canadian businessmen . 3 o
The transnational corporations of the centre and the branch plant economy of
the periphery were reduced by Canadian economists to the single equation : the
Canadian tariff created inefficient industry. What could have been a promising
approach was emasculated in the name of the most literal neo-classical
orthodoxy ; nature should copy art and Canadian secondary manufacturing could
sink or swim on the tide of free trade . A less ideological response could have led
to the writing of genuine industrial history - something that has still not been
done. From the perspective of economic history proper, it would have been the
most useful way to build on Innis - by blending the fact of dependent
industrialization explicitly into the staple approach - and, by providing critical
building blocks that the economist is best equipped to provide, would have given
a firm foundation to the work of political, social and labour historians 3 ' and led
thereby to a new, but still orthodox synthesis . "The surface of the economic
history of modern Canada has barely been scratched, and until that task is taken
up systematically it will be impossible to write a convincing new synthesis of our
past" (Cook) . 32
What was above all at risk was the discovery of dependency - a possibility
that could not be tolerated, for to do so would risk legitimizing nationalism. The
result was to strangle economic history of the Innis variety . This decline of
economic history is evidence of the high cost of the evasion and suppression that
inheres in the dominant paradigm . The staple theory was at best tolerated only
within the context of the Mackintosh version where it could, by quantitative
testing, provide work for economic historians deemed appropriate by
economists . Nor were the historians proper guiltless ; Paul Craven (who calls the
Mackintosh version "the whig-staples view") writes with respect to j .B .
Brebner's classic North Atlantic Triangle :

Brebner's refinement of the whig-staples approach was to


make it explicitly continentalist in scope . The staples
orientation of the Canadian economy was an expression of
natural advantage, and the expansion of the turn of the century

19
MEL WATKINS

reflected a continental partnership between a highly


industrialized United States running short of natural resources
and a newly united Canada rich in them.33

If the early Innis was laundered, the later Innis was simply beyond the ken .
Even those otherwise sympathetic to Innis (like Easterbrook) failed to see any
message in Innis' later writings for Canadian economic history, and certainly not
his recognition of Canada's increasingly satellitic status (contained in the now
often-quoted phrase of "colony to nation to colony") nor his trenchant warnings
against the newly intensified economic imperialism of the United States backed
by the might of the military and the mass media. The costs of compartment-
alizing Innis into the staples phase and the communications phase have been
very high for Canadian economic history.
These matters cut deeply, for they tell us much about the colonial intellectual
and the colonization of the mind. Writes John Watson :

It is Innis' colonial background which provides an explanation


for his intellectual tragedy . It offered him the orientation and
subject matter which eventually led, at the height of the Cold
War, to his incisive critique of American imperialism . Andyet,
the same background dictated that his thought, though lauded,
would not be fully appreciated and pursued.34

Watson calls this "colonial myopia" ; not to admit Canada's colonial situation was
a way for the Canadian intellectual to avoid facing his own colonial situation .
A re-stated staple theory of growth in terms of the leading role of exports and
in the context of an international economy powerfully influenced by
transnational corporations was one possiblity ; another was (and is) the
development of an Innisian theory of growth in terms of rigidities, monopolies,
imbalances, radical instability, etc. Even a casual reader of Innis quickly becomes
aware of his concern with constraints resulting from overhead costs, unused
capacity, the burden ofdebt, and so on. Robin Neill was the first to systematically
draw our attention to Innis' emphasis on the cyclonic nature of economic
development in Canada. (The contrast with the Mackintosh conception is stark.)
Drache has now generalized these themes in Innis' writings into an Innisian
theory of Canadian capitalist development . 35 Orthodox economics offers an
equilibrium model of capitalist growth through markets, linkages, harmonies,
etc. Innis offers us, Drache suggests, a disequilibrium model of rigidities; in
effect, a special, or limiting, case within the general model, with the further
critical feature that, unlike the neo-classical equilibrium model, it is an
open-ended, or dialectical, model. In Drache's terms, "rigidities" result in
"incomplete development" or dependency . Watson independently makes the

