Doganova - Muniesa - 2015 - Capitalization Devices
Doganova - Muniesa - 2015 - Capitalization Devices
Doganova - Muniesa - 2015 - Capitalization Devices
Capitalization Devices
Business Models and the Renewal of Markets
Introduction
109
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
stake here, another form of valuation going on. To grasp it, we need to move
beyond the entrepreneurs’ viewpoint and look at the investors whom they
are trying to convince.
Bernard is a venture capitalist. Meeting entrepreneurs like Robert and their
technologies with numerous and certainly valuable applications is his daily
routine. But applications are not what he is looking for. He recalls the case
of one of his most successful investments. The start-up’s founders contacted
him, praising the merits of the software they had developed—a technology
that large organizations, ranging from banks through insurance companies
to hospitals, could use in order to search within their voluminous dispersed
databases. At first, the venture capitalists said no ‘because selling software
tools to people is both difficult and of little ambition’, adding with a bit of
dismay that ‘there are tons of people who invent software tools every morn-
ing’ and that ‘it does not mean that you can make a firm with that’. Their
argument was also about the figures: ‘We may be able to sell it a first time for
100,000 euros, a second time for 50,000, a third time for 10,000, and then we
will have a firm that will make a turnover of one million over twenty years’.
The advice Bernard gave to this start-up was to go for a ‘new business
model’: use their technology to make a search engine that would allow inter-
net users to find the best price for a product and hence allow online merchants
to attract these willing-to-buy customers in exchange for a small contribution
paid to the search engine for each relevant click. The start-up followed the
advice, and Bernard’s venture capital firm made the investment. A few years
later, the search engine proudly showed millions of clicking and buying users
and was sold to an internet giant for no less than 475 million euros.
What we are interested in here is not a Google-like fabulous success story,
but the kind of problem that the new business model allowed to solve. That
problem, we argue, lies in transforming a technology into an asset that has
the power to generate a steady stream of future cash flows, that is, into capital.
What is at stake here is a peculiar way of making things valuable. The chapter
discusses how the business model instruments such a mode of valuation,
which we call capitalization. In order to do so, we characterize the particular
kind of encounter that this mode of valuation requires between someone like
Robert and someone like Bernard, that is, an entrepreneur and an investor.
The chapter proceeds as follows. We start by documenting the rise of busi-
ness models, emphasizing their focus on the notion of value and the contro-
versies that they have triggered among management scholars. The chapter
then introduces recent approaches to business models, which shed light on
the performative role that they can play, and explains the approach adopted
here, which examines business models as valuation devices (Doganova
2011) and, more narrowly, as capitalization devices. An empirical section
follows which investigates how business models work by focusing on two
110
Capitalization Devices
111
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
The quote from Porter captures quite well the main lines of criticism addressed
to the business model in the management literature. They can be summed up
into three key problems: the problem of definition, the problem of reference,
and the problem of (in/dis)utility. First, scholars have pointed out, the busi-
ness model is untruthful to itself, because it does not have a stable definition.
It remains, as Porter puts it, ‘murky at best’, in spite of academics’ and practi-
tioners’ continuous attempts to find the essence of the business model and fix
it in a correct and clear definition. Second, the business model is untruthful to
its external reference, that is, the enterprise that it is supposed to describe. It is
no more than a ‘loose conception of how a company does business’. It fails to
fulfil its predictions—some have even denounced it as serving the purposive
concealment of charlatan-entrepreneurs’ real intentions. Third, the business
model is not useful. Modelling, several studies have shown, does not help
entrepreneurs in their planning endeavours, does not improve the perfor-
mance of new ventures, and even harms it, by inducing managers into what
Porter describes as ‘faulty thinking and self-delusion’.
The harsh criticism that business models have received in the academic
literature stands in sharp contrast to their widespread use by practitioners.
