Song 2011

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 72

American Economic Review 101 (February 2011): 196–233

http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.101.1.196

Growing Like China

By Zheng Song, Kjetil Storesletten, and Fabrizio Zilibotti*

We construct a growth model consistent with China’s economic


transition: high output growth, sustained returns on capital, reallo-
cation within the manufacturing sector, and a large trade surplus.
Entrepreneurial firms use more productive technologies, but due to
financial imperfections they must finance investments through internal
savings. State-owned firms have low productivity but survive because
of better access to credit markets. High-productivity firms outgrow
low-productivity firms if entrepreneurs have sufficiently high savings.
The downsizing of financially integrated firms forces domestic sav-
ings to be invested abroad, generating a foreign surplus. A calibrated
version of the theory accounts quantitatively for China’s economic
transition. (JEL E21, E22, E23, F43, L60, O16, O53, P23, P24, P31)

Over the last 30 years, China has undergone a spectacular economic transforma-
tion involving not only fast economic growth and sustained capital accumulation,
but also major shifts in the sectoral composition of output, increased urbanization
and a growing importance of markets and entrepreneurial skills. Reallocation of
labor and capital across manufacturing firms has been a key source of productivity
growth. The rate of return on investment has remained well above 20 percent, higher
than in most industrialized and developing economies. If investment rates have been
high, saving rates have been even higher: in the last 15 years, China has experienced
a growing net foreign surplus: its foreign reserves swelled from 21 billion USD in
1992 (5 percent of its annual GDP) to 2,130 billion USD in June 2009 (46 percent
of its GDP); see Figure 1.
The combination of high growth and high return to capital, on the one hand,
and a growing foreign surplus, on the other hand, is puzzling. A closed-economy

* Song: School of Economics, Fudan University, 618–600 GuoQuan Road, Shanghai 200433, China and
Chinese University of Hong Kong, 929 Esther Lee Building, Shatin, Hong Kong (e-mail: zheng.michael.song@
gmail.com); Storesletten: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 90 Hennepin Avenue,
Minneapolis, MN 55401 (e-mail: [email protected]); Zilibotti: Department of Economics, University
of Zurich, Mühlebachstrasse 86, CH-8008 Zurich (e-mail: [email protected]). We thank the two ref-
erees, Chong-En Bai, Francesco Caselli, Chang-Tai Hsieh, Yikai Wang, and Xiaodong Zhu for comments. We
also thank participants at the LSE conference on “The Emergence of China & India in the Global Economy”
(July 3–5, 2008), the China Economics Summer Institute 2009, the 2009 Minnesota Workshop in Macroeconomic
Theory, and the 2009 Tsinghua Workshop in Macroeconomics, and seminar participants at various departmental
seminars. Financial support from the European Research Council (ERC Advanced Grant IPCDP-229883), from the
Swiss National Science Foundation (100014-122636), from the Research Council of Norway (grants 162851 and
183522), from the 985 platform at Fudan, the Social Science Foundation of China (06CJL004), and the Natural
Science Foundation of China (70703006) are gratefully acknowledged. This paper is part of the research activities
at ESOP supported by the Research Council of Norway (179522). Any views expressed here are those of the authors
and not those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis or the Federal Reserve System.

196
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 197

60
Foreign reserves
Difference between deposits and loans

50

40
Percentage of GDP

30

20

10

0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Year

Figure 1. Foreign Reserves and the Difference between Deposits and Loans

Note: The figure plots China’s foreign reserves (solid line) and the domestic bank deposits minus
domestic loans (dotted line), both expressed as a percentage of GDP.
Source: CSY, various issues.

n­ eoclassical growth model predicts that the high investment rate would lead to a fall
in the return to capital. An open-economy model predicts a large net capital inflow
rather than an outflow, owing to the high domestic return to capital. In this paper,
we propose a theory of economic transition that solves this puzzle while being con-
sistent with salient qualitative and quantitative features of the Chinese experience.
The focal points of the theory are financial frictions and reallocation of resources
across firms. In our theory, both the sustained return to capital and the foreign sur-
plus arise from the reallocation of capital and labor from less productive externally
financed firms to entrepreneurial firms that are more productive but have less access
to external financing. As financially integrated firms shrink, a larger proportion of
the domestic savings is invested in foreign assets. Thus, the combination of high
growth and high investment is consistent with the accumulation of a foreign surplus.
Our paper is part of a recent literature arguing that low aggregate total factor pro-
ductivity (TFP)—especially in developing countries—is the result of micro-level
resource misallocation (see Stephen L. Parente, Richard Rogerson, and Randall
Wright 2000; Francesco Caselli and Wilbur J. Coleman II 2001; Abhijit Banerjee
and Esther Duflo 2005; Diego Restuccia and Rogerson 2008; Gino Gancia and
Fabrizio Zilibotti 2009; and Chang-Tai Hsieh and Peter J. Klenow 2009). While
pockets of efficient firms using state-of-the-art technologies may exist, these firms
fail to attract the large share of productive resources that efficiency would dictate,
due to financial frictions and other imperfections. Most of the existing literature
198 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

e­ mphasizes the effects of resource misallocation on average productivity. In con-


trast, our paper argues that when a country starts from a situation of severe ineffi-
ciency but manages to ignite the engine of reallocation, it has the potential to grow
fast over a prolonged transition, since efficient firms can count on a highly elastic
supply of factors attracted from the less productive firms.
To analyze such a transition, we construct a model in which firms are heteroge-
neous in productivity and access to financial markets. High-productivity firms are
operated by agents with entrepreneurial skills who are financially constrained and
who must rely on retained earnings to finance their investments. Low-productivity
firms can survive due to their better access to credit markets, since the growth poten-
tial of high-productivity firms is limited by the extent of entrepreneurial savings. If
the saving flow is sufficiently large, high-productivity firms outgrow low-produc-
tivity ones, progressively driving them out of the market. During the transition, the
dynamic equilibrium has AK features: within each type of firm, the rate of return
to capital is constant due to labor mobility and to the financial integration of the
low-productivity firms. Due to a composition effect, the aggregate rate of return to
capital actually increases. Moreover, the economy accumulates a foreign surplus.
While investments in the expanding firms are financed by the retained earnings of
entrepreneurs, wage earners deposit their savings with intermediaries who can invest
them in loans to domestic firms and in foreign bonds. As the demand for funds from
financially integrated domestic firms declines, a growing share of the intermediated
funds must be invested abroad, building a growing foreign surplus. This prediction
is consistent with the observation that the difference between deposits and domestic
bank loans has been growing substantially, tracking China’s accumulation of foreign
reserves (see again Figure 1). After the transition, the economy behaves as in a stan-
dard neoclassical model, where capital accumulation is subject to decreasing returns.
Reallocation within the manufacturing sector—the driving force in our model—
has been shown to be an important source of productivity growth in China. In an
influential paper, Hsieh and Klenow (2009) estimate that reallocation across manu-
facturing firms with different productivity accounted for an annual two percentage
point increase in aggregate TFP during 1998–2005. Loren Brandt, Johannes Van
Biesebroeck, and Yifan Zhang (2009) estimate that up to two-thirds of the aggregate
TFP growth in Chinese manufacturing was due to productivity differences between
entering and exiting firms during 1998–2005.
Our theory yields several additional predictions consistent with the evidence of
China’s transition:

(i) The theory predicts that the surplus—savings minus investment—should


increase with the share of entrepreneurial firms. Consistent with this predic-
tion, we find that the net surplus is significantly higher in Chinese provinces
in which the employment share of domestic private firms has increased faster.

(ii) In our benchmark model, all firms produce the same good and differ only in
TFP. We extend the theory to a two-sector model in which firms can special-
ize in the production of more or less capital-intensive goods. This extended
model predicts that financially constrained firms with high TFP will spe-
cialize in labor-intensive activities (even though they have no ­technological
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 199

c­ omparative advantage). Thus, the transition proceeds in stages: first low-


productivity firms retreat into capital-intensive industries, and then they
gradually vanish. This is consistent with the observed dynamics of sectoral
reallocation in China, where young high-productivity private firms have
entered extensively in labor-intensive sectors, while old state-owned firms
continue to dominate capital-intensive industries.

The theory is related to the seminal contribution of Arthur W. Lewis (1954), who
constructs a model of reallocation from agriculture to industry where the supply of
labor in manufacturing is unlimited due to structural overemployment in agriculture.
While his mechanism is similar in some respects to ours, productivity increases
in his model rely on some form of hidden unemployment in the traditional sector.
Lewis’ theory captures aspects of the reallocation between rural and urban areas in
China, while our focus is on the reallocation within the industrial sector. Our paper
is also related to Jaume Ventura (1997), who shows that in economies engaging in
external trade, capital accumulation is not subject to diminishing returns because
resources are moved from labor-intensive to capital-intensive sectors. Ventura’s
model does not assume any initial inefficiency, nor does it imply that TFP should
grow within each industry—a key implication of our theory.1
Neither Lewis’ nor Ventura’s theory has any implication regarding trade imbal-
ances. Kiminori Matsuyama (2004, 2005) shows that financial frictions may induce
trading economies to specialize in industries in which they do not have a technologi-
cal comparative advantage. See also the work of Pol Antràs and Ricardo J. Caballero
(2009). In our model, by a similar mechanism, less efficient firms can survive and
even outgrow more productive ones. Our two-sector extension also predicts that
financial constraints generate specialization in spite of the lack of any technological
comparative advantage, though the mechanism is different.
Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas and Olivier Jeanne (2009) document that it is common
to observe capital outflow from fast-growing developing economies with high mar-
ginal product of capital. As in the case of China, countries with fast TFP growth tend
to have both large capital outflows and large investment rates, while the opposite
is true for slow-growing countries. They label this finding the “allocation puzzle.”
Our theory can provide a rationale to this observation. In a related paper, Francisco
J. Buera and Yongseok Shin (2010) focus on the current account surpluses experi-
enced by a number of Asian economies in the 1980s (with the notable exception
of China, which experienced current account deficits during the 1980s). Buera and
Shin argue—as we do—that financial frictions can contribute to the explanation
of this puzzle. While in our paper the foreign surplus is driven by the dwindling
demand for domestic borrowing, due to the decline of financially integrated firms,
they emphasize increased domestic savings by agents who are planning to become
entrepreneurs but need to save to finance start-up costs.
A few recent papers address the more specific question of why China is accumu-
lating a large foreign surplus. Most papers emphasize the country’s high saving rate.
Louis Kuijs (2005) shows that household and enterprise saving rates in China are,

1 
In this respect, our work is related to the seminal papers of Simon Kuznets (1966) and Hollis Chenery and
Moises Syrquin (1975), who study sources of productivity growth during economic transitions.
200 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

respectively, 11.8 and 8.6 percentage points higher than those in the United States.
Demography, an imperfect financial sector, and the lack of welfare and pension ben-
efits are among the factors proposed as explanations for this (e.g., Aart Kraay 2000).
However, it remains unclear why domestic savings are not invested domestically
given the high rate of return to capital in China. Enrique G. Mendoza, Vincenzo
Quadrini, and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull (2009) argue that this may be explained by dif-
ferences in financial development inducing savers in emerging economies to seek
insurance in safe US bonds (see also Caballero, Emmanuel Farhi, and Gourinchas
2008; and Damiano Sandri 2010). Michael P. Dooley, David Folkerts-Landau, and
Peter Garber (2007) propose a strategic political motive: the Chinese government
would influence wages, interest rates, and international financial transactions so as
to foster employment and export-led growth.
Our paper is organized as follows. Section I describes some empirical evidence of
China since 1992. Section II describes the benchmark model and characterizes the
equilibrium. Section III discusses quantitative implications of the theory with the aid
of a calibrated economy. Section IV presents an extension to a two-sector environ-
ment that captures additional features of the Chinese transition. Section V concludes.
A technical Appendix available from our Web pages contains the formal proofs.

I. The Transition of China: Empirical Evidence

A. Political Events and Macroeconomic Trends

China introduced its first economic reforms in December 1978. The early reforms
reduced land collectivization, increased the role of local governments and communi-
ties, and experimented with market reforms in a few selected areas. After a period of
economic and political instability, a new stage of the reform process was launched in
1992, after Deng Xiaoping’s Southern Tour, during which the leader spoke in favor
of an acceleration of reforms. Since then, China has moved towards a full-fledged
market economy. The process gained momentum in 1997, as the 15th Congress of
the Communist Party of China officially endorsed an increase in the role of private
firms in the economy.
The focus of this paper is on the post-1992 Chinese transition, a period character-
ized by fast and stable growth and by a pronounced resource reallocation within the
manufacturing sector. In spite of very high investment rates (39 percent on average),
the rate of return to capital has remained stable: while the aggregate return to capital
has fallen slightly (from 28 percent in 1993 to 21 percent in 2005), the rate of return
to capital in manufacturing has been increasing since the early 1990s and climbed
close to 35 percent in 2003, according to Figure 11 in Chong-En Bai, Hsieh, and
Yingyi Qian (2006). High corporate returns have not been matched by the return on
financial assets available to individual savers: the average real rate of return on bank
deposits, the main financial investment of Chinese households, was close to zero
during the same period. Wage growth has been lower than growth in output per cap-
ita in recent years.2 Similarly, the labor share of aggregate output fell gradually from

2 
According to Judith Banister (2007, Table 10, based on the China Labor Statistical Yearbook) the average real
annual growth of wages in the urban manufacturing sector between 1992 and 2004 was 7.5 percent, and a mere
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 201

60

DPE/(DPE+SOE), in NBS
(DPE+FE)/Total, in NBS
50 DPE/(DPE+SOE), in CLSY
(DPE+FE)/Total, in CLSY

40
Percent

30

20

10

0
1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006
Year
Figure 2. Private Employment Share

Notes: The figure shows, first, the DPE share of employment as a share of SOE +  DPE employ-
ment in manufacturing (NBS 1998–2007) and in the urban sector (CLSY 1992–2007). Second,
it plots DPE + FE employment as a share of total employment in manufacturing (NBS 1998–
2007) and in the urban sector (CLSY 1992–2007).
Source: CSY and CLSY, various issues.

59 percent in 1998 to 47 percent in 2007 (Bai and Zhenjie Qian 2009, Table 4).3 The
falling labor share has contributed to rising inequality even across urban households
(Dwayne Benjamin, Brandt, John Giles, and Sangui Wang 2008).

B. Reallocation in Manufacturing

The reallocation of capital and labor within the manufacturing sector is a focal point
of our paper. Figure 2 plots alternative measures of the evolution of the employment
share of private enterprises. Our preferred measure is based on annual firm-level sur-
veys conducted by China’s National Bureau of Statistics (NBS), which include the
universe of Chinese industrial firms (manufacturing, mining, and construction) with
sales over 5 million RMB. The solid line plots the proportion of domestic ­private

4.6 percent if one excludes state-owned and collectively owned enterprises. In the same period, the average growth
rate of real GDP per capita was about 9 percent. Using data from the NBS Urban Household Surveys 1992–2006,
Suqin Ge and Dennis T. Yang (2009) report an annual growth rate of 4.1 percent for the basic wage (the lowest skill
category) and of 6.2 percent for workers with “middle-school education and below.” These are useful benchmarks
since they separate the wage growth due to technological progress from that due to human capital accumulation—
which reflects the increasing quantity and quality of education. Two additional remarks are in order. First, wages are
deflated using the provincial consumer price index (CPI). The annual CPI growth rate was on average 0.9 percent-
age points lower than that of the GDP deflator in these years. Second, the compliance rate for pension contributions
paid by employers declined dramatically in this period. Both considerations suggest that the growth of labor costs
per worker for firms was lower than the figures above.
3 
Bai and Qian (2009) report data until 2004. The estimates for 2004–07 were kindly provided by Bai and Qian.
202 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

enterprises (DPE) as a percent of DPE plus state-owned enterprises (SOE) in the


NBS surveys. It shows an increase from 4 percent in 1998 to 56 percent in 2007.
This is the most relevant measure for our theory.4 However, it excludes two impor-
tant firm categories: foreign enterprises (FE) and collectively owned ­enterprises
(COE). Therefore, for completeness, we also report a broader measure of the private
employment share, namely, (DPE+FE)/(DPE+FE+SOE+COE); see the dashed
line. The NBS measures of private employment share could be biased downwards,
due to the exclusion of small firms and nonindustrial firms. Therefore, we also report
the corresponding ratios from aggregate statistics from the China Labor Statistical
Yearbook (CLSY).5 According to this measure, the DPE/(DPE+SOE) share was 19
percent in 1997 and 54 percent in 2007. All measures suggest that the share of DPE
was low until 1997 and that most of the transition took place thereafter. This accords
well with the political events outlined above.

C. Productivity and Credit Frictions

DPE and SOE differ in two important aspects: productivity and access to financial
markets. SOE are, on average, less productive and have better access to external
credit than do DPE. This makes ownership structure a natural proxy for the different
types of firms in our theory. Figure 3 shows a measure of profitability, i.e., the ratio
of total profits (measured as operation profits plus subsidies plus investment returns)
to fixed assets net of depreciation. Based on this measure, the gap between DPE
and SOE is about 9 percentage points per year, similar to that reported by Nazrul
Islam, Erbiao Dai, and Hiroshi Sakamoto (2006).6 Large productivity differences
also emerge from TFP accounting: Brandt, Hsieh, and Xiaodong Zhu (2008, Table
17.3) estimate an average TFP gap between DPE and SOE of 1.8 during 1998–2004,
while Brandt and Zhu (2010) estimate a gap of 2.3 in 2004. Using a different meth-
odology, Hsieh and Klenow (2009) estimate a “revenue-TFP gap” of 1.42.
Financial and contractual imperfections are also well documented. In a cross-country
comparative study, Franklin Allen, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian (2005) find that China
scores poorly in terms of creditor rights, investor protection, accounting standards,
nonperforming loans, and corruption.7 In this environment, Chinese firms must rely
heavily on retained earnings to finance investments and operational costs. Financial
repression is far from uniform: private firms are subject to strong ­discrimination in

4 
NBS data are available only since 1998. The figure shows the share of firms classified as DPE by the NBS. If,
instead, we classify as DPE all firms with a private ownership share above 50 percent, the DPE shares would rise
from 12 percent in 1998 to 59 percent in 2007.
5 
One problem with the CLSY is that it does not classify ownership for all urban employment. More precisely,
the provincial data classifying employment according to ownership add up to only 60 percent of the aggregate
measure of urban employment. The dotted line is then computed by assuming that the ratio of DPE to SOE in the
unclassified aggregate data is the same as that in the provincial data.
6 
A concern with the official data is that the ownership classification is based on ownership at the time of initial
registration. However, many firms have subsequently been privatized. This problem is addressed by David Dollar
and Shang-Jin Wei (2007), who use survey data on 12,400 firms, classified according to their current ownership.
They find the average return to capital to be twice as high in private firms as in fully state-owned enterprises (Dollar
and Wei 2007, Table 6). Interestingly, collectively owned firms also have a much higher productivity than SOE.
7 
Interestingly, some reforms of the financial system have been undertaken, including a plan to turn the four
major state-owned commercial banks into joint-stock companies. This effort involves consulting foreign advisors to
improve the managerial efficiency of banks (Chi Hung Kwan 2006). In Section IIG we discuss the role of financial
development during the economic transition.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 203

35

SOE
DPE
30
FE

25

20
Percent

15

10

0
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007
Year

Figure 3. Total Profits over Net Value of Fixed Assets

Note: The figure plots the average ratio between total profits and the book value of fixed assets
across firms of different ownership, in percent.
Source: CSY, various issues.

credit markets. The Chinese banks—mostly state owned—tend to offer easier credit
to SOE (Genevieve Boyreau-Debray and Wei 2005). As a result, SOE can finance a
larger share of their investments through external financing. Figure 4 shows that SOE
finance more than 30 percent of their investments through bank loans compared to
less than 10 percent for DPE. Similarly, Dollar and Wei (2007, Table 3.1) and James
Riedel, Jing Jin, and Jian Gao (2007, Table 3.1) report that private enterprises rely
significantly less on bank loans and significantly more on retained earnings and family
and friends to finance investments. Other forms of market financing are marginal for
private firms. Despite the rapid growth of the Chinese stock market in recent years,
equity and debt markets continue to play an insignificant role for DPE, while these
markets have become increasingly important for large semiprivatized SOE (Neil
Gregory and Stoyan Tenev 2001; and Riedel, Jin, and Gao 2007, ch. 7).
Another sign that DPE are financially repressed is that both capital-output and cap-
ital-labor ratios are substantially lower in DPE than in SOE. In 2006, the average
capital-output ratio was 1.75 in SOE and 0.67 in DPE (China Statistical Yearbook
(CSY) 2007). In the same year, capital per worker was almost five times larger in SOE
than in DPE, although part of this difference reflects the higher average educational
attainment of SOE workers. This gap arises from both an intensive and an extensive
margin. First, SOE are more capital intensive even within three-digit manufacturing
industries, both in terms of capital per worker and in terms of the capital-output ratio
(Figure A1 in the Appendix). Second, DPE have taken over labor-intensive industries,
204 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

40

SOE
35 DPE
FE

30

25
Percent

20

15

10

0
1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Year

Figure 4. Share of Investment Financed by Bank Loans and Government Budgets

Note: The figure plots the average share of investment financed by bank loans and government
subsidies across firms of different ownership, in percent.
Sources: CSY 1998 to 2001 and 2003, China Economy and Trade Statistical Yearbook 2002
and 2004.

while the share of SOE remains high in capital-intensive industries. Panel A of Figure
5 plots the 2001 SOE share of total employment across three-digit manufacturing
industries against the capital intensity that each of these industries had in the United
States (2001 is the first year for which data are available). Already in 2001 SOE were
significantly more represented in those industries which are more capital intensive in
the United States. For instance, the SOE employment share in the ten most capital-
intensive industries was 57.9 percent, while in the ten least capital-intensive industries
it was 25.8 percent.8 The withdrawal of SOE from labor-intensive sectors has contin-
ued thereafter. Panel B of Figure 5 plots the percentage change in the SOE employ-
ment share between 2001 and 2007 against the capital intensity of the corresponding
industry in the United States. The correlation coefficient is highly positive (0.576).

D. Income Inequality

The economic transition of China has been accompanied by increasing income


inequality—even within the urban sector. For instance, the Gini coefficient of

8 
Industries are classified according to the capital-labor ratio in the United States in 1996 (classifying according to
their respective Chinese ratios would create an endogeneity problem). The US data are from NBER-CES Manufacturing
Industry Database, http://www.nber.org/nberces. We match the industries listed by the 2002, 2003, and 2004 China
Industrial Economy Statistical Yearbook (CIESY) to the SIC codes. Among 31 industries in CIESY, only 27 can be
matched, 18 at the SIC two-digit level and 9 at the SIC three-digit level. Details are available upon request.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 205

Panel A. 2001 employment share of SOE Panel B. Change in SOE employment share

100 20

Change in SOE empl. share, in percent


90
SOE empl. share, in percent

0
80
70 −20
60
50 −40
40
−60
30
20 −80
10
0 −100
0 50 100 150 200 250 300 0 50 100 150 200 250 300
Capital−labor ratio in United States Capital−labor ratio in United States

Figure 5. SOE Employment Shares across Industries

Notes: Panel A plots the 2001 employment share (in percent) of SOE in 28 major Chinese man-
ufacturing industries against their respective capital-labor ratio in the United States. Panel B
plots the change in SOE employment share (in percent) for these 28 industries between 2001
and 2007.
Sources: CIESY and CSY, various issues. We use the 1996 US capital-labor ratios, computed
from the NBER-CES manufacturing industry database. The industry petroleum and coal products
has extremely high capital labor ratio and is excluded from the figures for visual convenience.

income in China grew from 0.36 in 1992 to 0.47 in 2004. Our theory suggests that
this development may be due in part to the slow growth of wages relative to entre-
preneurial income. The pattern of income inequality across regions can offer some
insight. We classify Chinese provinces by the percentage of industrial workers who
are employed in DPE. Figure 6 shows a high positive correlation between the Gini
coefficient at the provincial level in 2006 and the employment share of DPE: prov-
inces with more private firms have a substantially higher income dispersion.

E. Foreign Surplus and Productivity Growth

Finally, the reallocation process in manufacturing has an interesting statistical


relationship with the accumulation of a foreign surplus and the productivity growth.
Consider, first, the foreign surplus. At the aggregate level, the timing of structural
change from SOE to DPE follows quite closely that of the accumulation of for-
eign reserves: Both accelerate around year 2000 (Figures 1 and 2). Interestingly, the
breakdown of the net surplus (savings minus investment) across provinces suggests
the same pattern in the cross section: the net surplus is systematically larger in prov-
inces with a larger increase in the DPE employment share.
We document this pattern by using data for 31 provinces with NBS data from
2001 to 2007.9 The dataset allows us to construct province-level measurements of
investment in fixed assets and savings (defined as provincial GDP minus private

The data cover all Chinese provinces for the years 2001–2003 and 2005–2007 (data for 2004 are not available).
9 

The employment statistics for 2001–2003 are from CIESY 2002–2004. The CSY 2006  –2008 provide data for
2005–2007. Annual data for investment, saving, and GDP are from the CSY (2002–2008).
206 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

0.65

0.6

0.55
Gini coefficient

0.5

0.45

0.4

0.35

0.3

0.25
0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1
DPE employment share

Figure 6. Income Inequality and Private Employment Share across Provinces

Notes: The figure plots the Gini coefficient of income against the DPE employment share across
31 Chinese provinces in 2006. The DPE share is computed as DPE/(DPE + SOE).
Source: CIESY 2007. Provincial Gini is from Report to the Seventeenth National Congress of
the Communist Party of China.

and ­government consumption expenditures). In column 1 of Table 1, we report


the results of a regression of the provincial net surplus-to-GDP ratio on the annual
change in the employment share of DPE, defined as the employment in DPE divided
by the sum of employment in DPE and SOE at the province level. To avoid that the
correlation be driven by a common trend in the two variables, we include time dum-
mies. The estimated coefficient is positive and highly significant: a 10 percentage
points larger increase in the DPE employment share is associated with an average
10 percentage point larger net surplus relative to GDP.10 Controlling for lagged pro-
vincial GDP per capita reduces the estimated coefficient from 1.0 to 0.89, which is
significant at the 10 percent confidence level.11

There is also a positive and highly significant (>99 percent) correlation between the ratio of net surplus to
10 

provincial GDP and the level of the DPE employment share. A 10 percentage point difference in the DPE employ-
ment share is associated with a 3.5 percentage point larger net surplus relative to GDP. In the theory presented in
Section II, both a high level and a high growth of the DPE share increase the foreign surplus, consistent with the
evidence in Table 1.
11 
All regressions described in this subsection are of the form
DEP_VA​R​rt​  = ​αt​​  + ​β1​​ (EMP​L​ PRIV  ​ )  + ​εr ​t​  ,
rt​  ​  −  EMP​L​ rt−1​
PRIV

where the dependent variable, DEP_VA​R ​r  t​  , is the provincial net surplus (savings minus investments) over GDP
in columns 1 and 2, the growth rate of provincial GDP per capita in columns 3 and 4, and the growth rate of the
industry-level value added per worker in columns 5 and 6. EMP​L​ PRIVrt​  ​denotes the DPE (or non-SOE, as discussed in
the text) employment share. In columns 2, 4 and 6, we control for lagged GDP per capita (value added per worker).​
α​t​denotes time-dummies, included in all regressions. Standard errors are clustered at the province (industry) level.
The coefficient of interest is ​β​1​.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 207

Table 1

(S-I)/GDP Growth rate of GDP p.c. Growth rate of VA p.w.


Dependent variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
D.(EMPLPRIV) 0.9964** 0.8920* 0.1893*** 0.1903*** — —
(0.4889) (0.4659) (0.0603) (0.0610)
D.(EMPLNONSOE) — — — — 1.4257*** 1.5973***
(0.4785) (0.3572)
L.(GDP p.c.) — 6.6268*** — −0.0646 — —
(2.3952) (0.2136)
L.(VA p.w.) — — — — — 0.1283***
(0.0152)
Year dummy Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Observations 124 124 124 124 112 112
R2 0.0424 0.1984 0.2252 0.2258 0.2104 0.2577

Notes: Dependent variables: (S-I)/GDP*100 is the provincial ratio of net surplus over GDP. S and I stand for aggre-
gate savings and investment, respectively. S = GDP − C − G, where C and G are household consumption and
government consumption expenditures, respectively. GDP p.c. is the real provincial GDP per capita in the value
of 10 thousand RMB (adjusted by provincial GDP deflators). VA p.w. is the industry value-added per worker (10
thousand RMB). Growth rates are in percent. Regressors: EMPLPRIV is equal to DPE/(DPE + SOE)*100, i.e., the
ratio of private employment over the sum of private and state employment. EMPLNONSOE is equal to (1 − SOE/
Total)*100, i.e., the ratio of non-SOE employment over total employment. D.(·) and L.(·) stands for the difference
and the one-period lag, respectively. Standard errors clustered at the province or industry level. Robust standard
errors are in brackets.
*** Significant at the 1 percent level.
  ** Significant at the 5 percent level.
   * Significant at the 10 percent level.

