Regionalism, Development and The Post-Commodities Boom in South America
Regionalism, Development and The Post-Commodities Boom in South America
Regionalism, Development and The Post-Commodities Boom in South America
Regionalism, Development
and the Post-Commodities
Boom in South America
Series Editor
Timothy M. Shaw
Visiting Professor
University of Massachusetts Boston, USA
Emeritus Professor
University of London, UK
The global political economy is in flux as a series of cumulative crises
impacts its organization and governance. The IPE series has tracked its
development in both analysis and structure over the last three decades. It
has always had a concentration on the global South. Now the South
increasingly challenges the North as the centre of development, also
reflected in a growing number of submissions and publications on indebted
Eurozone economies in Southern Europe. An indispensable resource for
scholars and researchers, the series examines a variety of capitalisms and
connections by focusing on emerging economies, companies and sectors,
debates and policies. It informs diverse policy communities as the estab-
lished trans-Atlantic North declines and ‘the rest’, especially the BRICS,
rise.
Regionalism,
Development and the
Post-Commodities
Boom in South
America
Editor
Ernesto Vivares
International Studies and Communication
FLACSO Sede Ecuador
Quito, Ecuador
Few would deny that the world is in flux. Since the end of the Cold War
many observers have offered their views about world order transforma-
tion, as illustrated by arguments about the end of history, globalization,
clash of civilizations, chaos and disorder, a world of regions, and a world
dominated by new and emerging powers, to name only a few.
South America is arguably one of the most interesting regions of the
world, both because its future is so deeply intertwined with world order
transformation, but also because of its rich and varied intellectual com-
munity. Ernesto Vivares and his colleagues carry forward this proud intel-
lectual heritage as they provide us with a compelling account about South
America’s insertion into an unequal world. Apart from the many empirical
insights, the book offers at least three important theoretical and method-
ological contributions. The book’s approach is “critical”, “global”, and it
moves beyond the conventional “formal” IPE to include “informal”
dimensions and issues. Its novelty lies in the combination of these
contributions.
First, Vivares and colleagues argue in favor of critical, alternative and
interdisciplinary theoretical approaches that confront state-centric or
economistic views about how the world hangs together. A fundamental
distinction in this type of research is between “problem-solving” theory,
which takes the world as given, and, on the whole, as “good” and “criti-
cal” theory that is concerned with how the existing order came into being
and what the possibilities are for structural and social change. Critical IPE
theory challenges problem-solving features such as the separation of sub-
ject and object, fact and value, and rationalist epistemologies. Critical IPE
v
vi FOREWORD
This project was born during August, 2015, at the Third Latin American
and Caribbean Congress of Social Sciences, when nearly 200 regional
scholars met to present their latest research and hold discussions regarding
their increasing concern about the South American IPE, regionalism, and
global insertions after the end of the commodities boom and the changing
and unsettle global order. The discussion was friendly but intense, in par-
ticular about the lack of Southern voices in an international debate,
monopolized and understood by and from the North academy in terms of
neoclassical economics and political sciences, based on two major unques-
tioned assumptions. The first is the assumption that everything moves to
the achievement and wisdom of the industrialized north, and second, that
the fluctuations of South America are causal and directly related to the
oscillations of the commodity cycles, as the region never has managed to
rule capitalism. For the South American scholars and partners at the
Congress it was that the undeniable time after decades to endeavor open,
critical, and multidisciplinary academic studies and discussions upon the
IPEs of regional development and global insertion as a contribution from
the South. The result is this book composed of the efforts of a great deal
of colleagues, South Americans, and others from many parts of the world,
whose contributions in recent years have been vital for the return and
development of the IPE germinal epistemic community in the Southern
Cone. To all them, my thanks.
First, I am pleased to thank Professor Timothy Shaw, editor of this
International Political Economic Series, for friendship, loyal support, and
invaluable advice to the scholarship in the region, FLACSO, and to myself
ix
x ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
xi
xii Contents
15 Conclusions333
Ernesto Vivares
Index341
List of Contributors
xv
xvi List of Contributors
José Rosero is the Deputy Director of the Statistics Division of the Food and
Agriculture Organization of the UN (FAO). Previously he served as Executive
Director of the National Institute of Statistics and Censuses of Ecuador, as a Vice-
minister of Social Development and as Coordinator of the Integrated System of
Social Indicators (SIISE). He holds a PhD in economics from Amsterdam
University, Netherlands.
Raúl Salgado holds a PhD in Political Science and International Studies from the
University of Birmingham, United Kingdom. He is a professor in the Department
of International Studies, FLACSO Ecuador, where he teaches Political Thought,
Foreign Policy, and Research Methods. His research focuses upon foreign policy
and diplomacy of small South American countries in regional and global institu-
tions, as well as South American geopolitics in the changing world order.
Timothy M. Shaw is a research professor at the Department of Conflict Resolution,
Human Security, and Global Governance; McCormack Graduate School Graduate
Program Director, Global Governance and Human Security PhD Program. His
most recent coedited works include “Africa & IR in the 21st Century” (2015);
“Africa’s Challenge to International Relations Theory” (2013), “Comparative
Regionalism for Development in the 21st Century: Insights from the Global South” (2013).
Leonardo E. Stanley is Associate Researcher at the Center for the Study of State
and Society (CEDES). He has published in journals and written several book
chapters and is working on a book entitled Emerging Markets and Financial
Liberalization: Comparing the Experiences of Argentina, Brazil, China, India and
South Korea, to be published by Anthem Press.
Maria Cristina Vallejo is a research professor of Economics and Ecological
Economy of Development at the Department of Development, Environment, and
Territory, FLACSO, Ecuador. Professor Vallejo’s main research is on Regional
Ecological Economy and World Economy. She is author of “Biophysical structure
of the Ecuadorian economy, foreign trade and policy implications” (2010).
Ernesto Vivares is a research professor in International Political Economy,
Regionalism, and Methodology at the Department of International Studies and
Communication, FLACSO, Ecuador. His research focus is the Political Economy
of South American Regionalism, and Critical Theory of Regionalism and
Development. His latest publication is “Two regionalisms, two Latin Americas, or
beyond Latin America” (2015).
Rob Vos is Director of Agricultural Development Economics of the Food and
Agriculture Organization of the UN (FAO). Prior to joining FAO in 2013, he has
served as Director of Development Policy Analysis and chief economist of the UN
Secretariat in New York and, before that, as Vice-Rector and Professor of Finance
and Development at the International Institute of Social Studies of Erasmus
University.
List of Abbreviations
xix
xx LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS
Fig. 2.1 Estimates of the projected rise of the global middle class,
2015–203027
Fig. 2.2 Ecuador: Income inequality, 1990–2015. (Gini coefficient) 30
Fig. 2.3 Ecuador: Informal sector employment, 2007–2016
(Percentage of total employed labor force). Informal sector
employment defined here as workers of establishments
without tax registration (left axis), and workers without
access to (formal) social security (right axis))33
Fig. 2.4 Within-country income inequality by regions, 1988–2013
(Gini–weighted)34
Fig. 2.5 LA’s top, middle, and bottom of the income distribution,
around 2013 (income shares of bottom 40%, middle 40%
and top 20%; ranked by income share of middle class) 35
Fig. 2.6 Ecuador’s rising middle class, 1990–2016 (population
shares by income categories) 36
Fig. 2.7 Ecuador: Growth of real per capita household income by
deciles, 1991–2016 38
Fig. 3.1 Performance of total export and exports towards the region
of South America and the rest of the LAC. Left axis—millions
of US dollars; Right axis—percentage of total exports
Key: South America LAC/world (right axis), rest of LAC
LAC/world (right axis), exports from South America to the
world (left axis), exports from South America to LAC
(left axis), exports from the rest of LAC to the world
(left axis), exports from the rest of LAC to LAC (left axis) 57
xxv
xxvi List of Figures
xxix
xxx List of Tables
Ernesto Vivares
This book is about the IPE of the unequal and the unstable structures of
South American regional development and their uneven links with the
global order after the decline of the commodities boom. The book explores
the extent to which the South American development concerns are related
to the decline of commodities and/or the historical political structures of
unequal development and international insertion. The specific aim of this
collection is to open up regional research agenda through multidisci-
plinary and eclectic approaches to critical and empirical study of the
region, beyond the limitations of North American and European
approaches. As Söderbaum points out, “the problem is not … theory and
practice per se [of North American and European approaches] but … a
particular reading of [those] formal and state-centric models” (2000: 1).
The assumption here is that the regionalisms of the Global South, cannot
be studied and evaluated as variations of those models. Rather, South
American regionalism requires that that we pay attention to its specificities,
E. Vivares (*)
Department of International Studies, FLACSO Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
emerging markets and regions (Shaw, Chap. 14 in this book). The two
regions provide necessary comparative cases, showing similar flawed neo-
liberal narratives underscored by optimism of alternative development
paradigms, within a world order dominated by neoliberal economics,
institutionalized globalization, and liberal peace-war (ibid.). However,
the new global divide was marked by normative and progressive assump-
tions, sustaining imprecise categories, bearing different political and nor-
mative interpretations upon the future, despite their real achievements.
South America was at the forefront of experiments with alternatives to
neoliberalism; 56 million people came out of poverty, 20 million stepped
out of extreme poverty, and an historical reduction in income inequality
and democratic stability followed, where evident. However, with still
nearly half of the population at risk of falling into poverty (UNDP 2014;
Cord et al. 2014).
4 E. VIVARES
Even so, suddenly, several countries in the region have gone from very
positive circumstances to critically dire situations, with the decline and col-
lapse of progressive governments and what once were the stars of the
global heterodox progressive change. Beyond the widely recognized
changes, something had not changed as the historical structures of unequal
development were still there, bouncing and shifting back and forth,
between the realities of neoliberal and conservative orientations. Is the
South American regional shift back to conservatism and neoliberalism just
another chapter in the old tale of the chronic LA capitalism, driven by
populist governments unable to follow the universal economic wisdom of
the North? Are we seeing the impact of the End of the Commodities
Boom? Or is it an undeniable part of its global regional transformation
defined by a particular piece of the regional puzzle of development, unat-
tached under different orientations of development, but with the same
international insertions throughout history? To what extent are inequality
and uneven regional structures responsible for these issues? Finally, how
do we grasp these realities in the critical and eclectical IPEs of regions and
development? The research presented here is open to the task of challeng-
ing new and old regional scholars; this section aims only to set out ques-
tions and general methodological lines of reflection and concepts to
explore.
The beginning of the new century was full of regional development
narratives, filled with diagnoses about a historical countries´ growth and
convergence, all in favor of alternative policies, and claims that the South
would eventually decouple from the North and drive its own growth
(Nossel 2016). The rapid rise and new configuration of the Global South
were undoubtedly evident, but these did not provide an idyllic alternative
world, but one within all the contradictions of the historical framework of
neoliberal globalization and the Western peacekeeping of the last decades.