20
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

same point : "In the 'staples' period Innis was primarily concerned with
Icyclonics' or radical instability . . ." ; "By definition, an understanding of the
hinterland context revolves around a conception of imbalance, or disequilibrium
or dependency" 36 Notwithstanding the sharp contrast with the neo-classical
model, Drache reminds us that Innis never fully abandoned neo-classical
economics . Rather, the neo-classicists abandoned him . They have ignored and
suppressed the essence of Innisian theory because it was necessary to do so to
avoid facing its implications of inherent tendencies toward hinterland
dependency . 31 Significantly, Drache shows us how Innis can be understood
within the liberal paradigm, though he himself opts for the perspective of the
Marxist paradigm.
What actually happened was not the realization of any of these possiblities, but
rather the destruction of Innisian economic history ; the latter being central to
political economy, its destruction contributed to the destruction of political
economy . It is useful to imagine what might have been . A central theme for Innis
and his school was the notion of "centre-margin" ; in fact, I think we should say
the central theme in that, following Easterbrook, it is a unifying theme for
historical analysis . The terminology is Innis', from his masterful "Conclusion" to
The Fur Trade in Canada, where he writes of "the discrepancy between the centre
and the margin of western civilization . "38 Others have rephrased the theme in
the more popular terminology of "metropolis-hinterland ."
The theme is indeed pervasive in the writings of the old political economy.
Donald Creighton's Laurentian school of Canadian historiography, the
counterpart to Innis' staple approach, explored the interaction of economics and
politics in the creation of a transcontinental national economy, the empire of the
St . Lawrence born and reborn . 39 No one has shown as effectively as Creighton the
power of this theme to focus on the 'separateness' of northern North America.
Canada as 'hinterland' is explicit throughout . The beleaguered St . Lawrence
merchants face not only the competition of New York/Albany, but the
indifference of the British Colonial Office to their grand (sub-) imperial designs .
On the whole, though, the metropolis-hinterland relationship within the British
Empire is seen as a mutually beneficial rather than exploitative arrangement, at
least in contrast to later experience within the American empire (a similar bias is
evident in Innis' writing and is instructive in understanding the nature of his
nationalism) . The rise of the empire of the St . Lawrence in the British era is
followed by its "decline and fall" in the American era4° and the successors to Sir
John A . Macdonald become little more than puppets that dance to the tune of
American imperialism ; to read Creighton is never to be in doubt that Canada is
now an American dependency.
Where he errs" is in exaggerating the nationalism of the National Policy, and
in blaming Mackenzie King for a branch plant economy whose origins are to be
found in the years immediately after 1879 and which was already fully evident by
1913 in the leading sectors of the Second Industrial Revolution . Macdonald's
National Policy politically had an aura of "home rule" 42 and "American industry
in Canada" economically ; the basis was fully laid for the "unequal alliance" 43 of

21
MEL WATKINS

hinterland and metropole . Indeed, even the St. Lawrence merchants of the early
Creighton limited themselves to searching for a better deal within the British
Empire; when it failed in the late 1840s, not a few of them sought to move fully
into the American empire; they were a most colonial-minded group.44 What
follows, then, is that Canada has always been more of a hinterland or colony
(subjected to, and its elites complicit in, metropolitan imperatives) than
Creighton tells us - though none of this is to deny that Creighton deserves
enormous credit for maintaining the focus on dependency .
In economic history based on the staple approach, the focus on the hinterland
status of Canada was less firmly maintained. In part, the problem was the initial
difference between Innis and Mackintosh, and their influence . Mackintosh's
study for the Rowell-Sirois Commission constituted a general economic history
of the years from Confederation to the '30s (the impressive historical overview
of Book I of the Report) ; it shows, in conjunction with Creighton on the
immediate pre-Confederation period, how a national polity and economy were
created but the problem of growing American influence (beyond the re-
orientation of Canadian trade patterns) is ignored . To Easterbrook, who
clearly worked out of the Innis tradition, Canada is characterized by a centralized,
more controlled kind of growth ("a pattern of persistence" appropriate to a
"margin"), in contrast to the more vital and diversified development of the
United States ("a pattern of transformation" appropriate to a "centre") . The
notion of Canada as a satellite ofthe United States would appear inherent to such
a view, but Easterbrook's writing contains little that is explicit on Canadian
dependency. 45
In the centre-margin/metropolis-hinterland framework, there is not only an
external dimension, but also an internal dimension of internal metropolis (or
sub-metropolis)/internal hinterlands . Innis' writings, notwithstanding his
emphasis on the 'naturalness' of Canada in terms ofgeography (the St. Lawrence
River and the Precambrian Shield) and the character of the great staple trades of
fur and wheat, always show a firm grasp of this (from the grievances of the
Western farmers against the C.P.R. in his first book to those of the Maritime
Provinces against Central Canada in The Cod Fisheries, and his appendix to the
1951 Royal Commission on Transportation) . 46 In many ways, the most
important writing in the Innis tradition has been the development of this theme:
for example, S.D. Clark on the Canadian frontier, with its protest movements as
controlled margins ; A.R.M. Lower on the forest frontier and the 'rip-off' by
Toronto and, beyond, New York; W.L. Morton on the West - regional history
important in its own right and essential, given the interplay of economic centres
and subordinate areas, to the writing of national history; George Britnell on the
impact of wheat on the West; Vernon Fowke on the exploitation of the western
farmer by the National Policy; C.B. Macpherson on the political protest of
Alberta wheat farmers and its limitation (emphasized, in the same series on
Social Credit, by J.B. Mallory's study of federalism) ; A.G. Bailey on the culture
of the Maritime Provinces as a marginal area.4'
The centre/margin or metropolis/hinterland framework is not only

22
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

two-dimensional ; what is also critical is the interrelatedness of the two . Again


this was clearly understood by Innis, as is evident in the following passage first
published in 1937:

The end of the period of expansion based on the St . Lawrence


and trade with Great Britain coincided roughly with the
achievement of dominion status which followed the Great War
and which was marked by the Statute of Westminster. The end
of the struggle for control over external policy has been
followed by problems of internal policy ; and the decline of the
St. Lawrence as a factor contributing to the centralization of
the Dominion has been accompanied by the increasing
importance of regionalism evident in the growth of the powers
of the provinces ....The extension of the American empire, the
decline of its natural resources, and the emergence of
metropolitan areas, supported capitalist expansion in Canada
and reinforced the trend of regionalism . The pull to the north
and south has tended to become stronger in contrast with the
pull east and west."