Consider, next, productivity growth. Columns 3–4 of Table 1 show that labor pro-
ductivity has grown faster in provinces where the DPE employment share has grown
faster. A 10 percentage points larger increase in the DPE share is associated with
a 1.9 percentage points higher annual productivity growth rate. Similar evidence
emerges from looking at the variation of the speed of reallocation across industries;
see columns 5–6.12 In this case, a direct measure of the DPE employment share
is not available before 2005, so we use the employment share of non-SOE over
total employment as a measure of reallocation. The coefficient of interest is positive
and significant. The quantitative effect is even larger: a 10 percentage points larger
increase in the non-SOE employment share is associated with a 14.3 percentage
points higher growth rate of productivity. The correlation is strengthened when con-
trolling for industry-specific lagged productivity.
The province-level results of columns 1–4 are mainly driven by cross-province
variation. The estimated coefficients become smaller and statistically insignificant
when province fixed effects are included (only marginally insignificant in the pro-
ductivity regressions of columns 3–4). In contrast, the cross-industry results hold
up to the inclusion of industry fixed effects, which leave the estimated coefficient
almost unchanged. Thus the results of columns 5–6 are mostly driven by within-
industry variation.

The data cover 28 major manufacturing industries. The sample period is 2001–07 (data for 2004 are not avail-
12 

able). The data for 2001–03 are from the CIESY (2002–04). The data for 2005–07 are from the CSY (2006–08).
208 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

II. The Benchmark Model

In this section, we develop a theory of economic transition consistent with the


empirical facts documented in the previous section.

A. Preferences, Technology, and Markets

The model economy is populated by overlapping generations of two-period


lived agents who work in the first period and live off savings in the second period.
Preferences are parameterized by the following time-separable utility function:

1− ​ _
1 ​   1− ​ _
1 ​  
​​(​c​1t​)​​ θ ​ − 1 ​​(​c2t+1
​ ​)​​ θ ​ − 1
(1) ​U​t​  = ​ _ +  β   ​ __
 ​  
      ​ 
,
1 − ​ _ ​  
1 1 − ​ _
1 ​  
θ θ
where β is the discount factor and θ is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in
consumption ​ct​​. We focus on the case when agents’ savings are nondecreasing in the
rate of return, i.e., when θ ≥ 1.
Agents have heterogeneous skills. Each cohort consists of a measure ​N​t​of agents
with no entrepreneurial skills (workers), and a measure μ  ​N​t​ of agents with entre-
preneurial skills (entrepreneurs) which are transmitted from parents to children.13
The population grows at the exogenous rate ν; hence, ​Nt​+1​ = ​(1 + ν)​​N​t​  . The rate
ν captures demographic trends, including migration from rural to urban areas. For
simplicity ν is assumed to be exogenous.
There are two types of firms, both requiring capital and labor as well as one man-
ager. Financially integrated (F) firms are owned by intermediaries (to be defined
below) and operate as standard neoclassical firms. Entrepreneurial (E) firms are
owned by old entrepreneurs. The entrepreneurs are residual claimants on the profits
and hire their own children as managers (cf. Caselli and Nicola Gennaioli 2006).
The key assumption is that, due to financial and contractual imperfections, only
some firms (F firms) have access to the deep pockets of banks, which are perfectly
integrated in international financial markets. Other firms (E firms) are owned by
agents who have superior skills and can run more productive technologies. However,
there are frictions restricting the flow of funds from the agents with a deep pocket
to those with superior skills. As a result, the latter end up being credit constrained.
This, in turn, allows less productive firms to survive in equilibrium.
Different microfoundations would be consistent with heterogeneous productivity
across firms to exist in equilibrium. Here, we present one such example: following
Daron Acemoglu et al. (2007), we assume that each firm can choose between two
modes of production: either the firm delegates decision authority to its manager, or
it retains direct control of strategic decisions. There is a trade-off. On the one hand,
delegation leads to higher total factor productivity (TFP)—e.g., the manager makes
decisions based on superior information. Thus, a firm delegating authority can attain
χ > 1 extra efficiency units per worker compared with a firm retaining centralized

13 
Lowercase characters will denote per capita or firm-level variables; uppercase, aggregate variables.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 209

authority. On the other hand, delegation raises an agency problem: the manager
can divert a positive share of the firm’s output for his own use. Such opportunistic
behavior can only be deterred by paying managers a compensation that is at least
as large as the funds they could steal. The key assumption is that entrepreneurs are
better at monitoring their managers, so that E firm managers can steal only a share
ψ < 1 of output. In contrast, F firms are weak at corporate governance and cannot
effectively monitor their managers: under delegation, all output would be stolen.
Thus, F firms will always choose a centralized organization, while E firms opt for
delegation, given a condition that will be spelled out below. Of course, less produc-
tive firms could not survive unless they had the benefit of having better access to
external funds. Such advantage is due to entrepreneurs being subject to credit con-
straints, as explained below.
The technology of F and E firms are described, respectively, by the following
production functions:

​y​Ft​  = ​k​ αFt ​​​(​
​  At​​ ​n​Ft​)1−α
​​ ​,  ​y​Et​  = ​k​ αEt ​​​(χ​
​  At​​ ​n​Et​)1−α
​​ ​,

where y is output and k and n denote capital and labor, respectively. Capital depreci-
ates fully after one period. In the case of F firms, the input of the manager is equiva-
lent to that of a regular worker and is included in ​nF​ ​. The technology parameter A
grows at an exogenous rate z; A ​ ​t+1​ = ​(1 + z)​​A t​ ​.
We now analyze agents’ savings. Young workers earn a wage w and deposit their
savings with a set of competitive intermediaries (banks) paying a gross interest rate​
R​ d​. These workers choose savings so as to maximize utility, (1), subject to an inter-
temporal budget constraint, ​c​ W 1t​ ​ + ​
c​ W  ​/
2t+1 ​ ​R​ d​ = ​wt​​  . This yields the optimal savings​
s​ t​ ​ = ​ζ​ ​​w​t​, where ​ζ​ ​ ≡ ​​(1 + ​β​ ​​R​ ​)​​ ​. Young entrepreneurs in E firms earn a
W W W −θ 1−θ −1

managerial compensation, ​m​ t​  . Their savings can be invested either in bank deposits
or in their family business.
Banks collect savings from workers and invest in loans to domestic firms and
foreign bonds. The bonds yield a gross return R. Contractual imperfections plague
the relationship between banks and entrepreneurs. The output of E firms is nonveri-
fiable, and entrepreneurs can only pledge to repay a share η of the second-period
net profits.14 In a competitive equilibrium, the rate of return on domestic loans must
equal the rate of return on foreign bonds, which in turn must equal the deposit rate.
However, lending to firms is subject to an iceberg cost ξ, which captures operational
costs, red tape, etc. Thus, ξ is an inverse measure of the efficiency of intermedia-
tion. In equilibrium, ​R​ d​ = R and ​R​ l​ = R/​(1 − ξ)​, where ​R​ l​ is the lending rate to
domestic firms.15
For F firms, profit maximization implies that ​R​ l​ equals the marginal product of
capital and that wages equal the marginal product of labor:

​  α  ​ 
​ αl  ​​  ​1−α ​ ​A​t​. ( )
_
(2) ​w​t​  = ​(1 − α)​ _
​R​ ​
14 
The assumption that output is not verifiable rules out that financially integrated firms hire old entrepreneurs. If
the entrepreneurs could commit to repay, all firms would be run by private entrepreneurs.
In the analysis of this section, ξ plays no role, so we could set ξ = 0 without loss of generality. However, ξ will
15 

become important in the extension about financial development.


210 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

Consider now the value of an E firm, owned by an old entrepreneur with capital​
k​Et​. This value is the solution to the following problem:
   
(3) ​ ​)​  = ​  
​Ξ​t​​(​kEt max     ​​{
 ​​(​kEt ​​ ​  − ​mt​​  − ​wt​​ ​n​Et​}​
​ ​)α​​ ​​​(χ​At​​​ n​Et​)1−α
​m ​​ , ​n​ ​
t Et

subject to the incentive constraint that ​m​t​ ≥ ψ​​(​kEt


​ ​)α​​ ​​​(​AEt
​ ​ ​n​Et​)1−α
​​ ​, where ​m​t​ is, again,
the payment to the manager, and arbitrage in the labor market implies that the wage
is as in (2).16 The optimal contract implies that the incentive constraint is binding:

(4) ​m​t​  =  ψ​​(​kEt


​ ​)α​​ ​​​(χ​At​​ ​n​Et​)1−α
​​ ​.

Taking the first-order condition with respect to ​n​E​and substituting in the equilib-
rium wage given by (2) yields that

( )
_
​ 1  ​  ​  l 1−α ​ kE​ t​ ​  1   ​ 
(5) ​n​Et​  =  ((1 − ψ)χ​)​α ​​​ _​ Rα​ ​​   ​​ ​ ​ _
_
  ​. 
χ​At​​

Plugging (4) and (5) into (3) yields the value of the firm:

_
1 _
(6) ​Ξ​t​​(​kE​ t​)​  = ​​(1 − ψ)​ ​​α  ​ ​​χ​​  α ​ 
​​R​​ ​k​Et​  ≡ ​ρE​ ​ ​k​Et​ ,
 l
1−α

where ​ρE​ ​ is the E firm rate of return to capital. In order to ensure that ​ρE​ ​ > ​Rl​​, we
make the following assumption.

χ​   ≡ ​​ _
_
​     ​ 
( )
1
ASSUMPTION 1: χ  > ​_ ​  1   ​ 
​​1−α ​.
1 − ψ
Given this assumption, (i) E firms prefer delegation to centralization and (ii)
young entrepreneurs find it optimal to invest in the family business. If Assumption 1
were not satisfied, there would be no E firms in equilibrium. Thus, a sufficiently
large productivity difference is necessary to trigger economic transition.
Consider, next, the contract between banks and entrepreneurs. The E firm’s
capital stock comprises the savings of the young entrepreneur and the bank loan,
​k​Et​ = ​s​ Et−1
  ​ 
​ + ​l​ Et−1
  ​.​
 The incentive-compatibility constraint of the entrepreneur implies
that ​R  ​​​l​ ​ ≤ η​ρE​ ​​(​s​E​ + ​l ​E​ )​. This constraint is binding if and only if η < ​R l​​/​ρE​ ​, which
l   E

we assume to be the case. Thus, the share of investments financed through bank
loans is

​l​E​ η​ρ​E​
(7) ​ _ = ​ _
   ​    ​  
.
​l​E​ + ​sE​ ​ ​R l​​

The managerial compensation must also exceed the workers’ wage rate (​mt​​ > ​wt​​ ). We restrict attention to
16 

parameters such that the participation constraint is never binding in equilibrium. In contrast, F firms are not subject
to any incentive constraint since their managers make no discretionary decisions. Thus, the managers’ participation
constraint is binding, and they earn the same wage as ordinary workers.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 211

The entrepreneur’s investment problem can be expressed as the choices of ​lE​ ​and ​sE​ ​
that maximize discounted utility, U, subject to ​c1​​  =  m − ​sE​ ​, ​c2​​  = ​ρ​E​​(​l​E​ + ​sE​ ​)​ − ​
R​l​​l​E​, and the incentive-compatibility constraint, (7). If we use (7) to substitute away​
l​E​, the problem simplifies to

( )
​(1 − η)​​ρ​E​ ​R​ l​ 1− ​ _θ ​  
1
1−  ​ _
1 ​   _
​​ ​    l  
 ​​ s​
  E​ ​​ ​ − 1
  __ ​
  ​​(m − ​sE )
​ ​
​ θ ​ − 1
__ ​R​​ − η​ρE​ ​
​  ​s​  ​ ​​  

max          +  β  ​ 
 ​       ​     .
E
1 − ​ _
1 ​   1 − ​ _ 1 ​  
θ θ
This implies that the optimal savings are s​ E​ ​  = ​ζE​ ​m, where

( ( ) )
1−θ −1
​(1 − η)​​ρ​E​​ R ​l​
​ζ​ ​  ≡ ​​ 1 + ​β ​ ​ ​​ _
E −θ
​  l     ​  ​​ ​ ​​ .​
​R​​ − η​ρE​ ​

B. Discussion of Assumptions

Before discussing equilibrium dynamics, we review our main assumptions.


The theory describes a growth model characterized by heterogeneous firms that
differ in productivity and access to credit markets. In the application to China, the
natural empirical counterparts of E firms and F firms are private and state-owned
enterprises, respectively. In our model, we do not emphasize the public ownership
of less productive firms. However, we focus on two salient features that are related
to the ownership structure. First, due to their internal bureaucratic structure, SOE are
weak in corporate governance and grant less autonomy and incentives to their man-
agement. This feature is well documented. For instance, Deqiang Liu and Keijiro
Otsuka (2004) show that profit-linked managerial compensation schemes are rare
for SOE, while they are 10 to 20 times more prevalent for township and village
enterprises. The rigidity of the SOE structure is emphasized by Eric C. Chang and
Sonia M. L. Wong (2004). Second, thanks to connections to state-owned banks,
SOE enjoy better access to borrowing (as suggested in the evidence discussed in
Section I).
In assuming F firms to be “competitive,” we abstract from other institutional fea-
tures, such as market power or distortions in the objectives pursued by firms and
their managers, that may be important in Chinese SOE. We do so partly for trac-
tability. However, we should note that since the 1990s, SOE have been subject to
an increased competitive pressure that has forced many of them to shut down or
restructure. Thus, we find the abstraction of competitive profit-maximizing firms
to be fruitful since it helps us to focus on the two distortions discussed above (in
Section IVB we explore the implications of granting F firms market power). Also
for simplicity, we model the labor market as competitive and frictionless. While
the Chinese labor market is characterized by important frictions (e.g., barriers to
geographical mobility), we do not think that including such frictions would change
any of the qualitative predictions of the theory, although it would affect the speed of
reallocation and wage growth.
212 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

The assumption that private firms are less financially integrated is also well rooted
in the empirical evidence discussed in Section I, showing that Chinese private firms
rely heavily on self-financing and receive only limited funding from banks and
insignificant equity funding. The assumption that monitoring is easier within flex-
ible organizations—and most notably in family firms—seems natural. In the model,
we do not emphasize interfamily altruistic links: parents transmit genetically entre-
preneurial skills to their children but also must provide them with incentives to avoid
opportunistic behavior. Alternatively, we could have focused on parental altruism
and assumed that incentive problems are altogether absent in family firms. In such
an alternative model, parents would leave voluntary bequests to their children, who
in turn would invest in the family firm.
The essential feature of our model’s reallocation mechanism is that financial and
contractual frictions obstruct the flow of capital towards high-productivity entre-
preneurial firms. If the entrepreneurs could borrow external funds without impedi-
ments, the transition would occur instantaneously, and only the more efficient E
firms would be active in equilibrium. The fact that the growth of E firms is con-
strained by the savings of entrepreneurs implies a gradual transition.

C. Equilibrium during Transition

In this section, we characterize the equilibrium dynamics during a transition in


which there is positive employment in both E and F firms. We drop time subscripts
when this causes no confusion. We start by showing that, due to the disadvantage
in raising funds, E firms choose in equilibrium a lower capital-output ratio than do
F firms. To see this, denote by ​κ​J​ ≡ ​kJ​​/​(​AJ​​ ​n​J​)​the capital per effective unit of labor.
As discussed above, in a competitive equilibrium, the lending rate ​R​ l​pins down the
marginal product of capital of F firms. Thus,

( )
​ αl  ​​  ​1−α ​ .
_
​κF​ ​  =  _
​  1   ​ 
(8)
​R​​

Since ​κF​ ​ is constant, the equilibrium wage in (2) grows at the rate of technical
change, z, as in standard neoclassical open-economy growth models. Equation (5)
then implies immediately that
−  ​ _
​κ​E​  = ​κF​ ​ ((1 − ψ)χ​)​ α .​
1  ​ 
(9)

Lemma 1: Let Assumption 1 hold, i.e., χ  > ​_ χ​.  Then E firms have a lower capital-
output ratio (​κE​ ​ < ​κF​ ​) and a lower capital-labor ratio than F firms.

Consider, next, the equilibrium dynamics. The key properties of the model are
that (i) ​KE​ t​ and ​At​​ are state variables (whereas ​KFt
​ ​ is determined by equation (8)
and is therefore not a state variable), (ii) capital per effective unit of labor for each
type of firm, ​κ​E​ and ​κF​ ​, is constant for each type of firm, and (iii) entrepreneurial
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 213

savings in period t (hence, ​K​Et+1​) is linear in ​KEt


​ ​  . These three properties imply
that the employment, capital and output of E firms grow at a constant rate during
transition.

Lemma 2: Given ​K​Et​ and ​At​​, the equilibrium dynamics of total capital and
employment of E firms during transition are given by ​KE​ t+1​/​KEt ​ ​ = 1 + ​γ​K​ E​ ​​ and​
N​Et+1​/​NEt
​ ​ = ​(1 + ​γ​K​ E​ ​​)​/​(1 + z)​ ≡ 1 + ​νE​ ​  , where

( ( ) )
−1
​R​l​   ​ ​​  ​(1 − η)​​ρ​E​​R​l​ 1−θ _ ψ _ ​ρ​ ​
(10) 1  + ​γ​K​ E​ ​​  = ​ _ + ​
β  −θ _
​ ​ ​​ ​   ​​ ​ ​​ ​​     ​ ​ 
 E ​  ,
1 − ψ α
1   ​ 
​Rl​​ − η​ρE​ ​ ​Rl​​ − η​ρE​ ​

and ​ρE​ ​ = (1 − ψ)1/α χ(1−α)/α ​Rl​​ and ​Rl​​ = R/​(1 − ξ)​. There exists χ​ ​  


= ​ χ​ (β, χ, ψ, η, α, ν, z, R, ξ) < ∞ such that the employment share of E firms ​NE​ ​/N

grows over time (i.e., ​ν​E​ > ν) if and only if χ > ​ χ​
 . χ​
​   is defined in the Appendix.
Moreover, χ​ ​   is decreasing in β and in η and increasing in ν and in z. Thus, the
employment share of E firms grows if, ceteris paribus, β or η are sufficiently large
or if ν or z are sufficiently small.

Equation (10) follows from the aggregation of the E firm investments, after
r­ ecalling that ​k​Et+1​ = ​s​ Et​ ​ + ​l​ Et​ ​, where ​s​ Et​ ​ = ​ζE​ ​​m​t​(with ​m​t​being determined by (4)),
and ​l​ Et​ ​is determined by (7). The constant growth rate of K hinges on the facts that
the rate of return to capital in E firms is constant and that young entrepreneurs’
earnings and savings are proportional to E firms’ profits. To illustrate this point,
suppose that z = 0. In this case, the workers’ wage remains constant during the
transition. However, the managerial compensation, ​mt​​, still grows in proportion to
the output of E firms. The growing earning inequality between workers and entre-
preneurs is key for the transition to occur, since (i) the investment of E firms is
financed by entrepreneurial savings, and (ii) constant wages avoid a falling return
to investment. If young entrepreneurs earned no rents and just earned a work-
ers’ wage, entrepreneurial investments would not grow over time. Substituting
the expression of ​ρ​E​ into (10) shows that the growth rate is hump-shaped in ψ. If
entrepreneurial rents are low (small ψ), young entrepreneurs are poor, and there
is low investment. However, if ψ is large, the profitability and growth of E firms
(​ρE​ ​) fall.
Note that both assumptions, that χ > ​χ _ ​ and that χ > ​ χ​  , require the TFP gap,​
χ​1−α​, to be large. Thus, generically, only one of them will be binding. Interestingly,
the theory can predict failed take-offs. For instance, suppose that initially both con-
ditions were satisfied. Then, the saving rate ​ζ​ E​would fall, due to, e.g., a fall in β, so
that χ​​​  (·, β)​ > χ > ​_
χ​ after the shock. Then investment by E firms would continue to
be positive, but their employment share would shrink over time.
The equilibrium dynamics of the set of F firms can be characterized residually
from the condition that ​K​Ft​ = ​κF​ ​   ​A​t​​(​N​t​ − ​NEt ​ ​)​, namely, F firms hire all workers not
employed by the E firms, and ​K​F​adjusts to the optimal capital-labor ratio. Standard
algebra shows that, as long as the employment share of E firms increases, the growth
214 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

rate of ​K​F​ declines over time.17 The aggregate capital accumulation of F firms is
hump-shaped during the transition. Initially, when the employment share of E firms
is small, ​KF​ ​grows at a positive rate (provided that either ν > 0 or z > 0). However,
as the transition proceeds, its growth rate declines and eventually turns negative.
Finally, standard algebra shows that GDP per worker is given by

​Nt​​
​Y​Ft​ + ​YE​ t​
(11) ​ _t  ​  = ​ _
​Y​​
 ​ 
​Nt​​
= ​κ​ αF​ ​​ 1 + ​ _
  
ψ _ ​N​ t​
   ​ ​ 
 E ​
1 − ψ ​Nt​​ t
  ​​A​​. ( )
The growth rate of GDP per worker accelerates during a transition as long as χ > ​ χ​  ,
reflecting the resource reallocation towards more efficient firms. Under the same
condition, the average rate of return to capital in the economy increases during the
transition, due to a composition effect, even though the rates of return to capital in
E firms and F firms are constant. Intuitively, this reflects the increasing share of the
capital stock of E firms that yields the high return ​ρ​E​.18
Figure 7 illustrates the transitional dynamics of employment, wages, output,
the average rate of return, foreign reserve over GDP, and the saving rate in the
model economy. In the figure, the transition ends in period T, when all workers are
employed by E firms. During the transition, the employment share of E firms grows
(panel A). Moreover, the average rate of return (panel B) and the output per effec-
tive units of labor (panel D) are growing, whereas wages per effective units of labor
(panel C) remain constant.

D. Foreign Surplus, Savings, and Investments

In this section, we derive the implications of the model for the accumulation of
foreign surplus, which is a focal point of our theory. Consider the banks’ balance
sheet:
η​ρ​E​
(12) ​K​Ft​  + ​ _    Et​  + ​Bt​​  = ​ζW
 ​ ​K​ ​ ​​w​t−1​​N​t−1​.
​Rl​​
The left-hand side of (12) consists of the banks’ assets: loans to F firms, loans to
E firms (as in equation (7)), and foreign bonds, ​B​t​. The right-hand side of (12)
captures their liabilities (deposits). The analysis of the previous section leads to the
following Lemma:

17 
More formally,
_​K​ ​
​  Ft+1 ​ 
​KF​ t​
​AFt+1
  = ​ _

​ ​_
​AFt

 ​ ​ 
​N​ ​
​ ​ ​NFt ​​
  (​N​E0​ _
  =  (1 + z)(1 + ν)​ 1 − ​ _
  Ft+1 ​     ​ 
 ​ ​​
​N0​​ 1 + ν (
1 + ​ν​E​ t+1

 ​
  ) )/ (
​N​E0​ _
​​ ​ ​   1 − ​ _  ​​​  ​ 
​ 0​​ 1 + ν
N (
1 + ​ν​E​ t

 ​
  ))
​​​   ≡  1 + ​γ​K​ F​ ​ t​  ,

( )( ) ( ( ))
−2
​N​ ​ 1 + ​ν​E​ t _ 1 + ​ν​E​ 1 + ​ν​E​ t
where ​ _
d  ​( 1 + ​γ​ ​ )  = ​ 1 + z _
​KF
​  t​ ( )​​  E0 ​​​  _
​   
 ​
  ​​​​ ln ​   
 ​
  ​​(ν − ​νE​ ​)​ 1 − ​​ _
​   
 ​
  ​​​   < 0 iff ​νE​ ​ > ν.
dt ​N0​​ 1 + ν 1 + ν 1 + ν
18 
More formally, the average rate of return is
​ρE​ ​​K​Et​ + ​ρF​ ​​K​Ft​ ​R   
​​
​ρt​ ​ = ​ __  ​  = ​ ___
( )
l
          ​,
​KE​ t​ + ​KF​ t​ 1  ​  ​N​Et​
1 − ​ 1 − χ((1 − ψ)χ​)​ α ​ ​ ​ _
−​ _
 ​  
​Nt​​
which is increasing as long as ​NE​ t​/​Nt​​increases.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 215

Panel B. Return on capital ( ρ)


E firm employment share Panel A. E firm employment share
1

Annualized return
Return E firms ↓
1.06

0.5 1.04
Average return ρt →

1.02 Return F firms ↑


0
T T
Time Time
Wage rate per efficiency unit

Output per efficiency unit


Panel C. Wage rate Panel D. Output
0.18
0.4
0.16
0.35
0.14
0.3
0.12 0.25
T T
Time Time

Panel E. Foreign surplus−GDP ratio, B/Y Panel F. Aggregate savings rate: S/Y
Savings rate

0.15 0.28
B/Y

0.1 0.26

0.05
0.24
0
T T
Time Time

Figure 7. Transition in the Analytical Model

Notes: The figure shows the evolution of key variables during and after the transition in the analytical model. Time
T denotes the end of the transition, when all workers are employed in E firms.

Lemma 3: The country’s foreign surplus is given by

(13) ​B​t​  = ​ ​ζ​W__


​​ 
(​ 1 − α)​​κ​ α−1
  
F​  ​
(
   ​  −  1  + ​(1  −  η)_
​(1 + z)​​(1 + ν)​
​N​ t​
​​  E ​   ​​κ​ ​ ​A​​ ​N​​  .
​Nt​​ F t t )
As long as the employment share of the E firms (​N​Et​/​Nt​​) increases during the
transition, the country’s foreign surplus per efficiency unit, ​B​t​/(​At​​​ N​t​), increases.
When the transition is completed (in period T, say) and all workers are
employed by E firms (​N​ET​/​NT​​ = 1), the net foreign surplus becomes ​B​T​
= (​ζ ​W​(1 − α)​κ​ α−1
F​  ​/((1 + z)(1 + ν)) − η)​ κ​ αF​ ​ ​A​T​ ​N​T​. If E firms are sufficiently
credit constrained (i.e., if η is low), then the transition necessarily ends with a posi-
tive net foreign position.
The intuition for the growing foreign surplus is that as employment is reallocated
towards the more productive E firms, investment in the financially integrated F firms
shrinks. Hence, the demand for domestic borrowing falls and banks must shift their
portfolio towards foreign bonds. Although there is a potentially increasing demand
216 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

of loans from E firms, this is small, due to the financial frictions. The growth rate of
the foreign surplus can exceed that of GDP, resulting in a growing ​B​t​/​Y​t​ratio (as in
panel E of Figure 7). This is the case if ψ and η are sufficiently small, i.e., if (asym-
metric) credit market and contractual imperfections are sufficiently severe.19
During the transition, the country’s gross saving rate, ​S​t​/​Y​t​(where ​St​​ = ​ζW
​ ​​w​t​ ​N​t​ + ​
ζ​  ​μ​mt​​), increases (panel F of Figure 7), whereas the gross investment rate, ​I​t​/​Y​t​
E

(where ​I​t​ = ​KEt+1
​ ​ + ​KFt+1
​ ​), falls. Both forces contribute to the growing foreign sur-
plus during the transition. The aggregate saving rate grows for two reasons. First,
workers employed by the F firms earn a constant share, 1 − α, of the output of those
firms and save a fraction ​ζW ​ ​. In contrast, workers employed by E firms save a frac-
tion ​ζW​ ​​(1 − α)​​(1 − ψ)​of the output of those firms. Second, young entrepreneurs
save a share ​ζ​ E​ψ. Thus, the saving rate out of the output of E firms equals (​ 1 − α)​​ζ​ W​
+ αψ​ζ​ E​ + ​(1 − α)​ψ​(​ζ  ​E​ − ​ζ  ​W​ )​which exceeds the saving rate out of the output of
F firms, since ​ζ​ E​ ≥ ​ζ​ W​.20
Next, consider the country’s investment. Suppose, for simplicity, that z = ν = 0.
Then every worker who is shifted from an F firm to an E firm works with less
capital. Therefore, domestic investment falls during the transition (a result which
generalizes to positive z and ν). We return to this prediction in Section IIG. For now,
we note that the growing foreign surplus does not hinge on a falling investment rate
since the saving rate is growing during the transition. The following proposition
summarizes the main results so far.

Proposition 1: Suppose that χ > max{​_ χ​,  ​  


χ​}. Then, during the transi-
tion, the equilibrium employment among the two sets of firms is given by ​NE​ t​
= ​K​Et​/​(​At​​​κ​F​​​(1 − ψ)−1/α
​​ ​​χ​−​(1−α)​/α​)​ and ​N​Ft​ = ​Nt​​ − ​NE​ t​ , where ​κ​F​ is given by
(8), and ​K​Et​ and ​A​t​ are predetermined in period t. The rate of return to capital is
constant over time for both types of firms, and higher in E firms than in F firms:
​ρ​F​ = ​Rl​​ and ​ρ​E​ = ​​(1 − ψ)1/α ​​ ​​χ​​(1−α)​/α​​R​l​. Capital and employment in E firms grow
over time as in Lemma 2. The stock of foreign assets per efficiency unit grows over
time, as in equation (13). If ψ and/or η are sufficiently small (strong contractual
imperfections and/or credit market discrimination), then the foreign surplus-to-
GDP ratio increases during the transition.