Market-led global economic stagnation, the Panama Papers, Britain’s exit
from the EU (in the form of Brexit), declining cities, refugees and mass
exodus, famine, media environment destruction, Middle-East globalized
national and religious wars, and the growth in global scale of organized
crime are just some of the parts of unforeseen neoliberal global develop-
ment. This historical global development is one in which we do not know
yet if it can be understood as the end of the post-1945 world order, or a
post-crisis and world disorder, triggered by the 2008 crisis (Kaletsky
2017). Evidently, countries that have somehow temporarily succeeded
using market signals, state intervention, and international competition to
THE IPE PUZZLE OF REGIONAL INEQUALITY, INSTABILITY... 5
the micro levels of analysis. For instance, the impact of a structure of trade
is not the same in the formal or informal sector of the economy, very much
less over primary, industrial sectors, or regional valued changes. The same
can be said about organized crime (e.g., see Moreira Lima, Chap. 8, and
that of Ponton and Guayasamin, Chap. 12 in this book). In this sense, the
concept of unequal structures of regional and national development is use-
ful but for the understanding of some aspects of the world, as these are
historical and contextual frameworks of action, they do not determine
actions but constitute the material ideational configurations where they
take place (Cox and Schechter 2002). On the one hand, they are, at a
micro level, a particular amalgam between material capabilities, institu-
tions, and ideas (e.g., migration, organized crime, knowledge, cities, etc.)
On the other hand, the entire set of these configurations interact multidi-
mensionally in three macro levels; social forces, forms of state-society
complex, and world orders (ibid.). Accordingly, any particular unequal or
asymmetric structures of development can be analytically approached from
a specific research focus, for instance, domestic or international, formal or
informal, ideational, institutional, or as a political economic process, and
grasped in its specificity.
Bibliography
Acharya, A. 2011. Dialogue and Discovery: In Search of International Relations
Theories Beyond the West. Millennium: Journal of International Studies
39 (3): 619–637.
———. 2014. Global International Relations (IR) and Regional Worlds. A New
Agenda for International Studies. International Studies Quarterly 58 (4):
647–659.
———. 2015. Regionalism Beyond EU-Centrism. In The Oxford Handbook of
Comparative Regionalism, ed. Tanja A. Borzel and T. Risse. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Astorga, P. 2015. Functional Inequality in Latin America: News from the Twentieth
Century. Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History, No 135.
Bertola, L., and J.A. Ocampo. 2012. El desarrollo económico de América Latina
desde la independencia. Oxford: Oxford University.
Bøås, M., and D. McNeill, eds. 2004. Global Institutions and Development:
Framing the World. New York: Routledge.
Bøås, M., M. Marchand, and T. Shaw, eds. 2005. The Political Economy of Regions
and Regionalism. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Bonilla, A., and G. Long. 2010. Un nuevo regionalismo sudamericano. Íconos:
revista de Ciencias Sociales 38: 23–28.
Braudel, F. 1979. Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Pres.
Briceño-Ruiz, J. 2007. La integración regional en América Latina y el Caribe.
Procesos históricos y realidades comparadas. Caracas: Centro Editorial Litorama.
———. 2014. Autonomía: genealogía y desarrollo de un concepto. Su relación
con el regionalismo en América Latina. Cuadernos Sobre Relaciones
Internacionales, Regionalismo Y Desarrollo 9 (18): 9–41.
Bulmer-Thomas, V. 2003. The Economic History of Latin America Since
Independence. 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Burgess, R. 1982. The Role of Theory in Field Research. In Field Research:
A Sourcebook and Field Manual, ed. R. Burgess, 209–212. London: Routledge.
Buzan, B., and R. Little. 2000. International System in World History: Remaking
the Study of International Relations. New York: Oxford University Press.
Carr, E. 1967. The Twenty Years’ Crisis. New York: Perennial.
Cord, L. et al. 2014. Inequality Stagnation in Latin America in the Aftermath of
the Global Financial Crisis. Word Bank. Available at: http://documents.world-
bank.org/curated/en/908771468088775560/Inequality-stagnation-in-
Latin-America-in-the-aftermath-of-the-global-financial-crisis
Cox, R. 1981. Social Forces, States and World Orders: Beyond International
Relations Theory. Millennium Journal of International Studies 10 (2):
126–155.
20 E. VIVARES
Cox, R., and M. Schechter, eds. 2002. The Political Economy of a Plural World:
Critical Reflections on Power, Morals and Civilizations. London: Routledge.
De Ferranti, D., G. Perry, F. Ferreira, and M. Walton. 2004. Inequality in Latin
America and the Caribbean: Breaking with History? Washington, DC: The
World Bank.
De Lombaerde, P., and F. Söderbaum, eds. 2014. Regionalism. Belgium:
SAGE – UN.
Deciancio, M. 2016. International Relations from the South: A Regional Research
Agenda for Global IR. International Studies Review 18 (1): 1–14.
Deutsch, K., S. Burrell, and R. Kann. 1958. Political Community in the North
Atlantic. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Duffield, M. 2001. Global Governance and the New Wars. The Merging of
Development and Security. London: Zed Books.
Dumitru, A. et al. 2015. Latin America After the Commodity Boom. Rabobank.
Available at: https://economics.rabobank.com/publications/2015/september/
latin-america-after-the-commodity-boom/
Dunne, T., L. Hansen, and C. Wight. 2013. The End of International Relations
Theory? European Journal of International Relations 19 (3): 405–425.
Estay, J., and G. Sánchez (coord). 2005. El ALCA y sus peligros para América
Latina. Buenos Aires: CLACSO.
Estevadeordal, A., and K. Suominen. 2007. Sequencing Regional Trade and
Cooperation Agreements. Internal Paper. Washington: Integration and Regional
Programs Department, Inter-American Development Bank.
Falconi, F. 2014. Al Sur de las decisiones: Enfrentando la crisis del siglo XXI. Quito:
El Conejo.
Frankema, E. 2009. Has Latin America Always Been Unequal? A Comparative
Analysis of Asset and Income Inequality in the Long Twenty Century. Leiden:
Brill.
Gamble, A., and A. Payne. 1996. Regionalism and World Order. London: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Gasparini, Leonardo, and Nora Lustig. 2011. The Rise and Fall of Income
Inequality in Latin America, 27. Buenos Aires: Universidad de La Plata,
ECINEQ WP/CEDLAS.
Griffith-Jones, S. 1984. International Finance and Latin America. New York: St.
Martin Press.
Haas, E. 1958. The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social and International
Organization. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Halperin Donghi, T. 1995. The Contemporary History of Latin America. London:
Duke University Press, Fourth Edition.
Hay, C., and A. Payne. 2013. The Great Uncertainty. In SPERI Paper No 5,
pp. 2–3.
THE IPE PUZZLE OF REGIONAL INEQUALITY, INSTABILITY... 21
Hettne, B., and F. Söderbaum. 2000. Theorising the Rise of Regionness. New
Political Economy 5 (3): 457–474.
Hettne, B., A. Inotai, and O. Sunkel, eds. 1999. Globalism and the New
Regionalism. London: Macmillan.
Higgott, R. 2006. The Theory and Practice of Region. In Regional Integration in
East Asia and Europe: Convergence or Divergence, ed. B. Fort and D. Webber,
17–38. New York: Routledge.
Hobsbawn, E. 1998. Fractured Times: Culture and Society in the Twentieth
Century. New York: The New Press.
Ikenberry, J. 2011. Liberal Leviathan: The Origins, Crisis, and Transformation of
the American World Order. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Jackson, P. 2011. The Conduct of Inquiry in International Relations: Philosophy of
Science and Its Implications for the Study of World Politics. New York: Routledge.
Kaletsky, A. 2017. Trumping Capitalism? Available at: https://www.
projectsyndicate.org/onpoint/trumping-capitalism-by-anatole-kaletsky-
201701?barrier= accessreg
Katzenstein, P. 2005. A World of Regions: Asia and Europe in the American
Imperium. Cornell: Cornell University Press.
———. 2009. Civilizations in World Politics: Plural and Pluralist Perspectives.
New York: Routledge.
King, G., R. Keohane, and S. Verba. 1994. Designing in Social Inquiry: Scientific
Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Lombaerde, P. 2016. Theorizing Latin American Regionalism in the 21st Century.
IN Federalisme Regionalisme 16.
Luhnow, D. 2014. The Two Latin Americas. A Continental Divide Between One
Bloc That Favors State Controls and Another That Embraces Free Markets. The
Wall Street Journal. New York, January 3. that.
Lustig, N., L. Lopez-Calva, and E. Ortiz-Juarez 2012. Declining Inequality in
Latin America in the 2000s: The Cases of Argentina, Brazil and Mexico. Working
Papers 307, CGDEV.
Makram, H. 2006. How “International” Are Theories in International Relations?
The View from Latin America. San Diego: Paper presented at the Annual
Meeting of the International Studies Association.
Malamud, A. 2011. Conceptos, teorías y debates sobre la integración regional.
Norteamérica 6,2 (6–12): 219–249.
Malamud, A., and G. Gardini. 2012. Has Regionalism Peaked? The Latin American
Quagmire and Its Lessons. The International Spectator 47–1 (3): 116–133.
Mitrany, D. 1966. A Working Peace System. Chicago: Quadrangle Books.
Nelson, M., and J. Gustafsson, eds. 2012. Latin America Responses to Globalization
in the 21st Century. London: Palgrave.
22 E. VIVARES
Introduction
According to an influential study by Homi Kharas (2010), the increase in
average income and the fall in levels of absolute poverty, in particular
during the last decade, suggest that an increasing proportion of the
world’s population is neither rich nor poor by national standards but finds
itself in the middle of the income distribution. This expansion continues.
Despite the global economic slowdown following the Great Recession of
J. Ponce (*)
FLACSO Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
R. Vos
FAO, Food and Agricultural Organization of United Nations, Rome, Italy
J. Rosero
Statistics Division of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the
United Nations (FAO), Rome, Italy
R. Castillo
National Institute of Statistics and Censuses of Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
Fig. 2.1 Estimates of the projected rise of the global middle classa, 2015–2030.
(Source: Kharas (2017: Tables 2 and 3); Note: a Global middle class is defined here
as the population with a per capita income of between US$10 and US$100 per day
in Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) in 2011)
28 J. PONCE ET AL.
internationally comparable income levels. The most often cited studies see
the global middle class as those households with per capita incomes
between PPP$10 and PPP$100 per person per day in PPP terms (Kharas
2010, 2017; World Bank 2007; Ernst and Young 2013; Bank of America
Merrill Lynch 2016). This implies an annual income for a four-person
middle-class household of US$14,600 to US$146,000. For the case of
Ecuador we consider a similar definition, but taking the range of PPP$10
to PPP$50 of daily per capita income. In nominal 2015 dollars that trans-
lates into a monthly per capita income of between US$191 and US$954,
or, for a family of four, annual household incomes of between US$9000
and US$46,000 per year. The reason to put the upper bound for the
middle class at PPP$50 per person per day is that, beyond that level, only
a very small share remains for the richest group.2
Figure 2.6a–c show the trends in the size of Ecuador’s middle class
from the early 90s for urban areas and nationwide trends from 2000.