His later writings show a persistent concern with this issue of political
disintegration and balkanization in the face of Americanization . Garth
Stevenson refers to this as a "thin line of intellectual tradition, which... has ...
drawn attention to the relatedness of the internal and external threats ."49
Indeed, not all if Innis' successors have been able to keep their eyes focused
to see both threats and their deadly interaction. Creighton powerfully ana-
lyses the external threat, but has no sympathy for "regionalism ." "In all his
works," Berger tells us, "Creighton concentrated on the centre, not on the
periphery ofthe country .. ..He viewed with sarcastic disfavour both the growth of
provincial powers and scholarly efforts concentrated on regional history. "so
Morton, on the other hand, in Berger's elegant phraseology, maintained "the
delicate balance of region and nation."
In recent years, the Quebec question has increasingly intruded upon this
matter. The issue is not central to Innis - indeed, there is little in his writings
about Quebec which speaks to his limitations as an English-Canadian intellectual
- but it has much exercised his successors whose responses starkly indicate the
limitations, if not of Innis, then of the school . Creighton's rejection of the
nationalist aspirations of the Quebecois are well known and consistent with his
general stand on regionalism, but what may be more significant is the vehemence
with which both Morton and Lower have taken the same position on Quebeos 1
despite their general tolerance of regionalism (and Morton's long-standing
sympathy with the rights of francophones as well as Lower's for the aspirations
of Quebecers). I do not pretend to know where Innis might have stood on the

23
MEL WATKINS

matter of Quebec, but it must be insisted upon that he was consistently suspicious
of centralization. He wrote of "the lack of unity which has preserved Canadian
unity.. ." and of "the common basis of union (being) one of debt and taxes ."'
According to Neill : "He exposed the underlying forces both of unity and
diversity, for the most part emphasizing the latter", 53 and Berger adds: "Innis
may have demonstrated the case for Canadian unity, but this dimension of his
accomplishment was exaggerated by those who were either oblivious of, orchose
to ignore, his own hostility to centralization of power and his concern with
staples that had diverse effects on the country."54 In the context of the recent use
(that is, misuse) ofnational unity to put down the aspirations of the Quebecois, it
is essential to insist that appeal to the old political economy need not lock us into
a one-Canada, anti-Quebec position .
The discussion may also cast light on the argument by William Christian that
Innis was not a nationalist ." It is, to say the least, an original position, the
counter-position being held by such diverse people as Creighton, Brebner,
Berger, Drache, Neill, Cook, etc. In terms of the above, Christian makes two
elementary errors. He fails to distinguish between the nationalism of the centre
and the nationalism of the periphery ; that is, between agressive nationalism
and defensive nationalism, the first being imperialist and the second
anti-imperialist. Secondly, he shows no grasp at all of the two-dimensional
character of the centre-margin dialectic and of the need, in the Canadian context,
to distinguish between nationalism as "national independence" and nationalism
as "national unity" (or what Drache has called, respectively, the nationalism of
dependency or self-determination and the nationalism of domination 56. With
a populist-like distrust of the Ottawa establishment, Innis did not relate well to
the latter . This is not to deny the subtlety of Innis' position, particularly in his
later works, nor the important point made by Watson (hinted at by Berger but
which escapes Christian) that "Innis was not an anti-imperialist in the sense of
having a prejudice against large-scale empires . On the contrary, he felt the
balanced empire represented that which was best in human achievement ." 51
This could have been Christian's strongest argument for the view that Innis was
not a nationalist, but it was the fatal flaw - for Christian's argument - that is
also explains why Innis was, in his later years, a Canadian nationalist. For, to
again Watson, Innis "was an anti-imperialist in the modern sense of being
committed to opposing the imbalance (in the form of military expansionism)
of contemporary empires . "58 This shows the importance of relating ideas to
the understanding of praxis. At the same time, it demonstrates the severe pit-
falls inherent to textual criticism per se. 59
Another major theme for Innis and the school was that of "the state and
economic life." In the nature of the case, the theme linked economics (or
economic history) and political science ; it also stood out as a theme for historians
(particularly Creighton) and for the sociologist S.D. Clark.b° An argument
central toInnis was that the hinterland state itself was almost a by-product ofthe
exigencies of staple production as defined by the imperial state. Both the Act of
Union and Confederation were essentially dictated by the need to create a larger

24
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

state to provide security for foreign capital to build first the canals and then the
railways to facilitate the movement of staples ; Creighton's British North
America at Confederation brilliantly documented the latter . Within economic
history proper, Fowke and Aitken showed how "the state and economic life"
could be a powerful unifying theme to the long sweep of Canadian history while
Alfred Dubuc, in another seminal article, spoke directly of the post-Confederation
period and the material basis for the erosion of federal authority. 61 In political
science, Drache contrasts the older statist tradition ofJ .A . Corry (that is, the state
actively engaged in the process of creating economic growth) with the new
"social democratic" theorists (for example, Frank Scott and Eugene Forsey) and
the role of the state as a housekeeper in an advanced capitalist economy . In the
latter, dependency tends to drop away in a manner analogous to its fate in the
Mackintosh approach (relative to the Innis approach) . Political science, like
economics, ceases to be political economy . 6 z C .B . Macpherson has described how
the search for discipline autonomy, in the context of American influence, worked
to sever the link between the state and economic life :