19 
More formally,
(​ 1 − α)​​κ​ α−1
F​  ​ ​N​ t​
​ __
​ζW ​​        ​ − 1 + ​(1 − η)_​​  E ​   
​_​t​
B ___ ​
( 1 + z )(
​​ 1 + ν )​ ​N​t​
​   ​   = ​             1−α
 ​​ κ​  F​  ​
,
​Yt​​ ψ _ ​N​ t​
1 + ​ _    ​ ​  E ​  
1 − ψ ​Nt​​
​ ​/​Nt​​provided that
which is increasing with ​NEt
__ ψ α​(1 + ν)​​(1 + z)​ _
1 + ​β−θ
​ ​​R​1−θ​
​      ​  < ​ __     
 ​ ​   ​      .
1 − η​(1 − ψ)​ ​(1 − α)​ ​R​l​
The set of parameters satisfying this condition together with Assumption 1 and the condition of Lemma 2 is
nonempty.
20 
To see this, recall that ​ρ​E​ > ​R​ l​. Since the intertemporal elasticity of substitution θ ≥ 1, the young entrepre-
neurs have a higher saving rate than the workers: ​ζ​ E​ ≥ ​ζ​ W​. This is the only result in the paper that hinges on the
restriction that θ ≥ 1.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 217

E. Post-Transition Equilibrium

Once the transition is completed (in period T in Figure 7) all workers are employed
by E firms. Thereafter, the theory predicts standard OLG-model dynamics. Consider,
for instance, the case of θ → 1 (log preferences). Then, the aggregate capital stock
is given by ​KE​ t+1​ = (β/(1 + β))(​Rl​​/(​Rl​​ − η​ρEt
​ ​))​mt​​, which implies—after substi-
tuting in the equilibrium expressions of ​m​t​ and ​ρ​Et​—a standard neoclassical law of
motion (see Appendix):
β __ ψ ​Rl​​     ​​ ​(​κ​ ​)α​​ ​.
(14) ​κ​Et+1​  = ​ _    ​ ​ 
      ​ ​ __
1 + β ​(1 + z)​​(1 + ν)​ ​R​​ − ηα​(1 − ψ)​​κ​ α−1
l
Et​  ​
Et

Investments bring about capital deepening until either the rate of return to capital
falls to ​R​ l​or the capital per efficiency unit converges to a steady state such that the
rate of return to capital exceeds ​R​ l​. Along the converging path, wages and output per
effective units, as well as the net foreign surplus, increase, while the rate of return
to capital falls.

F. Discussion of Results

Our theory fits some salient features of the recent Chinese growth experience
discussed in Section I. First, in spite of the high investment and growth of industrial
production, the rate of return of firms does not fall. Second, E firms—similarly to
DPE in China—have a higher TFP and less access to external financing than other
firms. This induces a lower capital intensity in E firms than in F firms (Lemma 1)—
again in line with the empirical evidence. Moreover, the rate of return to capital is
higher in E firms than in F firms, just as in the data DPE are more profitable than
SOE. Third, the transition is characterized by factor reallocation from financially
integrated firms to entrepreneurial firms, which is similar to the reallocation from
SOE to DPE in the data. Fourth, such reallocation leads to an external imbalance—
as in the data, the economy runs a sustained foreign surplus. Finally, the model
predicts a growing inequality between workers’ wages and entrepreneurial earnings.
While the focus of our paper is on China, our model can also cast light on the
experience of other industrializing countries. In particular, it provides a potential
explanation for Gourinchas and Jeanne’s (2009) observation that developing coun-
tries with high (low) TFP growth experience current account surpluses (deficits).
The hallmark of our theory is the reallocation from less to more financially con-
strained firms, which sustains high productivity growth and feeds a growing gap
between domestic saving and investment.21 According to Gourinchas and Jeanne
(2009), capital flows out of Korea and Taiwan in the 1980s represent two canonical
examples of the “allocation puzzle.” Similar to China 20 years later, those econo-
mies experienced an acceleration of productivity growth at a time in which they ran
large balance of payment surpluses.22

21 
Note that a low χ can make our mechanism go in reverse. As discussed above, if _​χ​ < χ < ​ 
  χ​
 , the employment
share of the E firms would fall over time, causing low TFP growth and a falling foreign balance. This is reminiscent
of the negative part of the allocation puzzle.
The annual growth rate of GDP per worker went up from 4.5 percent (1972–82) to 6.9 percent (1982–92) in
22 

Korea, and from 5.3 percent (1972–82) to 6.8 percent (1982–92) in Taiwan (Penn World Tables 6.2).
218 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

In the 1960s and 1970s, the industrialization process of South Korea relied sub-
stantially on foreign loans. As of the early 1980s, Korea had one of the highest ratios
of foreign debt to GDP ratio among developing countries. The imbalance was sig-
nificantly corrected in the 1980s. Especially in the second half of that decade, Korea
experienced booming growth and a sequence of large current account surpluses.
This structural change coincided with important changes in the Korean development
strategy. In the period 1960–1980, the government had provided strong support to
the large local conglomerates (chaebol). One pillar of this strategy was the strong
integration between banks and chaebol that granted the latter privileged access to
low-cost credit. Barriers to entry were substantial. In 1980, the ten largest chaebol
accounted for 48 percent of the Korean GNP (Linsu Kim 1997), while the employ-
ment share of manufacturing of small and medium enterprises (SME) with fewer
than 200 workers had declined from 68 percent in 1960 to less than 50 percent in
1980. Following the crisis of 1979–1980, the Korean government set out a major
policy shift. The Fair Trade Act of 1980 introduced a set of measures aimed to favor
competition and the entry of small firms, by, e.g., reducing subsidies to large firms,
regulating the chaebol’s market power, and offering tax breaks to SME (Heather
Smith 1994). As a result, the activity of SME soared. Their number more than dou-
bled between 1980 and 1990 (Moon-Gi Suh 1998, Table 3.13), and their employ-
ment share in manufacturing increased to 62 percent, a trend that continued in the
early 1990s (Jeffrey Nugent and Seung-Jae Yhee 2002, Table I). While the Korean
reform package included some elements of financial liberalization (privatization
of commercial banks), there were no major financial reforms until the 1993–1997
Financial Sector Reform Plan. Thus, throughout the 1980s and early 1990s, the
growing SME continued to be subject to heavy credit-market discrimination (Yung
Chul Park 1994; and Hyun-Han Shin and Young S. Park 1999). Similar to China,
the differential access to bank loans in Korea resulted in different capital intensi-
ties: in the period 1979–1997 the ratio of gross value added to total assets was 46
percent higher in large enterprises than in SME. Moreover, again similar to China,
“in the latter half of the 1980s the chaebol placed an increasingly disproportionate
emphasis on capital-intensive industries, using their ability to raise funds as the
main source of their competitiveness” (Smith 2000, 64). During the same period,
the chaebol system showed increasing cracks, resulting in a growing share of non-
performing loans and government-sponsored bailouts.23
Taiwan recorded trade deficits in all but two years during 1951–1970 (the sur-
pluses in 1964 and 1966 were merely 0.75 percent and 0.27 percent of GDP, respec-
tively). Thereafter, the trade balance turned consistently positive, except during the
oil shock (1974–1975) and in 1980, which had a tiny deficit. The size of the surplus
became especially remarkable in the 1980s: the annual net export–GDP ratio was a
staggering 12 percent in 1982–1988. Compared with Korea’s, the Taiwanese SME

23 
Park and Dong Won Kim (1994) note that “it was an open secret that Korea’s commercial banks were awash
in a sea of nonperforming loans” (p. 212). To remedy this situation, the government often identified healthy com-
panies in the same chaebol and induced them to absorb the troubled companies in exchange for subsidies or pref-
erential credit arrangements. For instance, in 1978 and 1986, Daewoo acquired at the government’s request the
Kyungnam enterprise, receiving in exchange preferential loans for 230 million USD and a transfer from the Korean
Development Bank for 50 million dollars to bail out its shipbuilding activity that was in distress. This influx of
money contributed significantly to the subsequent expansion of Daewoo. The Daewoo case is a good example of
how credit arrangements were biased in favor of large chaebol.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 219

played a more important role all along the process of industrialization. Nevertheless,
the U-shaped trajectory of the Taiwanese SME share is reminiscent of that of Korea:
the employment share of firms employing fewer than 100 persons fell from 58 per-
cent in 1961 to 36 percent in 1971 and then went up again to 59 percent in 1991.
This reversal was encouraged by policy changes, such as the plan of economic lib-
eralization of 1984 (Smith 1997).
Although bank-firm ties were weaker than in Korea and mainland China, access
to credit markets was highly unequal across Taiwanese firms. Public and large pri-
vate enterprises satisfied more than 90 percent of their external borrowing from the
formal financial sector, while SME had to rely on the informal curb market for a
large fraction of their financial needs.24 Jia-Dong Shea (1994) reports that “over the
1965–1988 period the rate of loans from financial institutions relative to value added
averaged 47 percent for public enterprises but only 29 percent for private enter-
prises” (p. 242). This was largely due to an “emphasis on collaterals rather than the
profitability or productivity of the borrowers” (p. 241). The interest in the informal
lending market was more than twice as high as the bank lending rate for unsecured
loans (see Smith 1997, Table 6). Shea (1994) concludes that
… easier access to bank loans by public enterprises and large firms inevitably induced
them to adopt more capital-intensive technologies, the result of which is a higher pro-
ductivity for labor and a lower productivity for capital in larger enterprises relative to
private and medium and small enterprises. If we could reallocate resources in such a way
to shift some capital from public and large enterprises to private and medium and small
enterprises … the total productivity of the whole economy might increase (p. 244).

Given these premises, the growth in the share of credit-constrained SME during
the 1980s contributed to productivity growth in Taiwan. Interestingly, the timing of
reallocation coincides with the massive accumulation of foreign reserves.
In conclusion, in spite of important differences, the 1980s experiences of Korea
and Taiwan share some commonalities with the recent development of China. All
featured a pronounced reallocation within the manufacturing sector characterized
by a strong growth of credit-constrained high-productivity firms. The reallocation
was accompanied on the macroeconomic front by an acceleration in productivity
growth and a foreign surplus. These features are consistent with the predictions of
our theory.

G. Financial Development

In Section IID, we noted that the theory predicts falling investment rates during
the transition. Different from a standard neoclassical growth model, the investment
rate does not fall in our theory because of capital deepening bringing about decreas-
ing returns. Rather, the fall is due to a composition effect: financially constrained
firms—which have a lower capital-output ratio—expand, while financially uncon-

24 
The Taiwanese curb market consists of all borrowing and lending activities occurring outside of the supervi-
sion and regulation of monetary authorities. According to Smith (1997), private enterprises borrowed 35 percent of
their external finance from such an informal market in the period 1981–1987. In the same period, SME borrowed
about four times as much from it as did large enterprises (see Smith 2000, Table 4.3).
220 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

strained firms contract. However, in the Chinese experience there is no evidence of


a falling investment rate: Bai, Hsieh, and Qian (2006) document that this rate has
instead followed an U-shaped pattern over the period 1992–2006.
One way to reconcile our theory with the data is to introduce a mechanism that
generates capital deepening within both E and F firms. A simple such mechanism is
a reduction of financial frictions during the transition. This change is motivated by
the observation that over the last decade the Chinese government has made consid-
erable effort to improve the financial system. For instance, the lending market has
been deregulated, allowing for both more competition and more flexibility in the
pricing of loans.25 A symptom of the improvement in the efficiency of the banking
system is the sharp reduction in the ratio of nonperforming loans (Podpiera 2006).
We incorporate financial development into our theory by letting the ice-
berg intermediation cost, ξ, fall over time, causing a decrease in the lending rate
​R​ lt​ ​ = R/​(1 − ​ξt​​)​. Ceteris paribus, a reduction in ξ and ​R​ lt​​ pushes up wages and capi-
tal-labor ratios in both E and F firms. The reduction in ξ over time can offset the ten-
dency for the investment rate to fall (and for the average rate of return to increase).
Such financial development slows the transition via two channels: (i) it increases
wages, which in turn strengthens the comparative advantage of F firms—entrepre-
neurs must save more to attract workers from F firms—and (ii) it reduces ​ρE​ ​and the
saving rate of entrepreneurs.26 We will return to the effects of financial development
in the next section.

III. Quantitative Analysis

We have focused so far on qualitative predictions of the theory. In this section,


we show that a calibrated version of our theory can also account quantitatively for
China’s growth experience during 1992–2007. In particular, it captures the rise in
private employment, the rise in foreign surplus and the U-shaped rates of investment
and aggregate savings.

A. The Quantitative Multiperiod Model

Given the goal to match the theory with China’s experience over the last 15 years,
a two-period OLG model, in which one period corresponds to 30 years, would be
inadequate. Therefore, we extend our theory to an Auerbach-Kotlikoff OLG model,
in which agents live T periods. Preferences are CRRA as in the model above, U
= ​∑ t=1 ​  ​​β​ t(​ (​ct​​)1−1/θ − 1)/​(1 − 1/θ)​. Agents are born with zero wealth and cannot
  ​ 
T

die with negative wealth. Workers supply one unit of labor each period. They retire
after J years of work. Their lifetime budget constraint is ∑ ​  t=1
  ​ 
​  ​​R​  −t​​c​t​ = ​∑ t=1
  ​ 
​  ​​R​  −t​ ​w​t​  ,
T J

where w ​ ​t​is the wage in period t.

25 
Before 1996, banks in China had to lend at the official lending rate. In 1996, a reform allowed them to set
the rate between 0.9 and 1.1 times the official rate. The upper limit gradually increased to 1.3 times for small and
medium enterprises in the late 1990s and was eventually removed completely in 2004 (Richard Podpiera 2006). The
increase in competition can also be seen in the loan share of the four major state-owned banks, which fell from 61
percent in 1999 to 53 percent in 2004, and by the growing equity market.
26 
An alternative form of financial development would be a reduction of η, i.e., better credit market access for
entrepreneurs. This would unambiguously speed up transition without affecting either capital intensity (​κE​ ​) or
wages. In China, there is no clear evidence that credit market access of DPE improved relative to SOE; see Figure 4.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 221

Young entrepreneurs work as managers for T/2 periods and as entrepreneurs


for the remaining T/2 periods—in line with the two-period model above. During
each period of their management phase, they earn a compensation given by (4) and
deposit their savings in banks.27 As they become entrepreneurs, they invest their
accumulated wealth, ∑ ​  t=1​ ​  ​​R​T/2−t​​(​mt​​ − ​ct​​)​, in E firms. They borrow part of the capi-
T/2

tal from banks, as in the two-period model (see equation (7)). After becoming entre-
preneurs, their budget constraint becomes

​R​ lt​​ρ​
​  Et​
​ ​  = ​ _
​c​t​  + ​sEt+1 s​Et​  ,
  ​ ​ 
​R​ t​ ​ − η​ρEt
l
​​

where the net return on equity, ​R​ lt​​ρ​


​  Et​/​(​R​ lt​ ​ − η​ρEt
​ ​)​, incorporates the gain from lever-
ing up equity by borrowing at a rate R ​ ​ lt​.​ 
Given an aggregate entrepreneurial capital stock ​KE​ t​  , prices and aggregate alloca-
tions are determined as in the two-period model. However, capital no longer depre-
ciates fully, so the law of motion for aggregate capital is ​K​t+1​ = ​(1 − δ)​​K​t​ + ​It​​,
where δ < 1 denotes the constant depreciation rate. Equations (2), (4), (5), and (7)
are unchanged, while equations (3), (6), (8), and (9) are modified to incorporate
the new assumption that δ < 1. To avoid the counterfactual prediction of declining
investment rates, we follow the discussion in Section IIG and allow ​ξt​​ to change
over time due to financial development. Aggregate savings equal aggregate produc-
tion minus consumption minus intermediation costs. Aggregate bank deposits is the
aggregate financial wealth of workers, retirees and managers. The initial distribution
of wealth is the only state variable. Given this, the model is solved by standard itera-
tion on the sequence of wage rates {​​ ​wt​​}​​ ∞ t=0 ​
. 28

B. Calibration

The calibration of our multiperiod model focuses on matching empirical moments


during 1998–2005 because this is the period covered by NBS. Some parameters are
calibrated exogenously. The rest are estimated within the model.
Consider, first, the parameters set exogenously. One period is one year. Agents
enter the economy at age 28 and live until 78 (T = 50). The average retirement age
in China is 58, so workers retire after J = 30 years of work. The annual deposit rate
is R = 1.0175, which is the average one-year real deposit rate (deflated by the CPI)
during 1998–2005. The capital share is set to α = 0.5, consistent with Bai, Hsieh,

27 
We assume that entrepreneurs must pay a (possibly infinitesimal) fixed turnover cost if they replace the man-
ager (e.g., new managers must be trained). Then, the T/2-period optimal contract has the same solution as the
repeated one-period contract. This is easily shown through backward induction. In the last-period stage game the
manager would steal unless his incentive constraint, (4), is met. Suppose that in the second-to-last period the entre-
preneur offered the manager a lower compensation and threatened to replace him if he stole. Such threat would not
be credible, as a new manager would be subject to the same incentive constraint in the last period. In addition, the
entrepreneur would have to pay the turnover cost. The same argument applies to earlier periods. So, the optimal
contract implies a managerial compensation given by (4) in every period.
28 
Given a guess for ​​{​wt​​}​​ ∞  ​
t=0 and the initial wealth distribution, the prices and allocations are given by the modi-
fied version of (2)–(9) and the individuals’ savings problems. Recall that in equilibrium ​w​t​ must be given by (2)
as long as ​NEt ​ ​ < ​Nt​​, and it is given by neoclassical dynamics after the end of the transition. If the implied alloca-
tions are consistent with the guess for ​​{​wt​​}​​ ∞  ​
t=0 , then an equilibrium has been found. Otherwise, update the guess for
​​{​wt​​}​​ t=0 ​. Iterate until convergence.

222 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

and Qian (2006), and the annual depreciation rate of capital is set to δ = 0.1. The
annual population growth rate is set to ν = 0.03, which is the average urban popula-
tion growth during 1998–2005 (according to the World Bank’s World Development
Indicators). Finally, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is set to θ = 2.
We now turn to the remaining parameters, which are estimated within the model.
The discount factor β is calibrated to match China’s average aggregate saving rates
during 1998–2005. This gives β = 0.997.
Recall that SOE report to have a more than three times larger share of invest-
ments financed through bank loans than do DPE (Figure 4). Since DPE have some
alternative sources of financing in addition to bank loans and withheld earnings,
such as friends and family, we assume that E firms can finance externally half their
investments. This implies that the share of profits entrepreneurs can pledge to repay
is η = 0.86.29
The parameters χ and ψ are set so as to match two empirical moments: (i) the
capital-output ratio of Chinese SOE is 2.65 times larger than that of DPE (average
1998–2005); and (ii) the rate of return to capital is 9 percent higher for E firms
than F firms (in line with Figure 3 and Islam, Dai, and Sakamoto 2006). This yields
χ = 4.79 and ψ = 0.45. This calibration implies a TFP gap of 2.2, which is in the
upper end of the range of the estimates in the literature discussed in Section I.30
The initial iceberg intermediation cost ξ is set so that the gross aggregate rate
of return to capital is 20 percent in the 1990s (in line with the estimates of Bai,
Hsieh, and Qian 2006). This implies that ​ρF​ ​ = 9.3 percent, ​ρ​E​ = 18.3 percent and​
ξ​t​ = ξ = 0.069 for 1992 ≤ t < 2000. For t ≥ 2000, the sequence of intermedia-
tion costs {​​ ​ξt​​}​​ ∞ 
t=2000 ​ 
is calibrated so as to best fit, given the other calibrated param-
eters, the time path of aggregate investment. In particular, we assume that ​ξ​t​ = 0
for t ≥ 2020 and set ​ξ​t​ = (1 − ((t − 2000)/19)υ)ξ for t ∈ ​[2000, 2019]​, where
υ = 2.38 is set to match the aggregate investment rate in 2007. The ​ρF​ t​implied by
the assumed sequence of ξ​ t​​is illustrated in panel A of Figure 8.
The rate of secular labor-augmenting technical progress is set to z = 3.8 percent
so as to target an annual 11.2 percent output growth rate over 1998–2005. This is
slightly lower than the output growth rate of China’s urban areas (based on the 35
largest cities, 11.7 percent) and slightly higher than the growth rate of industrial
output (10.4 percent).
Finally, consider the initial conditions. The initial entrepreneurial wealth is set so
as to match the average DPE employment share during 1998–2005. This yields a
1992 E firm employment share of 3 percent, which is close to the empirical obser-
vation. The initial life-cycle distribution of wealth for managers and entrepreneurs
is similar to a scaled-up version of the distribution of wealth over the life cycle for
workers in the initial steady state. The initial assets of the workers and retirees are

29 
In the data, even SOE finance about half of their investments through internal savings (China Fixed Asset
Investment Statistical Yearbook, various issues). However, this observation is per se no evidence of SOE being
subject to large credit constraints. For our purposes, it is crucial that DPE be significantly more credit constrained
than SOE. Therefore, we retain the convenient assumption that SOE are unconstrained.
30 
The comparison between TFP in the model and in the data is complicated by the peculiar technology of our
E firms. An income-based TFP calculation that excluded the payments to management would yield a TFP gap of
1.62. Given this ambiguity, we chose to calibrate χ so as to match the observed rates of return to capital rather than
matching TFP differences.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 223

Panel A. Rate of return in F firms Panel B. E firm employment share


0.8
0.1
0.6

0.4
0.05
0.2

0 0
1995 2000 2005 2010 1995 2000 2005 2010
Year Year

Panel C. Aggregate saving rate Panel D. Aggregate investment rate


0.6

0.4
0.5

0.35
0.4
0.3
1995 2000 2005 2010 1995 2000 2005 2010
Year Year

Panel E. Foreign reserve/GDP Panel F. TFP growth rate


0.1
0.6

0.4 0.05

0.2

0 0
1995 2000 2005 2010 1995 2000 2005 2010
Year Year

Figure 8. Transition in the Calibrated Economy

Notes: The figure shows the evolution of key variables during and after the transition in the calibrated economy. The
solid and dashed lines refer to the simulated results from the model and the data, respectively. The dashed and dotted
lines in panel B refer to private employment shares in NBS and CLSY data, respectively (see Figure 2).

set to 60 percent of the wealth in a steady state where there are only F firms. This
ensures that the model matches China’s net foreign surplus-to-GDP ratio in 1992.

C. Results

The dynamics of the calibrated multiperiod economy are illustrated in Figure 8.


Panels B–F display various salient macroeconomic outcomes of the model versus
the data.
First of all, the calibrated economy generates a speed of employment reallocation
comparable to its empirical counterpart (panel B). Second, the aggregate saving rate
(panel C) tracks remarkably well the U-shaped dynamics of the Chinese aggregate
saving rate. Recall that the economy is calibrated to match the average saving rate,
but not its time path. The decline during the 1990s is due to the assumption of low
initial wealth of workers, implying that they save a lot initially. The rise after 2000
is driven by the fast reallocation towards E firms, the managers of which have high
­saving rates. This is the mechanism driving increased savings in the ­two-period
model (Figure 7). Third, the calibrated model matches closely the trend of the net
224 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

foreign surplus (panel E), although the predicted growth is slightly too high in
1998–2002 and slightly too low in 2003–2007. Since the model matches the saving
rate, its success in this dimension hinges on predicting accurately the investment
rate (panel D). This was not a calibration target because ​ξt​​ determines the invest-
ment’s dynamics, not its level. Interestingly, the model predicts an acceleration in
the foreign surplus from 2007 onwards. This is driven by a continued increase in the
saving rate and a declining investment rate.
Consider now the evolution of aggregate TFP, computed as a standard Solow
residual of a one-sector aggregate production function using aggregate capital and
labor as inputs. This is plotted in panel F. The 1998–2005 annualized growth rate is
5.9 percent. This is in the range of the estimates from empirical productivity studies.
Barry Bosworth and Susan M. Collins (2008) estimate a TFP growth rate in indus-
try of 6.1 percent over the period 1993–2004. Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang
(2009) report estimates of the annual TFP growth of 4 percent and 7.7 percent.31
We can decompose the TFP growth rate into one part due to exogenous technical
change and another part due to reallocation. Reallocation yields 4.2 percent annual
TFP growth. Thus, about 70 percent of the 1998–2005 TFP growth in our model
is driven by reallocation from less efficient F firms to more efficient E firms. This
large effect is broadly consistent with the findings of Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and
Zhang (2009), who estimate that between 42 percent and 67 percent of the aggre-
gate TFP growth in Chinese manufacturing was due to productivity differences
between firms entering and exiting during 1998–2005. They also document that
SOE and collectively owned enterprises represent the lion’s share of exiting firms,
while most that enter are DPE. See their Figure 1.32 However, our model implies
a substantially larger gain from reallocation than what Hsieh and Klenow (2009)
estimate; they find an annual TFP growth gain from reallocation between Chinese
manufacturing firms of 2 percent. Finally, the model predicts an increasing TFP
growth over time (panel F). This is also consistent with Brandt, Van Biesebroeck,
and Zhang (2009), who find an even steeper increase in the growth rate than pre-
dicted by our model.
Finally, our model implies an average wage growth of 5 percent per year, which
is reasonable given the discussion in footnote 2. In the model, wage growth arises
from both technical change and capital deepening. The assumption of a competitive
and frictionless labor market implies that during transition the growth of DPE has no
effect on wages. Introducing frictions may deliver higher wage growth.
The most problematic feature of our calibration concerns the average rates of
return within SOE and within DPE. In the calibration these rates fall due to financial
development (recall that ​ρ​F​ and ​ρE​ ​ would be constant in the absence of ­financial

Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang (2009) use the NBS. The 4 percent estimate is obtained by calculating
31 

the difference between the weighted average productivity level of all firms active in 2006 and in 1998 (Table 7).
The 7.7 percent estimate is the authors’ “preferred estimate” found by averaging year-to-year productivity growth
over the entire sample of firms (Figure 3).
Brandt, Van Biesebroeck, and Zhang (2009) conclude that “relative to the US experience, productivity growth
32 

in China’s manufacturing sector is to a much greater extent due to changes at the extensive margin, entry and exit.”
In our model, the number of firms is indeterminate, due to constant returns to scale. Thus, we cannot distinguish
between reallocation along an extensive and an intensive margin. Alternatively, we could have considered a model
where firms face entry costs and decreasing returns. In such a model, reallocation would occur along both the
extensive and intensive margin.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 225

development). However, Figure 3 suggests that both rates of return increased ­during
1998–2005. This hints at the presence of additional sources of efficiency gains
within SOE and DPE that offset the decreasing returns. In part, this discrepancy
can be related to the stark way in which we have mapped the theory into the data.
In particular, we have interpreted F and E firms as SOE and DPE, respectively,
abstracting from within-group heterogeneity. Since our theory emphasizes realloca-
tion across firms of heterogeneous productivities, it is natural to expect that some
reallocation took place within each group, e.g., through the entry of new efficient
firms and the exit of less productive ones. A simple extension of our theory where
entrepreneurs differ in human capital and productivity (i.e., with a distribution of​
χ​i​across E firms) would be consistent with the observation of an increasing return
to capital within DPE. Intuitively, since the growth of E firms is constrained by
retained earnings, more productive E firms would grow faster, causing an increase
of the average productivity of E firms over time.33 No such straightforward exten-
sion works for F firms, since there can be no productivity differences across them in
equilibrium. This is due to the simplifying assumption that F firms are subject to no
credit constraints. In principle, one could relax this assumption and generate real-
location within SOE. We do not pursue this extension. Instead, in the next section
we explore an alternative multi-industry set-up in which F firms have market power
in some industries. This extension predicts increasing profit rates in surviving SOE.
In conclusion, this calibration exercise has shown that reallocation from F firms to
E firms can generate quantitative outcomes that are broadly in line with the empiri-
cal facts for China, suggesting that our mechanism might be important for under-
standing the empirical facts laid out in Section I.

D. Robustness

To illustrate the behavior of the model we examine four alternative parameteriza-


tions: (1) no financial development, (2) no borrowing for entrepreneurs, (3) log
preferences, and (4) low TFP advantage. In each case we change β so as to match
the average aggregate saving rates during 1998–2005, as we did in the benchmark
calibration. Suppose first that there is no financial development. This case is labeled
experiment 1 and is plotted against the benchmark calibration in Figure 9. The
dynamics of the no–financial development economy are very similar to those of the
benchmark economy until 1999. As discussed in Section IIG, the investment rate in
this experiment falls monotonically during the transition and increases sharply when
the transition is completed. The transition is faster than in the benchmark economy
because F firms are not able to borrow at lower and lower interest rates after 1999.
Thus, without financial development the foreign reserves and TFP would grow sub-
stantially faster after 1999.
Consider now the case when entrepreneurs cannot borrow at all, i.e., η = 0 (exper-
iment 2 in Figure 9). For simplicity, we maintain the assumption that ​ξ​t​is constant

Let ​χ​i​denote firm ​i′​  s productivity and ​K​i​be the corresponding capital stock. Then, the rate of return to capital
33 
 
for firm i is = ​ρiE
​ ​ (​ 1 − ψ)1/α​  ​χ​ (1−α)/α
i​  ​ ​R​ l​. If ​ρEt
​ ​ = ​∑ ​  ​   ​​ρ​iE​​K​it​/​KEt
​ ​ denotes the average rate of return of E firms, it is
easy to show that ​ρE​ ​grows over time, because the growth rate of ​K​it​is increasing in ​χi​​ . Intuitively, more efficient E
firms have higher earnings and can finance larger investments. So they grow faster than less efficient firms, thereby
increasing the average rate of return of DPEs over time. We develop this extension in the Appendix.
226 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

Panel A. Rate of return in F firms Panel B. E firm employment share


1
0.1

benchmark
experiment 1
0.5
0.05
experiment 2
experiment 3
0 0
1995 2000 2005 2010 1995 2000 2005 2010
Year Year

Panel C. Aggregate saving rate Panel D. Aggregate investment rate


0.6
0.6
0.4
0.5

0.4 0.2

0.3 0
1995 2000 2005 2010 1995 2000 2005 2010
Year Year

Panel E. Foreign reserve/GDP Panel F. TFP growth rate


1.5
0.15
1
0.1
0.5
0.05
0
0
1995 2000 2005 2010 1995 2000 2005 2010
Year Year

Figure 9. Sensitivity Analysis

Notes: The figure shows the evolution of key variables in the calibrated economy (solid line) and various alter-
native parameterizations. Experiment 1 has a constant ξ. Experiment 2 has η = 0. Experiment 3 has logarithmic
preferences.