We compare its evolution with the prevalence of extreme and moderate
poverty (at international poverty lines of, respectively, PPP$1.90 and
IS LATIN AMERICA’S RISE OF THE MIDDLE CLASSES LASTING OR... 35
Fig. 2.5 LA’s top, middle, and bottom of the income distribution, around 2013
(income shares of bottom 40%, middle 40% and top 20%; ranked by income share
of middle class) (Source: World Bank, Poverty, and Inequality Database)
Fig. 2.6 Ecuador’s rising middle class, 1990–2016 (population shares by income
categories) (Source: INEC (various years); Note: See text for the definition of
income groups)
IS LATIN AMERICA’S RISE OF THE MIDDLE CLASSES LASTING OR... 37
irrors that of urban areas with further growth of the size of the middle
m
class coming to a halt (and even turning into a slight decline) from 2014,
as the economy, real wages, and the agricultural terms of trade went into
a tailspin.
Figure 2.6a–c further show the staggering decline in extreme and
moderate poverty, as measured against international poverty lines of,
respectively, PPP$1.90 and PPP$4.00 per day.3 Between 2000 and 2016,
the extreme poverty incidence fell from 23.0% to 5.5% for the country at
large. The rural extreme poverty incidence was cut by more than two
thirds: from 38.6% in 2000 to 11.6% in 2016. Extreme poverty in urban
areas had dropped from almost 23% in 1990 to 9% in 1997, but rose
again to initial levels towards the end of the decade as a result of the eco-
nomic and political crisis. During the 2000s, urban extreme poverty was
nearly wiped out, dropping to under 5% of the urban population by 2010
and to under 3% by 2016. Declines in moderate poverty (those living on
between PPP$1.90 and PPP$4.00 per day) were also substantial, though
less dramatic. Many of those lifted out of poverty transited to the group
of vulnerable households and many in that category into the middle class.
The transition matrices presented in the next section and the decomposi-
tion of income changes during 2000–2015 disentangle the underlying
dynamics.
which provided the Ecuadorian government with the fiscal space to under-
pin expansive labor policies (through minimum wage increases) and social
policies (expanding social transfers and public infrastructure). Fiscal reform
and a strong government push to expand coverage of the social security
system increased the share of workers in formal employment, especially in
services and benefiting unskilled workers. As analyzed by Ponce and Vos
(2014), the boost in purchasing power among broad segments of the pop-
ulation facilitated a further expansion of the market size of an already large
informal sector (in agriculture, but especially in urban services), as well as
that of modern urban service, generating multiplier effects on employ-
ment and real wage and farm income growth. This growth pattern is also
reflected in a lowering of the wage premium for skilled labor and a rising
wedge between informal and formal sector labor incomes.
Turning first to the decline in the skill premium, existing studies have
suggested that much of the increase in income inequality in LA during the
90s was on account of increasing wage differentials between skilled and
unskilled workers. The increase would have been produced by more skill-
intensive technological change induced by trade and capital account open-
ing.5 The greater demand for skilled labor would have increased the wage
gap between skilled and unskilled workers.6 During the 2000s, in contrast,
the increase in the educational level of the work force would have counter-
acted the increase in the demand for skilled labor, reducing the wage gap.7
To analyze whether this pattern also occurred in Ecuador case, we ran
a Mincerian wage regression for the population aged 25–55 years. The
estimation model is as follows:
Yi = α + βCi + γXi + εi
Table 2.2 Ecuador: Skill-based wage premium for urban workers (Beta coeffi-
cients estimated using a Mincerian wage equation)
Urban area
72% more than unskilled workers in 2000, up from 48% in 1990. A similar
trend is observed for male and female workers. These trends reversed dur-
ing the 2000s, as the wage gap decreased. The skill premium reduced
from 72% to 50% in 2015. The trend is also similar for both male and
female workers. The improvements in the skill level of the labor force are
closely associated with the recovery of real public spending in education
during the 90s and the cash transfer programs of the 2000s and 2010s,
which helped improve access to education. At the same time, the struc-
tural change towards an expanding informal sector economy slowed the
demand for skilled workers, which does not augur well for sustained pro-
ductivity and income growth moving forward.
Using the same Mincerian model above, we also tested the trend in the
wage premium for modern sector workers by taking the results of the
dummy variable for the sector of employment. The dummy takes the value
of 1 if the worker is employed in the modern sector and 0 if employed in
the informal sector. The coefficient is indicative of the gap in labor income
between modern and informal sector workers, after controlling for skill
levels and work experience. As shown in Table 2.3, the modern sector
wage premium for urban workers increased strongly during the 90s and
2000s.
The implications of this finding are not immediately clear, but one
inference could be that for further sustained upward mobility towards the
middle class, an expanding modern sector in agro-industries and other
non-extractive productive sectors would be needed. This would help
reduce the vulnerability of the economy to swings in world market
42 J. PONCE ET AL.
Table 2.3 Ecuador: Wage premium for urban workers in the modern sector
(Dummy coefficients for the modern sector)
Urban area
c ommodity prices and in the related fiscal space, and it would allow the
income growth for the middle classes to be underpinned by higher pro-
ductivity growth and broader based sector development. Indeed, as shown
in section 2 above , the downturn in the economy affected the services
sector activity the most, notably reversing the trend of increased formal
sector employment and social security coverage. Alongside, poverty reduc-
tion came to a halt and growth of Ecuador’s middle class stagnated. On
the positive side, the middle class did not collapse under the weight of the
economic downturn, as happened during the crisis of the late 90s. Yet, like
the poor and vulnerable, the middle-class welfare position remains highly
vulnerable to macroeconomic swings.
Conclusions
The strong rise of Ecuador’s middle class coincided with a period of eco-
nomic recovery and growth. Part of the surge had its origins in real wage
growth and an increased wage premium for skilled workers associated with
trade and financial liberalization of the 90s. However, during that period,
macroeconomic as well as political instability brought about fluctuating
trends in real wage growth, as much as in poverty and inequality, mitigat-
ing the expansion of the middle class. Both income inequality and poverty
saw sustained reductions from the early 2000s onwards. Much of this had
to do with the recovery from the El Niño natural disaster and deep eco-
nomic and financial crisis in the late 90s. This was reflected in strong real
IS LATIN AMERICA’S RISE OF THE MIDDLE CLASSES LASTING OR... 43
Crafting continued political support for the middle class may present a
greater challenge. Unless globalization can be reframed into a win-win for
the middle class in each country, the political narrative can be distorted into
one of colliding interests between the middle class in emerging economies
like Ecuador and those in advanced economies. A new package of “inclusive
growth” must be constructed based on the common theme that continued
widening of income and opportunity inequality, and the barriers these cre-
ate to social mobility, must be forcefully tackled while preserving the ben-
efits afforded by globalization and technological change and innovation.
Notes
1. The high dollar inflation was the result of setting a sucre-dollar conversion
rate at a level much higher than the peak market exchange rate before dol-
larization and failure to introduce enough small-denomination dollar coins,
which pushed up prices for many basic products (by rounding to one dol-
lar). See Vos (2000).
2. Please note that the size of the upper middle-income and rich household
group in Ecuador is probably strongly underestimated because of under-
reporting of incomes by those households in the household surveys used for
the present analysis.
3. The results presented in this chapter are based on a new and robust procedure
to reconstruct series of poverty and income distribution data for the labor
force surveys conducted in Ecuador since 1990. The surveys have gone
through several methodological changes in questionnaire design and sam-
pling. Also, the dollarization of the economy in 2000 poses problems in proper
deflating nominal incomes for the currency change. The set of deflators for
national and international poverty lines used to construct the time-consistent
poverty and real income estimates are available from the authors upon request.
4. The results on mobility presented in this chapter follow the same procedure
as the study of Pesantez (2014), which also estimates transition matrices
based on Ecuador’s labor force surveys, but covers the period 2007–2013.
5. For the case of LA and Ecuador, see, respectively, Vos et al. (2006) and Vos
and León (2003). The Brazilian case represents an exception in this sense,
given that trade liberalization generated a reduction of inequality. See
Ferreira et al. (2008)
6. Critical stances regarding the focus on technological change with a bias
towards skilled labor can be found in Card and Di Nardo (2002), Morissette
and Drolet (1998), Oosterbeek (1997), and Entorf et al. (1999). For
Ecuador see Oosterbeek and Ponce (2011).
7. See, for example, López Calva and Lustig (2010).
IS LATIN AMERICA’S RISE OF THE MIDDLE CLASSES LASTING OR... 45
Bibliography
Bank of America Merrill Lynch Global Research. 2016. Theme Watch: Rise of
Bottom Billions. CIO Weekly Letter, June 21. New York: BofAML. https://
olui2.fs.ml.com/Publish/Content/application/pdf/GWMOL/
GWIMCIOWeeklyLetter6212016.pdf.
Card, David, and John Di Nardo. 2002. Skill-Biased Technological Change and
Rising Wage Inequality: Some Problems and Puzzles. Journal of Labor
Economics 20 (4): 733–783.
Dang, Hai-Anh, Peter Lanjouw, Jill Luoto, and David McKenzie. 2011. Using
Repeated Cross-Sections to Explore Movements In and Out of Poverty, World
Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5550. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Entorf, Horst, Michael Gollac, and Francis Kramarz. 1999. New Technologies,
Wages, and Worker Selection. Journal of Labor Economics 17 (3): 464–491.
Ernst & Young. 2013. Hitting the Sweet Spot: The Growth of the Middle Class
in Emerging Markets. http://www.ey.com/gl/en/issues/driving-growth/
middle-class-growth-in-emerging-markets.
FAO. 2017. The Future of Food and Agriculture: Trends and Challenges. Rome:
Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.
Ferreira, F.H.G., P.G. Leite, and J.A. Litchfield. 2008. The Rise and Fall of
Brazilian Inequality: 1981–2004. Macroeconomic Dynamics 12: 199–230.
Hirschman, Albert O., and Michael Rothschild. 1973. The Changing Tolerance
for Income Inequality in the Course of Economic Development: With a
Mathematical Appendix. Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (4): 544–566.
INEC. (various years). Encuesta Nacional de Empleo, Desempleo y Subempleo
(ENEMDU). Quito: Ecuador National Statistical Office.
———. 2016. Reporte de pobreza por consumo, 2006–2014. Quito: Instituto
Nacional de Estadística y Censos.
Kharas, Homi. 2010. The Emerging Middle Class in Developing Countries, OECD
Development Centre Working Paper No. 285. Paris: OECD.
———. 2017. The Unprecedented Expansion of the Global Middle Class: An Update,
Brookings Global Economy & Development Working Paper No. 100.
Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution (February).