Recent studies have suggested that this discrepancy may be due to the fail-
ure of prevalent theoretical approaches to account for what business models
are and what they do (Doganova and Eyquem-Renault 2009; Baden-Fuller
and Morgan 2010; Perkmann and Spicer 2010), a failure due to the essen-
tialist or functionalist perspectives that these approaches tend to adopt. An
essentialist perspective searches for the essence of the business model, try-
ing to provide a clear, precise, unambiguous definition of an object that
seems to inevitably escape such attempts. A functionalist perspective assigns
a presupposed function to the business model and tries to assess its effi-
ciency accordingly. In so doing, prevalent theoretical approaches make two
strong assumptions. The first is that the lack of a stable definition impedes
the working of business models. The second is that the function of busi-
ness models, known a priori, is to describe, faithfully represent, or accu-
rately predict the characteristics of the external entity—a present or future
enterprise—to which it refers.
However, as demonstrated elsewhere (Doganova and Eyquem-Renault
2009; Eyquem-Renault 2011), it is precisely the plasticity of the business
112
Capitalization Devices
113
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
A business model is actually a single slide. That’s all it is. It’s a single slide, a dia-
gram, that shows all of the flows between your company and your customers.
It’s a single PowerPoint slide that you could put up and say: ‘Here’s our busi-
ness model’. And in that one slide you have your material costs, you have your
distribution channel, you have your customer acquisition cost. You have eve-
rything: your revenue, your expenses. And someone looking at that goes: ‘I get
it. I disagree with this line and with this line and with this line, but I get it.’
(Transcribed from video footage of Cleantech Open 2009)3
Business models have the capacity to travel—not only within the entre-
preneurial collective that emerges as a new venture is built, but also in the
broader time and space of industries and management science. Baden-Fuller
and Morgan (2010) analyse business models as ‘role models’, maintained by
management scholars’ labelling and classifying activities, and as ‘recipes’,
114
Capitalization Devices
lying between general principles and exact templates. As such, business mod-
els lend themselves to replication, and this is where a third dimension of their
performativity is to be found. Business models that have proved to ‘work’ in
the past are reproduced in press articles, textbooks, and the practitioners’
and academic literature. They are working examples that entrepreneurs can
copy and that investors can use as benchmarks to assess the propositions
submitted to them. By associating themselves with a particular type and plac-
ing themselves in a particular category, firms gain legitimacy (Perkmann and
Spicer 2010). They also spare modelling efforts.
Business models are thus performative in (at least) three ways: as perfor-
mances, when the model is exhibited and put on stage; as scale models,
which draw and build relationships, and hence help bring into existence that
which they purport to describe; as role models, that are followed and imitated
by new ventures. One question remains though: if business models are per-
formative, what do they perform? That is, what worlds do they carry? And
what do the new ventures that are built with them look like? We would like to
address these questions by taking on board the observation of Ghaziani and
Ventresca (2005) and Zott et al. (2011) that business models are intimately
associated with the notion of value, and terms such as ‘value creation’ and
‘value capture’. The very notion of ‘value creation’ (i.e. the generation of
revenue) appears indeed as a crucial marker of the investment imagination
(Ortiz 2013, 2014) of the business model. So what kind of value is this valua-
tion device meant to prompt, and what difference does this make?
115
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
model for its search engine. The invention of this business model—known as
AdWords at Google, ‘pay per click’, or ‘sponsored search’—was no less impor-
tant for the development of the company than the PageRank algorithm.
The business model that made Google’s success was invented in 1998
by a start-up called GoTo.com (later renamed Overture). At that time, the
predominant business model in the industry followed classic advertising
methods. Internet start-ups provided their users with free services and made
money (if they did) by displaying ads on their websites—ads that visitors
were faced with and on which they were likely to click if interested. The
key metric here was that of traffic: the more traffic a website (e.g. Yahoo’s
portal) had, the higher price it could require from advertisers willing to
display themselves on the website in the hope to redirect some of the traf-
fic that it drew onto their own websites. The intuition of GoTo.com was
the following: it was not only traffic—the numbers of visitors coming to a
website—that had value, but the ways in which these visitors were behav-
ing, and more precisely the words that they were typing. These words
had potentially commercial value, for they expressed the—potentially
buying—intentions of the visitor. To put it in marketing terms, visitors with
a ‘purchase intention’ had much greater value for the online merchants to
which they could be matched, and a lower ‘cost of acquisition’ than that
incurred by placing an ad in front of numerous but undifferentiated inter-
net users who were most likely uninterested, and sometime even irritated,
by the ads that they were forced to see.