(no financial development). The key difference relative to the benchmark economy
is that the transition is slower. For example, the E firm employment share reaches
20 percent in 2015, while in the benchmark this level is reached already in 2000.
Consequently, both the growth in foreign surplus and TFP are substantially slower
than in the benchmark economy. The foreign reserves-to-GDP ratio, for instance,
starts to grow only after 2000 and then gradually climbs up to 25 percent in 2017
and 50 percent in 2021.
To examine the role of intertemporal elasticity to substitution θ we solve the
model for θ → 1, i.e., logarithmic preferences (experiment 3 in Figure 9). We also
recalibrated the sequence {​​ ​ξt​​}​​ ∞  
t=2000 ​ 
so as to match the investment rate in 2007 (recall
that the benchmark economy was calibrated in the same way). The results are quali-
tatively similar to the benchmark case, including a growing foreign surplus. However,
the transition is slower. This implies a higher investment rate and a lower growth of
foreign reserves and TFP. The two-period OLG model provides intuition for the slow
transition. The entrepreneurs’ savings rate ​ζ​ E​is lower when θ is lower, and Lemma 2
showed that in the analytical model the speed of transition is increasing in ζ​ ​ E​.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 227

Finally, suppose the TFP advantage of E firms is low, ​χ1−α ​ ​ = 2.0, compared to
2.2 in the benchmark calibration. This implies a smaller difference ​ρ​E​ − ​ρF​ ​ and a
smaller difference between capital-output ratios of E firms and F firms than in the
benchmark calibration. This in turn implies a slower transition because entrepre-
neurial firms are less profitable. To understand why, recall that a lower χ implies
a lower return ​ρ​E​. This in turn lowers the rate of transition because entrepreneurs
and managers have less income and, hence, less savings. Quantitatively, the low-
χ economy is almost indistinguishable from experiment 3, so we omitted it from
Figure 9.

IV.  A Two-Sector Model

In this section, we extend the model to a two-sector environment in which


industries have different capital intensities. In such environment, credit-market
discrimination generates an endogenous comparative advantage for E firms in labor-
intensive industries, leading them to specialize in those industries, and inducing F
firms to retreat to capital-intensive industries. This prediction is consistent with the
empirical evidence: as we documented in Section I, the share of SOE has declined
dramatically in Chinese labor-intensive industries, while remaining high in capital-
intensive industries. The retreat from labor-intensive industries has further widened
the gap between the capital-output ratio of SOE and that of private firms since the
mid-1990s (Robert Dekle and Guillaume Vandenbroucke 2006).
For simplicity, we specialize the analysis to logarithmic utility and assume that
η = 0 ; i.e., entrepreneurs cannot get any external financing. Moreover, we assume
that ν = ξ = z = 0. None of these assumptions are essential for the results.

A. Capital- and Labor-Intensive Industries

In this section, we assume the final good, ​Yt​​, to be a CES aggregate of two inter-
mediate goods:

( )
_ σ
σ−1
​ _ σ−1
​ _   ​    ​ 
(15) ​Y​t​  = ​​ φ(​Y​ k t​ ​​)​ σ ​  +  (​Y​ lt​ ​​ )​ σ ​ ​​σ−1 ​ .

 ​   ​ 

The superscripts k and l stand for capital- and labor-intensive intermediate goods,
respectively, and σ is the elasticity of substitution between these goods. Both goods
can be produced by either E or F firms, with the following technologies:

(16) ​y​ lJ ​ ​  = ​​(​A​ lJ ​)​  1−α


​​ ​ ​​(​k​ lJ ​)​  ​​ ​ ​​(​n​ lJ ​)​  1−α
​​ ​,  ​y​ kJ​ ​  = ​​(​A​ kJ​)​  1−α
α
​​ ​​k​ kJ​,​ 

where J ∈ ​{E, F}​. The production technology for the labor-intensive good is identi-
cal to that of our benchmark model. The assumption that the capital-intensive good
is produced without labor is for convenience. We assume the same TFP gap between
E and F firms in the two industries. More formally, χ ≡ ​A​ kE ​/​  ​A​ kF ​ ​ = ​A​ lE ​/​  ​A​ lF ​.​  Raising
both ​A​ kJ​​ and ​A​ lJ ​​ to the power of 1 − α ensures that the TFP gap is the same across
industries.
228 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

We set the final good to be the numeraire. Profit maximization of final producers
subject to (15) yields that

( )
σ

(17) ​ _
​Y​ k ​​   = ​​ φ ​ _​P​ l​  ​ ​​ ​,
​Y​ l​ ​P​ k​

where ​P​ k​and ​P​ l​are goods prices. The standard price aggregation holds:

( ) ​ _
1   ​ 
(18) ​​ ​φσ​ ​​(P k​​​)1−σ
​ ​  +  (​P  ​l​  ​)1−σ
​ ​ ​​1−σ ​  =  1.

When F firms are active in the production of the labor-intensive good, they behave
as in the benchmark model of Section II. In particular, the following analogues of
equations (2) and (8) hold:
α
(19) w  = ​P​ lt​​(​  1 − α)​​A​ lF ​​​(​  ​κ​ lF ​)​  ​​ ​,

( ) ​P​  l​α ​ 
​κ​ lF ​ ​  = ​​ ​ _
_
​     ​ 
1
(20)  ​​1−α ​ .
R
In addition, when F firms are active in the production of the capital-intensive
good, perfect competition pins down its price level:

(21) ​P​ k​​​(​A​ kF ​)​  1−α


​​ ​  =  R.

Given these equilibrium conditions, we can determine the return E firms require
to invest in each industry. The following lemma characterizes the patterns of spe-
cialization of F and E firms. Recall that ​KE​ t​is predetermined by the entrepreneurial
savings.

Lemma 4: (i) If, in period t, ​K​ lF t​ ​ > 0 and ​K​ kF t​ ​ > 0, then ​ρ​ lEt  ​ ​ > ​ρ​ kEt  ​,​  implying that​
K​ lE t​ ​ = ​KE​ t​ and ​K​ kE t​ ​ = 0. (ii) If, in period t, ​K​ lE t​ ​ > 0 and ​K​ kE t​ ​ > 0, then R ≥ ​ρ​ kFt  ​ ​ >
​ρ​ lFt  ​,​  implying that K ​ ​ lF t​ ​ = 0 and K
​ ​ kF t​ ​ ≥ 0.

Lemma 4 characterizes the dynamics of the equilibrium in the two-sector model.


There are four distinct stages of the transition:

Stage 1: Only F firms invest in the capital-intensive sector, while both E and F
firms invest in the labor-intensive sector. The employment share of F firms declines
as entrepreneurial investment increases. Consequently, the employment share of F
firms decreases over time in the labor-intensive industry. However, the capital-inten-
sive good is produced only by F firms. This is consistent with the retreat of Chinese
SOE from labor-intensive industries. Due to this specialization in the capital-inten-
sive industry, the average capital-output ratio of F firms increases during the transi-
tion, consistent again with the Chinese evidence. Eventually, F firms completely
abandon the labor-intensive activity.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 229

Stage 2: All workers are employed by E firms. Entrepreneurs continue to invest


their savings in the labor-intensive sector since it yields a higher return than do both
foreign bonds and investment in the capital-intensive industry. However, the labor-
intensive sector’s rate of return falls over time, because employment cannot grow,
and investment leads to capital deepening. Consequently, wages grow. Eventually,
the incentive to accumulate capital in the labor-intensive industry comes to a halt.
​ ​ > α​(1 + β)​/​(βψR)​, entrepreneurs turn to the capital-intensive industry and
If ​χ1−α
the economy enters stage 3. If ​χ1−α​ ​ < α​(1 + β)​/​(βψR)​, the economic transition
stops and the capital-intensive industry remains dominated by F firms, in spite of
their lower productivity.

Stage 3: E firms invest in both industries. Gradually, F firms are crowded out of
the capital-intensive industry.

Stage 4: The economy enters the post-transition equilibrium of Section IIE.

Table 2 summarizes the main features of each of the four stages of the transition.
The complete characterization of the equilibrium can be found in the Appendix.
In conclusion, this extension of our benchmark model has shown that the pres-
ence of asymmetric credit frictions generates comparative advantages for credit-
constrained firms to specialize in labor-intensive activities. Since the growth of E
firms is only gradual, we see F firms first withdrawing from labor-intensive indus-
tries and then, possibly, from capital-intensive industries. The theory also offers
the interesting possibility that E firms never take over capital-intensive industries.
The steady state may be characterized by high-productivity firms in labor-intensive
industries and low-productivity firms in capital-intensive industries.

B. Monopoly in the Capital-Intensive Industry

As discussed in Section IIIC, there is evidence that profits have increased over
time in surviving SOE. This may seem puzzling since a large number of SOE have
been declining. In this section, we extend the two-sector model and assume that
the labor-intensive industry is competitive, while the capital-intensive industry is
monopolized by a large F firm. With this set-up, the theory predicts that as the tran-
sition proceeds, the increased efficiency in the labor-intensive industry increases the
profit of the monopolist F firm.
The assumption that SOE have market power in capital-intensive industries is
consistent with the industrial policy in China. Since 1997, under the slogan “Zhuada
Fangxiao” (“grab the big ones and release the small ones”), the Ninth Five-Year
Plan exposed SOE to competition in labor-intensive industries, while promoting the
merger and restructuring of SOE in strategic capital-intensive sectors—e.g., pet-
rochemicals, railway, and telecommunication—into large transregional groups.34
This strategy gave surviving SOE a significant monopoly power in their industries.

34 
By the end of 2001, there were 179 Chinese enterprises with value added over 500 million USD. Of them, 165
were state-owned or state-controlled groups. The stated objective of the policy was to help large SOE be competi-
tive internationally like chaebol in Korea.
230 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

Table 2—Investment Patterns in E and F Firms, across Transition Stages

Stage 1 Stage 2 Stage 3 Stage 4


Industry E F E F E F E F
Labor-intensive Yes Yes Yes No Yes No Yes No
Capital-intensive No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes No

Arguably, this has been a main reason why SOE profits have soared over the last ten
years (Figure 3).
Without loss of generality, we normalize ​A​ kF ​ ​ = 1. Moreover, to guarantee that
the problem of the monopolist is well defined, we assume that σ > 1. The model is
identical to the two-sector model of Section IVA, except that the capital-intensive
sector is now a legal monopoly. We assume the monopoly firm to be one-period
lived, and to be owned by a set of old agents (“bureaucrats”) who are neither work-
ers nor entrepreneurs, and who neither produce nor consume in the first period of
their lives. This implies that the monopoly has a static objective function.35
Formally, the equilibrium allocation differs from the competitive equilibrium
of Section IVA in two respects. First, ​y​ kE ​ ​ = 0, since E firms cannot enter the
capital-intensive industry. Second, equation (21) does not hold, since there is no
competition driving profits to zero in the capital-intensive industry. Instead, ​P​ k​ is
determined by the profit-maximizing choice of a price-setting monopolist, max​ ​P​    ​k​​ ​Π​ kt​ ​
≡ ​(​P​ kt​ ​ − R)​​K​ k​, subject to technology (16) and the equilibrium conditions (17),
(18), and (20).

Proposition 2: The optimal markup set by the monopolist in the capital-inten-


sive industry, ​P​ k​/R, is the unique solution satisfying the following condition:

( ) ( ( ) )( )
−1 −1
​P​ k​ ​ ​P​ k​ ​ ​Y​ lF t​​ 
(22) σ ​​ _
​  t ​   ​​ ​ − ​(σ − 1)​  = ​ 1 − ​​ _
​  t ​   ​​ ​ ​​ σ − 1 + ​ _   _
1   ​ ​   ​  ​
R R 1 − α ​Y​ lt​​ 

​φ​σ​​R​1−σ​​​(​P   ​k​/R)​1−σ
​ ​
× ​ __       ​.
1 − ​φ​ ​​R​ ​​​(​P  ​​/R)​1−σ
σ 1−σ k
​ ​

The optimal markup is decreasing in the share of F firms (​Y​ lF ​/​  ​Y​ l​ ) in the labor-
intensive industry. Thus, monopoly power increases during a transition in which the
share of F firms declines in the labor-intensive industry.

Note that the left-hand side of (22) is decreasing in ​P​   k​/R, while the right-hand
side is increasing in ​P  ​k​. This guarantees that (22) pins down the unique equilibrium
solution. Since the right side is increasing in ​Y​ lF ​/​  ​Y​ l​, it is then immediate to establish
that the markup is decreasing in the share of F firms in the labor-intensive industry.

35 
Since F firms have no equity capital and perfect access to external finance, they face no dynamic investment
problem. However, a long-lived monopoly could use its market power to affect the speed of transition, which in turn
would affect its future profits. This is an artifact of the assumption (which is made for simplicity) that there is only
one large monopolized industry in the economy. If there were a continuum of monopolized industries, each firm
would maximize its period-by-period monopoly profit, and the results would be identical to those in this section.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 231

Intuitively, as the productivity of the labor-intensive industry increases during the


transition, so does the demand for the capital-intensive good, which strengthens the
power of the monopolist.36

V.  Conclusions

In this paper, we have constructed a neoclassical model augmented with financial


and contractual imperfections that affect different types of firms in the economy
asymmetrically. The model is consistent with salient patterns of the recent Chinese
experience, most notably sustained high returns on investment in spite of high
capital accumulation, large productivity differences across firms, reallocation from
low-productivity to high-productivity firms (as documented by Hsieh and Klenow
2009), and the accumulation of a large foreign surplus. A calibrated version of the
model has been shown to be quantitatively consistent with these facts.
A number of simplifications that were made for the sake of tractability will be
relaxed in future research. In particular, we do not explore in depth potential deter-
minants of the high household savings in China. Theories of entrepreneurial sav-
ings with financial constraints such as Quadrini (1999) and Marco Cagetti and
Mariacristina De Nardi (2006) could add new insights to reinforce and complement
the mechanism of our theory. Moreover, by assuming an exogenous rate of TFP
growth, we have abstracted from endogenous technology adoption, which may be
an important driver of China’s performance.
In spite of these limitations, we believe the theory explored here offers a useful
tool for understanding one of the major puzzles of the recent growth experience:
how is it that China grows at such a stellar rate and at the same time increases its for-
eign surplus? Some commentators have tried to explain this puzzle by attributing it
to government manipulation of the exchange rate that holds the value of the Chinese
currency artificially low. This argument is controversial, as it attributes a long-stand-
ing imbalance to a nominal rigidity, without explaining why the peg of the nominal
exchange rate did not trigger an adjustment of the real exchange rate through infla-
tionary pressure (see Song, Storesletten, and Zilibotti 2010). In this paper we have
provided substantial empirical evidence corroborating the economic mechanism of
an alternative theory that explains the build-up of a large foreign surplus in China as
the outcome of structural imperfections. We believe this is a more credible explana-
tion for a phenomenon that has by now persisted for almost two decades.

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion, Claire Lelarge, John Van Reenen, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2007.
“Technology, Information, and the Decentralization of the Firm.” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
122(4): 1759–99.
Allen, Franklin, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian. 2005. “Law, Finance, and Economic Growth in China.”
Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1): 57–116.
Antrás, Pol, and Ricardo J. Caballero. 2009. “Trade and Capital Flows: A Financial Frictions Perspec-
tive.” Journal of Political Economy, 117(4): 701–44.

36 
A closed-form solution obtains as σ → 1 (Cobb-Douglas). Then, ​P​ k​/R = 1 + ​(1 − α)​​(1 − φ)​/​(φ​Y​ lFt  ​/​  ​Y​ lt​)​  ​.
Note that in this particular case the markup goes to infinity as the share of F firms goes to zero, due to the unit
demand elasticity.
232 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW february 2011

Bai, Chong-En, and Zhenjie Qian. 2009. “Factor Income Share in China: The Story behind the Statis-
tics.” Jingji Yanjiu/Economic Research Journal, 44(3): 27–41.
Bai, Chong-En, Chang-Tai Hsieh, and Yingyi Qian. 2006. “The Return to Capital in China.” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, 2006(2): 61–88.
Banerjee, Abhijit, and Esther Duflo. 2005. “Growth Theory through the Lens of Development Eco-
nomics.” In Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1A. Handbooks in Economics 22, ed. Philippe
Aghion, and Steven N. Durlauf, 473–552. New York: Elsevier.
Banister, Judith. 2007. “Manufacturing in China Today: Employment and Labor Compensation.” Con-
ference Board Economics Program Working Paper 07-01.
Benjamin, Dwayne, Loren Brandt, John Giles, and Sangui Wang. 2008. “Income Inequality during
China’s Economic Transition.” In China’s Great Economic Transformation, ed. Loren Brandt, and
Thomas G. Rawski, 729–75. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bosworth, Barry, and Susan M. Collins. 2008. “Accounting for Growth: Comparing China and India.”
Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(1): 45–66.
Boyreau-Debray, Genevieve, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2005. “Pitfalls of a State-Dominated Financial Sys-
tem: The Case of China.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 11214.
Brandt, Loren, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2010. “Accounting for China’s Growth.” Institute for the Study of
Labor Discussion Paper 4764.
Brandt, Loren, Chang-Tai Hsieh, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2008. “Growth and Structural Transformation
in China.” In China’s Great Economic Transformation, ed. Loren Brandt, and Thomas G. Rawski,
683–728. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Brandt, Loren, Johannes Van Biesebroeck, and Yifan Zhang. 2009. “Creative Accounting or Creative
Destruction? Firm-Level Productivity Growth in Chinese Manufacturing.” National Bureau of Eco-
nomic Research Working Paper 15152.
Buera, Francisco J., and Yongseok Shin. 2010. “Productivity Growth and Capital Flows: The Dynam-
ics of Reforms.” http://www.artsci.wustl.edu/~yshin/public/bs15.pdf.
Caballero, Ricardo J., Emmanuel Farhi, and Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas. 2008. “An Equilibrium Model
of ‘Global Imbalances’ and Low Interest Rates.” American Economic Review, 98(1): 358–93.
Cagetti, Marco, and Mariacristina De Nardi. 2006. “Entrepreneurship, Frictions, and Wealth.” Journal
of Political Economy, 114(5): 835–70.
Caselli, Francesco, and Wilbur J. Coleman, II. 2001. “The U.S. Structural Transformation and Regional
Convergence: A Reinterpretation.” Journal of Political Economy, 109(3): 584–616.
Caselli, Francesco, and Nicola Gennaioli. 2006. “Dynastic Management.” London School of Econom-
ics Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper 0741.
Chang, Eric C., and Sonia M. L. Wong. 2004. “Political Control and Performance in China’s Listed
Firms.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 32(4): 617–36.
Chenery, Hollis, and Moises Syrquin. 1975. Patterns of Development, 1950–1970. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Dekle, Robert, and Guillaume Vandenbroucke. 2006. “A Quantitative Analysis of China’s Structural
Transformation.” Institute of Economic Policy Research Working Paper 06.51.
Dollar, David, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2007. “Das (Wasted) Kapital: Firm Ownership and Investment Effi-
ciency in China.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 13103.
Dooley, Michael P., David Folkerts-Landau, and Peter Garber. 2007. “Direct Investment, Rising Real
Wages, and the Absorption of Excess Labor in the Periphery.” In G7 Current Account Imbalances:
Sustainability and Adjustment, ed. Richard H. Clarida, 103–26. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Gancia, Gino, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2009. “Technological Change and the Wealth of Nations.” Annual
Review of Economics, 1(1): 93–120.
Ge, Suqin, and Dennis T. Yang. 2009. “Accounting for Rising Wages in China.” Hong Kong Institute
for Monetary Research Seminar Paper 345.
Gourinchas, Pierre-Olivier, and Olivier Jeanne. 2009. “Capital Flows to Developing Countries: The
Allocation Puzzle.” http://socrates.berkeley.edu/~pog/academic/allocation_june09.pdf.
Gregory, Neil, and Stoyan Tenev. 2001. “The Financing of Private Enterprise in China.” Finance and
Development, 38(1): 14–17.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and
India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(4): 1403–48.
Islam, Nazrul, Erbiao Dai, and Hiroshi Sakamoto. 2006. “Role of TFP in China’s Growth.” Asian Eco-
nomic Journal, 20(2): 127–59.
Kim, Linsu. 1997. Imitation to Innovation: The Dynamics of Korea’s Technological Learning. Boston,
MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Kraay, Aart. 2000. “Household Saving in China.” World Bank Economic Review, 14(3): 545–70.
VOL. 101 NO. 1 song et al.: growing like china 233

Kuijs, Louis. 2005. “Investment and Saving in China.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
3633.
Kuznets, Simon. 1966. Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure and Spread. New Haven, CT: Yale
University Press.
Kwan, Chi Hung. 2006. “Capital Participation of Foreign Investors in China’s State-Owned Commer-
cial Banks – A Win-Win Game.” Nomura Capital Market Review, 9(1): 56–8.
Lewis, W. Arthur. 1954. “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor.” Manchester
School, 22(2): 139–91.
Liu, Deqiang, and Keijiro Otsuka. 2004. “A Comparison of Management Incentives, Abilities, and
Efficiency between SOEs and TVEs: The Case of the Iron and Steel Industry in China.” Economic
Development and Cultural Change, 52(4): 759–80.
Matsuyama, Kiminori. 2004. “Financial Market Globalization, Symmetry-Breaking and Endogenous
Inequality of Nations.” Econometrica, 72(3): 853–84.
Matsuyama, Kiminori. 2005. “Credit Market Imperfections and Patterns of International Trade and
Capital Flows.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 3(2–3): 714–23.
Mendoza, Enrique G., Vincenzo Quadrini, and José-Víctor Ríos-Rull. 2009. “Financial Integration,
Financial Development, and Global Imbalances.” Journal of Political Economy, 117(3): 371–416.
Nugent, Jeffrey B., and Seung-Jae Yhee. 2002. “Small and Medium Enterprises in Korea: Achieve-
ments, Constraints and Policy Issues.” Small Business Economics, 18(1–3): 85–119.
Parente, Stephen L., Richard Rogerson, and Randall Wright. 2000. “Homework in Development Eco-
nomics: Household Production and the Wealth of Nations.” Journal of Political Economy, 108(4):
680–87.
Park, Yung Chul. 1994. “Korea: Development and Structural Change of the Financial System.” In The
Financial Development of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan: Growth, Repression, and Liberalization, ed.
Hugh T. Patrick, and Yung Chul Park, 129–87. New York: Oxford University Press.
Park, Yung Chul, and Dong Won Kim. 1994. “Korea: Development and Structural Change of the Bank-
ing System.” In The Financial Development of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan: Growth, Repression, and
Liberalization, ed. Hugh T. Patrick, and Yung Chul Park, 188–221. New York: Oxford University
Press.
Podpiera, Richard. 2006. “Progress in China’s Banking Sector Reform: Has Bank Behavior Changed?”
International Monetary Fund Working Paper 06/71.
Quadrini, Vincenzo. 1999. “The Importance of Entrepreneurship for Wealth Concentration and Mobil-
ity.” Review of Income and Wealth, 45(1): 1–19.
Restuccia, Diego, and Richard Rogerson. 2008. “Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with
Heterogeneous Establishments.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(4): 707–20.
Riedel, James, Jing Jin, and Jian Gao. 2007. How China Grows: Investment, Finance, and Reform.
Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Sandri, Damiano. 2010. “Growth and Capital Flows with Risky Entrepreneurship.” International Mon-
etary Fund Working Paper 10/37.
Shea, Jia-Dong. 1994. “Taiwan: Development and Structural Change of the Financial System.” In The
Financial Development of Japan, Korea, and Taiwan: Growth, Repression, and Liberalization, ed.
Hugh T. Patrick, and Yung Chul Park, 222–87. New York: Oxford University Press.
Shin, Hyun-Han, and Young S. Park. 1999. “Financing Constraints and Internal Capital Markets: Evi-
dence from Korean ‘Chaebols.’” Journal of Corporate Finance, 5(2): 169–91.
Smith, Heather. 1994. “Korea’s Industrial Policy during the 1980s.” Pacific Economic Papers,
229(1994): 1–23.
Smith, Heather. 1997. “Taiwan’s Industrial Policy in the 1980s: An Appraisal.” Asian Economic Jour-
nal, 11(1): 1–33.
Smith, Heather. 2000. “The State, Banking and Corporate Relationships in Korea and Taiwan.” In
Reform and Recovery in East Asia: The Role of the State and Economic Enterprise, ed. Peter Drys-
dale, 61–100. New York: Routledge.
Song, Zheng, Kjetil Storesletten, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2010. “The ‘Real’ Causes of China’s Trade
Surplus.” Vox, May 2. http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/4985.
Suh, Moon-Gi. 1998. Developmental Transformation in South Korea: From State-Sponsored Growth to
the Quest for Quality of Life. Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers.
Ventura, Jaume. 1997. “Growth and Interdependence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1):
57–84.
This article has been cited by:

1. Ke Huang, Ying Zhu. 2022. China’s secondary privatization and corporate investment efficiency.
Research in International Business and Finance 61, 101651. [Crossref]
2. Lan Yu, Bingbing Zhang, Zhijun Yan, Lijuan Cao. 2022. How do financing constraints enhance
pollutant emissions intensity at enterprises? Evidence from microscopic data at the enterprise level in
China. Environmental Impact Assessment Review 96, 106811. [Crossref]
3. Changlin Zeng, Leng Yu. 2022. Do China’s Modern Agricultural Demonstration Zones work?
Evidence from agricultural products processing companies. Applied Economics 54:37, 4310-4323.
[Crossref]
4. Ting Chen, Wenjie Luo, Xunyong Xiang. 2022. Financial constraints, exchange rate changes and
export price: Evidence from Chinese exporters. Finance Research Letters 48, 102823. [Crossref]
5. Mengjun Yang, Shilin Zheng, Lin Zhou. 2022. Broadband internet and enterprise innovation. China
Economic Review 74, 101802. [Crossref]
6. Feng Dong, Yangfan Li, Chang Qin, Xiaoyun Zhang, Yuhuan Chen, Xu Zhao, Chao Wang. 2022.
Information infrastructure and greenhouse gas emission performance in urban China: A difference-
in-differences analysis. Journal of Environmental Management 316, 115252. [Crossref]
7. Rongsheng Tang, Yang Tang. 2022. Market formation in China from 1978. Regional Science and
Urban Economics 95, 103784. [Crossref]
8. Yizhong Wu, Chien-Chiang Lee, Chi-Chuan Lee, Diyun Peng. 2022. Geographic proximity and
corporate investment efficiency: Evidence from high-speed rail construction in China. Journal of
Banking & Finance 140, 106510. [Crossref]
9. Xiaoqian Zhang, Bin Huang. 2022. Does bank competition inhibit the formation of zombie firms?.
International Review of Economics & Finance 80, 1045-1060. [Crossref]
10. Zheming Liu, Saixing Zeng, Zhizhou Jin, Jonathan Jingsheng Shi. 2022. Transport infrastructure
and industrial agglomeration: Evidence from manufacturing industries in China. Transport Policy 121,
100-112. [Crossref]
11. Franklin Allen, Xian Gu, Julapa Jagtiani. 2022. Fintech, Cryptocurrencies, and CBDC: Financial
Structural Transformation in China. Journal of International Money and Finance 124, 102625.
[Crossref]
12. Haoyuan Ding, Bei Ni, Chang Xue, Xiaoyu Zhang. 2022. Land holdings and outward foreign direct
investment: Evidence from China. Journal of International Money and Finance 124, 102630. [Crossref]
13. Yanxiang Feng, Xinyang Tan, Ruixin Wang. 2022. The value of higher education to entrepreneurial
performance: Evidence from higher education expansion in China. China Economic Review 73, 101789.
[Crossref]
14. Shuaizhang Feng, Xiaoyu Xia. 2022. Heterogeneous firm responses to increases in high-skilled
workers: Evidence from China's college enrollment expansion. China Economic Review 73, 101791.
[Crossref]
15. Wenming Xu, Zhicheng Wu. 2022. Regulation-Driven Legal Doctrines of Investment Trusts in
China. European Business Organization Law Review 23:2, 391-421. [Crossref]
16. Laiqun Jin, Xiuyan Liu, Sam Hak Kan Tang. 2022. High-technology zones, misallocation of resources
among cities and aggregate productivity: evidence from China. Applied Economics 54:24, 2778-2794.
[Crossref]
17. Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira, Alberto Trejos. 2022. Trade and the propagation of global shocks. Economic
Inquiry . [Crossref]
18. Peng Wang, Bin Liu, Andrew Delios, Gongming Qian. 2022. Two-sided effects of state equity: The
survival of Sino–foreign IJVs. Journal of International Business Studies 37. . [Crossref]
19. Bo Zhang, Jian-Xun Chen, Amy Wei Tian, Fangcheng Tang, Yi Niu, Qi Zeng. 2022. The effects of
industry dynamism, firm size, and ownership on HR strategic integration in China. The International
Journal of Human Resource Management 33:9, 1782-1811. [Crossref]
20. Li Du, Xuesong Qian. 2022. Nexus of Interest Rate Liberalization and Loan Pricing: Evidence from
Entrusted Loans in China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 58:6, 1566-1577. [Crossref]
21. Ling Feng, Henan Lang, Tingting Pei. 2022. Zombie firms and corporate savings: Evidence from
Chinese manufacturing firms. International Review of Economics & Finance 79, 551-564. [Crossref]
22. Huanyu Ma, Dapeng Hao. 2022. Economic policy uncertainty, financial development, and financial
constraints: Evidence from China. International Review of Economics & Finance 79, 368-386. [Crossref]
23. Yan Wang, Juan Carlos Conesa. 2022. The role of demographics and migration for the future of
economic growth in China. European Economic Review 144, 104076. [Crossref]
24. Andrea Fracasso, Kun Jiang. 2022. The performance of private companies in China before and during
the global financial crisis: firms’ characteristics and entrepreneurs’ attributes. Economic Change and
Restructuring 55:2, 803-836. [Crossref]
25. Xiaojie Liu, Jim Huangnan Shen, Kent Deng. 2022. Endowment Structure, Property Rights and
Reforms of Large State-owned Enterprise (SOEs) in China: Past, Present and Future. Structural
Change and Economic Dynamics . [Crossref]
26. Qifan Huang, Castiel Chen Zhuang. 2022. Training, productivity and wages: An investigation of
China's manufacturing enterprises in a privatization era. Economics of Transition and Institutional
Change 30:2, 269-288. [Crossref]
27. Mengmeng Xu, Ruipeng Tan, Xinju He. 2022. How does economic agglomeration affect energy
efficiency in China?: Evidence from endogenous stochastic frontier approach. Energy Economics 108,
105901. [Crossref]
28. Haiwen Zhou. 2022. State Capacity and Leadership: Why Did China Take off?. The Chinese Economy
48, 1-19. [Crossref]
29. Yating Dai, Jian Cheng, Daolin Zhu. 2022. Understanding the Impact of Land Supply Structure on
Low Consumption: Empirical Evidence from China. Land 11:4, 516. [Crossref]
30. Jinjing Tian, Taining Wang, Joshua Hall. 2022. The effect of exports on labour share: A
semiparametric approach using Chinese manufacturing panel data. The World Economy 45:4,
1140-1178. [Crossref]
31. Huixuan Li, Jing Chen. 2022. Does higher investments necessarily reduce stock returns?. Pacific-
Basin Finance Journal 72, 101730. [Crossref]
32. Xiaoyi Ren, Huan Shao. 2022. Non-state shareholder governance and shadow banking business:
Evidence from Chinese state-owned manufacturing enterprises. Research in International Business and
Finance 60, 101631. [Crossref]
33. Hyun Lee, Kai Zhao, Fei Zou. 2022. Does the early retirement policy really benefit women?. Journal
of Economic Behavior & Organization 196, 330-345. [Crossref]
34. Jacek Rothert, Jacob Short. 2022. Non-traded goods, factor market frictions, and international capital
flows. Review of Economic Dynamics 126. . [Crossref]
35. Shangmei Zhao, Huibo Wang, Wei Li. 2022. Allocation of Credit Resources and “Borrow to Lend”
Activities: Evidence From Chinese-Listed Companies. Frontiers in Psychology 13. . [Crossref]
36. Phan Le. 2022. Capital Misallocation and State Ownership Policy in Vietnam*. Economic Record .
[Crossref]
37. Naiqian Wu, Weiguo Xiao, Wei Liu, Zhan Zhang. 2022. Corporate climate risk and stock market
reaction to performance briefings in China. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 30. .
[Crossref]
38. Logan (Geng) Li, Zhengwei Wang. 2022. Understanding the long‐term effects of Keju : The case of
entrepreneurship in China. Economics of Transition and Institutional Change 39. . [Crossref]
39. Jie Chen, Xiaoxin Guo, Shihu Zhong. 2022. The financialization of urban development and urban
labour productivity: evidence from China. Regional Studies 1, 1-13. [Crossref]
40. Guangyou Zhou, Jieyu Zhu, Sumei Luo. 2022. The impact of fintech innovation on green growth in
China: Mediating effect of green finance. Ecological Economics 193, 107308. [Crossref]
41. Xiaobing Lai, Shujing Yue, Hongtao Chen. 2022. Can green credit increase firm value? Evidence
from Chinese listed new energy companies. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 29:13,
18702-18720. [Crossref]
42. Daguo Lv, Lingyu Zhang, Ren Lu, Jingtao Yao. 2022. Industry characteristics and agglomeration of
heterogeneous firms. Journal of Industrial and Business Economics 49:1, 31-49. [Crossref]
43. Roger Fon, Ilan Alon. 2022. Governance, foreign aid, and Chinese foreign direct investment.
Thunderbird International Business Review 64:2, 179-201. [Crossref]
44. Emir Malikov, Jingfang Zhang, Shunan Zhao, Subal C. Kumbhakar. 2022. Accounting for cross‐
location technological heterogeneity in the measurement of operations efficiency and productivity.
Journal of Operations Management 68:2, 153-184. [Crossref]
45. Tinghua Liu, Fengjuan Kou, Xiao Liu, Ehsan Elahi. 2022. Cluster Commercial Credit and Total
Factor Productivity of the Manufacturing Sector. Sustainability 14:6, 3601. [Crossref]
46. Weijia Li, Gérard Roland, Yang Xie. 2022. Crony capitalism, the party-state, and the political
boundaries of corruption. Journal of Comparative Economics 77. . [Crossref]
47. Bao Khac Quoc Nguyen, Bao Cong Nguyen To, Nham Thi Hong Nguyen. 2022. Unexpected money
growth, nonfinancial firms as large shareholders and investment-cash flow relationship: Evidence from
Vietnam. Journal of Economics and Business 119, 106054. [Crossref]
48. Qinhua Xu, Buben Fu, Bin Wang. 2022. The effects of oil price uncertainty on China’s economy.
Energy Economics 107, 105840. [Crossref]
49. Yu Sheng, Yuhan Zhao, Qian Zhang, Wanlu Dong, Jikun Huang. 2022. Boosting rural labor off-farm
employment through urban expansion in China. World Development 151, 105727. [Crossref]
50. Firat Demir, Chenghao Hu, Junyi Liu, Hewei Shen. 2022. Local corruption, total factor productivity
and firm heterogeneity: Empirical evidence from Chinese manufacturing firms. World Development
151, 105770. [Crossref]
51. Xuemei Liu, Zi Nie, Bingcheng Li. 2022. Financial Mismatch and Default Risk: Evidence from
Chinese Nonfinancial Listed Private Enterprises. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 58:3, 852-862.
[Crossref]
52. Marta Alonso, Nuno Palma, Beatriz Simon-Yarza. 2022. The value of political connections: evidence
from China's anti-corruption campaign. Journal of Institutional Economics 49, 1-21. [Crossref]
53. Yidan Liang. 2022. Capital and labour distortion in China: a systematic literature review using
HistCite. Accounting & Finance 42. . [Crossref]
54. Yidan Liang. 2022. The effect of capital and labour distortion on innovation. Accounting & Finance
11. . [Crossref]
55. Bole Zhou, Shouguo Zhao. 2022. Industrial policy and corporate investment efficiency. Journal of
Asian Economics 78, 101406. [Crossref]
56. Le Tang. 2022. The dynamic demand for capital and labor: Evidence from Chinese industrial firms.
Economic Modelling 107, 105731. [Crossref]
57. Xiaoying Zhong, Guanghai Liu, Peng Chen, Kaili Ke, Ruhe Xie. 2022. The Impact of Internet
Development on Urban Eco-Efficiency—A Quasi-Natural Experiment of “Broadband China” Pilot
Policy. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 19:3, 1363. [Crossref]
58. Yun Liu, Yifei Zhang, Heyang Fang, Xin Chen. 2022. SMEs’ line of credit under the COVID-19:
evidence from China. Small Business Economics 58:2, 807-828. [Crossref]
59. Chien-Chiang Lee, Chih-Wei Wang, Shan-Ju Ho. 2022. Financial aid and financial inclusion: Does
risk uncertainty matter?. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 71, 101700. [Crossref]
60. Minjie Huang, Shunan Zhao, Subal C. Kumbhakar. 2022. Decomposition of Output, Productivity
and Market Structure Changes. European Journal of Operational Research 260. . [Crossref]
61. Bryan S. Weber, Toan Luu Duc Huynh. 2022. COVID‐19 challenges and firm responses: Analysis
of a city‐wide census in a developing country. Managerial and Decision Economics 128. . [Crossref]
62. Ana S. Manu, Peter McAdam, Alpo Willman. 2022. China’s great expansion: The role of factor
substitution and technical progress. European Economic Review 141, 103911. [Crossref]
63. Jing Ma, Qiuyun Zhao, Qing Li, Hao Yang. 2022. Financial Constraints, Corporate Savings and Labor
Income Share—Based on China’s Economic Transition. Sustainability 14:1, 346. [Crossref]
64. Torsten Heinrich, Jangho Yang, Shuanping Dai. 2022. Levels of structural change. Journal of
Evolutionary Economics 32:1, 35-86. [Crossref]
65. David Atkin, Dave Donaldson. The role of trade in economic development 1-59. [Crossref]
66. Cheryl Xiaoning Long, Lixin Colin Xu, Jin Yang. 2022. The government, private firms, and dual-
track private sector development: China's experience in two crucial decades. Journal of Government
and Economics 6, 100037. [Crossref]
67. Haichao Fan, Cui Hu, Faqin Lin, Huanhuan Wang. 2022. Trade liberalization and decentralization
of state‐owned enterprises: Evidence from China. Economic Inquiry 60:1, 224-246. [Crossref]
68. Tasso Adamopoulos, Loren Brandt, Jessica Leight, Diego Restuccia. 2022. Misallocation, Selection,
and Productivity: A Quantitative Analysis With Panel Data From China. Econometrica 90:3,
1261-1282. [Crossref]
69. Xiulu Huang, Pengfei Ge, Bole Zhou. 2021. Selective industrial policy and capital misallocation:
evidence from the ‘Revitalization Plan for Ten Industries’ in China. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy
4, 1-31. [Crossref]
70. Jing Tan, Hao Xu, Jingwen Yu, Valentin Radu. 2021. Consumption and savings of migrants in China
– social cohesion perspective. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja 10, 1-18. [Crossref]
71. Shenzhe Jiang, Jianjun Miao, Yuzhe Zhang. 2021. CHINA'S HOUSING BUBBLE,
INFRASTRUCTURE INVESTMENT, AND ECONOMIC GROWTH. International Economic
Review 37. . [Crossref]
72. Mei Chen, Peijie Ni, Torger Reve, Jing Huang, Ren Lu. 2021. Sales growth or employment growth?
Exporting conundrum for new ventures. Review of International Business and Strategy 31:4, 482-506.
[Crossref]
73. Sophia Chen, Lev Ratnovski, Pi-Han Tsai. 2021. Credit and fiscal multipliers in China: Evidence
from a political economy based estimation. Journal of International Money and Finance 119, 102481.
[Crossref]
74. Jiameng Cheng, Yanke Dai, Shu Lin, Haichun Ye. 2021. Clan culture and family ownership
concentration: Evidence from China. China Economic Review 70, 101692. [Crossref]
75. FENG DONG, YUMEI GUO, YUCHAO PENG, ZHIWEI XU. 2021. Economic Slowdown and
Housing Dynamics in China: A Tale of Two Investments by Firms. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking 37. . [Crossref]
76. Shuaizhang Feng, Naijia Guo. 2021. Labor market dynamics in urban China and the role of the state
sector. Journal of Comparative Economics 49:4, 918-932. [Crossref]
77. Feng Dong, Yangfan Li, Chang Qin, Jiaojiao Sun. 2021. How industrial convergence affects
regional green development efficiency: A spatial conditional process analysis. Journal of Environmental
Management 300, 113738. [Crossref]
78. Cheng Xu. 2021. Effects of urbanization on trust: Evidence from an experiment in the field. Journal
of Economic Psychology 87, 102450. [Crossref]
79. Zhenbing Yang, Shuai Shao, Lili Xu, Lili Yang. 2021. Can regional development plans promote
economic growth? City-level evidence from China. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 100, 101212.
[Crossref]
80. Guiqing Mo, Zhi Gao, Lei Zhou. 2021. China's no-bailout reform: Impact on bond yields and rating
standards. Journal of Banking & Finance 133, 106282. [Crossref]
81. Binkai Chen, Justin Yifu Lin. 2021. Development strategy, resource misallocation and economic
performance. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 59, 612-634. [Crossref]
82. Xinge Feng, Weijie Luo, Yong Wang. 2021. Economic policy uncertainty and firm performance:
evidence from China. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 150, 1-18. [Crossref]
83. Belton M. Fleisher, William H. McGuire, Xiaojun Wang, Min Qiang Zhao. 2021. Induced innovation:
evidence from China’s secondary industry. Applied Economics 53:52, 6075-6093. [Crossref]
84. Jizhe Yang, Tingfeng Jiang, Lu Dai. 2021. State‐ownership and corporate cash holding: Evidence
from China. Australian Economic Papers 57. . [Crossref]
85. Carlos Garriga, Aaron Hedlund, Yang Tang, Ping Wang. 2021. Rural-urban migration and house
prices in China. Regional Science and Urban Economics 91, 103613. [Crossref]
86. Wen-Tai Hsu, Lin Ma. 2021. Urbanization policy and economic development: A quantitative analysis
of China's differential hukou reforms. Regional Science and Urban Economics 91, 103639. [Crossref]
87. Dongxiao Niu, Weizeng Sun, Siqi Zheng. 2021. The role of informal housing in lowering China’s
urbanization costs. Regional Science and Urban Economics 91, 103638. [Crossref]
88. Hamid Beladi, Jie Deng, May Hu. 2021. Cross-border investment and corporate innovation: Evidence
from the Chinese market. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 75,
101446. [Crossref]
89. Sebastian Horn, Carmen M. Reinhart, Christoph Trebesch. 2021. China's overseas lending. Journal
of International Economics 133, 103539. [Crossref]
90. Reto Foellmi, Stefan Legge, Alexa Tiemann. 2021. Innovation and trade in the presence of
credit constraints. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 54:3, 1168-1205.
[Crossref]
91. Chun Guo, Wunhong Su, Xiaobao Song. 2021. THE SUBSTITUTION FINANCING EFFECT
OF SUPPLIERS’ TRADE CREDIT ON CUSTOMERS’ TRADE CREDIT IN CHINA. Journal
of Business Economics and Management 22:6, 1456-1475. [Crossref]
92. TONI M. WHITED, JAKE ZHAO. 2021. The Misallocation of Finance. The Journal of Finance
76:5, 2359-2407. [Crossref]
93. Guanchun Liu, Yuanyuan Liu, Chengsi Zhang. 2021. Human capital in the financial sector and
corporate debt maturity. China Economic Review 69, 101652. [Crossref]
94. Zhen Yu, Xiaoling Wu, Meng Li, Rufei Guo. 2021. Import competition and the gender gap in labor
force participation: Evidence from China. China Economic Review 69, 101689. [Crossref]
95. Wyatt J. Brooks, Joseph P. Kaboski, Yao Amber Li. 2021. Agglomeration, Misallocation, and (the
Lack of ) Competition. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 13:4, 483-519. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
96. Guanchun Liu, Yuanyuan Liu, Chengsi Zhang, Yueteng Zhu. 2021. Social insurance law and corporate
financing decisions in China. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 190, 816-837. [Crossref]
97. Feng Min, Fenghua Wen, Xiong Wang. 2021. Measuring the effects of monetary and fiscal policy
shocks on domestic investment in China. International Review of Economics & Finance 92. . [Crossref]
98. Danting Chang. 2021. Fundamental anomalies and the size puzzle in China: A data mining approach.
Finance Research Letters 42, 101907. [Crossref]
99. Qing Liu, Jian Wang. 2021. Spatial agglomeration and firm productivity: Does trade status matter?.
Regional Science Policy & Practice 118. . [Crossref]
100. Vo Phuong Mai Le, Kent Matthews, David Meenagh, Patrick Minford, Zhiguo Xiao. 2021. Shadow
banks, banking policies and China’s macroeconomic fluctuations. Journal of International Money and
Finance 116, 102415. [Crossref]
101. Julián Caballero. 2021. Corporate dollar debt and depreciations: All’s well that ends well?. Journal of
Banking & Finance 130, 106185. [Crossref]
102. Haichao Fan, Yuchao Peng, Huanhuan Wang, Zhiwei Xu. 2021. Greening through finance?. Journal
of Development Economics 152, 102683. [Crossref]
103. Feng Dong, Jianfeng Liu, Zhiwei Xu, Bo Zhao. 2021. Flight to housing in China. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 130, 104189. [Crossref]
104. Jian Yu, Xunpeng Shi, Tsun Se Cheong. 2021. Distribution dynamics of China's household
consumption upgrading. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 58, 193-203. [Crossref]
105. Vo Phuong Mai Le, Kent Matthews, David Meenagh, Patrick Minford, Zhiguo Xiao. 2021. China’s
market economy, shadow banking and the frequency of growth slowdown. The Manchester School
89:5, 420-444. [Crossref]
106. Chaowei Wang, Vo Phuong Mai Le, Kent Matthews, Peng Zhou. 2021. Shadow banking activity and
entrusted loans in a DSGE model of China. The Manchester School 89:5, 445-469. [Crossref]
107. Jianhong Cao, Siong Hook Law, Abdul Rahim Bin Abdul Samad, Wan Norhidayah Binti W.
Mohamad, Jianlong Wang, Xiaodong Yang. 2021. Impact of financial development and technological
innovation on the volatility of green growth—evidence from China. Environmental Science and
Pollution Research 28:35, 48053-48069. [Crossref]
108. Lei Zhao. 2021. Tourism, Institutions, and Poverty Alleviation: Empirical Evidence from China.
Journal of Travel Research 60:7, 1543-1565. [Crossref]
109. Jing Cao, Jie Mao. 2021. Firm performance and economic development: Evidence from a unique
dataset of China. Economics of Transition and Institutional Change 83. . [Crossref]
110. Taining Wang, Jinjing Tian, Feng Yao. 2021. Does high debt ratio influence Chinese firms’
performance? A semiparametric stochastic frontier approach with zero inefficiency. Empirical
Economics 61:2, 587-636. [Crossref]
111. Seung Mo Choi, Hwagyun Kim, Xiaohan Ma. 2021. Trade policies and growth in emerging
economies: policy experiments. Review of World Economics 157:3, 603-629. [Crossref]
112. Bihong Huang, Maria Teresa Punzi, Yu Wu. 2021. Do banks price environmental transition risks?
Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment in China. Journal of Corporate Finance 69, 101983.
[Crossref]
113. Zheng Liu, Hongtao Shen, Michael Welker, Ning Zhang, Yang Zhao. 2021. Gone with the wind: An
externality of earnings pressure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 72:1, 101403. [Crossref]
114. Quoc Trung Tran. 2021. State ownership and value of cash: new evidence from an emerging market.
International Journal of Emerging Markets 59. . [Crossref]
115. Quynh Nga Nguyen Thi, Quoc Trung Tran, Hong Phat Doan. 2021. Foreign ownership, state
ownership and cash holdings under the global financial crisis: evidence from the emerging market of
Vietnam. International Journal of Emerging Markets 100. . [Crossref]
116. Jian Gao, Bogang Jun, Alex ‘Sandy’ Pentland, Tao Zhou, César A. Hidalgo. 2021. Spillovers across
industries and regions in China’s regional economic diversification. Regional Studies 55:7, 1311-1326.
[Crossref]
117. Mi Dai, Francesco Nucci, Alberto F. Pozzolo, Jianwei Xu. 2021. Access to finance and the exchange
rate elasticity of exports. Journal of International Money and Finance 115, 102386. [Crossref]
118. Sai Ding, Alessandra Guariglia, John Knight, Junhong Yang. 2021. Negative Investment in China:
Financing Constraints and Restructuring versus Growth. Economic Development and Cultural Change
69:4, 1411-1449. [Crossref]
119. Yu-Hsiang Lei. 2021. Quid pro quo? Government-firm relationships in China. Journal of Public
Economics 199, 104427. [Crossref]
120. Julia Niemeläinen. 2021. External imbalances between China and the United States: A dynamic
analysis with a life-cycle model. Journal of International Economics 131, 103493. [Crossref]
121. Zhiyuan Chen, Xin Jin, Xu Xu. 2021. Is a Corruption Crackdown Really Good for the Economy?
Firm-Level Evidence from China. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 37:2, 314-357.
[Crossref]
122. Yong Xu, Xin Zhao, Xiaoxiao Zhou, Ling Yuan. 2021. Financial Structure and Capital Allocation
Efficiency: An Empirical Analysis of China from 2005–2018. Applied Economics 53:29, 3347-3358.
[Crossref]
123. Pei-Ju Liao, Ping Wang, Yin-Chi Wang, Chong K. Yip. 2021. Educational choice, rural–urban
migration and economic development. Economic Theory 15. . [Crossref]
124. SHI-ZHUAN HAN, HONGHONG WEI, BIHONG HUANG, JIE LI. 2021. THE 2008
ECONOMIC STIMULUS PLAN AND HOUSING PRICE: THE ROLE OF SOEs. The Singapore
Economic Review 11, 1-29. [Crossref]
125. Jinglin Jiang, Li Liao, Zhengwei Wang, Xiaoyan Zhang. 2021. Government Affiliation and Peer-To-
Peer Lending Platforms in China. Journal of Empirical Finance 62, 87-106. [Crossref]
126. Seung Mo Choi, Hwagyun Kim, Xiaohan Ma. 2021. Trade, structural transformation and growth.
The World Economy 44:6, 1770-1794. [Crossref]
127. Shiyu Bo. 2021. Environmental Regulations, Political Incentives and Local Economic Activities:
Evidence from China*. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 83:3, 812-835. [Crossref]
128. Lina Ma, Fengju Xu, Iqbal Najaf, Akther Taslima. 2021. How Does Increased Private Ownership
Affect Financial Leverage, Asset Quality and Profitability of Chinese SOEs?. Chinese Political Science
Review 6:2, 251-284. [Crossref]
129. Kaiming Guo, Jing Hang, Se Yan. 2021. Servicification of investment and structural transformation:
The case of China. China Economic Review 67, 101621. [Crossref]
130. Jingwen Wang, Guangjun Shen, Dunzhe Tang. 2021. Does tax deduction relax financing constraints?
Evidence from China's value-added tax reform. China Economic Review 67, 101619. [Crossref]
131. Yajie Sun, Wen-Chi Liao. 2021. Resource-Exhausted City Transition to continue industrial
development. China Economic Review 67, 101623. [Crossref]
132. Lei Fang, Berthold Herrendorf. 2021. High-skilled services and development in China. Journal of
Development Economics 151, 102671. [Crossref]
133. Arindam Mondal, Amit Baran Chakrabarti. 2021. Entrepreneurial orientation during adversity:
differences across ownership categories. International Journal of Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research
27:4, 845-865. [Crossref]
134. Bilge Erten, Jessica Leight. 2021. Exporting Out of Agriculture: The Impact of WTO Accession on
Structural Transformation in China. The Review of Economics and Statistics 103:2, 364-380. [Crossref]
135. Mariassunta Giannetti, Guanmin Liao, Jiaxing You, Xiaoyun Yu. 2021. The Externalities of
Corruption: Evidence from Entrepreneurial Firms in China*. Review of Finance 25:3, 629-667.
[Crossref]
136. Ke Ding, Helian Xu, Rongming Yang. 2021. Taxation and Enterprise Innovation: Evidence from
China’s Value-Added Tax Reform. Sustainability 13:10, 5700. [Crossref]
137. Howei Wu, Bin Xu. 2021. Did state-owned enterprises do better during COVID-19? Evidence from
a survey of company executives in China. Journal of Economics and Business 115, 105991. [Crossref]
138. Yi Che, Xiaoyu He, Yan Zhang. 2021. Natural resource exports and African countries' voting behaviour
in the United Nations: Evidence from the economic rise of China. Canadian Journal of Economics/
Revue canadienne d'économique 54:2, 712-759. [Crossref]
139. Wei Zhong, Chuang Wan, Wenyang Zhang. 2021. Estimation and Inference for Multi-Kink Quantile
Regression. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 17, 1-17. [Crossref]
140. Kevin Lefebvre, Nadia Rocha, Michele Ruta. Containing Chinese State-Owned Enterprises?: The
Role of Deep Trade Agreements . [Crossref]
141. Tiago Cavalcanti, Marcelo Santos. 2021. (MIS)Allocation Effects of an Overpaid Public Sector.
Journal of the European Economic Association 19:2, 953-999. [Crossref]
142. Zhiyuan Chen, Jie Zhang, Yuan Zi. 2021. A cost-benefit analysis of R&D and patents: Firm-level
evidence from China. European Economic Review 133, 103633. [Crossref]
143. Katja Hanewald, Ruo Jia, Zining Liu. 2021. Why is inequality higher among the old? Evidence from
China. China Economic Review 66, 101592. [Crossref]
144. Yue Cai. 2021. Expansionary monetary policy and credit allocation: Evidence from China. China
Economic Review 66, 101595. [Crossref]
145. Le Tang. 2021. Investment dynamics and capital distortion: State and non-state firms in China.
Journal of Asian Economics 73, 101274. [Crossref]
146. Yin Germaschewski, Jaroslav Horvath, Loris Rubini. 2021. Property rights, expropriations, and
business cycles in China. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 125, 104100. [Crossref]
147. Zheng Liu, Pengfei Wang, Zhiwei Xu. 2021. Interest Rate Liberalization and Capital Misallocations.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 13:2, 373-419. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
148. Jing Guo, Yanan Wang, Wei Yang. 2021. China's anti-corruption shock and resource reallocation in
the energy industry. Energy Economics 96, 105182. [Crossref]
149. Shen Guo, Zheng Jiang. 2021. The welfare implications of housing-related tax policies in China.
International Review of Economics & Finance 72, 135-153. [Crossref]
150. Alberto Martín, Enrique Moral-Benito, Tom Schmitz. 2021. The Financial Transmission of Housing
Booms: Evidence from Spain. American Economic Review 111:3, 1013-1053. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
151. Justin Yifu Lin, Wei Wang, Venite Zhaoyang Xu. 2021. Catch‐up industrial policy and economic
transition in China. The World Economy 44:3, 602-632. [Crossref]
152. Gang Jin, Binbin Yu, Kunrong Shen. 2021. Domestic trade and energy productivity in China: An
inverted U-shaped relationship. Energy Economics 78, 105234. [Crossref]
153. Yantao Wen, Yuanfei Kang, Yafeng Qin, Jeffrey C. Kennedy. 2021. Use of Derivative and Firm
Performance: Evidence from the Chinese Shenzhen Stock Exchange. Journal of Risk and Financial
Management 14:2, 83. [Crossref]
154. Yiming Hu, Mingxia Xu. 2021. Xi's anti-corruption campaign and the speed of capital structure
adjustment. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 65, 101483. [Crossref]
155. Jiandong Ju, Kang Shi, Shang-Jin Wei. 2021. Trade reforms and current account imbalances. Journal
of International Economics 117, 103451. [Crossref]
156. Ji Qi, Xin Tang, Xican Xi. 2021. The Size Distribution of Firms and Industrial Water Pollution: A
Quantitative Analysis of China. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 13:1, 151-183. [Abstract]
[View PDF article] [PDF with links]
157. Dong Cheng, Yong Tan, Jian Yu. 2021. Credit rationing and firm exports: Microeconomic evidence
from small and medium‐sized enterprises in China. The World Economy 44:1, 286-311. [Crossref]
158. Zhe Cheng, Huanming Wang, Wei Xiong, Dajian Zhu, Le Cheng. 2021. Public–private partnership
as a driver of sustainable development: toward a conceptual framework of sustainability-oriented PPP.
Environment, Development and Sustainability 23:1, 1043-1063. [Crossref]