López Calva, Luis, and Nora Lustig. 2010. Explaining the Decline in Inequality in
Latin America: Technological Change, Educational Upgrading and Democracy.
In En Declining Inequality in Latin America: A Decade of Progress? ed. Luis
López-Calva and Nora Lustig. Washington, DC/Baltimore: UNDP/Brookings
Institution Press.
Morissette, R., and M. Drolet. 1998. Computers, Fax Machines and Wages in
Canada: What Really Matters?, Working Paper 126. Statistics Canada.
Oosterbeek, Hessel. 1997. Returns from Computer Use: A Simple Test on the
Productivity Interpretation. Economic Letters 55: 273–277.
46 J. PONCE ET AL.
Oosterbeek, Hessel, and Juan Ponce. 2011. The Impact of Computer Use on
Wages in a Developing Country: Evidence from Ecuador. Labour Economics 18
(4): 434–440.
Pesantez, Ericka. 2014. Análisis de movilidad social en el Ecuador. Analítika –
Revista de análisis estadístico 8 (2): 53–68.
Ponce, Juan, and Rob Vos. 2014. Redistribution Without Structural Change in
Ecuador: Rising and Falling Income Inequality in the 1990s and 2000s. In
Falling Inequality in Latin America: Evidence from the Last Decade and
Prospects for the Future, ed. Giovanni Andrea Cornia. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Vos, Rob. 2000. Development and the Colour of Money: Should All Developing
Countries Have Their Own Currency? Inaugural Lecture, 7 December. The
Hague: Institute of Social Studies. Available at: www.repub.eur.nl/res/
pub/30875/InauguralAddress2000Dec7Vos.pdf
Vos, R. 2002. Ecuador: Economic Liberalization, Adjustment and Poverty. In
Economic Liberalization, Distribution and Poverty: Latin America in the 1990s,
ed. Rob Vos, Lance Taylor, and Ricardo Paes de Barros, 259–313. Cheltenham/
Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishers.
Vos, Rob, and Niek de Jong. 2003. Trade Liberalization and Poverty in Ecuador.
A Macro-Micro CGE Approach. Economic Systems Research 15 (2): 211–232.
(June, special issue).
Vos, Rob, and Mauricio León. 2003. Dolarización, Dinámica de Exportaciones y
Equidad: ¿Cómo Compatibilizarlas en el caso de Ecuador? Estudios e Informes
del SIISE. No.5. Quito: Secretaría Técnica del Frente Social.
Vos, Rob, Lance Taylor, and Ricardo Paes de Barros, eds. 2002. Economic
Liberalization, Distribution and Poverty: Latin America in the 1990s.
Cheltenham/Northampton: Edward Elgar Publishers.
Vos, Rob, Juan Ponce, Mauricio León, and José Cuesta. 2003. ¿Quién se beneficia
del gasto social en Ecuador? Desafíos para mejorar la eficiencia y la equidad del
gasto social. Quito: Abya Yala Publishers.
Vos, Rob, Enrique Ganuza, Samuel Morley, and Sherman Robinson, eds. 2006.
Who Gains from Free Trade? London: Routledge.
World Bank. 2007. Global Economic Prospects: Managing the Next Wave of
Globalization. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
———. 2016. Poverty and Shared Prosperity 2016: Taking on Inequality.
Washington, DC: The World Bank.
CHAPTER 3
Jaime Estay
In this text, we will identify the principal stages through which regional-
ism, in the context of its economic elements, in LAC has passed. In rela-
tion to these stages, we will revise the theoretical approaches which have
been present, as well as the context in which they have unfolded.
This chapter proposes that in the second half of the twentieth century,
two clearly distinct stages of economic integration developed in conjunc-
tion with two dominant patterns of economic operation that were in force
in the region. These patterns are both defined by a set of functions for
mechanisms of integration. In this century, while disparate strategies of
economic development in the region coexist, a third stage is unravelling
whose main feature is the increased heterogeneity within and between dif-
ferent integration projects in which important changes have taken place.
This is the case, particularly in South America, with regard to geographical
composition and with international trade which is increasing the impor-
tance of trade with China and accentuating the role played by primary
products to be exported.
J. Estay (*)
Benemérita Universidad Autónoma de Puebla, Puebla, Mexico
Even though the first integration mechanisms were created in the region
at the end of the 1950s, the pursuit of economic integration has been
included as part of the strategy of industrialization since the Economic
Commission of LA was first drafted and began activities in 1948.
In these initial terms, and with the advancement of integration, two
principle objectives were sought: (1) the creation of a common market
that embraced all or the majority of LAC countries; (2) given the obstacles
derived from the existence of multiple bilateral agreements of signed pay-
ments among countries in the region, a constitution of a union of pay-
ments was proposed.
With respect to both objectives, the immediate reference point was the
similar initiatives that were being pursued in Europe: on one hand the
negotiations for and subsequent implementation of the European
Community of Coal and Steel (1952), as well as the European Economic
Community (1958); on the other hand, the Intra-European Payments
Agreement of 1948 and 1949, and the creation, in 1950, of the European
Payments Union, which in 1958 was replaced by the European Monetary
Agreement.
Thus, the terms of LAC integration were nurtured by the theories of
European integration, which, in the main, were created from the perspec-
tive of traditional economic analysis and were based on “customs union
theory”, found in research by, for example, Viner (1950), Meade (1953,
1955), Lipsey (1957, 1960), Balassa (1961a, b and 1963) and Johnson
(1957, 1960a, b, 1965), amongst others. Other authors who influenced
the initial terms of the ECLAC are, for example, Meier (1960), Allen
(1961), Cooper and Massel (1965), and Mead (1968). In this research,
more reference was made to the situations of developing nations, above
all, necessities beyond free trade were considered, such as savings in for-
eign currency, the improvement of exchange rates, the increase of interna-
tional negotiation capacity, the formation of capital, and the achievement
of industrial development.
In this initial stage, the role allocated to economic integration in the
ECLAC strategy of the ISI model can be seen in the Economic Survey of
Latin America 1949 in which a review of the characteristics and the prob-
lems of the bilateral conventions between countries in the region suggests
that these conventions:
PAST AND PRESENT OF LATIN AMERICAN REGIONALISMS, IN THE FACE... 49
During the rest of the 50s, ECLAC introduced multiple resolutions with
regard to the increase in intra-regional trade, the creation of a common
market, the definition of a multilateral payment system, and policymaking
for industrialization at a regional level. These resolutions were mandates
for the elaboration of research on this topic as well as studies completed by
the secretary of ECLAC and recommendations made by the governments,
a large part of which was channeled through ECLAC’s trade committee,
created in 1955.
We are not attempting to provide a detailed account of all of the above,
but will simply highlight that the progress made in the analysis of this area
is reflected in the document of ECLAC’s trade committee, Recommendations
on the Structure and Norms of a Common Latin American Market, pub-
lished in March 1959 (CEPAL 1959) and in which 11 points and 12
norms are proposed referring to the “structure” of the common market
and which would frame its operation.
If what is suggested in this document is compared with the contents
expressed in the Treaty of Montevideo that was signed in February of 1960
creating the LAFTA, the differences are evident. For example, the “sub-
regional” character of the association—the Treaty of Montevideo was ini-
tially signed by seven countries—the lack of inclusion of a multilateral
compensation mechanism of balances,1 and the definition as an objective
of the association a free trade area rather than a common market.
The creation of the LAFTA marked the beginning of the first stage of
regional economic integration that corresponded to the ISI model. At this
stage, the CACM was also created with the signing of the Treaty of
Managua in December 1960, as well as the Andean Group, which in
1996 became the Andean Community with the signing of the Cartagena
Agreement, and the Caribbean Community (CARICOM) with the sign-
ing of the Treaty of Chaguaramas in July 1973, to which the replacement
of the LAFTA, the LAIA, was added with the signing of the Treaty of
Montevideo 80 (TM80) in August 1980.
50 J. ESTAY
During the first stage of regional integration, the founding texts of these
mechanisms and their development had specific characteristics as well as
differences between them, of which we will mention only a few: in CACM,
the intention to create “Central American Industries for Integration” and
a maximum momentum of intra-scheme commerce in comparison to pre-
vious mechanisms; in the Andean Group, a more complex institutional
structure with common procedures and norms on various topics with
“Sectoral Industrial Development Programs” and with some characteristics
of supranationality; in the Treaty of Chaguaramas and in the development
of the CARICOM, the importance of functional cooperation and the coor-
dination of foreign policy; in the LAIA, the greatest possible flexibility in
defining objectives, the absence of liberalization deadlines and the possibil-
ity of “partial scope” agreements—which according to the TM80 would
be object to a “progressive multilateralization” —compared to the LAFTA.
Despite these differences, the schemes share two characteristics and
general results that demonstrate the development of regional integration
during its first stage:
• On one hand, and in exactly the same way as happened with the
LAFTA, the initial definition of the remaining mechanisms also dis-
tances itself from the integration model created in the 50s, in such a
way that the objectives, for example, the regional character desired
for integration, the realization of common markets, and the incorpo-
ration of advanced models of monetary and financial co-operation,
were relegated, remaining at a declarative level.
• On the other hand, the operation of the mechanisms distanced
themselves swiftly from the fulfillment of the commitment and dead-
lines set, with which the progress made was only partial and time-
related. The results were partial because the only commitments that
were moderately fulfilled were those related to the mutual reduction
of tax and in some cases to the creation of credit mechanisms for
intra-scheme trade. This happened in such a way that the integration
almost exclusively manifested itself as growth of the aforementioned
trade; time-related because the “integrating stimulus” only lasted for
the period immediately after the creation of each scheme, after which
it fell into a period of stagnation and regression.
major regional crisis throughout this decade marked the final stage effort
of the ISI model and of the modality of integration associated with it.
Thus closing the first stage of integration with a global balance, which, at
the end of the 80s, CEPAL (1990: 164) summarized, identifying a “gen-
eral insatisfaction which can be observed in the countries of the region
with respect to the achievements of intraregional integration.”
In the context of this crisis, the decision of LA governments to generate
considerable commercial operations to serve the interest of the external
debt, had a large impact on integration. The operation of the mechanisms
suffered a sharp deterioration, the quantity of infringements, and existing
problems multiplied, new problems appeared, and even in those areas
where progress was previously being made there was a regression. As a
result, years later a new regional context arose with completely different
content assigned to integration.
During the 80s, a set of policies that implied substantial changes to the
economic and social operation of the countries in the region was applied.
Of these changes, amongst the most important were those which referred
to international integration modalities and to performance of the external
sector, in such a way that the new form of operation implied an accelerated
opening process of the market, modifying the previous approach in a way
that emphasis was on productive structures and internal markets—or
regional—that developed with important mediation with respect to the
world scene.
In this new context and since the end of this decade, there was a
“relaunch” of regional integration, beginning a second phase in which
there was not only new content but also a distinct positioning of the devel-
opment strategies present in the countries.