Much ingenuity has been used by American political scientists,


in the last twenty or thirty years particularly, in staking out a
territory distinct from any other social science . The
behaviouralists and systems analysts felt that they had to
establish their claims to a 'new' political science . The way to
escape from the confines of studying institutions was to see
politics as an activity . . . Not wishing to work with 'the state' as
the central concept, as the older political science had done, a
formulation which had at least allowed some interest in the
relation between the state and economic life, the new men in
effect built walls between the study of the state and the study of
the economy . 63

A return to a central concern with the state and economy-building is now evident
in general and, in particular, in important writings on the provinces . The
relevant disciplines are more often political science and history than economics
or economic history, and the authors are, to some extent, seen, by themselves and
others, as part of the new political economy and not merely as part of the
established order of their disciplines . 64
To return to the opening theme, I have argued that, post-World War II, the
dominant paradigm in economics suppressed Innis while paying him little more
than lip service . But the larger realities of the world could not be indefinitely
suppressed. In the world of ideas, political economy in general and Marxism in
particular have revived in the United States and elsewhere, including Canada, in
the past ten to fifteen years ; for Canada, this should be evident from the
bibliographic references presented so far in this paper. This development can be

25
MEL WATKINS

presumed to reflect the greater contradictions of capitalism that manifest


themselves in the new era of economic crisis. The neo-classical paradigm is again
in trouble. As the Keynesian consensus broke down - in the face of persistant
unemployment and permanent inflation, or so-called stagflation - it was met,
first and foremost, by a retreat to pre-Keynesianism called monetarism. At the
same time, Marxism, dormant since the 30s, experienced a major revival in the
context of the antiwar and student radicalism of the late 60s and early 70s, while
Keynesianism, in the face of monetarism, transformed itself into a more
institutionalist, or Galbraithian, post-Keynesianism. In Canada, because of the
central importance ofdependency, these developments have been animated by a
powerful strand of nationalism inherent to dissent from the orthodox paradigm
with its cosmopolitan, or pro-imperialist, bias toward free trade and free
mobility of capital . Hence, there has been a revival of interest in Innis precisely
be of his understanding of Canada's satellitic position, his distrust of
orthodox economics and, notwithstanding Christian, his nationalism when it
mattered . In the context of the revival of political economy and the right-wing
bias of the dominant monetarist, or neo-conservative economics, Innis became,
by default, the property of the left. This is admittedly ironic given Innis' own
unwillingness to have any truck or trade with the intellectual left, particularly as
represented by the League for Social Reconstruction in the 1930s .bs
It is a tribute to the vitality of the new political economy in Canada - albeit
more evident in political science, sociology, history and anthropology than in
economics proper - that it would necessitate a separate paper to describe it with
any justice .bb Brief comments must suffice here.
Though I myself am not in doubt as to the legacy of the old political economy of
Innis and his school, two qualifications are in order . The first is that there has
been increasing interest in Innis by scholars who would, I presume, not wish to be
seen as tainted either by the leftish or nationalist biases of the new political
economy : The leading case in point would be William Christian, arguably the
most productive of Innisian scholars .61 One must also include under this heading
an interest in Innis within orthodox writing that consists not merely in ignoring
and neglecting him but in explicit attacks against him . The most important
example here is William Eccles' "belated review" of Innis' Fur Trade: it is a
tribute to the new political economy that this instantly produced an impressive
defense of Innis and rebuttal of Eccles by Hugh Grant.b8 A recurring theme of
this paper is the nature of paradigms ; the issue between Eccles and Innis, and
Eccles and Grant, then, consists of the contrast between the political economy
paradigm of Innis and Grant and the orthodox Canadian history paradigm of
Eccles with its enormous distrust of explicit theorizing and its tendency to see
economic analysis as inherently deterministic (though it should be borne in mind
here that that other distinguished Canadian historian, Carl Berger, is mostly
favourable to Innis) .
The second qualification is that some within the new political economy who
label themselves Marxist political economists the better to distinguish
themselves from political economists in general are critical of the Innis legacy,

26
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

holding it to be counter-productive to the development of Marxist political


economy. The leading instances here are David McNally's just-published critique
both of the staple theory and those of us who have written of the wedding of
Innis and Marx.b9 At the risk of trying the patience of the reader, what is at issue
is the nature ofparadigms and so we so we should not be surprised that some new
political economists are more rigid or doctrinaire than others . It cannot be
denied, however, that what all but the most sectarian would regard as "political
economy" has been influenced to some degree (and in some cases - such as my
own - decisively so) by Innis and his school. As well, the use of the Innisian
strand of political economy has the great virtue of being a protection against the
mechanical application of Marxist models of Canada generated outside Canada,
what Drache has called "metropolitan Marxism ." Significantly, Innis explicitly
warned against the limitations of imported theory when he himself set out to
create an indigenous Canadian theory .10
Let me make two final observations on the Innis tradition that seem, to me, to
be relevant to our contemporary situation . The first is that the later Innis
deplored the militarism and irrationality he saw gripping the United States at
the time of the origins of the Cold War. Once again, in the time ofRonald Reagan
and the re-creation of the Cold War, there is surely much to deplore . The second
seems to me, from reading Watson, to be Innis' most important message to
Canadian intellectuals . It is that we must recognize, but refuse to accept, our lot
as colonial intellectuals . This paper has been an attempt to describe the powerful
constraints within Canadian scholarship. Innis' achievement is the proof that
there is more room for manoeuvre than the orthodox pretend and we are today
the stronger for it.
But the last word I will give to the person who is arguably the most
distinguished contemporary Canadian intellectual, Northrop Frye (although I do
so because his point in this quotation is particularly congenial) :