How can value be put on the words typed by a visitor in a search engine?
GoTo.com’s idea was to sell these words to online merchants. How can a price
be put on them? GoTo.com made online merchants bid for the keywords
they wanted to be associated with, and was paid for every click that led a
visitor from its search engine to a merchant’s website—hence the name ‘pay
per click’ for this business model. The idea was controversial: instead of rank-
ing webpages according to their content, as search engines did at that time,
or according to the links that pointed at them, as Google did, GoTo.com
was ranking webpages according to the price that those who produced them
were willing to pay. The most ‘relevant’ results were neither the most similar
in terms of content, nor the most popular on the web, but the ones that led
to the highest bidder. And yet, it worked: by 1999, GoTo.com had attracted
thousands of merchants and millions of searches. Two years later, Google
introduced AdWords, and started displaying the results of ‘sponsored’ search
(i.e. results displayed because merchants had paid to be associated with a
given keyword) next to those brought about by the ‘natural’ search instru-
mented by the PageRank algorithm. AdWords sold keywords through a com-
bination of bidding and pay per click—an imitation for which it was sued by
GoTo.com—while adding its own flavour in the ranking of results by taking
116
Capitalization Devices
into account the popularity of commercial links (i.e. the numbers of times
they had been clicked on) when ordering them.
In his reflections on the performativity of networks, Healy (2011) analyses
Google’s PageRank algorithm as perfomative, insofar as it was built upon a
network-based theory of relevance where citations indicate the relative impor-
tance of an object (be it an academic article or a webpage); assumed a certain
network structure where some nodes are more important than others for they
are more central, and at the same time helped reproduce this structure by rein-
forcing the centrality of the webpages that it ranked highest; was adopted by
many internet users in their practice and understanding of what web search
is; and was manipulated by some internet websites that played on the algo-
rithm’s assumptions to improve their ranking (giving rise to a new industry
called ‘search engine optimization’). This line of analysis may be extended to
the other major invention of Google. AdWords, and the sponsored search/
pay per click business model that it copied and popularized, helped establish
an internet market whose survival was still highly uncertain in the late 1990s
and seriously threatened by the 2000 crash. It served as a ‘role model’ for new
start-ups entering the market, and for the investors who funded them, both
copying a template that had proved its economic viability. By allowing to
target potential customers and hence to decrease their ‘cost of acquisition’, it
also unleashed markets for many small online shops which could not afford to
buy advertising space on central internet locations such as the Yahoo portal.
If the PageRank algorithm embeds citation-based definitions of relevance
and network imageries, the AdWords business model carries a peculiar the-
ory of valuation. Instead of lying in present size (e.g. the overall number of
visitors that an online portal reports, as indicated by ‘traffic’ or ‘audience’
metrics), here value is derived from the future flow of singular transactions,
each of which consists in a click that a particular user, driven by a ‘purchase
intention’, makes to reach a certain product and, thereby, the merchant who
happens to offer that product and rank well. In such a model, valuation both
occurs in ‘real time’—the time of users clicking on links and merchants bid-
ding for keywords—and deploys in the future, as the search engine gets a
grasp on the transactions to come and ‘monetizes’ them. The model thus ena-
bles both the creation of economic value, by turning the words that someone
types in a search engine into a commodity that can be sold and bid for, and
the capture of the value thus created, by means of a complex technology of
tracing clicks and visualizing transactions.