In general terms, the beginning of this second phase corresponded,
time-wise and with some of its content, with the boom of the so-called
“new regionalism”, which was deployed from developed countries and
whose main expression was the growing presence of trade agreements that
had been in existence since the second half of the 80s, and which Schiff
and Winters (2003: xi) describe as “one of the most significant develop-
ments in international relations in recent years”, and which is considered
by Bhagwati (1993) as the second wave of regionalism since WWII.
52 J. ESTAY
Let’s promote free trade at a world, regional and bilateral level […} (Zoellick
2002).
“Currently, any decision made by the WTO requires a consensus from its
144 members. Any country […] can paralyse the Doha Agenda […] If oth-
ers do not want to move forward, the United States will move forward with
those that want to […]”3 (ibid).
In parallel to the application of this strategy and since the 90s, consider-
able research has been conducted about the “competitive liberalization”
of the USA and about “new regionalism”, identifying its general charac-
teristics and its differences from previous regionalizm (Mistry 1995, 1999;
Bergsten 1997; Baldwin 1997; Ethier 1998a, b; Bouzas 1999; Burfisher
et al. 2003; Söderbaum and Shaw 2003; Söderbaum 2015); analyzing the
relationships between the development of blocks and multilateralism, as
well as the conditions or difficulties with which new regionalism leads to
global free trade (Summers 1991; Bhagwati 1993, 1995; Winters 1996;
Bhagwati and Panagariya 1999; Panagariya and Findlay 1994; Hettne and
Inotai 1994; Ethier 1998a; Hettne and Söderbaum 2000; Andriamananjara
2000, 2003; Hettne 2005; Baldwin 1999, 2006; Crawford and Laird
2001); critisizing the protectionist character, which would definitely con-
serve regionalism in its new forms (Krugman 1989, 1993; Oman
1994; Bhagwati 1995; Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD) 1995; Bhagwati et al. 2014; Bhagwati and Krishna
2016); and highlighting the importance of the attractions that the forma-
tion of a block has over non-member states (Baldwin 1995, 1997; Corden
1995), amongst others.
With “new regionalism” as a framework in the international economy
and the neoliberal trend in the world and in the region, the relaunch of
integration implied the abandonment of previous intentions to give it a
regional character—with a clear preference for agreements of a bilateral
nature or for small groups of countries—and, as a result, that it looks
beyond trade, adding, in some cases, the circulation of capital and people.
With regard to trade, a deepening of liberalization was proposed for the
54 J. ESTAY
changes that have occurred in the context of the neoliberal model was the
signing of numerous free trade treaties, to such an extent that—according
to the Organization of American States’ Foreign Trade Information
System—from the first half of the 90s until now, the countries in the
region have signed 23 treaties and 51 with partners outside the region.
Among those treaties with partners outside the region are those that
have been signed with the USA by 11 countries in the region,6 —agreed
in parallel with, or after, the negotiations of the FTAA. It is clear that a
large percentage of the countries in the region, and above all Mexico,
began with “asymmetrical bilateralism” (Bouzas et al. 2008). This nego-
tiation, in both the treaties and in the FTAA, was clearly a priority, both as
with other negotiations of other free trade agreements, as well as in rela-
tion to the development of regional integration schemes.
In conclusion, it should be noted that the official document elaborating
on integration from the region in this second stage, unlike what happened
with the ISI model, clearly took place before the redefining of the direc-
tion of regional integration, whose basic components were finalized
between the end of the 80s and the beginning of the following decade.
This suggests that the document intended to fine-tune itself to the new
integration format already in place, and with respect to this take on the
demand for an urgent neoliberal openness as well as take advantage of
integration.
With respect to this approach to integration, identified by the LA
Economic System (2002) as a “new stage” of integration and by the Inter-
American Development Bank (2002) as the “new regionalism in Latin
America”, the policy that had the greatest impact corresponded to the
ECLAC, which presented its proposal of “open regionalism” in 1994,
defining it as the “process that emerges while conciliating […] the inter-
dependence born from special agreements that had preferential character-
istics and that which was basically propelled by market signals resulting
from trade liberalisation in general” (CEPAL 1994:12).
In this document, which was complemented the following year by
another with a title of more general nature (CEPAL 1995), strategies were
proposed for incorporation into the international sphere and objectives
and functions of regional integration were defined, assuming the general
sense of what had already happened in this area, as well as locating “open
regionalism” in the proposal of “Changing Production Patterns with
Social Equity”, which ECLAC put forward at the beginning of the 90s
(CEPAL 1990, 1992).
56 J. ESTAY
600000 30
400000 20
300000 15
200000 10
100000 5
0 0
1989
2008
1988
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
Sudam ALC/ Mundo (Eje der) Resto ALC ALC/Mundo (Eje der) Exp. Sudam. al Mundo (Eje izq)
Exp. Sudam. a ALC (Eje izq) Exp. Resto de ALC al Mundo (Eje izq) Exp. Resto de ALC a ALC (Eje izq)
Fig. 3.1 Performance of total export and exports towards the region of South
America and the rest of the LAC. Left axis—millions of US dollars; Right axis—
percentage of total exports
Key: South America LAC/world (right axis), rest of LAC LAC/world (right axis),
exports from South America to the world (left axis), exports from South America
to LAC (left axis), exports from the rest of LAC to the world (left axis), exports
from the rest of LAC to LAC (left axis)
Source: ECLAC yearbook of statistics and database CEPALSTAT
58 J. ESTAY
in the total trade of both groups of countries (shown on the right axis)
shows that trade to the region, even though its importance increased
towards the end of the 80s—above all, for South America—did not do so
to expected levels, given the priority to the increase in trade links in open
regionalism, adding the dramatic fall in these percentages in the four years
of regional economic deterioration from 1998 to 2002, which has also
been happening in recent years, maintaining it like that—as occurred in
the 80s—the pro-cyclical character of intra-regional trade.
During the full implementation of “open regionalism”, and within the
countries, the incomplete character of the common external tariff was
inserted to the various mechanisms of integration, in addition to the lack
of political harmonization and the failure to reach the commitment and
deadlines set, amongst others. At the beginning of this century, the lack of
results in regionalism, with regard to what had been announced with its
application, was evident, in addition to the lack of coherence in the
“entanglement” of signed agreements by different governments and the
consequent absence of any sign of progress towards the promised “pro-
gressive multilateralization”.
At the change of the century, this lack of results for open regionalism
became evident in a new regional context, in which the growing rejection of
neoliberalism was embodied with the arrival of a significant number of gov-
ernments with projects, which to varying degrees, were opposed to the neo-
liberal model—Venezuela (1999), Brazil (2003), Argentina (2003), Uruguay
(2005), Ecuador (2007), Nicaragua (2007), and Paraguay (2008)—which
included international strategies for integration that were different to the
liberalizing trend, a clear decision to distance themselves from any extra-
regional mentorship and a redefinition of regional integration that assigned
distinct functions and objectives to those of open regionalism.
Thus, during the first decade of this century a new modality of region-
alism in the region unfolded, beginning a third stage of regional economic
integration, in part through changes in pre-existing mechanisms,10 and
primarily with the creation of new mechanisms: the ALBA in December
2004, the UNASUR in May 2008—as a predecessor to the South
American Community of Nations, and the CELAC in December 2011—
as a predecessor to the Rio Group created in 1986, and the presidential
summits that took place in 2008 and 2010.
Even though there are differences among these mechanisms, in general
terms, within them there is a notable increase of the action plans, the
themes, and the areas included in their respective agendas, in which, for
PAST AND PRESENT OF LATIN AMERICAN REGIONALISMS, IN THE FACE... 59
the ALBA and the UNASUR, Serbin (2011: 7–8, 2014: 54, 2012: 79)
summarizes as “a return to the development agenda”, “return to politics”,
and “return of the state”, which he expresses in at least three ways:
The new form of regionalism has been the subject of various denomi-
nations, depending on which characteristics and which of the mechanisms
involved are to be highlighted. Thus, the UNASUR and the ALBA refer
to a “post-hegemonic regionalism”, according to Riggirozzi (2012) and
Riggirozzi and Tussie (2012), with which Briceño (2014) agrees. The
UNASUR, the ALBA, and the CELAC refer to a “post-liberal regional-
ism”, according to Sanahuja (2009, 2012, 2014) and a “new multilateral-
ism” according to Yepe (2014); for Hettne and Söderbaum (2006), a
“regionalism geared towards development” is referred to in
the MERCOSUR and, at that time, in the Andean Community; for the
ALBA reference is made to a “new strategic regionalism”, according to
Aponte (2011, 2014, 2015) and a “counter-hegemonist integration”,
according to Puello-Socarras et al. (2014); for Preciado (2013) and
Preciado and Florido (2013), a “post-neoliberal integration with a
60 J. ESTAY
90
80
70
porcentajes del total
60
50
40
30
20
10
Fig. 3.2 Composition of exports from South America as well as the rest of the
LAC.
Y axis—percentage of total
Key: South American primary products, South American manufactured products,
primary products from the rest of the LAC, manufactured products from the rest
of the LAC
Source: ECLAC, database of foreign trade (BADECEL)
90
80
70
en porcentajes del total
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
China en las exp totales: Resto de ALC China en las exp totales: Suramérica
Exp. P Primarios en exp totales a China: Resto de ALC Exp. P Primarios en exp totales a China: Suramérica
Fig. 3.3 Total and primary exports to China from South America and the rest of
the LAC
Y axis—percentage of the total
Key: China in the total export: rest of the LAC, China in the total exports: South
America, primary export products within total exports to China: rest of the LAC,
primary export products within total export to China: South America
Source: UNCTAD, database UNCTADStat
arrival of capital coming from this country and the features characterizing
these links, has been the focus of increasing attention in the region, linked
also to a sharp increase of Chinese presence at a systematic level. We make
no intention here of explaining all of the above, even though it is interest-
ing to highlight that the importance of the relationship with China has led
to the possible emergence in LA of a “Beijing Consensus” — Slipak (2014),
Svampa and Slipak (2015)—and that, regarding exports to the aforemen-
tioned country, they have become an important motor and extreme expres-
sion of the reprimarization to which we have been referring.12
In contrast to the figures for the total exports to China, is the trade
within LAC. For several decades now, for the majority of these coun-
tries, regionally focused exports have been characterized as having a
64 J. ESTAY
by the remaining countries in the region, which for South America implies
a percentage that is substantially higher than the corresponding total
exports, shown in Fig. 3.2, and evidently the extreme opposite of the min-
imum level of manufactured exports to China.13
Consequently, this characteristic of intraregional trade is still present as
it has been throughout the three stages of economic integration. This has
kept open the possibility of increasing this trade in order to help to attenu-
ate the tendency towards reprimarization and enabling progress in the
creation of economies of scale in manufacturing, which could be the foun-
dation for initiatives of greater depth in the development of productive
links between the countries in the region.