159. Lingyun Huang, Zhuojun Lei. 2021. How environmental regulation affect corporate green
investment: Evidence from China. Journal of Cleaner Production 279, 123560. [Crossref]
160. Jing Zhao, Ziru Zhao, Huan Zhang. 2021. The impact of growth, energy and financial development on
environmental pollution in China: New evidence from a spatial econometric analysis. Energy Economics
93, 104506. [Crossref]
161. Jianwei Xu, Panpan Yang, Guangrong Ma. 2021. Why Has China's Current Account Balance
Converged after the Global Financial Crisis?. China & World Economy 29:1, 109-129. [Crossref]
162. Ren Wang, Jie Hou, Zhujun Jiang. 2021. Environmental policies with financing constraints in China.
Energy Economics 77, 105089. [Crossref]
163. Zheng Liu, Mark M. Spiegel, Jingyi Zhang. 2021. Optimal capital account liberalization in China.
Journal of Monetary Economics 117, 1041-1061. [Crossref]
164. Thomas Davoine. 2021. The long run influence of pension systems on the current account. Journal
of Pension Economics and Finance 20:1, 67-101. [Crossref]
165. Wyatt J. Brooks, Joseph P. Kaboski, Yao Amber Li, Wei Qian. 2021. Exploitation of labor? Classical
monopsony power and labor's share. Journal of Development Economics 83, 102627. [Crossref]
166. Andrey Tkachenko. 2021. State-business relations and access to external financing: evidence from
Russia. SSRN Electronic Journal 110. . [Crossref]
167. Salome Baslandze, Pengfei Han, Felipe Saffie. 2021. Imitation, Innovation, and Technological
Complexity: Foreign Knowledge Spillovers in China. SSRN Electronic Journal 10. . [Crossref]
168. Sarah Tang, Jim Huangnan Shen. 2021. Volatility, Adjustment Cost and Capital Misallocation:
Evidence from Chinese Industrial Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal 6. . [Crossref]
169. Manuel García-Santana, Josep Pijoan-Mas, Lucciano Villacorta. 2021. Investment Demand and
Structural Change. Econometrica 89:6, 2751-2785. [Crossref]
170. Yanli Wang, Xiaodong Lei, Fan Yang, Na Zhao. 2021. Financial friction, resource misallocation and
total factor productivity: theory and evidence from China. Journal of Applied Economics 24:1, 393-408.
[Crossref]
171. Gordon Hanson. 2020. Who Will Fill China&#8217;s Shoes? The Global Evolution of Labor-
Intensive Manufacturing. East Asian Economic Review 24:4, 313-336. [Crossref]
172. YI HUANG, MARCO PAGANO, UGO PANIZZA. 2020. Local Crowding‐Out in China. The
Journal of Finance 75:6, 2855-2898. [Crossref]
173. Can Wang, Mengzhi Deng, Junfeng Deng. 2020. Factor reallocation and structural transformation
implications of grain subsidies in China. Journal of Asian Economics 71, 101248. [Crossref]
174. Heiwai Tang, Fei Wang, Zhi Wang. 2020. Domestic segment of global value chains in China under
state capitalism. Journal of Comparative Economics 48:4, 797-821. [Crossref]
175. Kazumichi Iwasa, Laixun Zhao. 2020. Inequality and catching-up under decreasing marginal
impatience. Journal of Mathematical Economics 91, 99-110. [Crossref]
176. ZHIHONG JIAN, YEQING YANG. 2020. THE MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF
ENHANCED REFORMS IN CHINA. The Singapore Economic Review 65:06, 1619-1644. [Crossref]
177. Tingfeng Tang, Zhigang Li, Jinlan Ni, Jia Yuan. 2020. Land costs, government intervention, and
migration of firms: The case of China. China Economic Review 64, 101560. [Crossref]
178. Jaime Santos-Reyes. 2020. Using Logistic Regression to Identify Leading Factors to Prepare for
an Earthquake Emergency during Daytime and Nighttime: The Case of Mass Earthquake Drills.
Sustainability 12:23, 9. [Crossref]
179. Emmanuel K. Manu, Wen Xuezhou, Isaac O. Paintsil, Samuel Gyedu, Albert H. Ntarmah.
2020. Financial development and economic growth nexus in Africa. BUSINESS STRATEGY &
DEVELOPMENT 3:4, 506-521. [Crossref]
180. Jinyu Liu, Zhengwei Wang, Wuxiang Zhu. 2020. Does privatization reform alleviate ownership
discrimination? Evidence from the Split-share structure reform in China. Journal of Corporate Finance
101848. [Crossref]
181. Francesca de Nicola, Ha Nguyen, Norman Loayza. Productivity Loss and Misallocation of Resources
in Southeast Asia 1, . [Crossref]
182. Xuhua Wei, Huan Yang, Siyi Han. 2020. A meta-analysis of top management team compositional
characteristics and corporate innovation in China. Asia Pacific Business Review 59, 1-24. [Crossref]
183. Junqing Li, Qiheng Han, Pengfei Liu, Jianbo Zhang. 2020. Institutional Quality, Financial Friction,
and Sustained Economic Growth: The Case of China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 56:14,
3270-3293. [Crossref]
184. Guangyu Nie. 2020. Marriage squeeze, marriage age and the household savings rate in China. Journal
of Development Economics 147, 102558. [Crossref]
185. Jing Fang, Hui He, Nan Li. 2020. China's rising IQ (Innovation Quotient) and growth: Firm-level
evidence. Journal of Development Economics 147, 102561. [Crossref]
186. Harald Hau, Yi Huang, Gewei Wang. 2020. Firm Response to Competitive Shocks: Evidence from
China’s Minimum Wage Policy. The Review of Economic Studies 87:6, 2639-2671. [Crossref]
187. Zheming Liu, Bin Li, Saixing Zeng, Hongquan Chen. 2020. Spillovers from transport infrastructures
onto firm productivity: An analytical and empirical study. Review of Development Economics 24:4,
1583-1609. [Crossref]
188. Le Tang. 2020. Energy prices and investment in energy efficiency: evidence from Chinese industry
1997–2004. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 34:2, 93-105. [Crossref]
189. Shaojian Chen, Hui Mao, Zongxian Feng. 2020. Political uncertainty and firm entry: Evidence from
Chinese manufacturing industries. Journal of Business Research 120, 16-30. [Crossref]
190. Yang Han, Zehao Liu, Jun Ma. 2020. Growth cycles and business cycles of the Chinese economy
through the lens of the unobserved components model. China Economic Review 63, 101317. [Crossref]
191. Jiandong Ju, Justin Yifu Lin, Qing Liu, Kang Shi. 2020. Structural changes and the real exchange
rate dynamics. Journal of International Money and Finance 107, 102192. [Crossref]
192. Guanchun Liu, Chengsi Zhang, Yueteng Zhu. 2020. The interest group theory of banking sector
expansion in China: Evidence from a quasi-natural experiment. Journal of International Money and
Finance 107, 102225. [Crossref]
193. Liangxiong Huang, Shulin Liu, Yonghui Han, Keming Peng. 2020. The nature of state-owned
enterprises and collection of pollutant discharge fees: A study based on Chinese industrial enterprises.
Journal of Cleaner Production 271, 122420. [Crossref]
194. RETO FOELLMI, MANUEL OECHSLIN. 2020. Harmful Procompetitive Effects of Trade in
Presence of Credit Market Frictions. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 52:6, 1493-1525. [Crossref]
195. Xialei You, Shenghua Jia, Junsheng Dou, Emma Su. 2020. Is organizational slack honey or poison?
Experimental research based on external investors' perception. Emerging Markets Review 44, 100698.
[Crossref]
196. Yu Hao, Ling-Ou Wang, Chien-Chiang Lee. 2020. Financial development, energy consumption and
China's economic growth: New evidence from provincial panel data. International Review of Economics
& Finance 69, 1132-1151. [Crossref]
197. Dongyang Zhang. 2020. Do credit squeezes influence firm survival? An empirical investigation of
China. Economic Systems 44:3, 100790. [Crossref]
198. Pengfei Jia, King Yoong Lim. 2020. Tax Policy and Toxic Housing Bubbles in China. The B.E.
Journal of Macroeconomics, ahead of print. [Crossref]
199. CHANG RONG LU, JIA XIANG LI, YI SHENG. 2020. A STUDY ON THE NEGATIVE
EXTERNALITY OF USD LIQUIDITY — BASED ON THE ASSET ALLOCATION
EFFICIENCY OF US TREASURY SECURITIES. The Singapore Economic Review 27, 1-29.
[Crossref]
200. Kaivan Munshi. 2020. Social Networks and Migration. Annual Review of Economics 12:1, 503-524.
[Crossref]
201. Gaofeng Han. 2020. Structural transformation and its implications for the Chinese economy. Pacific
Economic Review 25:3, 339-383. [Crossref]
202. Lu Deng, Ping Jiang, Sifei Li, Mingqing Liao. 2020. Government intervention and firm investment.
Journal of Corporate Finance 63, 101231. [Crossref]
203. Felix Zhiyu Feng, Jianyu Lu, Jing Wang. 2020. Productivity and liquidity management under costly
financing. Journal of Corporate Finance 63, 101258. [Crossref]
204. Zhuo Chen, Zhiguo He, Chun Liu. 2020. The financing of local government in China: Stimulus loan
wanes and shadow banking waxes. Journal of Financial Economics 137:1, 42-71. [Crossref]
205. Jianhua Zhang, Zhao Zhao, Wenqing Jian. 2020. Do cash flow imbalances facilitate leverage
adjustments of Chinese listed firms? Evidence from a dynamic panel threshold model. Economic
Modelling 89, 201-214. [Crossref]
206. Zhao Li, Yujing Chu, Tianruo Gao. 2020. ECONOMIC GROWTH WITH ENDOGENOUS
ECONOMIC INSTITUTIONS. Macroeconomic Dynamics 24:4, 920-934. [Crossref]
207. Xiang Deng, Li Li. 2020. Promoting or Inhibiting? The Impact of Environmental Regulation on
Corporate Financial Performance—An Empirical Analysis Based on China. International Journal of
Environmental Research and Public Health 17:11, 3828. [Crossref]
208. Jingxian ZOU, Guangjun SHEN, Shen JIA. 2020. How does labour share respond to risk? Theory and
evidence from the Chinese industrial sector. International Labour Review 159:2, 259-281. [Crossref]
209. Jingxian ZOU, Guangjun SHEN, Shen JIA. 2020. Risque d'entreprise et part du travail: théorie et
faits observés dans l'industrie en Chine. Revue internationale du Travail 159:2, 285-309. [Crossref]
210. Jingxian ZOU, Guangjun SHEN, Shen JIA. 2020. Participación del trabajo y riesgo empresarial.
Teoría y evidencia de las manufacturas chinas. Revista Internacional del Trabajo 139:2, 279-303.
[Crossref]
211. MINGLI XU, WEI YANG, LIRANG PANG, DONGMIN KONG. 2020. R&D, FINANCIAL
CONSTRAINTS AND PRODUCTIVITY: EVIDENCE FROM THE CHINESE INDUSTRIAL
ENTERPRISES. The Singapore Economic Review 65:04, 947-967. [Crossref]
212. Chong-En Bai, Qing Liu, Wen Yao. 2020. Earnings inequality and China's preferential lending policy.
Journal of Development Economics 145, 102477. [Crossref]
213. Hui-Cheng Yu. 2020. Corporate philanthropic giving and sustainable development. Journal of
Management Development 39:7/8, 837-849. [Crossref]
214. Dongyang Zhang, Wenping Zheng. 2020. Does Financial Constraint Impede the Innovative
Investment? Micro Evidence from China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 56:7, 1423-1446.
[Crossref]
215. Paula Bustos, Gabriel Garber, Jacopo Ponticelli. 2020. Capital Accumulation and Structural
Transformation*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 135:2, 1037-1094. [Crossref]
216. Wyatt Brooks, Alessandro Dovis. 2020. Credit market frictions and trade liberalizations. Journal of
Monetary Economics 111, 32-47. [Crossref]
217. Haoran Zhang. 2020. Metro and urban growth: Evidence from China. Journal of Transport Geography
85, 102732. [Crossref]
218. Yikai Wang. 2020. The Politico-Economic Dynamics of China’s Growth. Journal of the European
Economic Association 6. . [Crossref]
219. Jun Bai, Xiaoyun Gong, Xiangfang Zhao. 2020. Credit mismatch and non-financial firms’ shadow
banking activities —evidence based on entrusted loan activities. China Journal of Accounting Studies
8:2, 249-271. [Crossref]
220. Andreas Beerli, Franziska J. Weiss, Fabrizio Zilibotti, Josef Zweimüller. 2020. Demand forces of
technical change evidence from the Chinese manufacturing industry. China Economic Review 60,
101157. [Crossref]
221. Junxue Jia, Guangrong Ma, Cong Qin, Liyan Wang. 2020. Place-based policies, state-led
industrialisation, and regional development: Evidence from China's Great Western Development
Programme. European Economic Review 123, 103398. [Crossref]
222. Damien Cubizol. 2020. Rebalancing in China: A taxation approach. China Economic Review 60,
101270. [Crossref]
223. Frédéric Gannon, Gilles Le Garrec, Vincent Touzé. 2020. The South's demographic transition and
international capital flows in a financially integrated world economy. Journal of Demographic Economics
86:1, 1-45. [Crossref]
224. Zhao Chen, Sandra Poncet, Ruixiang Xiong. 2020. Local financial development and constraints on
domestic private-firm exports: Evidence from city commercial banks in China. Journal of Comparative
Economics 48:1, 56-75. [Crossref]
225. Chuanchuan Zhang. 2020. Clans, entrepreneurship, and development of the private sector in China.
Journal of Comparative Economics 48:1, 100-123. [Crossref]
226. Saite Lu, Jim H. Shen, Weiping Li, Jun Zhang. 2020. A theory of economic development and
dynamics of Chinese economy. Economic Modelling 86, 69-87. [Crossref]
227. Chenyan Zhang, Yongqiao Chen, Huiyu Zhou. 2020. Zombie Firms and Soft Budget Constraints in
the Chinese Stock Market*. Asian Economic Journal 34:1, 51-77. [Crossref]
228. Ming He, Yang Chen, Charles van Marrewijk. 2020. The effects of urban transformation on
productivity spillovers in China. Economic Modelling . [Crossref]
229. Wenming Xu, Shaogang Zhu, Zhicheng Wu. 2020. Building a Junior Stock Exchange: Lessons from
China. European Business Organization Law Review 21:1, 139-170. [Crossref]
230. Ayşe İmrohoroğlu, Kai Zhao. 2020. HOUSEHOLD SAVING, FINANCIAL CONSTRAINTS,
AND THE CURRENT ACCOUNT IN CHINA. International Economic Review 61:1, 71-103.
[Crossref]
231. Sharon G. M. Koh, Grace H. Y. Lee, Eduard J. Bomhoff. 2020. The income inequality, financial
depth and economic growth nexus in China. The World Economy 43:2, 412-427. [Crossref]
232. Bingyang Lv, Yongzheng Liu, Yan Li. 2020. Fiscal incentives, competition, and investment in China.
China Economic Review 59, 101371. [Crossref]
233. Junmin Liao. 2020. The rise of the service sector in China. China Economic Review 59, 101385.
[Crossref]
234. D.J. Ji, P. Zhou. 2020. Marginal abatement cost, air pollution and economic growth: Evidence from
Chinese cities. Energy Economics 86, 104658. [Crossref]
235. Chun-kei Tsang, Sung-ko Li. 2020. Allocation of resources within subgroups of an industry: a case
study in the Chinese industrial sector. Journal of Productivity Analysis 53:1, 125-139. [Crossref]
236. Nicola Amendola, Lorenzo Carbonari, Leo Ferraris. 2020. Collateral and development. The B.E.
Journal of Macroeconomics 20:1. . [Crossref]
237. Shuhong Wang, Lu Xing, Hanxue Chen. 2020. Impact of marine industrial structure on
environmental efficiency. Management of Environmental Quality: An International Journal 31:1,
111-129. [Crossref]
238. Peixin Li, Lixia Li, Xueliang Zhang. 2020. Regional Inequality of Firms’ Export Opportunity in
China: Geographical Location and Economic Openness. Sustainability 12:1, 9. [Crossref]
239. Chenyan Liu, Zuoping Xiao, Hong Xie. 2020. Customer concentration, institutions, and corporate
bond contracts. International Journal of Finance & Economics 25:1, 90-119. [Crossref]
240. Minjia Chen, Roman Matousek. 2020. Do productive firms get external finance? Evidence from
Chinese listed manufacturing firms. International Review of Financial Analysis 67, 101422. [Crossref]
241. Lin Ma, Yang Tang. 2020. Geography, trade, and internal migration in China. Journal of Urban
Economics 115, 103181. [Crossref]
242. Shiyu Bo. 2020. Centralization and regional development: Evidence from a political hierarchy reform
to create cities in china. Journal of Urban Economics 115, 103182. [Crossref]
243. Chong-en Bai, Chang-Tai Hsieh, Zheng Song. 2020. Special Deals with Chinese Characteristics.
NBER Macroeconomics Annual 34, 341-379. [Crossref]
244. Alberto Gabriele. SOE Governance and Performance 81-93. [Crossref]
245. ## #. 2020. A Phased Analysis of the Transformation of the Economic Growth Mode in the Seventy
Years of New China. Advances in Social Sciences 09:06, 787-796. [Crossref]
246. Torsten Heinrich, Jangho Yang, Shuanping Dai. 2020. Levels of Structural Change: An Analysis of
China's Development Push 1998-2014. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
247. Hongmiao Wang, Ping Zhang. The Main Line of the Theoretical Study on China’s Economic
Growth: The Transformation of the Model of Economy Catch-up and the Paradigm of Growth
Theory 529-563. [Crossref]
248. Hongjun Liao, Gang-Zhi Fan. 2020. Aging and Entrepreneurship: Evidence from Urban China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
249. Jie Li, Naixin Zhang, Zhigang Ouyang. 2020. Firm Exports and Processing Trade under Credit
Constraints. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
250. Yin Germaschewski, Jaroslav Horvath, Loris Rubini. 2020. Property Rights, Expropriations, and
Business Cycles in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
251. Xiaoming Li, Zheng Liu, Yuchao Peng, Zhiwei Xu. 2020. Bank Risk-Taking and Monetary Policy
Transmission: Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
252. Xiao Cen, Vyacheslav Fos, Wei Jiang. 2020. A Race to Lead: How Chinese Government Interventions
Shape the Sino-US Production Competition. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
253. Peisen Liu, Houjian Li, Hua Guo. 2020. The impact of corruption on firms’ access to bank loans:
evidence from China. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja 33:1, 1963-1984. [Crossref]
254. Ashis Kumar Pradhan, Gourishankar S Hiremath. 2020. Do external commercial borrowings and
financial development affect exports?. Cogent Business & Management 7:1, 1796269. [Crossref]
255. Yifei Li, Yuan Tian, Tong Yu, Ran Zhang. 2020. Corporate Bonds with Implicit Government
Guarantees. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
256. Franklin Allen, Jun “QJ” Qian, Meijun Qian. 2019. A Review of China's Institutions. Annual Review
of Financial Economics 11:1, 39-64. [Crossref]
257. TAMAS Z. CSABAFI, MAX GILLMAN, RUTHIRA NARAIDOO. 2019. International Business
Cycle and Financial Intermediation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 51:8, 2293-2303. [Crossref]
258. Raoul Minetti, Tao Peng, Tao Jiang. 2019. Keeping up with the Zhangs and house price dynamics in
China. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 109, 103778. [Crossref]
259. Hongyun Han, Shuang Lin. 2019. Government Size and Regional Capital Flows in China.
Sustainability 11:23, 6653. [Crossref]
260. Jing Huang, Linyu Liu, Ren Lu. 2019. Industry risk taking and risk-taking strategy of born-global
firms. Asia-Pacific Journal of Business Administration 12:1, 1-21. [Crossref]
261. Na Tan, Wei Wang, Jiaohui Yang, Liang Chang. 2019. Financial Competitiveness, Financial Openness
and Bilateral Foreign Direct Investment. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 55:14, 3349-3369.
[Crossref]
262. Lanlan Liu, Dan Luo, Liang Han. 2019. Default risk, state ownership and the cross-section of stock
returns: evidence from China. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 53:4, 933-966. [Crossref]
263. Ernest Liu. 2019. Industrial Policies in Production Networks*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics
134:4, 1883-1948. [Crossref]
264. Cheng Chen, Wei Tian, Miaojie Yu. 2019. Outward FDI and Domestic Input Distortions: Evidence
from Chinese Firms. The Economic Journal 129:624, 3025-3057. [Crossref]
265. Colin Davis, Laixun Zhao. 2019. How do business startup modes affect economic growth?. Canadian
Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 52:4, 1755-1781. [Crossref]
266. Xun Zhang, Hua Niu, Guanghua Wan, Chen Wang. 2019. Investing for urban-rural migration: the
role of education. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 24:4, 578-594. [Crossref]
267. Steven Lugauer, Jinlan Ni, Zhichao Yin. 2019. Chinese household saving and dependent children:
Theory and evidence. China Economic Review 57, 101091. [Crossref]
268. Shiyi Chen, Bin Lin. 2019. Dual-track interest rates and capital misallocation. China Economic Review
57, 101338. [Crossref]
269. Jianhong Zhang, Shifan Quan, Jiangang Jiang. 2019. Corruption and private firms' survival in
transition economies: Evidence from China. China Economic Review 57, 101339. [Crossref]
270. Ning Zhang. 2019. Country portfolios under global imbalances. European Economic Review 119,
302-317. [Crossref]
271. Qiusha Peng. 2019. Financial frictions, entry and growth: A study of China. Review of Economic
Dynamics 34, 267-282. [Crossref]
272. Shen Guo, Zheng Jiang. 2019. OPTIMAL FISCAL POLICY WITH LAND FINANCING IN
CHINA. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23:07, 2649-2674. [Crossref]
273. Yousen Wang, Jian Wang. 2019. Does industrial agglomeration facilitate environmental performance:
New evidence from urban China?. Journal of Environmental Management 248, 109244. [Crossref]
274. Yanliang Miao, Tuo Deng. 2019. China’s capital account liberalization: a ruby jubilee and beyond.
China Economic Journal 12:3, 245-271. [Crossref]
275. Gen-Fu Feng, Mingbo Zheng, Jun Wen, Chun-Ping Chang, Yin E. Chen. 2019. The assessment
of globalization on innovation in Chinese manufacturing firms. Structural Change and Economic
Dynamics 50, 190-202. [Crossref]
276. Lin William Cong, Haoyu Gao, Jacopo Ponticelli, Xiaoguang Yang. 2019. Credit Allocation Under
Economic Stimulus: Evidence from China. The Review of Financial Studies 32:9, 3412-3460. [Crossref]
277. Yihong Ma, Yi Xue, Jiefei Yang. 2019. Credit card cash‐out as informal financing: Evidence from
China. Australian Economic Papers 58:3, 259-279. [Crossref]
278. QU FENG, ZHIFENG WANG, GUIYING LAURA WU. 2019. PRODUCTIVITY DYNAMICS
OF CHINESE MANUFACTURING FIRMS. The Singapore Economic Review 64:04, 899-919.
[Crossref]
279. Chang Xu, Jianbing Guo, Baodong Cheng, Yu Liu. 2019. Exports, Misallocation, and Total Factor
Productivity of Furniture Enterprises. Sustainability 11:18, 4892. [Crossref]
280. Longfeng Ye, Peter E. Robertson. 2019. Hitting the Great Wall: Structural change and China's growth
slowdown. China Economic Review 56, 101302. [Crossref]
281. Rui Mao, Yang Yao, Jingxian Zou. 2019. Productivity growth, fixed exchange rates, and export-led
growth. China Economic Review 56, 101311. [Crossref]
282. Zhiyuan Chen, Jie Zhang. 2019. Types of patents and driving forces behind the patent growth in
China. Economic Modelling 80, 294-302. [Crossref]
283. Shikong (Scott) Luo. 2019. Credit Misallocation, Endogenous TFP Changes, and Economic
Fluctuation in China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 55:9, 1909-1925. [Crossref]
284. Qing Han. 2019. International Real Business Cycles of the Chinese Economy: Asymmetric Preference,
Incomplete Financial Markets, and Terms of Trade Shocks. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade
55:9, 1926-1953. [Crossref]
285. Ligang Song, Yixiao Zhou, Luke Hurst. Deepening reform and opening-up for China to grow into
a high-income country 1-17. [Crossref]
286. Guiying Laura Wu. China’s economic development: A perspective on capital misallocation 19-31.
[Crossref]
287. Michael Joffe. 2019. Mechanism in behavioural economics. Journal of Economic Methodology 26:3,
228-242. [Crossref]
288. Weiying Zhang. 2019. The China model view is factually false. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business
Studies 17:3, 287-311. [Crossref]
289. Daisuke Ikeda, Toan Phan. 2019. Asset Bubbles and Global Imbalances. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 11:3, 209-251. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
290. Franklin Allen, Yiming Qian, Guoqian Tu, Frank Yu. 2019. Entrusted loans: A close look at China's
shadow banking system. Journal of Financial Economics 133:1, 18-41. [Crossref]
291. Leonardo Baccini, Giammario Impullitti, Edmund J. Malesky. 2019. Globalization and state
capitalism: Assessing Vietnam's accession to the WTO. Journal of International Economics 119, 75-92.
[Crossref]
292. Jin Tao, Chun-Yu Ho, Shougui Luo, Yue Sheng. 2019. Agglomeration economies in creative
industries. Regional Science and Urban Economics 77, 141-154. [Crossref]
293. Jinfeng Ge, Jie Luo, Yangzhou Yuan. 2019. Misallocation in Chinese Manufacturing and Services: A
Variable Markup Approach. China & World Economy 27:4, 74-103. [Crossref]
294. Chenlu Tao, Jinzhu Zhang, Baodong Cheng, Yu Liu. 2019. An Assessment of the Impact of Spatial
Agglomeration on the Quality of China’s Wood Processing Industry Products. Sustainability 11:14,
3961. [Crossref]
295. YUAN AN, KEBIN DENG, ZHONG DING, FOX GAO. 2019. THE ROLE
OF MARKETIZATION ON THE LINKAGE BETWEEN MISALLOCATION AND
PRODUCTIVITY DISPERSION: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA. The Singapore Economic Review
1950029. [Crossref]
296. Xun Zhang, Guanghua Wan, Zhi Luo, Chen Wang. 2019. Explaining the East Asia miracle: The role
of urbanization. Economic Systems 43:2, 100697. [Crossref]
297. Chuantao Cui, Leona Shao-Zhi Li. 2019. High-speed rail and inventory reduction: firm-level evidence
from China. Applied Economics 51:25, 2715-2730. [Crossref]
298. Lili Wang, Rui Zhuang, Shunwu Huang, Yong Zhao. 2019. Quality Competition Versus Price
Competition: Why Does China Dominate the Global Solar Photo-Voltaic Market?. Emerging Markets
Finance and Trade 55:6, 1326-1342. [Crossref]
299. Chun Chang, Zheng Liu, Mark M. Spiegel, Jingyi Zhang. 2019. Reserve requirements and optimal
Chinese stabilization policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 103, 33-51. [Crossref]
300. Xianjuan Chen. 2019. Born like China, growing like China. Pacific Economic Review 24:2, 325-347.
[Crossref]
301. Ling-Yun He, Liang Wang. 2019. Import Liberalization of Intermediates and Environment: Empirical
Evidence from Chinese Manufacturing. Sustainability 11:9, 2579. [Crossref]
302. Hongyi Chen, Ran Li, Peter Tillmann. 2019. Pushing on a string: State-owned enterprises and
monetary policy transmission in China. China Economic Review 54, 26-40. [Crossref]
303. Fahmida Laghari, Ye Chengang. 2019. Investment in working capital and financial constraints.
International Journal of Managerial Finance 15:2, 164-190. [Crossref]
304. Jianzhi Zhao. 2019. Chinese State-Owned Companies, Misallocation and the Reform Policy. Chinese
Political Science Review 4:1, 28-51. [Crossref]
305. Yao Yao. 2019. Does higher education expansion enhance productivity?. Journal of Macroeconomics
59, 169-194. [Crossref]
306. Qiang Gong, Justin Yifu Lin, Yilin Zhang. 2019. Financial Structure, Industrial Structure, and
Economic Development: A New Structural Economics Perspective. The Manchester School 87:2,
183-204. [Crossref]
307. Kalyan Singhal, Jaya Singhal. 2019. Technology and Manufacturing in China before the Industrial
Revolution and Glimpses of the Future. Production and Operations Management 28:3, 505-515.
[Crossref]
308. Jiatao Li, Peixin Li, Baolian Wang. 2019. The liability of opaqueness: State ownership and the
likelihood of deal completion in international acquisitions by Chinese firms. Strategic Management
Journal 40:2, 303-327. [Crossref]
309. Yiyun Wu, Xiwei Zhu, Nicolaas Groenewold. 2019. The determinants and effectiveness of industrial
policy in china: A study based on Five-Year Plans. China Economic Review 53, 225-242. [Crossref]
310. Zhiyong Yao, Dingwei Gu, Wen Cao. 2019. SOEs as intermediation: Leakage effect under financial
repression. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 53, 349-361. [Crossref]
311. Ruiming Liu. China’s SOEs’ Efficiency Losses: A Survey 1-34. [Crossref]
312. Canfei He, Shengjun Zhu. What Causes Firm Failure in China? 147-168. [Crossref]
313. Rod Tyers, Yixiao Zhou. 2019. Financial Integration and the Global Effects of China's Growth Surge.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
314. Sris Chatterjee, Xian Gu, Iftekhar Hasan, Haitian Lu. 2019. Ownership Structure and the Cost of
Debt: Evidence from Chinese Corporate Bond Market. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
315. Zhe Geng, Jun Pan. 2019. Price Discovery and Market Segmentation in China’s Credit Market. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
316. Viral V. Acharya, Jun Qian, Yang Su, Zhishu Yang. 2019. In the Shadow of Banks: Wealth
Management Products and Issuing Banks’ Risk in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
317. Feng Dong, Yumei Guo, Yuchao Peng, Zhiwei Xu. 2019. Economic Slowdown and Housing Dynamics
in China: A Tale of Two Investments by Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal 37. . [Crossref]
318. Feng Dong, Jianfeng Liu, Zhiwei Xu, Bo Zhao. 2019. Flight to Housing in China. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
319. Zhenhuan Lei, Jeffrey B. Nugent. 2018. Coordinating China's economic growth strategy via
its government-controlled association for private firms. Journal of Comparative Economics 46:4,
1273-1293. [Crossref]
320. Zi-Lin He, Tony W. Tong, Yuchen Zhang, Wenlong He. 2018. A database linking Chinese patents
to China’s census firms. Scientific Data 5:1. . [Crossref]
321. Qiuyi Yang, Youze Lang, Changsheng Xu. 2018. Is the High Interest Rate Combined with Intense
Deleveraging Campaign Desirable? A Collateral Mechanism under Stringent Credit Constraints.
Sustainability 10:12, 4803. [Crossref]
322. Xiao Xiaonan. New Ideas on Statistical Analysis of Comprehensive Benefits of Enterprises 875-879.
[Crossref]
323. Dongling Cai, Leonard Fengsheng Wang, Xiaokai Wu. 2018. Governance, privatization and foreign
direct investment. Nankai Business Review International 9:4, 569-586. [Crossref]
324. Laiqun Jin, Changwei Mo, Bochao Zhang, Bing Yu. 2018. What Is the Focus of Structural Reform
in China?—Comparison of the Factor Misallocation Degree within the Manufacturing Industry with
a Unified Model. Sustainability 10:11, 4051. [Crossref]
325. Florian Mayneris, Sandra Poncet, Tao Zhang. 2018. Improving or disappearing: Firm-level
adjustments to minimum wages in China. Journal of Development Economics 135, 20-42. [Crossref]
326. Zheng (Michael) Song, Wei Xiong. 2018. Risks in China's Financial System. Annual Review of
Financial Economics 10:1, 261-286. [Crossref]
327. Raül Santaeulàlia-Llopis, Yu Zheng. 2018. The Price of Growth: Consumption Insurance in China
1989–2009. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10:4, 1-35. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
328. Ingvild Almås, Åshild Auglænd Johnsen. 2018. The cost of a growth miracle – reassessing price and