Genentech
In his study of the ‘science business’ of biotech, Pisano (2006b) identifies the
birth of the biotechnology industry with the founding of Genentech, the first
117
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
118
Capitalization Devices
The invention of this business model was critical for the emergence of
the biotechnology market—a market in which promises of future drugs are
being bought and sold. It enabled the transformation of scientific or techno-
logical entities—such as recombinant DNA in the case of Genentech, a new
molecule, or knowledge about a biological mechanism of action—into eco-
nomically valuable assets that have the capacity to generate streams of future
cash flows. The profile of this stream is quite different from the one that we
examined above: instead of the series of almost continuous but very small
amounts of money generated by the pay per click model, only a few inflows,
but of a high magnitude, occur here. Typically, a start-up would raise several
rounds of venture capital investment; then, when establishing a partnership
with a pharmaceutical company, receive research funding and milestone pay-
ments on different stages of drug development, as well as royalties if a drug
reaches the market; finally, sell itself to the capital markets or to a larger com-
pany, with the money going back to the start-up’s founders and investors.
For example, Genentech was sold to Roche in 2009 for 43 billion dollars.
This, of course, is quite an exceptional case in the history of the biotechnol-
ogy market. Still, the amounts of money that flow between start-ups, inves-
tors, and pharmaceutical companies are often counted in millions of dollars.
A significant portion of these flows end up sinking, as the probabilities that a
development succeeds and a new drug reaches the market are very small, and
the chances that a start-up continues attracting the funding it needs until it
finds a buyer for its products or for itself are not high.
While Genentech’s business model was copied by many start-ups enter-
ing the biotechnology market that emerged from it, the development of the
industry gave rise to new business models (Mangematin et al. 2003 ; DiVito
2012). Nevertheless, this model left an enduring imprint, serving not only as
a template, but also as a foundational myth for the biotechnology commu-
nity whose members still regularly evoke that 1976 meeting between a Nobel
prize-winning scientist and a visionary venture capitalist (Pina Stranger
2011). It epitomizes the surprising capacity of business models to orchestrate
encounters and, in so doing, to transform a priori non-economic entities
(such as a genetic engineering technology) into assets that generate streams
of future revenues, that is, into capital.
119
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
120
Capitalization Devices
Conclusion
121
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
(Thompson and MacMillan 2010; Yunus et al. 2010). Envisaging the business
model as a device for capitalization—whose valuation principle consists in
transforming things into future flows of revenue, by detaching value from
present objects and attaching it to future relationships—helps us understand
why it developed first within the contexts of the biotech and internet busi-
ness ‘revolutions’, and how it managed to move beyond these particular set-
tings to incorporate other valuation themes, such as social entrepreneurship.
This capacity of business models to colonize not only the future, but also
spheres of activity which had hitherto remained out of the scope of capi-
talization reveals them as a particularly efficient instrument within the trend
of what Leyshon and Thrift (2007) have called the ‘capitalization of almost
everything’. Financial capitalism, they argue, ‘is dependent on the constant
searching out, or construction of, new asset streams’ (Leyshon and Thrift
2007, 98). Such kinds of analyses usually concentrate on the financial arena
proper, i.e. on processes of securitization, speculation, and financialization.
But, as instances of the wider problem of the logic of the investor, they meet
our observations on business models as performative instruments for the pro-
duction of ‘asset streams’. The realities explored here thus fall within the
scope of what Horacio Ortiz has aptly called ‘the limits of financial imagina-
tion’ (Ortiz 2011, 2014).
Should this be a source of concern? The performative capacities of business
models, and the key role they play in the financing of innovation, can of
course be praised for their contribution to the augmentation and improve-
ment of economic reality (and of society at large)—although one can rightly
ask whether this means the obliteration or not of other ways in which col-
lective decisions about the improvement of economic reality could or should
be taken (Ortiz 2014, 46). We do not explore this question further here. This
chapter is, first and foremost, an attempt at signalling the remarkable fea-
tures of the business model considered as an instrument for ‘making things
valuable’.
An instrument for ‘making things valuable’, the business model is also an
instrument for ‘making things’. Recall Bernard’s story evoked in the introduc-
tion of this chapter: the venture capitalist shaped the business model of the
start-up turning it from a software provider into a web search engine. The
enrolment of investors, conditioned upon the application of business models
that have the capacity to generate steady streams of future revenues, thus
has consequences for the characteristics of the products and services that
populate markets. Entrepreneurs profile their technologies for capitalization,
in anticipation, or as a consequence, of the investor’s gaze. Venture capital-
ists, faced with a range of investment proposals from which they need to pick
one or two, select the technologies that they will help move to the market.