Innis's influence, in Canada as elsewhere, will grow steadily,


because with practice in reading him he becomes constantly
more suggestive and rewarding . He was a curiously tentative
writer, which may account for something of his rather spastic
prose rhythm . He saw that every new form or technique
generates both a positive impulse to exploit it and a negative
impulse, especially strong in universities, to resist it, and that
the former always outmanoeuvres the'latter. But he had some-
thing of what I call the garrison mentality in him, the uni-
versity being still his garrison for all the obscurantism in it
that he comments on so dryly. Perhaps it is not possible to hold
a vision of that scope and range steadily in one's mind without
a more passionate commitment to society as well as to
scholarship. 7 l
Department of Political Economy
University of Toronto
27
MEL WATKINS

Notes

1 . Earlier versions of this paper have been presented to the Symposium on Harold Innis :
Legacy, Context, Direction at Simon Fraser University, March 1978 ; to the Annual
Conference of the Atlantic Provinces Political Studies Association, Charlottetown,
P .E .I ., 1978 ; to the Economic History Workshop, University of Toronto, October 1978 ;
and to the University College Lecture Series, University of Toronto, October 1981 . 1
have benefitted from discussions on these occasions . I am particularly indebted to
Professor Liora Salter of Simon Fraser University for first suggesting the topic to me.
The reader will note that I am discussing the Innis tradition only in Canadian political
economy and not in communications as well ; this narrowing reflects my interests and
competence . For one of the very few writers who is able to discuss both Innises with
insight, see A . John Watson, "Harold Innis and Classical Scholarship", Journal of
Canadian Studies, 12 :5 (Winter 1977), pp. 45-61 and Marginal Man : Harold Innis'
Communications Works in Context, Ph .D. thesis, University of Toronto (1981) .

2 . Thomas S . Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, Chicago, 1962 .

3 . H .A . Innis, Political Economy in the Modern State, Toronto, 1946, p . 100 .

4. Carl Berger, The Writing of Canadian History : Aspects of English-Canadian


Historical Writing, 1900-1970, Toronto, 1976; while Berger's book is most useful, it is
the history of history rather than the economic history of history; it describes ideas
with little or no reference to material circumstances and Realpolitik .

5 . Innis, Political Economy in the Modern State, p . 83 .

6. Hugh G.J . Aitken, "Myth and Measurement : the Innis Tradition in Economic History",
Journal of Canadian Studies 12 :5 (Winter, 1978), pp. 96-105 .

7. Herbert Heaton, "Clio's New Overalls", Canadian Journal of Economics and Political
Science (November, 1954) .

8. Paul Davenport, Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth, Ph .D . thesis,


University of Toronto (1976), pp . 342, 247.

9 . Ian Parker, "Harold Innis, Karl Marx and Canadian Political Economy", Queen's
Quarterly (Winter, 1967), p . 545 .

10 . Donald N . McCloskey, "The Achievements of the Cliometric School", Journal of


Economic History (March, 1978), pp . 13-28 .

11 . Mel Watkins, "The Staple Theory Revisited", Journal of Canadian Studies (Winter,
1977) p. 85 ; reprinted in William H . Melody, Liora R . Salter and Paul Heyer, eds .,
Culture, Comunication and Dependency : the Tradition of H .A . Innis, Norwood,
NJ ., 1981 .

12 . William L . Marr and Donald G. Paterson, Canada : an Economic History, Toronto,


1980.

13. Review by Kenneth H. Norrie, Canadian Historical Review, (September, 1981)


pp. 339-40 .

28
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

14 . The Writing of Canadian History, p . 191 .

15 . Daniel Drache, "Rediscovery Canadian Political Economy" in Wallace Clement


and Daniel Drache, eds ., A Practical Guide to Canadian Political Economy, Toronto,
1978, pp . 1-53 . For Mackintosh's view, see W .A . Mackintosh, "Economic Factors in
Canadian History" in W .T . Easterbrook and M .H . Watkins, eds ., Approaches to
Canadian Economic History, Toronto, 1967, pp. 1-15 .

16 . See David A . Wolfe, "Economic Growth and Foreign Investment: A Perspective on


Canadian Economic Policy, 1945-1957", Journal of Canadian Studies 13 :1 (Spring,
1978) pp. 3-20 .

17. "Rediscovering Canadian Political Economy" .

18. Mel Watkins, "The Dismal State of Economics in Canada" in Ian Lumsden, ed ., Close
the 49th Parallel, etc.: The Americanization of Canada, Toronto, 1970, p . 205 .

19. Innis, commentary in The State and Economic Life, Paris, 1934, p. 289 cited in Robin
Neill, A New Theory of Value: The Canadian Economics of H.A . Innis. Toronto, 1972,
p. 61 .

20 . Ibid., p. 118.

21 . For a critique of the latter, see my "The economics of nationalism and the nationality
of economics : a critique of neoclassical theorizing", Canadian Journal of Economics
(November 1978, supplement), pp . S87-S120 .