poverty trends in China. Review of Economic Dynamics 30, 239-264. [Crossref]
329. Erin H. Kao, Chih-Chuan Yeh, Li-Hsun Wang, Hung-Gay Fung. 2018. The relationship between
CSR and performance: Evidence in China. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 51, 155-170. [Crossref]
330. Samuel Adams, Edem Kwame Mensah Klobodu. 2018. Capital flows and economic growth revisited:
evidence from five Sub-Saharan African countries. International Review of Applied Economics 32:5,
620-640. [Crossref]
331. Peng Bin, Xiaolan Chen, Andrea Fracasso, Chiara Tomasi. 2018. Resource allocation and productivity
across provinces in China. International Review of Economics & Finance 57, 103-113. [Crossref]
332. Erzi Tang, Chong Peng, Yilan Xu. 2018. Changes of energy consumption with economic development
when an economy becomes more productive. Journal of Cleaner Production 196, 788-795. [Crossref]
333. Yongnian Zheng, Yanjie Huang. Market in State 50, . [Crossref]
334. Jinchuan Shi, Xiaoqian Zhang. 2018. How to explain corporate investment heterogeneity in China's
new normal: Structural models with state-owned property rights. China Economic Review 50, 1-16.
[Crossref]
335. Russell Cooper, Guan Gong, Ping Yan. 2018. Costly Labour Adjustment: General Equilibrium
Effects of China's Employment Regulations and Financial Reforms. The Economic Journal 128:613,
1879-1922. [Crossref]
336. Xiaoguang Liu, Raphael Lam, Alfred Schipke, Guangjun Shen. 2018. A generalized Okun's Law:
Uncovering the myth of China's labor market resilience. Review of Development Economics 22:3,
1195-1216. [Crossref]
337. Chanbora Ek, Guiying Laura Wu. 2018. Investment-cash flow sensitivities and capital misallocation.
Journal of Development Economics 133, 220-230. [Crossref]
338. Yu Hao, Ling'ou Wang, Lingyun Zhu, Minjie Ye. 2018. The dynamic relationship between energy
consumption, investment and economic growth in China's rural area: New evidence based on provincial
panel data. Energy 154, 374-382. [Crossref]
339. Jun Wen, Gen-Fu Feng, Chun-Ping Chang, Zhao-Zhen Feng. 2018. Stock liquidity and enterprise
innovation: new evidence from China. The European Journal of Finance 24:9, 683-713. [Crossref]
340. Shen Guo, Zheng Jiang, Huimin Shi. 2018. The business cycle implications of bank discrimination
in China. Economic Modelling 73, 264-278. [Crossref]
341. Ayşe İmrohoroğlu, Kai Zhao. 2018. The chinese saving rate: Long-term care risks, family insurance,
and demographics. Journal of Monetary Economics 96, 33-52. [Crossref]
342. Shiyu Li, Shuanglin Lin, Suresh Narayanan. 2018. The Effect of an Introduction of Retail Sales Tax
in China. Asian Economic Papers 17:2, 1-20. [Crossref]
343. Hao Qi. 2018. “Distribution According to Work”: An Historical Analysis of the Incentive System in
China’s State-Owned Sector. Review of Radical Political Economics 50:2, 409-426. [Crossref]
344. Malin Song, Mei Chen, Shuhong Wang. 2018. Global supply chain integration, financing restrictions,
and green innovation. The International Journal of Logistics Management 29:2, 539-554. [Crossref]
345. Ayşe İmrohoroğlu, Kai Zhao. 2018. Intergenerational transfers and China’s social security reform.
The Journal of the Economics of Ageing 11, 62-70. [Crossref]
346. Hua Shang, Teng Zhang, Puman Ouyang. 2018. Credit Allocation and Firm Productivity Under
Financial Imperfection: Evidence from Chinese Manufacturing Firms. Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade 54:5, 992-1010. [Crossref]
347. Yanbin Chen, Kai Liu, Zhexi Liu. 2018. U.S. Money Supply and China’s Business Cycles. Emerging
Markets Finance and Trade 54:5, 957-980. [Crossref]
348. Zhigang Li, Mingqin Wu. 2018. Education and welfare program compliance: Firm-level evidence
from a pension reform in China. China Economic Review 48, 1-13. [Crossref]
349. Xun Zhang, Zongyue He, Jiali Zhu, Jing Li. 2018. Quantity of finance and financial crisis: A
non-monotonic investigation#. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance 44, 129-139.
[Crossref]
350. Ruipeng Tan, Boqiang Lin. 2018. What factors lead to the decline of energy intensity in China's
energy intensive industries?. Energy Economics 71, 213-221. [Crossref]
351. Damien Cubizol. 2018. Transition and capital misallocation: the Chinese case. Journal of International
Money and Finance 81, 88-115. [Crossref]
352. Sandra Eickmeier, Markus Kühnlenz. 2018. CHINA'S ROLE IN GLOBAL INFLATION
DYNAMICS. Macroeconomic Dynamics 22:2, 225-254. [Crossref]
353. Qian Weng, Måns Söderbom. 2018. Is R&D cash flow sensitive? Evidence from Chinese industrial
firms. China Economic Review 47, 77-95. [Crossref]
354. Jian Gao, Tao Zhou. 2018. Quantifying China’s regional economic complexity. Physica A: Statistical
Mechanics and its Applications 492, 1591-1603. [Crossref]
355. HONG RU. 2018. Government Credit, a Double-Edged Sword: Evidence from the China
Development Bank. The Journal of Finance 73:1, 275-316. [Crossref]
356. Finn E. Kydland. Does Policy Consistency Affect Economic Growth? 3-18. [Crossref]
357. Huijiong Wang, Shantong Li. Indicators, Models and Mathematical Modeling 249-304. [Crossref]
358. Mian Yang, Fuxia Yang, Chuanwang Sun. 2018. Factor market distortion correction, resource
reallocation and potential productivity gains: An empirical study on China's heavy industry sector.
Energy Economics 69, 270-279. [Crossref]
359. Guiying Laura Wu. 2018. Capital misallocation in China: Financial frictions or policy distortions?.
Journal of Development Economics 130, 203-223. [Crossref]
360. Kaiming Guo, Jing Hang, Se Yan. 2018. Servicification of Investment and Structural Transformation:
The Case of China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
361. Damien Cubizol. 2018. Rebalancing in China: A Taxation Approach. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
362. Zhenhuan Lei, Jeffrey B. Nugent. 2018. Coordinating China's Economic Growth Strategy via Its
Government-Controlled Association for Private Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
363. Andreas Beerli, Franziska Weiss, Fabrizio Zilibotti, Josef Zweimmller. 2018. Demand Forces of
Technical Change: Evidence From the Chinese Manufacturing Industry. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
364. Chun Chang, Kaiji Chen, Daniel F. Waggoner, Tao A. Zha. 2018. Trends and Cycles in China's
Macroeconomy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
365. Yiping Huang, Yang Ji, Xiaoran Ni, Yuyan Tan, Xu Wang. 2018. Economic Policy Uncertainty, State
Ownership, and Credit Allocation. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
366. Mayank Gupta, Massimiliano Caporin. 2018. The Evolution of Shadow Banking System in Emerging
Economies: The Role of Entrusted Loans in Chinaas Capital Market. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
367. Shuo Yan. 2018. Corporate Political Connections and the Finance-Growth Nexus: Evidence from
China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
368. Kezhou Xiao. 2018. Becoming Global Billionaires from Mainland China: A Theoretical Investigation.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
369. Yin Germaschewski. 2018. House Price, Credit Supply, and Government Policy in China. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
370. John B. Donaldson, Christos Koulovatianos, Jian Li, Rajnish Mehra. 2018. Demographics and FDI:
Lessons from China's One-Child Policy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
371. Jae Wook Jung, Kyunghun KIim. 2018. Financial Market Integration and Income Inequality. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
372. Saite Lu, Jim Huangnan Shen, Jun Zhang. 2018. The Role of the Financial Sector in Economic
Development. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
373. Zhuo Chen, Zhiguo He, Chun Liu. 2018. The Financing of Local Government in China: Stimulus
Loan Wanes and Shadow Banking Waxes. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
374. Samir Amine, Wilner Predelus. Employment Protection Legislation in Emerging Economies 29-47.
[Crossref]
375. Guangyu Nie. 2018. Marriage Squeeze, Marriage Age and the Household Savings Rate in China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
376. Franklin Allen, Jun “QJ” Qian, Meijun Qian. 2018. A Review of China’s Institutions. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
377. Josef Schroth. 2018. Capital Flows Across Developing Countries: Is There an Allocation Puzzle?.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
378. Thomas Fischer. 2018. Spatial Inequality and Housing in China. SSRN Electronic Journal 95. .
[Crossref]
379. Julan Du, Chang Li, Yongqin Wang. 2017. A comparative study of shadow banking activities of non-
financial firms in transition economies. China Economic Review 46, S35-S49. [Crossref]
380. Xingquan Yang, Liang Han, Wanli Li, Xingqiang Yin, Lin Tian. 2017. Monetary policy, cash holding
and corporate investment: Evidence from China. China Economic Review 46, 110-122. [Crossref]
381. Fangbin Qiao. 2017. Increasing wage, mechanization, and agriculture production in China. China
Economic Review 46, 249-260. [Crossref]
382. Xun Zhang, Guanghua Wan, Xu Wang. 2017. Road infrastructure and the share of labor income:
Evidence from China’s manufacturing sector. Economic Systems 41:4, 513-523. [Crossref]
383. Yan Xu, Yougui Wang, Xiaobo Tao, Lenka Ližbetinová. 2017. Evidence of Chinese income dynamics
and its effects on income scaling law. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 487, 143-152.
[Crossref]
384. Dong He, Paul Luk. 2017. A MODEL OF CHINESE CAPITAL ACCOUNT LIBERALIZATION.
Macroeconomic Dynamics 21:8, 1902-1934. [Crossref]
385. Peilin Liu, Shen Jia, Xun Zhang. 2017. Catch-up cycle: A general equilibrium framework. Review of
Development Economics 21:4, 1327-1340. [Crossref]
386. Qianyu Zhao, Zhanlu Zhang. 2017. Does China’s ‘increasing versus decreasing balance’ land-
restructuring policy restructure rural life? Evidence from Dongfan Village, Shaanxi Province. Land
Use Policy 68, 649-659. [Crossref]
387. Dongyang Zhang. 2017. Is working capital management value-enhancing through alleviating financial
constraints? Evidence from Chinese non-listed firms. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies
15:4, 373-406. [Crossref]
388. Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2017. Growing and Slowing Down Like China. Journal of the European Economic
Association 15:5, 943-988. [Crossref]
389. Daniel Berkowitz, Hong Ma, Shuichiro Nishioka. 2017. Recasting the Iron Rice Bowl: The Reform
of China's State-Owned Enterprises. The Review of Economics and Statistics 99:4, 735-747. [Crossref]
390. Hao Li, Yuhuan Zhao, Xiaoyong Qiao, Ya Liu, Ye Cao, Yue Li, Song Wang, Zhonghua Zhang,
Yongfeng Zhang, Jianfeng Weng. 2017. Identifying the driving forces of national and regional CO2
emissions in China: Based on temporal and spatial decomposition analysis models. Energy Economics
68, 522-538. [Crossref]
391. Shiyuan Pan, Kang Shi, Lisheng Wang, Juanyi Xu. 2017. Excess liquidity and credit misallocation:
evidence from China. China Economic Journal 10:3, 265-286. [Crossref]
392. Paolo Epifani, Gino Gancia. 2017. Global imbalances revisited: The transfer problem and transport
costs in monopolistic competition. Journal of International Economics 108, 99-116. [Crossref]
393. Guido Cozzi, Margaret Davenport. 2017. Extrapolative expectations and capital flows during
convergence. Journal of International Economics 108, 169-190. [Crossref]
394. Diego Restuccia, Richard Rogerson. 2017. The Causes and Costs of Misallocation. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 31:3, 151-174. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
395. Samuel Cudré, Mathias Hoffmann. 2017. A provincial view of global imbalances: regional capital
flows in China. Review of World Economics 153:3, 573-599. [Crossref]
396. George Alessandria, Horag Choi, Dan Lu. 2017. Trade Integration and the Trade Balance in China.
IMF Economic Review 65:3, 633-674. [Crossref]
397. Xun Zhang, Guanghua Wan, Chen Wang, Zhi Luo. 2017. Technical change and income inequality
in China. The World Economy 113. . [Crossref]
398. Qiong Zhang, Yupeng Shi, Angda He, Xueting Wen. 2017. Property rights security and firm survival:
Micro-data evidence from China. China Economic Review 44, 296-310. [Crossref]
399. Guangjun Shen, Binkai Chen. 2017. Zombie firms and over-capacity in Chinese manufacturing. China
Economic Review 44, 327-342. [Crossref]
400. Zhigang Li, Mingqin Wu, Bin R. Chen. 2017. Is road infrastructure investment in China excessive?
Evidence from productivity of firms. Regional Science and Urban Economics 65, 116-126. [Crossref]
401. Lily H. Fang, Josh Lerner, Chaopeng Wu. 2017. Intellectual Property Rights Protection, Ownership,
and Innovation: Evidence from China. The Review of Financial Studies 30:7, 2446-2477. [Crossref]
402. Yousha Liang, Kang Shi, Lisheng Wang, Juanyi Xu. 2017. Local Government Debt and Firm
Leverage: Evidence from China. Asian Economic Policy Review 12:2, 210-232. [Crossref]
403. Hangtian Xu, Kentaro Nakajima. 2017. Highways and industrial development in the peripheral regions
of China. Papers in Regional Science 96:2, 325-356. [Crossref]
404. Jianwei Xu, Panpan Yang, Guangrong Ma. 2017. Accounting for China's Saving-Investment Imbalance
from 2002-2008. Review of Income and Wealth 63:2, 234-252. [Crossref]
405. Zhiyuan Chen, Jie Zhang, Wenping Zheng. 2017. Import and innovation: Evidence from Chinese
firms. European Economic Review 94, 205-220. [Crossref]
406. Ren Wang, Jie Hou, Xiaobei He, Hui Song. 2017. Borrowing constraint, heterogeneous production
sectors and policy implications: The case of China. International Review of Economics & Finance 49,
568-581. [Crossref]
407. Fabrice Defever, Alejandro Riaño. 2017. Subsidies with export share requirements in China. Journal
of Development Economics 126, 33-51. [Crossref]
408. Fengliang Liu, Xin Yi, Ze Yu. 2017. Structural change in China: the role of factor market distortions.
Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 15:2, 185-204. [Crossref]
409. Kaiji Chen, Yi Wen. 2017. The Great Housing Boom of China. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 9:2, 73-114. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
410. Ya Tang, Jianguo Xu, Xun Zhang. 2017. China's investment and rate of return on capital revisited.
Journal of Asian Economics 49, 12-25. [Crossref]
411. Cristina Jude, Gregory Levieuge. 2017. Growth Effect of Foreign Direct Investment in Developing
Economies: The Role of Institutional Quality. The World Economy 40:4, 715-742. [Crossref]
412. Shaosheng Jin, Haiyue Guo, Michael S. Delgado, H. Holly Wang. 2017. Benefit or damage? The
productivity effects of FDI in the Chinese food industry. Food Policy 68, 1-9. [Crossref]
413. Elena Seghezza, Pierluigi Morelli, Giovanni B. Pittaluga. 2017. Reserve accumulation and exchange
rate policy in China: The authoritarian elite's aim of political survival. European Journal of Political
Economy 47, 163-174. [Crossref]
414. Chadwick C. Curtis, Steven Lugauer, Nelson C. Mark. 2017. Demographics and aggregate household
saving in Japan, China, and India. Journal of Macroeconomics 51, 175-191. [Crossref]
415. Alvaro Aguirre. 2017. Contracting institutions and economic growth. Review of Economic Dynamics
24, 192-217. [Crossref]
416. Cheng Li, Xiaojing Zhang. 2017. Renminbi Internationalization in the New Normal: Progress,
Determinants and Policy Discussions. China & World Economy 25:2, 22-44. [Crossref]
417. Jianglong Li, Boqiang Lin. 2017. Does energy and CO2 emissions performance of China benefit from
regional integration?. Energy Policy 101, 366-378. [Crossref]
418. Lucas Bretschger, Lin Zhang. 2017. Carbon policy in a high-growth economy: The case of China.
Resource and Energy Economics 47, 1-19. [Crossref]
419. Jie Li, Jing Lu, Mobing Jiang. 2017. Political Economy Model of Cross-Border Mergers Under Mixed
Oligopoly. Pacific Economic Review 22:1, 83-100. [Crossref]
420. Pengfei Wang, Yi Wen, Zhiwei Xu. 2017. Two‐Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances. The
Economic Journal 127:599, 229-269. [Crossref]
421. David Tan, Justin Tan. 2017. Far from the Tree? Do Private Entrepreneurs Agglomerate Around
Public Sector Incumbents During Economic Transition?. Organization Science 28:1, 113-132.
[Crossref]
422. Yasushi Suzuki, Mohammad Dulal Miah. 2017. China’s ”New Normal”: An Interpretation from
Institutional and Marxian Views. Journal of Comparative Asian Development 16:1, 21-46. [Crossref]
423. Yasushi Suzuki, Mohammad Dulal Miah. China’s ‘New Normal’: Explaining China’s Economic
Development from Institutional and Marxian Perspectives 21-41. [Crossref]
424. Ren Wang, Jie Hou, Xiaobei He. 2017. Real estate price and heterogeneous investment behavior in
China. Economic Modelling 60, 271-280. [Crossref]
425. Elena Seghezza, Pierluigi Morelli, Giovanni B. Pittaluga. 2017. Reserve accumulation and exchange
rate policy in China: The authoritarian elite's aim of political survival. European Journal of Political
Economy 46, 40-51. [Crossref]
426. John Joshua. Economic Policies of Economic Growth and Development 45-80. [Crossref]
427. John Joshua. International Trade Relations 99-130. [Crossref]
428. Jinyu Liu, Zhengwei Wang, Zhu Wuxiang. 2017. Does Privatization Reform Alleviate Ownership
Discrimination? Evidence from the Split-Share Structure Reform in China. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
429. Zilong Zhang, Shuang Jin. 2017. Political Connections, Government Subsidies, and Capital
Misallocation: Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
430. Noemie Lisack. 2017. Alternative Finance and Credit Sector Reforms: The Case of China. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
431. Ji Qi, Xin Tang, Xican Xi. 2017. The Size Distribution of Firms and Industrial Water Pollution: A
Quantitative Analysis of China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
432. Zhangkai Huang, Lixing Li, Guangrong Ma, Jun Qian. 2017. Limit to Autocracy: An Analysis of
China's Renationalization. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
433. Sergei M. Guriev. 2017. Soft Budget Constraints and State Capitalism. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
434. Hailong Jin, Tong Wang. 2017. Dynamic Currency Intervention and International Monetary
Neutrality. Theoretical Economics Letters 07:03, 575-581. [Crossref]
435. International Monetary Fund.. 2017. Vietnam: Selected Issues. IMF Staff Country Reports 17:191,
1. [Crossref]
436. Dong Cheng, Yong Tan, Jian Yu. 2017. Credit Rationing and Firm Exports: Microeconomic Evidence
from SMEs in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
437. Lin William Cong, Haoyu Gao, Jacopo Ponticelli, Xiaoguang Yang. 2017. Credit Allocation Under
Economic Stimulus: Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
438. Paula Bustos, Gabriel Garber, Jacopo Ponticelli. 2017. Capital Accumulation and Structural
Transformation. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
439. Simon Alder, Lin Shao, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2016. Economic reforms and industrial policy in a panel
of Chinese cities. Journal of Economic Growth 21:4, 305-349. [Crossref]
440. José R. Sánchez-Fung. 2016. Reviewing Trade Policy in China During the Transition to Balanced
Economic Growth. The World Economy 39:12, 1934-1946. [Crossref]
441. Sara Hsu, Alba Carolina Melchor Simon. 2016. China’s structural transformation: reaching potential
GDP in the financial services sector. China Finance and Economic Review 4:1. . [Crossref]
442. Yasheng Huang, Yue Ma, Zhi Yang, Yifan Zhang. 2016. A fire sale without fire: An explanation of
labor-intensive FDI in China. Journal of Comparative Economics 44:4, 884-901. [Crossref]
443. Sewon Hur, Illenin O. Kondo. 2016. A theory of rollover risk, sudden stops, and foreign reserves.
Journal of International Economics 103, 44-63. [Crossref]
444. David H. Autor, David Dorn, Gordon H. Hanson. 2016. The China Shock: Learning from Labor-
Market Adjustment to Large Changes in Trade. Annual Review of Economics 8:1, 205-240. [Crossref]
445. Yu Hao, Zong-Yong Zhang, Hua Liao, Yi-Ming Wei, Shuo Wang. 2016. Is CO2 emission a side
effect of financial development? An empirical analysis for China. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 23:20, 21041-21057. [Crossref]
446. Halvor Mehlum, Ragnar Torvik, Simone Valente. 2016. The savings multiplier. Journal of Monetary
Economics 83, 90-105. [Crossref]
447. Qian Zhang, Zhongxiao Sun, Feng Wu, Xiangzheng Deng. 2016. Understanding rural restructuring
in China: The impact of changes in labor and capital productivity on domestic agricultural production
and trade. Journal of Rural Studies 47, 552-562. [Crossref]
448. Sai Ding, Wei Jiang, Puyang Sun. 2016. Import competition, dynamic resource allocation and
productivity dispersion: micro-level evidence from China. Oxford Economic Papers 68:4, 994-1015.
[Crossref]
449. Yong Ma. 2016. Nonlinear monetary policy and macroeconomic stabilization in emerging market
economies: Evidence from China. Economic Systems 40:3, 461-480. [Crossref]
450. Xing Liu, Shuiquan Jiang. 2016. Bank equity connections, intellectual property protection and
enterprise innovation – A bank ownership perspective. China Journal of Accounting Research 9:3,
207-233. [Crossref]
451. Dejing Kong, David Dickinson. 2016. Investigating the Impact of Income on Savings Using a Chinese
Household Level Dataset. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 52:8, 1775-1796. [Crossref]
452. Laura Policardo, Lionello F. Punzo, Edgar J. Sánchez Carrera. 2016. Brazil and China: Two Routes
of Economic Development?. Review of Development Economics 20:3, 651-669. [Crossref]
453. Hans Degryse, Liping Lu, Steven Ongena. 2016. Informal or formal financing? Evidence on the co-
funding of Chinese firms. Journal of Financial Intermediation 27, 31-50. [Crossref]
454. Chadwick C. Curtis. 2016. Economic reforms and the evolution of China's total factor productivity.
Review of Economic Dynamics 21, 225-245. [Crossref]
455. Yong Zhao, Lili Wang, Yihua Yu. 2016. Trade Liberalization and China’s Exports of Renewable
Energy Products: Evidence from Product Level Data. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 52:6,
1281-1297. [Crossref]
456. Jingting Fan, Şebnem Kalemli-Özcan. 2016. Emergence of Asia: Reforms, Corporate Savings, and
Global Imbalances. IMF Economic Review 64:2, 239-267. [Crossref]
457. Sai Ding, Alessandra Guariglia, Richard Harris. 2016. The determinants of productivity in Chinese
large and medium-sized industrial firms, 1998–2007. Journal of Productivity Analysis 45:2, 131-155.
[Crossref]
458. Yi Yang, Renwen Lin. 2016. Property protection, financial constraints and economic growth. Journal
of Shanghai Jiaotong University (Science) 21:2, 192-198. [Crossref]
459. Sai Ding, Puyang Sun, Wei Jiang. 2016. The Effect of Import Competition on Firm Productivity
and Innovation: Does the Distance to Technology Frontier Matter?. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics 78:2, 197-227. [Crossref]
460. Qingyuan Du, Shang-Jin Wei. 2016. A Darwinian perspective on “exchange rate undervaluation”.
European Economic Review 83, 111-138. [Crossref]
461. Liuchun Deng, Boqun Wang. 2016. Regional capital flows and economic regimes: Evidence from
China. Economics Letters 141, 80-83. [Crossref]
462. Wei Shen, Qiong Zhou, Chung-Ming Lau. 2016. Empirical Research on Corporate Governance in
China: A Review and New Directions for the Future. Management and Organization Review 12:01,
41-73. [Crossref]
463. Yuyan Tan, Yang Ji, Yiping Huang. 2016. Completing China's Interest Rate Liberalization. China &
World Economy 24:2, 1-22. [Crossref]
464. Canfei He, Rudai Yang. 2016. Determinants of Firm Failure: Empirical Evidence from China. Growth
and Change 47:1, 72-92. [Crossref]
465. Guohua Peng, Fan Xia. 2016. The size distribution of exporting and non-exporting firms in a panel
of Chinese provinces. Papers in Regional Science 95, S71-S85. [Crossref]
466. Jihai Yu, Li-An Zhou, Guozhong Zhu. 2016. Strategic interaction in political competition: Evidence
from spatial effects across Chinese cities. Regional Science and Urban Economics 57, 23-37. [Crossref]
467. Ronald Ravinesh Kumar, Peter Josef Stauvermann, Aristeidis Samitas. 2016. The effects of ICT⁎ on
output per worker: A study of the Chinese economy. Telecommunications Policy 40:2-3, 102-115.
[Crossref]
468. Zhiyuan Chen, Yong Li, Jie Zhang. 2016. The bank–firm relationship: Helping or grabbing?.
International Review of Economics & Finance 42, 385-403. [Crossref]
469. Heng An, Yanyan Chen, Danglun Luo, Ting Zhang. 2016. Political uncertainty and corporate
investment: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance 36, 174-189. [Crossref]
470. Chun Chang, Kaiji Chen, Daniel F. Waggoner, Tao Zha. 2016. Trends and Cycles in China’s
Macroeconomy. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 30:1, 1-84. [Crossref]
471. John Fernald. 2016. Comment. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 30:1, 90-100. [Crossref]
472. Zhefan Piao, Jini Jia, Fangyan Shen, Rongda Chen. 2016. Research of Microcosmic Affection Factors
on Capital Misallocation: A Case of Chinese Listed Companies. Mathematical Problems in Engineering
2016, 1-12. [Crossref]
473. Wei Jin, ZhongXiang Zhang. 2016. China's Pursuit of Environmentally Sustainable Development:
Harnessing the New Engine of Technological Innovation. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
474. Jacek Rothert, Jacob M. Short. 2016. Non-Traded Goods, Structural Change, and Capital Flows to
Developing Countries. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
475. Samuel Cudrr, Mathias Hoffmann. 2016. A Provincial View of Global Imbalances: Regional Capital
Flows in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
476. Shiyuan Pan, Kang Shi, Lisheng Wang, Juanyi (Jenny) Xu. 2016. Excess Liquidity and Credit
Misallocation: Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
477. Harald Hau, Yi Huang, Gewei Wang. 2016. Firm Response to Competitive Shocks: Evidence from
Chinaas Minimum Wage Policy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
478. Jinyu Liu, Zhengwei Wang, Zhu wuxiang. 2016. Ownership and Financing Discrimination: Evidence
from the Split-Share Structure Reform in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
479. Yi Huang, Marco Pagano, Ugo Panizza. 2016. Public Debt and Private Firm Funding: Evidence from
Chinese Cities. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
480. Lin William Cong, Jacopo Ponticelli. 2016. Credit Allocation under Economic Stimulus: Evidence
from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
481. Chuanchuan Zhang. 2016. Culture and the Economy: Clan, Entrepreneurship, and the Development
of Private Sector in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
482. Franklin Allen, Jun Qian, Susan Chenyu Shan, Lei Zhu. 2016. Dissecting the Long-Term
Performance of the Chinese Stock Market. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
483. Christos P. Mavis, Sarmistha Pal. 2016. Why Stock Market Reform May Not Always Boost
Firm Efficiency? Assessing the Impact of Non-Tradeable Shares Reform in China&#9824;. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
484. Xiaojie Liu, Huangnan Shen Jim. 2016. From Nash to Pareto in a Market-Leninist Economy: How
to Deepen Reforms of Large State-Owned Enterprises in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
485. Joel David, Venky Venkateswaran. 2016. Frictional Investment and the Sources of Misallocation. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
486. Feifei Zhu, Guo Li, Jie Hu. 2016. Regional Financial Developments and Research and Development
Investment Cash Flow Sensitivity: Evidence on Chinese Public High-Tech Companies. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
487. Hui He, Nan Li, Jing Fang. 2016. China's Rising IQ (Innovation Quotient) and Growth: Firm-level
Evidence. IMF Working Papers 16:249, 1. [Crossref]
488. Paula Bustos, Gabriel Garber, Jacopo Ponticelli. 2016. Capital Allocation Across Regions, Sectors and
Firms: Evidence from a Commodity Boom in Brazil. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
489. Yuan Yangzhou. 2016. Comments by Yuan Yangzhou, on Unemployment and the Speed of Transition
in China. Asian Economic Papers 15:1, 171-172. [Crossref]
490. Mariassunta Giannetti, Guanmin Liao, Jiaxing You, Xiaoyun Yu. 2016. The Externalities of
Corruption: Evidence from Entrepreneurial Activity in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
491. Philippe Bacchetta, Kenza Benhima. 2015. THE DEMAND FOR LIQUID ASSETS,
CORPORATE SAVING, AND INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS. Journal of the European
Economic Association 13:6, 1101-1135. [Crossref]
492. Pu Chen, Chunyang Wang, Yangyan Liu. 2015. Real estate prices and firm borrowings: Micro evidence
from China. China Economic Review 36, 296-308. [Crossref]
493. Puyang Sun, Wei Jiang. 2015. The Squeezed Middle: Political Affiliation and Financial Constraints
in China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 51:6, 1074-1083. [Crossref]
494. Margaux MacDonald. 2015. Patterns of International Capital Flows and Productivity Growth: New
Evidence. Review of International Economics 23:5, 846-872. [Crossref]
495. Jian Wang, Xiao Wang. 2015. Benefits of foreign ownership: Evidence from foreign direct investment
in China. Journal of International Economics 97:2, 325-338. [Crossref]
496. Nicolas Coeurdacier, Stéphane Guibaud, Keyu Jin. 2015. Credit Constraints and Growth in a Global
Economy. American Economic Review 105:9, 2838-2881. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
497. Bo Zhao. 2015. Rational housing bubble. Economic Theory 60:1, 141-201. [Crossref]
498. Karine Gente, Miguel A. León-Ledesma, Carine Nourry. 2015. External constraints and endogenous
growth: Why didn't some countries benefit from capital flows?. Journal of International Money and