However, it is necessary to recognize that regional economic integra-
tion, in its third stage, is experiencing not only difficult moments but is
also full of uncertainty, both economically and politically, within the
region, as well as through the traits that characterize the global system and
international economic relations, including trade.
From outside the region, in addition to the systemic economic down-
turn that has persisted since the outbreak of the crisis in 2008, the serious
problems in trade multilateralism expressed in the Doha Round crisis and
the end of the “boom” for primary products, we can add the uncertainties
created by Brexit, the future development of the EU and, above all, the
arrival of Donald Trump to the US government. This could mark the
beginning of a period of increased protectionism, of trade wars, and
greater use of “economic nationalism” —with the removal of the USA
from the TTP, anti-immigrant politics, and questioning of the NAFTA, as
steps in this direction. To all of these can be added uncertainties about the
role that China will play as a global actor in response to the new strategies
for global insertion and international relations that the US government
seems prepared to deploy.
Within the region, and since 2014, to the heterogeneity characteristic
of the third stage of integration, the fall in export revenues of the recent
four-year period, and the drastic regional economic decline—and of the
intra-regional trade—has been added the predictable continuity of repri-
marization and the changes present in the political situation of the differ-
ent countries, which are already impacting on the operation of different
integration mechanisms. All certainly leading us to a yet more complex
scenario, in which the definition of a “common minimum” in order to
move forward, and the generation of a consensus about improved integra-
tion, will definitely become more difficult.
66 J. ESTAY
Notes
1. Only in September 1965 was LAFTA/LAIA’s Treaty for Payments and
Reciprocal Credits signed, which, despite some changes and additions, is
still in force today.
2. A detailed revision of the contents of the new agreements can be found in
WTO (2011).
3. The original formulation of “competitive liberalization”, which took place
quite some time before the following citation, corresponds to Bergsten
(1996) in which he suggests in an article:
argues that the term is fraught with danger as it intertwines two concepts
that within themselves are contradictory.
9. In addition to the various texts mentioned previously, further examples of
research with assessments of this period are Devlin and Ffrench-Davis
(1999), Devlin and Estevadeordal (2001), Phillips (2003), Bouzas (2005),
Sanahuja (2007), Bouzas et al. (2008), Torrent (2009), Wollrad et al.
(2011), and Briceño (2011).
10. In particular, the MERCOSUR, which in the first five years of the 2000s—
specifically with the signing of the Consensus of Buenos Aires by Kirchner
and Lula in October 2003—signified a move towards a more integral pro-
file, with an extension of its objectives and the incorporation of new areas,
which in part implied the recuperation of the previous content of the
Treaty of Asuncion, mentioned in previous paragraphs, and, in part, cor-
responded to the new profile of regional integration that was taking shape.
11. Three books that collate the research referring to the impact of extractiv-
ism in different areas of LA and the resistance that has been generated are
those of Delgado (2013), the OLCA and OCMAL (2014), and Alvarez
et al. (2015).
12. In this respect, the following paragraph of the Panorama de la Inserción
Internacional 2015, of ECLAC, synthesizes the profile of such exports:
“In spite of its dynamism, trade between Latin America and the Caribbean
and China has a number of gaps. The regional exports to this country are
highly concentrated in few countries, products and companies, and basi-
cally consist of primary products. These characteristics are causing a repri-
marization of the regional exports, a high environmental cost, a
concentration of sales to China with a reduced number of economic opera-
tors, an accelerated deindustrialization of the economies and an absence of
indirect dissemination effects […]” (CEPAL 2015: 63).
13. In the case of the “Rest of the LAC” excluding Mexico—which targets
most of its manufactured exports at the US market—for the other coun-
tries the share of manufacturing in its exports to the region is also substan-
tially higher than the share of its total exports.
Bibliography
Acosta, A. 2009. La maldición de la abundancia. Quito: Abya-Yala.
———. 2011. Extractivismo y neoextractivismo: Dos caras de la misma maldición.
In Más allá del desarrollo, Grupo Permanente de Trabajo sobre Alternativas al
Desarrollo. Quito: Abya Yala.
ALADI. 1983. Evolución y estructura del intercambio comercial de los países que
integran la ALADI, 1952–1980. Montevideo: ALADI, March 7.
68 J. ESTAY
———. 2014. El ALBA: una discusión de su modelo, sus resultados y sus perspec-
tivas en Andrés Serbin, Laneydi Martínez y Haroldo Ramanzini Júnior (coords.)
Anuario de Integración No. 10, Coordinadora Regional de Investigaciones
Económicas y Sociales, Argentina.
Burfisher M., R. Sherman, and K. Thierfelder. 2003. Regionalism: Old and New,
Theory and Practice. Ponencia presentada en la Conferencia Internacional
Agricultural Policy Reform and the WTO:Where Are We Heading? Italia, June.
Caetano, G. 2011. Breve historia del MERCOSUR en sus 20 años. Coyuntura e
instituciones (1991–2011). In MERCOSUR 20 años, coordinated by Gerardo
Caetano. Uruguay: CEFIR.
Caldentey. 2000. El desarrollo económico de Centroamérica en el marco de la inte-
gración regional. Honduras: Banco Centroamericano de integración económica.
CEPAL. 1951. Economic survey of Latin America 1949. New York. Available at:
http://repositorio.cepal.org/handle/11362/1003
———. 1959. Recomendaciones acerca de la estructura y normas del Mercado
Común Latinoamericano. Informe que el Grupo de Trabajo del Mercado
Regional Latinoamericano eleva a la Secretaría Ejecutiva de la Comisión
Económica para América Latina con el fin de que sea transmitido al segundo
período de sesiones del Comité de Comercio, February 27. Available at:
http://repositorio.cepal.org/handle/11362/18695
———. 1990. Transformación productiva con equidad. La tarea prioritaria de
América Latina y El Caribe productiva. Santiago de Chile, March.
———. 1992a. Equidad y transformación productiva: un enfoque integrado.
Santiago de Chile.
———. 1992b. Comercio intrazonal de los países de la Asociación Latinoamericana
de Integración, según capítulos de la Clasificación Uniforme para el Comercio
Internacional, revisión 2. Cuaderno Estadístico de la CEPAL, May, Santiago de
Chile, Available at: http://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/4293-comercio-
intrazonal-paises-la-asociacion-latinoamericana-integracion-segun
———. 1994a. El regionalismo abierto en América Latina y el Caribe. La inte-
gración económica al servicio de la transformación productiva con equidad.
Santiago de Chile, January.
———. 1994b. Desarrollo reciente de los procesos de integración en América Latina
y El Caribe. Santiago de Chile, May 5. Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.
org/handle/11362/30243
———. 1994c. El dinamismo reciente del comercio intrarregional de la Asociación
Latinoamericana de Integración (ALADI). Santiago de Chile, August 23.
Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.org/handle/11362/30290
———. 1995a. América Latina y el Caribe: políticas para mejorar su inserción en
la economía mundial. Santiago de Chile, April.
———. 1995b. Desenvolvimiento de los procesos de integración en América Latina
y El Caribe. Santiago de Chile, 16 May, Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.
org/handle/11362/30426
PAST AND PRESENT OF LATIN AMERICAN REGIONALISMS, IN THE FACE... 71
OECD. 1995. Regional Integration and the Multilateral Trading System: Synergy
and Divergence. Paris: OECD.
Oman, C. 1994. Globalisation and Regionalisation: The Challenge for Developing
Countries, OECD. Available at: http://www.eldis.org/vfile/upload/1/docu-
ment/0708/DOC4404.pdf
OMC. 1995. Regionalism and the World Trading System. Ginebra: OMC.
OMC (WTO). 2011. Informe sobre el Comercio Mundial 2011. La OMC y los
acuerdos comerciales preferenciales: de la coexistencia a la coherencia. Ginebra:
OMC. https://www.wto.org/spanish/res_s/publications_s/wtr11_s.htm.
Accessed Apr 2017.
Panagariya, A. and R. Findlay. 1994. A Political-Economy Analysis of Free Trade
Areas and Customs Unions, Policy Research Working Paper No. 1261.
Washington: Banco Mundial. Available at: http://documents.worldbank.org/
curated/en/802761468739131604/pdf/multi0page.pdf
Phillips, N. 2003. The Rise and Fall of Open Regionalism? Comparative Reflections
on Regional Governance in the Southern Cone of Latin America. Third World
Quarterly 24 (2): 217–234.
Preciado, J. 2013. Paradigma social en debate; aportaciones del enfoque geo-
político crítico. La CELAC en la integración autónoma de América Latina. In
América Latina en la crisis global. Problemas y Desafíos, coordinated by Martha
Nélida Ruiz. México: fronterAbierta and Koeyu.
Preciado, J., and A. Florido. 2013. La Comunidad de Estados Latinoamericanos y
Caribeños (CELAC); integración ‘postneoliberal’, neoliberal ortodoxa y con-
trahegemónica. In Nuevos Escenarios para la Integración de América Latina,
cordinated by C. Silva and C. E. Martins. Santiago de Chile: Arcis and
CLACSO.
Puello-Socarrás, J., J. Fal, and L. Castiglioni. 2014. ¿Hacia dónde va la integración
regional en Nuestra América? Un balance necesario. Argentina: FISyP.
Riggirozzi, P. 2012. Re-territorializando consensos: Hacia un regionalismo post-
hegemónico en América Latina. In El regionalismo “post–liberal” en América
Latina y el Caribe: Nuevos actores, nuevos temas, nuevos desafíos Anuario de la
Integración Regional de América Latina y el Gran Caribe 2012, ed. A. Serbin,
L. Martínez, and H. Ramanzini Júnior. Buenos Aires: CRIES.
Riggirozzi, P., and D. Tussie. 2010. Region, Regionness and Regionalism in Latin
America: Towards a New Synthesis, Latin American Trade Network Working Paper
130. Available at: http://www19.iadb.org/intal/intalcdi/PE/2012/10382.pdf
———. 2012. The Rise of Post–Hegemonic Regionalism: The Case of Latin
America. In The Rise of Post-Hegemonic Regionalism, ed. P. Riggirozzi and
D. Tussie. Londres: Springer.
Sáez, S. 2008. La integración en busca de un modelo: los problemas de convergencia
en América Latina y el Caribe. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
Saludjian, A. 2004. Hacia otra integración sudamericana: Criticas al MERCOSUR
Neoliberal. Buenos Aires: Libros del Zorzal.
PAST AND PRESENT OF LATIN AMERICAN REGIONALISMS, IN THE FACE... 75
Svampa, M., and A. Slipak. 2015. China en América Latina: del Consenso de los
Commodities al Consenso de Beijing. Ensambles 2 (3): 34–63. Argentina.
Torrent, R. 2009. La integración regional ante un nuevo cambio de paradigma:
reflexiones desde una perspectiva histórica y comparada. Guatemala: Secretaría de
la integración económica centroamericana.
Vaillant, M. 2007. Convergencias y divergencias en la integración sudamericana.
Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
Vázquez López, R. 2011. Integración económica en América Latina: la visión
teórica de la CEPAL confrontada con la evolución del proyecto en la región.
Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Science., ESAN, Perú 16
(31): 107–118.
Viner, J. 1950. The customs Union Issue. Nueva York: Carnegie Endowment for
International Peace.
Vivares, E., P. Torres, and K. Cvetich. 2010. Enfoques y cárceles conceptuales en
el entendimiento de los nuevos regionalismos latinoamericanos. In Desafíos
estratégicos del regionalismo contemporáneo: CELAC e Iberoamérica, ed.
A. Bonilla and I. Álvarez. San José: Secretaría General de FLACSO.
Winters, L.A. 1996. Regionalism Versus Multilateralism, Policy Research Working
Paper No. 1687. Washington, DC: World Bank, International Economics
Department, International Trade Division.
Wollrad, D., G. Maihold, and M. Mols, eds. 2011. La agenda internacional de
América Latina: entre nuevas y viejas alianzas. Buenos Aires: Nueva Sociedad.
Yepe, R. 2014. CELAC y el multilateralismo regional. In Desafíos estratégicos del
regionalismo contemporáneo: CELAC e Iberoamérica, ed. Adrián Bonilla e Isabel
Álvarez. San José: Secretaría General de FLACSO.
Zoellick, R. 2002. Unleashing the Trade Winds. The Economist, December 13.
CHAPTER 4
Steen Christensen
Introduction
This chapter analyzes China-South America relations since the beginning
of the twenty-first century, a period in which China has gained a strong
presence in South America (Brandt et al. 2012: 3). It focuses mainly on
bilateral economic relations between China and South American coun-
tries, but also considers a more comprehensive set of interconnected
issues, such as geopolitics, alliance patterns, and domestic politics in South
American countries, and how this connects to China-South America
relations.
The analysis is oriented by a comparative approach that considers three
“types” of South American countries. The three typologies are based on
three elements: economic policy, foreign policy, and economic develop-
ment model. These elements are considered to be potentially significant
when comparing the relations of different South American countries with
China. The first category is the “liberal” category, exemplified in this anal-
ysis by Peru and Chile. This category is characterized by liberal market-
oriented economic policies, foreign policies guided by commercial
S. Christensen (*)
Institut for Kultur og Globale Studier, Aalborg University, Aalborg, Denmark
infrastructure and in the oil sector is thus growing strongly. In this way,
China seems set to live up to its promise in the China-CELAC Cooperation
Plan 2015–2019 of stepping up trade and investment relations with LAC
(Rosales 2015: 67–76) in the case of Peru. Finally, China has also become
an important lender to Peru during the last decade (OECD, UN, CAF
2015: 211–212).
Economic relations between the two countries take on a decidedly
North-South pattern: China imports commodities from Peru and exports
manufacturing products. A huge 95% of Chinese exports to Peru are from
this sector and is dominated by relatively advance segments of manufactur-
ing. Although competition from Chinese manufacturing is quite relevant,
Peru maintains an important manufacturing capacity (Sanborn and Chonn
2015: 8).
Of the five countries emphasized in this analysis, Peru ran the biggest
trade deficit in 2014, though its deficit of US$1445 billion is a far cry
from Mexico’s deficit of more than US$60 billion in that same year
(Rosales 2015: 41).
The general focus of the Peruvian government’s policy towards China
follows a liberal commercially oriented focus. Peru does not seem inter-
ested in entering into the realm of geopolitics with regard to the possible
competition between China and the USA for influence in the region.
Nevertheless, Peru’s room of maneuver and thus autonomous policy space
has increased since 1990. This is, in large part, thanks to its economic
strengthening, but China’s rising importance as an economic partner, as
well as Peru’s own economic diversification strategy, have also contributed
towards this situation as they strongly reduced Peru’s economic depen-
dency on the USA.
Chile’s relationship with China is similar to Peru’s. It is guided by a
liberal commercial strategy and its strategy of diversification. It emphasizes
bilateral economic relations and does not emphasize geopolitics. China
and the USA are key economic partners for Chile, as in the case of Peru.
Unlike Peru, Chile did not face a foreign debt crisis in the early 1990s.
Chile introduced a very orthodox neoliberal economic strategy in the 70s
during the dictatorship of Augusto Pinochet (Rindefjäll 2009: 180),
although Chile did not privatize copper, which is a key export resource for
Chile, and state-owned CODELCO remained the dominant actor in the
copper sector. Chile’s abandonment of the import substitution and indus-
trialization strategy in the 70s led to a tendency towards de-industrialization
(Castillo and Martins Neto 2016: 12), and the orthodox neoliberal
THE IMPACT OF CHINA ON SOUTH AMERICA POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC... 81
and costly nationalization strategy in the oil sector and in other sectors.
Venezuela’s strategy of moving towards socialism and the government’s
aggressive anti-imperialist rhetoric worsened the situation further as
Venezuela’s creditworthiness suffered a severe blow in international finan-
cial markets (ECLAC 2015a: 73).
In 2009, China had become Venezuela’s third biggest export market
and its fourth biggest source of imports (Dussel Peters 2011: 94). China
also became increasingly important as a lender and as an investor, particu-
larly in the oil sector. Venezuela was by far the biggest recipient of lending
from Chinese public banks between 2005 and 2016 (Gallagher and Myers
2016). Many development cooperation projects and joint productive
projects were celebrated (Giacalone and Briceño-Ruiz 2013), and
Venezuela became increasingly dependent on China, although the USA
remained its largest export destination (García Agustín 2016: 105–106).
With this support as well as with higher oil prices again, Venezuela achieved
decent economic growth results in 2011 and 2012. However, the interna-
tional financial crisis had provoked a severe worsening of the Venezuelan
financial situation, and when oil prices started falling again from 2013,
Venezuela lost control of its financial situation. The Venezuelan economy
is currently in a deep crisis with an expected negative economic growth of
8.0% in 2016 and an expected contraction of 4.0% in 2017 (ECLAC
2016b).
In the chaotic economic, social, and financial situation this has created,
the Nicolás Maduro government is facing strong political opposition. The
opposition is questioning the lack of transparency in the credit dealings
between the Venezuelan government and China and it criticizes the risk to
Venezuelan sovereignty that relations with China imply, according to its
view (Pérez Flores and Jatobá 2016: 140–141). This situation introduces
uncertainty as to Venezuela’s future development strategies as well as to its
relationship with China.
However, an eventual future liberal government is not likely to pursue
an anti-American foreign policy and would most likely follow a more lib-
eral orientation both in terms of foreign policy and economic policy. This
will most likely not mean that China will lose importance for Venezuela,
since China plays a significant role for Venezuela.
However, the preference for China-based cooperation and alliances in
global politics is likely to give way to a new approach from Venezuela.
China on its part can also not be counted on for unlimited financial
support. The Chinese government has recently expressed concerns about
86 S. CHRISTENSEN
However, unlike the other countries analyzed, Brazil emerged from the
debt crisis of the 80s with a highly diversified economic development
model with a relatively strong manufacturing sector, although the share of
the manufacturing sector in total GDP had fallen a little since its peak in
the early 80s. The manufacturing sector’s share in overall employment
peaked in the late 80s and then saw a major decline in the 90s (Castillo
and Martins Neto 2016: 8 and 13).
In 2000, just 2% of Brazilian exports went to China; Brazil’s 12th larg-
est export destination (Rosales and Kuwayama 2012: 78; Dussel Peters
2011: 94), although Brazil and China had celebrated a strategic partner-
ship in 1993.
Bilateral relations developed further during the presidency of Lula da
Silva (2003–2010). In 2004, China’s President Hu Jintao visited Brazil
promising to intensify bilateral relations. For this purpose, the two gov-
ernments agreed on the establishment of a COSBAN (Tavares Maciel and
Nedal 2011: 243), and Brazil accepted China as a “market economy”.
Inside Brazil this measure was controversial and met opposition from the
representatives of the manufacturing sector, headed by the São Paulo
branch FIESP, which found that China should not be considered a market
economy due to the nature of the link between the Chinese government
and the Chinese productive system. Accepting China as a market economy
made it more complicated to use safeguard mechanisms against China at
the WTO and thus constituted a major competitive challenge for the man-
ufacturing sector (Vadell 2013: 51; Pérez Flores and Jatobá 2016: 145).
Bilateral trade rose dramatically in the decade of the 2000s in response
to the commodity boom (2003–2008) and Chinese manufacturing
exports to Brazil. Brazilian exports to China were dominated by soybeans
and iron ore. With the growing price and export volume of these com-
modities China became Brazil’s greatest export market in 2009 with a
13.2% share (Rosales and Kuwayama 2012: 76 and 78).
Exports to China kept rising until 2013 when bilateral trade between the
two countries reached a historical record of US$83.3 billion (Brun 2016:
201–202).Growing export receipts helped Brazil stabilize its economy,
build up reserves, and to achieve a period of dynamic economic growth
until a short-lived economic recession hit in 2008 and 2009, as a conse-
quence of the international financial crisis. As in the case of Chile, Peru, and
Bolivia, the Brazilian government pursued prudent m acroeconomic policies
with high primary budget surpluses and foreign trade surpluses. The gov-
ernment, furthermore, introduced a development strategy that emphasized
90 S. CHRISTENSEN
greater active state intervention in the economy than in the neoliberal 90s.
State-business cooperation was a significant component of the strategy. The
government cooperated with the industrial sector in order to promote its
expansion and to work against the de-industrialization that had been expe-
rienced in the 90s (Coutinho 2007). This led to a significant increase in
employment in the manufacturing sector until 2008 (Castillo and Martins
Neto 2016: 13). At the same time, the government also backed the agricul-
tural sector, for instance, through its activist international trade policy in the
WTO where it formed a South-South coalition, the G20, with countries
such as China, India, South Africa, and several LA countries. The purpose
was to promote the liberalization of agricultural markets in developed coun-
tries (Christensen 2012).
In spite of participating in the G20 coalition, the Chinese leadership
stressed that its priority in relations with LA as a whole was strictly focused
on the economic area, as it wanted to calm potential US worries of China
becoming a challenge to US influence in the region (Vadell et al. 2014:
100). Brazil, in turn, was more openly seeking to strengthen its influence
on the global political scene through different South-South coalitions.
Brazil’s economic downturn in late 2008 and in 2009 turned out to be
short-lived. In late 2009, Brazil resumed its economic growth path with
the use of counter-cyclical policies. Chinese growing imports and improved
commodity prices contributed to the resumption of Brazilian growth
(Brun 2016: 202). At the same time, China started to invest more in
Brazil and to offer loans. In 2009, when credit conditions were difficult
due to the international financial crisis, the Chinese Development Bank
and the Brazilian state-owned oil company, Petrobras, agreed on a US$10
billion loan-for-oil deal (Wise 2016: 29). In 2010, Chinese FDI in Brazil
rose tremendously from a very low level (Oviedo 2014). Investments were
largely directed towards oil and mining (Bernal-Meza 2016: 36). A
US$7.1 billion investment by Sinopec in the oil sector was the biggest
individual investment (Planas 2011). Economic relations with China thus
helped Brazil to weather the economic crisis, and in 2010, Brazil achieved
7.5% economic growth.