22 . See Daniel Drache, "Harold Innis : a Canadian nationalist", Journal of Canadian


Studies (May 1979), pp. 7-12 .

23 . Watkins, "A Staple Theory of Economic Growth", and Gordon W. Bertram,


"Economic Growth and Canadian Industry, 1870-1915 : the Staple Model and the
'Take-Off Hypothesis'," (May, 1963), Canadian Journal of Economics and Political
Science, pp. 141-58 and pp. 162-84 ; both are reprinted in Easterbrook and Watkins.

24 . Watson is critical of those who "use" Innis' work rather than "understanding" it, but it
is valid to translate from one paradigm (Innisian) to another (neoclassical or Marxist)
as a way of generating insights . As well, while every effort should be made to
understand Innis on his own terms (as Watson is doing), the ultimate test of the use of
anyone's work, including Innis', is putting it to use ; otherwise, scholarship bogs down
in textual criticism .

25 . With respect to the latter, see Richard E . Caves, " 'Vent for Surplus' Models of Trade
and Growth" in Trade, Growth and the Balance of Payments: Essays in Honour of
Gottfried Haberler, Chicago, 1965 .

26 . Eric Kierans, Report on Natural Resource Policy in Manitoba, Manitoba, 1973 ; Aitken,
"Defensive Expansion: the State and Economic Growth in Canada" in Easterbrook
and Watkins, pp. 183-221 ; Aitken, "The Changing Structure of the Canadian
Economy with Particular Reference to the Influence of the United States" in Aitken
et.al., The American Economic Impact on Canada, Durham, N .C ., 1959, pp . 3-35 ; H .V.
Nelles, The Politics of Development : Forest, Mines and Hydro-electric Power in

29
MEL WATKINS

Ontario, 1849-1941, Toronto, 1974 . Innis saw the importance of rents and their
tendency to manifest themselves as profits; as well as royalties, taxes and license fees
as devices to capture rents, he advocated using the tariff on machinery and
equipment "to skim off a substantial portion of the cream by taxing equipment, raising
costs of production and thereby reducing profits which would otherwise flow off into
the hands of foreign investors" ; suggested labour legislation "be designed to prevent
exploitation of labour" ; favoured "the investment of surplus by large compannies in
Canadian enterprises and the holding of stock by Canadian shareholders" ;
supported devices for increasing the prices of raw materials ; and concluded,
cryptically with the note "Government ownership as a means." Innis, "Snarkov
Island," Appendix to Neill, pp. 146-9.

27 . "Innis himself was keenly aware of the necessity of fixed investment for
industrialization. He often stressed the link between staple exports and capital
accumulation after Confederation, as in his Problems of Staple Production in Canada
(Davenport, op .cit. 2) ; Kenneth Buckley, Capital Formation in Canada, 1896-1930,
Toronto, 1955 .

28. Alfred Chandler, Strategy and Structure, Cambridge, Mass ., 1966 and The Visible
Hand, Cambridge, Mass ; 1977 ; Mira Wilkins, The Emergence of Multinational
Enterprise: American Business Abroad from the Colonial Era to 1914, Cambridge,
Mass ., 1970 and The Maturing of Multinational Enterprise: American Business
Abroad from 1914 to 1970, Cambridge, Mass ., 1974.

29. Stephen Scheinberg, "Invitation to Empire : Tariffs and American Economic


Expansion in Canada" in Glen Porter and Robert D. Cuff, (eds .), Enterpise and
National Development: Essays in Canadian Business and Economic History,
Toronto, 1973, pp . 80-100 ; Aitken, American Capital and Canadian Resources,
Cambridge, Mass ., 1961 ; Stephen Hymer, "Direct Foreign Investment and the
National Economic Interest" in Peter Russell, (ed .), Nationalism in Canada, Toronto,
1966, pp . 191-202, and The International Operations of National Firms: A Study in
Direct Foreign Investment, Cambridge, Mass., 1976; Kari Levitt, Silent Surrender. The
Multinational Corporation in Canada, Toronto, 1970 ; Abraham Rotstein, The
Precarious Homestead, Toronto, 1973 ; Rotstein, "Canada: The New Nationalism,"
Foreign Affairs (October, 1976); Rotstein, "Is There an English-Canadian
Nationalism?" Journal of Canadian Studies (Summer, 1978).

30. This is not overwriting on my part ; vide Harry Johnson's vituperative comment on
"the shallow and frequently near-psychotic writings of some Canadians employed in
otherwise reputable economics departments, on such subjects as American
investment in Canada.. ." : "The current and prospective state of economics in
Canada" in T .N . Guinsburg and G.L . Reuber, eds., Perspectives on the Social
Sciences in Canada, Toronto, 1974 .

31 . Labour historians, notably Clare Pentland, Bryan Palmer and Greg Keeley, have had to
write industrial history themselves in order to write labour history, and with some
tendency to get the former wrong . See H. Clare Pentland, Labour and . Capital in
Canada 1630-1860, edited by Paul Phillips, Toronto, 1981 ; Bryan D . Palmer, A Culture
in Conflict : Skilled Workers and Industrial Capitalism in Hamilton, Ontario,
1860-1914; Gregory S . Keeley, Toronto Workers Respond to Industrial Capitalism
1867-1892. For a perceptive critique of Palmer and Keeley on this point, see the
review by Leo Panitch, Canadian Journal of Political Science, XIV:2 (tune, 1981),
pp. 434-7 .