Finance 56, 223-249. [Crossref]
499. Gong Cheng. 2015. A GROWTH PERSPECTIVE ON FOREIGN RESERVE ACCUMULATION.
Macroeconomic Dynamics 19:6, 1358-1379. [Crossref]
500. Ruixue Jia, Masayuki Kudamatsu, David Seim. 2015. POLITICAL SELECTION IN CHINA:
THE COMPLEMENTARY ROLES OF CONNECTIONS AND PERFORMANCE. Journal of the
European Economic Association 13:4, 631-668. [Crossref]
501. Giuseppe Bertola, Anna Lo Prete. 2015. Reforms, Finance, and Current Accounts. Review of
International Economics 23:3, 469-488. [Crossref]
502. Belton M. Fleisher, William H. McGuire, Adam Nicholas Smith, Mi Zhou. 2015. Knowledge capital,
innovation, and growth in China. Journal of Asian Economics 39, 31-42. [Crossref]
503. Daron Acemoglu, Gino Gancia, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2015. Offshoring and Directed Technical Change.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7:3, 84-122. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
504. Thomas J. Holmes, Ellen R. McGrattan, Edward C. Prescott. 2015. Quid Pro Quo: Technology
Capital Transfers for Market Access in China. The Review of Economic Studies 82:3, 1154-1193.
[Crossref]
505. Kalina Manova, Shang-Jin Wei, Zhiwei Zhang. 2015. Firm Exports and Multinational Activity Under
Credit Constraints. Review of Economics and Statistics 97:3, 574-588. [Crossref]
506. Xue-Jie Bai, Wen-Kai Yan, Yung-Ho Chiu. 2015. Performance evaluation of China's Hi-tech zones in
the post financial crisis era — Analysis based on the dynamic network SBM model. China Economic
Review 34, 122-134. [Crossref]
507. Ying Wu, Hong Yao. 2015. Income Inequality, State Ownership, and the Pattern of Economic Growth
– A Tale of the Kuznets Curve for China since 1978. Atlantic Economic Journal 43:2, 165-180.
[Crossref]
508. M. Duschl, S.-S. Peng. 2015. The patterns of Chinese firm growth: a conditional estimation approach
of the asymmetric exponential power density. Industrial and Corporate Change 24:3, 539-563.
[Crossref]
509. Guiying Laura Wu. 2015. Investment Frictions and the Aggregate Output Loss in China. Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 77:3, 437-465. [Crossref]
510. Haichao Fan, Edwin L.-C. Lai, Yao Amber Li. 2015. Credit constraints, quality, and export prices:
Theory and evidence from China. Journal of Comparative Economics 43:2, 390-416. [Crossref]
511. Chadwick C. Curtis, Steven Lugauer, Nelson C. Mark. 2015. Demographic Patterns and Household
Saving in China. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7:2, 58-94. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
512. Zheng Song, Kjetil Storesletten, Yikai Wang, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2015. Sharing High Growth
across Generations: Pensions and Demographic Transition in China. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 7:2, 1-39. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
513. Almukhtar Al-Abri, Hamid Baghestani. 2015. Foreign investment and real exchange rate volatility in
emerging Asian countries. Journal of Asian Economics 37, 34-47. [Crossref]
514. Shen Guo, Lezheng Liu, Yan Zhao. 2015. The business cycle implications of land financing in China.
Economic Modelling 46, 225-237. [Crossref]
515. Leila Torki, Ahmad Ali Rezaei. Analyzing the impact of electronic business on investment in Iran
during the period from 1981 to 2012 1-6. [Crossref]
516. Yong Wang. 2015. A model of sequential reforms and economic convergence: The case of China.
China Economic Review 32, 1-26. [Crossref]
517. Garry D. Bruton, Mike W. Peng, David Ahlstrom, Ciprian Stan, Kehan Xu. 2015. State-owned
Enterprises Around the WORLD as Hybrid Organizations. Academy of Management Perspectives 29:1,
92-114. [Crossref]
518. Sara Eugeni. 2015. An OLG model of global imbalances. Journal of International Economics 95:1,
83-97. [Crossref]
519. Yuchao PENG, Lili Yan. 2015. Political Connections, Discriminatory Credit Constraint and Business
Cycle. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
520. Jian Wang, Xiao Wang. 2015. Benefits of Foreign Ownership: Evidence from Foreign Direct
Investment in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
521. Hao Wang, Honglin Wang, Lisheng Wang, Hao Zhou. 2015. Shadow Banking: China's Dual-Track
Interest Rate Liberalization. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
522. Diego Restuccia, Raul Santaeulalia-Llopis. 2015. Land Misallocation and Productivity. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
523. Meng Miao. 2015. Using City Mayoral Replacements to Estimate the Effect of Property Rights
Protection on Investment. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
524. Meng Miao. 2015. The Cyclicality of Political Connections: An Investigation into Changes in Reserve
Requirements in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
525. Jaume Ventura, Hans-Joachim Voth. 2015. Debt into Growth: How Sovereign Debt Accelerated the
First Industrial Revolution. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
526. Chun Chang, Kaiji Chen, Daniel F. Waggoner, Tao Zha. 2015. Trends and Cycles in China's
Macroeconomy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
527. Damien Cubizol. 2015. Transition and Capital Misallocation: The Chinese Case. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
528. Lily H. Fang, Josh Lerner, Wu Chaopeng. 2015. Intellectual Property Rights Protection, Ownership,
and Innovation: Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
529. Marie Albert, Cristina Jude, Cyril Rebillard. 2015. The Long Landing Scenario: Rebalancing from
Overinvestment and Excessive Credit Growth. Implications for Potential Growth in China. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
530. Albert Park, Yao Amber Li, Chen Carol Zhao. 2015. Credit Distribution and Exports: Microeconomic
Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
531. Franklin Allen, Jun Qian, Lin Shen. 2015. Corruption and Competition. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
532. Hao Jin. 2015. Foreign Exchange Interventions, Capital Controls and Monetary Policy: The Case of
China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
533. Damien Cubizol. 2015. Unbalanced Privatization in Emerging Economies and Capital Flows. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
534. Felix Zhiyu Feng, Jianyu Lu, Jing Wang. 2015. Productivity and Liquidity Management. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
535. Qingyuang Du, Shang-Jin Wei. 2015. A Darwinian Perspective on 'Exchange Rate Undervaluation'.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
536. Diego Anzoategui, Mali Chivakul, Wojciech Maliszewski. 2015. Financial Distortions in China: A
General Equilibrium Approach. IMF Working Papers 15:274, 1. [Crossref]
537. Raphael Lam, Xiaoguang Liu, Alfred Schipke. 2015. China’s Labor Market in the “New Normal”.
IMF Working Papers 15:151, 1. [Crossref]
538. Hong Ru. 2015. Government Credit, a Double-Edged Sword: Evidence from the China Development
Bank. SSRN Electronic Journal 20. . [Crossref]
539. Jianguo Xu, Xun Zhang. 2014. China's sovereign debt: A balance-sheet perspective. China Economic
Review 31, 55-73. [Crossref]
540. David E. Bloom, Elizabeth T. Cafiero-Fonseca, Mark E. McGovern, Klaus Prettner, Anderson
Stanciole, Jonathan Weiss, Samuel Bakkila, Larry Rosenberg. 2014. The macroeconomic impact of
non-communicable diseases in China and India: Estimates, projections, and comparisons. The Journal
of the Economics of Ageing 4, 100-111. [Crossref]
541. Yin-Wong Cheung, Dagfinn Rime. 2014. The offshore renminbi exchange rate: Microstructure and
links to the onshore market. Journal of International Money and Finance 49, 170-189. [Crossref]
542. Weina Zhou. 2014. Brothers, household financial markets and savings rate in China. Journal of
Development Economics 111, 34-47. [Crossref]
543. Amanda Michaud, Jacek Rothert. 2014. Optimal borrowing constraints and growth in a small open
economy. Journal of International Economics 94:2, 326-340. [Crossref]
544. Laura Alfaro, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, Vadym Volosovych. 2014. SOVEREIGNS, UPSTREAM
CAPITAL FLOWS, AND GLOBAL IMBALANCES. Journal of the European Economic Association
12:5, 1240-1284. [Crossref]
545. Simon Sturn. 2014. From internal imbalances to global imbalances: a survey on the causes of China’s
export-led growth. China Economic Journal 7:3, 320-342. [Crossref]
546. Loren Brandt, Johannes Van Biesebroeck, Yifan Zhang. 2014. Challenges of working with the Chinese
NBS firm-level data. China Economic Review 30, 339-352. [Crossref]
547. Chong-En Bai, Jie Mao, Qiong Zhang. 2014. Measuring market concentration in China: the problem
with using censored data and its rectification. China Economic Review 30, 432-447. [Crossref]
548. Li Liao, Bibo Liu, Hao Wang. 2014. China#s secondary privatization: Perspectives from the Split-
Share Structure Reform. Journal of Financial Economics 113:3, 500-518. [Crossref]
549. Bin R. Chen, Mingqin Wu. 2014. INDUSTRIAL AGGLOMERATION AND EMPLOYER
COMPLIANCE WITH SOCIAL SECURITY CONTRIBUTION: EVIDENCE FROM CHINA.
Journal of Regional Science 54:4, 586-605. [Crossref]
550. Zheng Song, Kjetil Storesletten, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2014. Growing (with Capital Controls) like China.
IMF Economic Review 62:3, 327-370. [Crossref]
551. Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, M  Ayhan Kose. 2014. Asia: Challenges of Stability and Growth. IMF
Economic Review 62:3, 323-326. [Crossref]
552. Kjetil Storesletten, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2014. China’s Great Convergence and Beyond. Annual Review
of Economics 6:1, 333-362. [Crossref]
553. Damiano Sandri. 2014. Growth and Capital Flows with Risky Entrepreneurship. American Economic
Journal: Macroeconomics 6:3, 102-123. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
554. Shiyi Chen, Jane Golley. 2014. ‘Green’ productivity growth in China's industrial economy. Energy
Economics 44, 89-98. [Crossref]
555. Ciprian V. Stan, Mike W. Peng, Garry D. Bruton. 2014. Slack and the performance of state-owned
enterprises. Asia Pacific Journal of Management 31:2, 473-495. [Crossref]
556. Rudai Yang, Canfei He. 2014. The productivity puzzle of Chinese exporters: Perspectives of local
protection and spillover effects. Papers in Regional Science 93:2, 367-384. [Crossref]
557. Haitian Lu, Jiajia Fu. 2014. Structural Changes in the Chinese Stock Market: A Review of Empirical
Research. China Accounting and Finance Review 16:2. . [Crossref]
558. Pablo N. D#Erasmo, Hernan J. Moscoso Boedo, Aslı Şenkal. 2014. Misallocation, informality, and
human capital: Understanding the role of institutions. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 42,
122-142. [Crossref]
559. Darong Dai. 2014. A Golden Formula in Neoclassical-Growth Models with Brownian-Motion
Shocks. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 61:2, 211-228. [Crossref]
560. Xin Gu, Zhang-Yue Zhou, A.B.M. Rabiul Alam Beg. 2014. What determines China's trade balance
dynamics: a disaggregate analysis of panel data. Journal of the Asia Pacific Economy 19:2, 353-368.
[Crossref]
561. Philippe Bacchetta, Kenza Benhima, Yannick Kalantzis. 2014. Optimal Exchange Rate Policy in a
Growing Semi-Open Economy. IMF Economic Review 62:1, 48-76. [Crossref]
562. Suqin Ge, Dennis Tao Yang. 2014. CHANGES IN CHINA'S WAGE STRUCTURE. Journal of the
European Economic Association 12:2, 300-336. [Crossref]
563. Gianluca Benigno. 2014. The Never-Ending Debate on Capital Flows. International Finance 17:1,
121-134. [Crossref]
564. Virgiliu Midrigan, Daniel Yi Xu. 2014. Finance and Misallocation: Evidence from Plant-Level Data.
American Economic Review 104:2, 422-458. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
565. Jürgen von Hagen, Haiping Zhang. 2014. International Capital Flows in the Model with Limited
Commitment and Incomplete Markets. Open Economies Review 25:1, 195-224. [Crossref]
566. Kiminori Matsuyama. 2014. INSTITUTION-INDUCED PRODUCTIVITY DIFFERENCES
AND PATTERNS OF INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL FLOWS. Journal of the European Economic
Association 12:1, 1-24. [Crossref]
567. Jiaqian Chen, Patrick Imam. 2014. Consequences of asset shortages in emerging markets.
Macroeconomics and Finance in Emerging Market Economies 7:1, 4-35. [Crossref]
568. Nicholas Crafts, Kevin Hjortshøj O’Rourke. Twentieth Century Growth 263-346. [Crossref]
569. Yang Yao. The Chinese Growth Miracle 943-1031. [Crossref]
570. Jonathan Heathcote, Fabrizio Perri. Assessing International Efficiency 523-584. [Crossref]
571. Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas, Hélène Rey. External Adjustment, Global Imbalances, Valuation Effects
585-645. [Crossref]
572. Jürgen von Hagen, Haiping Zhang. 2014. Financial development, international capital flows, and
aggregate output. Journal of Development Economics 106, 66-77. [Crossref]
573. Finn E. Kydland. On Policy Consistency 77-95. [Crossref]
574. Paul Mizen, Serafeim Tsoukas. 2014. What promotes greater use of the corporate bond market? A
study of the issuance behaviour of firms in Asia. Oxford Economic Papers 66:1, 227-253. [Crossref]
575. Dong He, Honglin Wang, Xiangrong Yu. 2014. Interest Rate Determination in China: Past, Present,
and Future. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
576. Pablo D`Erasmo, Hernan J. Moscoso Boedo, Asli Senkal. 2014. Misallocation, Informality, and
Human Capital: Understanding the Role of Institutions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
577. Philippe Bacchetta, Kenza Benhima, Yannick Kalantzis. 2014. Optimal Exchange Rate Policy in a
Growing Semi-Open Economy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
578. Masaya Sakuragawa, Kaoru Hosono. 2014. Regulatory Arbitrage and Bad Loans. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
579. Axel F. A. Adam-Muller, Renn Andres, Jorn H. Block, Christian Fisch. 2014. Socialist Heritage and
Image of Entrepreneurs in Europe: Micro-Level Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
580. Yin-Wong Cheung, Dagfinn Rime. 2014. The Offshore Renminbi Exchange Rate: Microstructure
and Links to the Onshore Market. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
581. Samuel Cudrr. 2014. Capital's Long March West: Saving and Investment Frictions in Chinese Regions.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
582. Samuel Cudrr, Mathias Hoffmann. 2014. A Provincial View of Global Imbalances: Regional Capital
Flows in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
583. Lucas Bretschger, Lin Zhang. 2014. Carbon Policy in a High-Growth Economy: The Case of China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
584. Guo Li, Jie Hu. 2014. Regional Financial Development and Financing Constraints in R&D
Investments: A Panel Study of Chinese High-Tech Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
585. Zhangkai Huang, Lixing Li, Guangrong Ma, Jun Qian. 2014. The Political Economy of Corporate
Finance: Evidence from Re-nationalizationn in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
586. Kaiji Chen, Yi Wen. 2014. The Great Housing Boom of China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
587. Tri Vi Danag, Honglin Wang, Aidan Yao. 2014. Chinese Shadow Banking: Bank-Centric
Misperceptions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
588. Loren Brandt, Johannes Van Biesebroeck, Yifan Zhang. 2014. Challenges of Working with the
Chinese NBS Firm-Level Data. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
589. Raul Santaeulalia, Yu Zheng. 2014. Partial Insurance and Aggregate Welfare in China, 1989-2009.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
590. Meng Miao. 2014. Property Rights Protection and Investment: A Natural Experiment from China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
591. Winston W. Chang, Youhui Wu. 2014. Ownership and R&D Intensity in Foreign Affiliates Under
Incomplete Capital Market. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
592. Haichao Fan, Edwin L.-C. Lai, Yao Amber Li. 2014. Credit Constraints, Quality, and Export Prices:
Theory and Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
593. Collin Rabe. 2014. A Welfare Analysis of 'New Mercantilist' Foreign Reserve Accumulation. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
594. Xi Chen, Michael Funke. 2013. The dynamics of catch-up and skill and technology upgrading in
China. Journal of Macroeconomics 38, 465-480. [Crossref]
595. F. Kamal, M. E. Lovely. 2013. Labor Allocation in China: Implicit Taxation of the Heterogeneous
Non-State Sector. CESifo Economic Studies 59:4, 731-758. [Crossref]
596. Carlo Milana, Jinmin Wang. 2013. Fostering Entrepreneurship in China: A Survey of the Economic
Literature. Strategic Change 22:7-8, 387-415. [Crossref]
597. Dennis Reinhardt, Luca Antonio Ricci, Thierry Tressel. 2013. International capital flows and
development: Financial openness matters. Journal of International Economics 91:2, 235-251. [Crossref]
598. Qingyuan Du, Shang-Jin Wei. 2013. A theory of the competitive saving motive. Journal of
International Economics 91:2, 275-289. [Crossref]
599. Jess Benhabib, Pengfei Wang. 2013. Financial constraints, endogenous markups, and self-fulfilling
equilibria. Journal of Monetary Economics 60:7, 789-805. [Crossref]
600. P.-O. Gourinchas, O. Jeanne. 2013. Capital Flows to Developing Countries: The Allocation Puzzle.
The Review of Economic Studies 80:4, 1484-1515. [Crossref]
601. Jongchul Lee. 2013. A provincial perspective on income inequality in urban China and the role of
property and business income. China Economic Review 26, 140-150. [Crossref]
602. Chaochao Lei, Rengui Zhang, Baocheng Wu. 2013. Labor reallocation in China: 1978–2011.
Economic Modelling 35, 668-673. [Crossref]
603. Gabriel Zucman. 2013. The Missing Wealth of Nations: Are Europe and the U.S. net Debtors or net
Creditors?*. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 128:3, 1321-1364. [Crossref]
604. Henrique Schneider. 2013. An Austrian view on the middle income trap. Journal of Chinese Economic
and Business Studies 11:3, 169-178. [Crossref]
605. Philippe Bacchetta,, Kenza Benhima,, Yannick Kalantzis. 2013. Capital Controls with International
Reserve Accumulation: Can this Be Optimal?. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5:3,
229-262. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
606. Han Li, Zhigang Li. 2013. Road investments and inventory reduction: Firm level evidence from China.
Journal of Urban Economics 76, 43-52. [Crossref]
607. Luigi Bonatti, Andrea Fracasso. 2013. Regime switches in the Sino-American co-dependency: Growth
and structural change in China. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 25, 1-32. [Crossref]
608. Wolfgang Keller, Ben Li, Carol H Shiue. 2013. Shanghai's Trade, China's Growth: Continuity,
Recovery, and Change since the Opium Wars. IMF Economic Review 61:2, 336-378. [Crossref]
609. Benjamin C. Powell, Joan M. Donohue, Xiaoya Liang, Jeremy B. Fox. 2013. Sales growth of Chinese
private owned enterprises (POEs): an exploratory analysis. Journal of Chinese Entrepreneurship 5:2,
104-121. [Crossref]
610. Sai Ding, Alessandra Guariglia, John Knight. 2013. Investment and financing constraints in China:
Does working capital management make a difference?. Journal of Banking & Finance 37:5, 1490-1507.
[Crossref]
611. Dawei Che, Ling Shen. 2013. The co-development of economies and institutions. Economics of
Transition 21:2, 241-268. [Crossref]
612. Donghua Chen, Saqib Khan, Xin Yu, Zhou Zhang. 2013. Government Intervention and Investment
Comovement: Chinese Evidence. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 40:3-4, 564-587. [Crossref]
613. Zhichao Zhang, Frankie Chau, Li Xie. 2013. Accumulation of large foreign reserves in China: a
behavioural perspective. Economic Change and Restructuring 46:1, 85-108. [Crossref]
614. Soohyung Lee, Benjamin A. Malin. 2013. Education's role in China's structural transformation.
Journal of Development Economics 101, 148-166. [Crossref]
615. Chiara Franco, Riccardo Leoncini. 2013. Measuring China's innovative capacity: a stochastic frontier
exercise. Economics of Innovation and New Technology 22:2, 199-217. [Crossref]
616. Linxiu Zhang, Eli Pollak, Ross Darwin, Matthew Boswell, Scott Rozelle. 2013. Are elite university
graduates aiding China’s transition to an innovation-based economy? Results from a career choices
survey among would-be innovators in China and the USA. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting &
Economics 20:1, 58-69. [Crossref]
617. Yi Che, Danny T. Wang. 2013. Multinationals, Institutions and Economic Growth in China. Asian
Economic Journal 27:1, 1-16. [Crossref]
618. Olivier Jeanne. 2013. Capital Account Policies and the Real Exchange Rate. NBER International
Seminar on Macroeconomics 9:1, 7-42. [Crossref]
619. Kenza Benhima. 2013. Financial integration, capital misallocation and global imbalances. Journal of
International Money and Finance 32, 324-340. [Crossref]
620. Luigi Bonatti, Andrea Fracasso. 2013. Hoarding of international reserves in China: Mercantilism,
domestic consumption and US monetary policy. Journal of International Money and Finance 32,
1044-1078. [Crossref]
621. Nicolas L. Ziebarth. 2013. Are China and India backward? Evidence from the 19th century U.S.
Census of Manufactures. Review of Economic Dynamics 16:1, 86-99. [Crossref]
622. Loren Brandt, Trevor Tombe, Xiaodong Zhu. 2013. Factor market distortions across time, space and
sectors in China. Review of Economic Dynamics 16:1, 39-58. [Crossref]
623. Simon Sturn, Till van Treeck. The Role of Income Inequality as a Cause of the Great Recession and
Global Imbalances 125-152. [Crossref]
624. John Whalley, Hejing Chen. 2013. Are Offshore RMB Arrangements the Basis for a Long-term
Exchange Rate System without Convertibility?. China & World Economy 21:1, 26-46. [Crossref]
625. Sewon Hur, Illenin Kondo. 2013. A Theory of Rollover Risk, Sudden Stops, and Foreign Reserves.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
626. Byoung Hoon Seok. 2013. Growth and Global Imbalances: The Role of Learning-by-Exporting.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
627. Suparna Chakraborty, Keisuke Otsu. 2013. Business Cycle Accounting of the Bric Economies. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
628. Masaya Sakuragawa. 2013. Bubble Cycle. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
629. Daisuke Ikeda, Toan Phan. 2013. Toxic Asset Bubble and Global Imbalances. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
630. Dong He, Paul Luk. 2013. A Model of Chinese Capital Account Liberalisation. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
631. Gong Cheng. 2013. A Growth Perspective on Foreign Reserve Accumulation. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
632. Jiandong Ju, Kang Shi, Shang-Jin Wei. 2013. Trade Reforms and Current Account Imbalances. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
633. Philippe Bacchetta, Kenza Benhima, Yannick Kalantzis. 2013. Optimal Exchange Rate Policy in a
Growing Semi-Open Economy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
634. Mina Kim, Deokwoo Nam, Jian Wang, Jason Wu. 2013. International Trade Price Stickiness and
Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Micro Data: A Case Study on US-China Trade. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
635. Zhangkai Huang, Lixing Li, Guangrong Ma, Jun Qian. 2013. The Political Economy of Corporate
Finance: Evidence from Re-Nationalizationn in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
636. Lance Kent. 2013. Rare Institutional Disruptions and Uphill Capital Flows. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
637. Qingyuan Du, Shang-Jin Wei. 2013. A Theory of the Competitive Saving Motive. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
638. Zhigang Li. 2013. Road Investments and Inventory Reduction: Firm Level Evidence from China.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
639. Malhar Nabar, Papa M'B. P. N'Diaye. 2013. Enhancing China’s Medium-Term Growth Prospects:
The Path to a High-Income Economy. IMF Working Papers 13:204, 1. [Crossref]
640. Felix Zhiyu Feng. 2013. Savings Gluts and Asset Price Booms: The Impact of Domestic Imperfect
Enforcement and Global Financial Integration. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
641. Chong-En Bai, Hong Ma, Wenqing Pan. 2012. Spatial spillover and regional economic growth in
China. China Economic Review 23:4, 982-990. [Crossref]
642. Olivier Jeanne. 2012. The dollar and its discontents. Journal of International Money and Finance 31:8,
1976-1989. [Crossref]
643. Dennis Tao Yang. 2012. Aggregate Savings and External Imbalances in China. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 26:4, 125-146. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
644. Keyu Jin. 2012. Industrial Structure and Capital Flows. American Economic Review 102:5, 2111-2146.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
645. Xianguo Yao, Minghai Zhou. China's Economic and Trade Development: Imbalance to Equilibrium
19-34. [Crossref]
646. Gordon H. Hanson. 2012. The Rise of Middle Kingdoms: Emerging Economies in Global Trade.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 26:2, 41-64. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
647. Carlo Milana, Harry X. Wu. 2012. Growth, institutions, and entrepreneurial finance in China: a
survey. Strategic Change 21:3-4, 83-106. [Crossref]
648. Jun Li, Xin Wang. 2012. Energy and climate policy in China's twelfth five-year plan: A paradigm
shift. Energy Policy 41, 519-528. [Crossref]
649. Hans Degryse, Liping Lu, Steven R. G. Ongena. 2012. Informal or Formal Financing? Or Both?
First Evidence on the Co-Funding of Chinese Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
650. Jingwen Yu. 2012. Financial Constraint and Corporate Payout Policies: Evidence from a Natural
Experiment in China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
651. Xi Li, Xuewen Liu, Yong Wang. 2012. A Model of China's State Capitalism. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
652. Olivier Jeanne. 2012. The Dollar and Its Discontents. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
653. Haitian Lu, Hongbo Pan, Chenying Zhang. 2012. Property Rights Protection Through Litigations:
Ownership Bias and the Role of Political Connections. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
654. Yi Wen, Pengfei Wang, Zhiwei Xu. 2012. Two-Way Capital Flows and Global Imbalances: A
Neoclassical Approach. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
655. Robert Zymek. 2012. Factor Proportions and the Growth of World Trade. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
656. Haichao Fan, Edwin L.C. Lai, Yao Amber Li. 2012. Credit Constraints, Quality, and Export Prices:
Theory and Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
657. Olivier Jeanne. 2012. Capital Account Policies and the Real Exchange Rate. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
658. Daron Acemoglu, Gino A. Gancia, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2012. Offshoring and Directed Technical
Change. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
659. Philippe Bacchetta, Kenza Benhima, Yannick Kalantzis. 2012. Capital Controls with International
Reserve Accumulation: Can This Be Optimal?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
660. Gong Cheng. 2012. A Growth Perspective of Foreign Reserve Accumulation. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
661. Zheng Michael Song, Kjetil Storesletten, Yikai Wang, Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2012. Sharing High Growth
across Generations: Pensions and Demographic Transition in China. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
662. Patrick A. Imam, Jiaqian Chen. 2012. Consequences of Asset Shortages in Emerging Markets. IMF
Working Papers 12:102, 1. [Crossref]
663. Xianguo Yao, Minghai Zhou. 2011. China’s Economic and Trade Development: Imbalance to
Equilibrium. The World Economy 34:12, 2081-2096. [Crossref]
664. Tang Li, Zuwei Yu. Adoption barrier, financial imperfection and technology diffusion 4337-4341.
[Crossref]
665. Tang Li, Zuwei Yu. Notice of Retraction Appropriate technology, credit constraint and economic
transition 4342-4346. [Crossref]
666. Zuwei Yu, Tang Li. Notice of Retraction Investment protection, financial imperfection and
endogenous technological change 4347-4350. [Crossref]
667. Cheryl Long, Xiaobo Zhang. 2011. Cluster-based industrialization in China: Financing and
performance. Journal of International Economics 84:1, 112-123. [Crossref]
668. Olivier Jeanne, Pierre-Olivier Gourinchas. 2011. Capital Flows to Developing Countries: The
Allocation Puzzle. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
669. Yi Wen. 2011. Making Sense of China’s Excessive Foreign Reserves. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
670. Chiara Franco, Riccardo Leoncini. 2011. Measuring China’s Innovative Capacity: A Stochastic Frontier
Exercise. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
671. Sai Ding, Alessandra Guariglia, John B. Knight. 2011. Investment and Financing Constraints in
China: Does Working Capital Management Make a Difference?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
672. Luigi Bonatti, Andrea Fracasso. 2011. Hoarding of International Reserves in China: Mercantilism,
Domestic Consumption and US Monetary Policy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
673. Yi Wen. 2011. Explaining China's Trade Imbalance Puzzle. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
674. Laura Alfaro, Sebnem Kalemli-Ozcan, Vadym Volosovych. 2011. Sovereigns, Upstream Capital Flows
and Global Imbalances. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
675. Mathias Hoffmann. 2010. What Drives China's Current Account?. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]

You might also like