This is both complicated and consequential. It is complicated, but it becomes
122
Capitalization Devices
simpler when technologies become comparable once they have been pushed
through the mechanism of the business model and transformed into streams
of cash flows which can then be capitalized and summed up to a unique
number: e.g. the investment’s net present value or its rate of return. This (and
here comes the consequentiality) inevitably gives priority to projects that
score highest. As capitalization devices, thus, business models certainly pro-
pel innovation—although they do not do it in a very innovative way.
Notes
1. The work on which this chapter is based was partly supported by the European
Research Council (ERC Starting Grant 263529). We thank Horacio Ortiz, Alvaro
Pina-Stranger, Martin Kornberger, Lise Justesen, Anders Koed-Madsen, and Jan
Mouritsen for comments and suggestions on an earlier draft. We also thank par-
ticipants in the workshop ‘Unpacking performativity processes in organizations’
in May 2014 at MINES ParisTech and in the symposium ‘Theories of performativ-
ity and the performativity of theories’ at the Academy of Management Meeting in
Philadelphia, where this chapter was presented.
2. The illustrations in the introduction are taken from Doganova (2012). The quotes
are excerpts from the author’s interviews with Robert and Bernard (for confidential-
ity reasons, these are fictitious names).
3. Steve Blank’s presentation at the 2009 edition of the Cleantech Open (an impor-
tant business fair) is available online from YouTube: <http://www.youtube.com/
watch?v=CSDXxkSLBzw>, accessed 20 June 2014.
4. An iconic reportage is available from the website of the Life Science Foundation:
<http://www.lifesciencesfoundation.org/events-Genentech_Inc.html>, accessed 20
June 2014.
References
123
Liliana Doganova and Fabian Muniesa
124
Capitalization Devices
Pisano, G. 2006a. ‘Can Science be a Business? Lessons from Biotech’. Harvard Business
Review 84(10): 114–25.
Pisano, G. 2006b. Science Business: The Promise, the Reality, and the Future of Biotech.
Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Porter, M. E. 2001. ‘Strategy and the Internet’. Harvard Business Review 79(3): 62–78.
Rosental, C. 2007. Les capitalistes de la science. Enquête sur les démonstrateurs de la Silicon
Valley et de la NASA. Paris: CNRS Editions.
Sosna, M., R. N. Trevinyo-Rodríguez, and S. R. Velamuri. 2010. ‘Business Model
Innovation through Trial-and-Error Learning: The Naturhouse Case’. Long Range
Planning 43(2–3): 383–407.
Star, S. L. and J. R. Griesemer. 1989. ‘Institutional Ecology, “Translations” and Boundary
Objects: Amateurs and Professionals in Berkeley’s Museum of Vertebrate Zoology,
1907–39’. Social Studies of Science 19(3): 387–420.
Stark, D. 2009. The Sense of Dissonance: Accounts of Worth in Economic Life.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Stark, D. and V. Paravel. 2008. ‘PowerPoint in Public: Digital Technologies and the New
Morphology of Demonstration’. Theory, Culture & Society 25(5): 30–55.
Thompson, J. D. and I. C. MacMillan. 2010. Business Models: Creating New Markets
and Societal Wealth’. Long Range Planning 43(2–3): 291–307.
Wheelwright, S. and K. B. Clark. 1992. Revolutionizing Product Development: Quantum
Leaps in Speed, Efficiency, and Quality. New York: Free Press.
Yaneva, A. 2005. ‘Scaling Up and Down: Extraction Trials in Architectural Design’.
Social Studies of Science 35(6): 867–94.
Yunus, M., B. Moingeon, and L. Lehmann-Ortega. 2010. ‘Building Social Business
Models: Lessons from the Grameen Experience’. Long Range Planning 43(2–3): 308–25.
Zott, C., R. Amit, and L. Massa. 2011. ‘The Business Model: Recent Developments and
Future Research’. Journal of Management 37(4): 1019–42.
125