30
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

32. Ramsay Cook, "History : the invertebrate social science", Guinsburg and Reugen,
op .cit ., p . 144.

33 . Paul Craven, An Impartial Umpire': Industrial Relations and the Canadian State,
1900-1911 ; Ph .D . thesis, University of Toronto, (1975), p. 32 ; subsequently published
in revised form under the same title : Toronto, 1980. It should be noted that Craven's
comments on industrial history are not subject to the critique made in note 31 .

34 . "Harold Innis and Classical Scholarship", p . 32

35 . Daniel Drache, "Disequilibrium economics and Canadian capitalist development :


The Innis paradigm" (mimeo, 1979) .

36. "Harold Innis and Classical Scholarship", pp . 55, 54.

37.1 have chosen to focus on the implications for dependency of Innisian theory as
adumbrated by Drache for the purposes of this paper, but that is to do less than full
justice to either Innis or Drache . In fact, a reading of Drache's paper suggests that
Innis can be read as having a theory of capitalist growth and not simply of Canadian
capitalist growth, albeit drawing primarly on the Canadian experience . Certainly a
"disequilibrium model of rigidities" implies a more general relevance with the
rigidities varying with the case. Also, Ian Parker has pointed out to me that the
neo-classical theory of growth is, at least from any Marxist perspective, itself a special
case of a general theory . In principle, Innnisian theory may be at least as much a
general theory as neo-classical theory and, since everything depends on where one
stands, as Marxist theory . Hence, Parker himself shows (see note 9) that it not only
helps our understanding of Innis to know our Marx, it also helps our understanding of
Marx to know our Innis.

38. H .A . Innis, The Fur Trade in Canada: An Introduction to Canadian Economic History,
Revised Edition: Toronto 1956, p . 385.

39. D.G. Creighton, The Empire of the St. Lawrence, Toronto, 1956 ; 2nd ed.

40 . Creighton, "The Decline . and Fall of the Empire of the St . Lawrence" in Towards the
Discovery of Canada : Selected Essays, Toronto, 1972 .

41 . Creighton, Canada's First Century, 1867-1967, Toronto, 1970 .

42. Drache, "The Canadian bourgeoisie and its national consciousness" in Lumsden,
op . cit ., p . 10 .

43. This is the major theme of Wallace Clement, Continental Corporate Power: Economic
Linkages between Canada and the United States, Toronto, 1977 .

44. Tulchinsky goes so far as to argue that "the high drama of the annexation crisis,
which passed so quickly, masks the fact that Montreal merchants had always been
continentalists. . ."; see Gerald J .J . Tulchinsky, The River Barons : Montreal Business
and the Growth of Industry and Transportion 1837-53, Toronto, 1977, p. 237 . He also
writes : "The merchants had never been nationalists and never would be - unless it
was in their economic interest" (p. 236) but fails to draw the inference that for a
capitalist class not to be nationalist is to be colonial-minded .

31
MEL WATKINS

45 . W.A . Mackintosh, The Economic Background of Dominion-Provincial Relations, a


study done for the Royal Commission on Dominion-Provincial Relations, Book 1,
"Canada, 1867-1939", Carleton Library, Toronto, 1963 ; Creighton, British North
America at Confederation, a study done for the Royal Commission on Dominion-
Provincial Relations, Ottawa, 1940; W .T. Easterbrook, "Long-Period Comparative
Study: Some Historical Cases," Journal of Economic History, (December, 1957) .

46. Innis, A History of the Canadian Pacific Railway, 1st ed., 1923 ; 2nd ed ., Toronto, 1971 ;
The Cod Fisheries: The History of an International Economy, 1st ed., 1940 ; 2nd ed .,
Toronto, 1954 ; "Memorandum on Transportation" in Report of the Royal
Commission on Transportation, Ottawa, 1951 .

47 . See in particular S .D . Clark, Movements of Political Protest in Canada, 1640-1840


Toronto, 1959; A .R .M. Lower, The North American Assault on the Canadian Forest,
Toronto, 1938; W.L . Morton, Manitoba, a History, Toronto, 1957 ; George Britnell, The
Wheat Economy, Toronto, 1939 ; V.C Fowke, The National Policy and the Wheat
Economy, Toronto, 1957 ; C.B . Macpherson, Democracy in Alberta : the Theory and
Practice of a Quasi-Party System, Toronto, 1953 ; J .R . Mallory, Social Credit and the
Federal Power in Canada, Toronto, 1954 ; A .G . Bailey, Culture and Nationality,
Carleton Library, Toronto, 1972 .

48 . Innis, Essays in Canadian Economic History, Toronto, 1957, p. 209 .

49. Garth Stevenson, "Continental Integration and Canadian Unity" in Andrew Axline et
al., (eds .), Continental Community? Independence and Integration in North America,
Toronto, 1974, p . 195 .

50. Writing of Canadian History, pp. 235-6.

51 . See, for example, Morton, "Quebec in Revolt," Canadian Forum (February, 1977), p .
13, and Lower, "The Problem of Quebec," Journal of Canadian Studies (July, 1977),
pp . 93-97.

52 . Innis, Political Economy in the Modern State.

53 . New Theory of Value, p. 46.

54. Writing of Canadian History, p . 261 .

55 . William Christian, "The Inquisition of Nationalism", Journal of Canadian Studies


(Winter, 1977), pp. 62-72 and Christian's "Preface" to The Idea File of Harold Adams
Innis, Toronto, 1980.

56. Daniel Drache, "The Enigma of Canadian Nationalism", Symposium on Creative


Modes of Nationalism in New Zealand, Canada and Australia, The Australian and
New Zealand Journal of Sociology, 14 :3 (Part Two), (October, 1978), pp . 310-21 .

57 . "Harold Innis and Classical Scholarship", p. 56.

58. Ibid.

59. Christian also argues, even more improbably, that George Grant is not a Canadian

32
INNIS AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

nationalist "in any commonly understood sense" ; see William Christian, "George
Grant and the Terrifying Darkness" in Larry Schmidt, ed., George Grant in Process :
Essays and Conversations, Toronto, 1978 . It is difficult not to conclude at some point
that what is at issue is not the nationalism of Innis or Grant but the anti-nationalist
bias of Christian who respects Innis and Grant but wants to wish away their
nationalism. Because the writings of Innis and Grant are undeniably rich and
complex, Christian apparently imagines that they cannot believe in anything so
'simple-minded' (to him) as nationalism. A similar kind of (impoverished) reasoning
presumably underlies as well John Muggeridge's denial of Grant's nationalism; see
Muggeridge, "George Grant's Anguished Conservatism", also in Schmidt, ed .,
George Grant in Process, pp . 40-8.

60 . Creighton, British North America at Confederation; S.D . Clark, The Developing


Canadian Community, Toronto, 1962 ; 2nd ed. 1968.

61 . Vernon Fowke, "The National Policy - Old and New" in Easterbrook and Watkins; Aitken,
"Defensive Expansion. . ." ; Alfred Dubuc, "The Decline of Confederation and the New
Nationalism" in Peter Russell, ed., Nationalism in Canada, Toronto, 1966, pp. 112-32 .

62 . Drache, "Rediscovering Canadian Political Economy" . As well as Corry, Drache


should have recognized the contribution of Alexander Brady; see his "The State and
Economic Life in Canada" (originally published in 1950) in K.J. Rea and J.T . McLeod,
eds., Business and Government in Canada : Selected Readings, 2nd ed ., Toronto,
1976, pp . 28-42, where he writes "The role of the state in the economic life of Canada
is really the modern history of Canada" (p . 28).

63. C.B . Macpherson, "After strange gods : Canadian political science 1973" in
Guinsburg and Reuber, eds., Perspectives on the Social Sciences in Canada, p. 67 .

64. See Nelles, The Politics of Development; the collection of essays of a Marxist
tendency edited by Leo Panitch, The Canadian State : Political Economy and Political
Power, Toronto, 1977 ; John Richards and Larry Pratt, Prairie Capitalism : Power and
Influence in the New West, Toronto, 1979 . Also as evidence of the revival of this
theme, the University of Toronto Press launched a new series in the late '70s titled
"The Sate and Economic Life", co-edited by Leo Panitch and myself.

65 . On the latter, see Michael Horn, "Academics and Canadian Social and Economic
Policy in the Depression and War Years", Journal of Canadian Studies, (Winter,
1978-79), pp. 3-10.

66. For a bibliographic guide that is already dated see Clement and Drache's Practical
Guide published in 1978 . For a collection of essays on Innis that grew out of a
symposium at Simon Fraser University on the occasion of a quarter-century after his
death, see William H. Melody, Liora R. Salter and Paul Heyer, eds., Culture,
Communication and Dependency: The Tradition of H.A. Innis, Norwood, NJ ., 1981 .

67 . As well as Christian's paper on Innis' nationalism and his editing of The Idea File, see
his "Harold Innis as Political Theorist", Canadian Journal of Political Science (March,
1977), pp . 21-42 and Innis on Russia: The Russian Diary and Other Writings, edited
with a Preface by William Christian, Toronto, 1981 .

68 . W.J. Eccles, "A Belated Review of Harold Adam Innis, The Fur Trade in Canada",
Canadian Historical Review (December, 1979), pp . 419-41 and Hugh M. Grant, "One

33
MEL WATKINS

Step Forward, Two Steps Back : Innis, Eccles, and the Canadian Fur Trade",
Canadian Historical Review (September, 1981), pp . 304-322 . The latter also includes
"A Response to Hugh M. Grant on Innis" by Eccles, pp . 323-29 which, in the
customary tradition of academic rejoinders, adds nothing but vituperation to
the discussion .

69. David McNally, "Staple Teory as Commodity Fetishism : Marx, Innis and Canadian
Political Economy", Studies in Political Economy (Autumn, 1981), pp . 35-63. I am
presently writing, at the request of the editors of SPE, a critique of this paper.

70. Haold Innis, "The Teaching of Economic History in Canada" in his Essays in Canadian Economic
History, Toronto, 1956 ; the essay was first published in 1930.

71 . Northrop Frye, "Across the River and Out of the Trees" in W.J . Keith and B .-Z. Shek, eds ., The
Arts in Canada: The Last Fifty Years, Toronto, 1980, pp. 1-14 .

You might also like