As a reaction to the international financial crisis, China began to put
more emphasis on its relations with Brazil and on South-South relations
more generally (Haibin 2010: 186). Xing Li (2016: 1) argues that the
international financial crisis led to a greater assertiveness of China on the
global political scene. The so-called “emerging powers” were also increas-
ingly recognized as important global political players by the dominant
THE IMPACT OF CHINA ON SOUTH AMERICA POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC... 91
developed countries. For instance, the USA, that was hosting the 2008
meeting of the G8, decided to invite the countries of the financial G20 to
the meeting. This group includes the greatest economies in the world and,
therefore, also China, India, and Brazil. This changed the political dynam-
ics of global economic governance (Visentini 2013) as the BRIC coun-
tries, Brazil, Russia, India, andChina, started to coordinate their
negotiating positions within the G20. In 2009, the BRIC countries had
their first Presidential summit thus institutionalizing their network coop-
eration in something that seems like an informal coalition (Christensen
2013). Similarly, Brazil collaborated in the BASIC coalition with China,
India, and South Africa in negotiations on global climate change politics.
China-Brazil relations were further strengthened with the signing in 2010
of a Joint Action Plan for the period 2010–2014. The plan focused both
on bilateral relations and on their collaboration on a range of multilateral
issues (Haibin 2010: 186).
In spite of these favorable developments in China-Brazil relations, ten-
sions between the two countries started to grow on the bilateral economic
front due to a negative Brazilian perception of the North-South pattern of
bilateral economic relations. A number of issues provoked dissatisfaction
from the Brazilian side, particularly the growing competitive pressure
from China in the manufacturing sector. The issue of the revaluation of
the Brazilian exchange rate was of great importance to the competitive
pressure. The Brazilian Real strengthened for a number of reasons. One
was the US policy of monetary easing. Another was China’s defensive
exchange rate policy. A third reason was the “Dutch Disease” phenome-
non that affected Brazil due its high export receipts from commodities.
Brazil’s counter-cyclical expansionary policies during the financial crisis
also contributed towards this outcome, as did the inflow of financial spec-
ulative investments in Brazil (Christensen 2013). Between early 2009 and
January 2011, the Brazilian Real thus rose by 38% against the US$
(Economist, January 13, Economist 2011), as well as it strengthened
against the Chinese currency.
This led to a surge in imports, not the least from China. In 2010,
FIESP criticized “excessive imports” of consumer goods and the loss of
thousands of jobs in the manufacturing sector to China (ibid). The FIESP
President, Paulo Skaf, pointed out that, although Brazil had a trade sur-
plus with China in 2010, there was a Brazilian deficit of around US$25
billion in manufacturing sector trade with China (Vadell 2013: 53). The
Brazilian finance minister, Guido Mantega, spoke of a “currency war” or
92 S. CHRISTENSEN
an indirect “trade war” among Brazil, the USA and China (Economist,
January 13, Economist 2011). This concern was shared by Dilma Rousseff
(Vadell 2013: 52), who became Brazil’s new President in 2011. She
argued that bilateral economic relations should move “beyond comple-
mentarity” and allow for greater Brazilian manufacturing exports to China
(Guilhon-Albuquerque 2014). Her government, and the Lula govern-
ment before her, introduced a range of policies aimed at promoting
Brazilian manufacturing production. In 2010, the government introduced
a “buy national” public procurement policy aimed at favoring national
producers (Fleischer July 30, 2010). Another policy in 2010, made
Petrobras participation of at least 30% in all oil exploration mandatory.
Furthermore, in 2010, Brazil put limits on the purchase or control of land
by foreign capital in Brazil in order to avoid “land grabbing”. This policy
was to a large extent a reaction to growing Chinese interest in investing in
the Brazilian soybean sector (Hearn 2015: 306–311).
Furthermore, in 2011, the Dilma government introduced a new indus-
trial development policy, “Brasil Maior” (Greater Brazil) after having
reached an understanding with the industrial sector through government-
business dialog (Ogier 2013). These initiatives did little to improve the
situation of the Brazilian manufacturing sector, though. It has remained
basically stagnant since 2012 (Christensen 2016a, b: 100). Recently, it has
even gone into negative terrain (Economist October 29, 2016a, b).
Similarly, economic growth has faltered since then, not the least due to
volatility in commodity export prices. This has led to growing external
economic imbalances.
In 2015, Brazil experienced negative economic growth. In this context,
Brazil has received growing amounts of Chinese lending, part of which
went to Petrobras in a loan-for-oil deal as in 2009. Furthermore, a US$20
billion Brazil-China Fund of Cooperation aimed at expanding productive
capacity in Brazil was created in 2015 with two-thirds of the funding from
China. Chinese FDI to Brazil has been growing since 2013 and it has
gone through a diversification towards infrastructural investments and
market-seeking investments in the manufacturing and services sectors
(Brun 2016: 200). This development is in line with the Chinese “going
out” strategy after the international financial crisis (Vadell et al. 2014:
102; Li 2016: 1 and 16–17) that aims at Chinese global investment diver-
sification and China’s political strengthening on the global scene. It can be
seen as a strategy of competing with the USA for influence in different
world regions (see e.g., Li 2016: 16–17). In spite of tensions over trade
THE IMPACT OF CHINA ON SOUTH AMERICA POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC... 93
issues, China and Brazil have thus maintained close bilateral economic
relations as well as pursuing common agendas on the global political scene
in different international coalitions.
In 2016, President Dilma was impeached, and her vice-President,
Michel Temer, from the coalition party PMDB, took over the presidency.
The new leadership has taken new steps that could be seen as a correction
in the strategy pursued by the PT-led governments. The new government
may be leaning towards a foreign policy strategy and an economic strat-
egy similar to that of the liberal countries that now include Argentina
after Mauricio Macri took over power in 2015. In the realm of economic
policy, the Temer government is dropping the local content policy intro-
duced in 2010 as well as the policy guaranteeing a minimum investment
share of at least 30% to Petrobras in all oil exploration projects in the
pre-salt petroleum deposits (under the seabed) (Fleischer, October 7,
2016a). Transpetro, a private company in the oil sector, recently
announced that it had cancelled the construction of 17 oil tankers by
Brazilian shipbuilders as the policy of Lula and Dilma of obliging the
company to buy from Brazilian producers has been discontinued
(Fleischer, October 28, 2016c). In spite of a 5.2% fall in industrial pro-
duction in Brazil between August 2015 and August 2016 (ibid), the
Temer government has thus introduced a more liberal policy in the area
of public procurement.
The fiscal situation is still deteriorating, and public debt has moved up
over 70% of GDP (Fleischer, October 7, 2016a), and Temer has made fis-
cal consolidation his government’s number one priority (CELC 2016: 4).
In October, Michel Temer participated in the 2016 BRICS summit in
India. Russian President Putin, however, did not wish to meet with him
due to issues that the Russian President has had with the impeachment of
Dilma. Thus, the BRICS coalition seems hurt. After the BRICS Summit,
Temer went to Japan where he attended a meeting of Japanese and
Brazilian business leaders and had a long talk with Japanese Prime Minister,
Shinzo Abe. This was the first visit of a Brazilian president to Japan in 15
years (Fleischer, October 21, 2016b).
The Temer government seems to be focusing on a commercial agenda
that no longer emphasizes South-South relations from a geopolitical stra-
tegic position. Trade agreements with developed countries have moved up
amongst the top priorities in Brazil’s foreign policy. The policy should not
be seen as being against China, though. Brazil still collaborates with China
and Chinese investments in Brazil remain solid (CELC 2016: 10).
94 S. CHRISTENSEN
Conclusion
The historical comparative analysis of the five South American cases
grouped into three typologies allow us to draw a number of conclusions
on recent China-South America relations.
Relations between China and South American countries intensified
after the year 2000 for all three typologies. This intensification was par-
ticularly caused by China’s economic rise and impact on international
commodity prices. China’s growing import of commodities and its impact
on commodity prices was an opportunity for all of the countries studied,
even for Bolivia whose exports to China were very limited. Rising prices of
commodity exports helped all five countries assure economic strengthen-
ing and greater room of maneuver during the commodity boom
(2003–2008), and they all pursued development strategies based on the
centrality of commodity exports, although particularly Brazil also had
some emphasis on industrial policy.
China’s main focus was on bilateral economic relations, initially with an
emphasis on access to commodity imports needed in the Chinese develop-
ment process but also with an interest in the diversification of its manufac-
turing exports. In the early part of the 2000s, trade relations were most
developed with those countries that specialized in the mining sector, i.e.,
Chile and Peru. This was followed by growing trade and economic rela-
tions with oil producing countries and then countries with significant agri-
cultural production, particularly soy. At the end of the decade, China was
amongst the main economic partners for all of the case countries with the
exception of Bolivia due to its particular specialization in the gas sector.
Venezuela on its part became increasingly dependent on Chinese financ-
ing in the context and in the aftermath of the international financial crisis
when faced with volatile oil prices and poor access to international capital
markets. The other four case countries managed this crisis better due to
their stronger financial situations.
The international financial crisis also led to greater emphasis on South-
South collaboration through coalitions. This was particularly relevant in
the case of Brazil due to its stronger role in the international system.
In the second decade of the twentieth century, China has become
extremely central from the perspective of all of the five country cases,
especially due to its contribution to external financing of development
through FDI and loans, which has become increasingly important after
the end of the commodity boom in 2013. This particularly is the case for
THE IMPACT OF CHINA ON SOUTH AMERICA POLITICAL AND ECONOMIC... 95
Bibliography
Armony, A.C. 2011. The China-Latin America Relationship: Convergences and
Divergences. In China Engages Latin America: Tracing the Trajectory, ed.
A.H. Hearn and J. León-Manriquez, 23–50. Boulder/London: Lynne Rienner.
Bauman, R. 2009. Some Recent Features of Brazil-China Economic Relations
(Preliminary Version). Brazilian: Economic Commission for Latin America and
the Caribbean.
Bernal-Meza, R. 2016. China and Latin America Relations: The Win-Win
Rhetoric. In Journal of China and International Relations, Special Edition:
China-Latin America Relations in an Era of Changing World Order, ed.
S.F. Christensen and D.R.S. Becard, 27–43. Aalborg: Journal of China and
International Relations.
Brandt, J. et al. 2012. Chinese Engagement in Latin America and the Caribbean:
Implications for US Foreign Policy. Washington, DC: American University
School of International Service. Available at: http://www.american.edu/sis/
usfp/upload/Chinese-Engagement-in-LAC-AU_US-Congress-FINAL.pdf.
Brun, É. 2016. Brail-China: Varios Torrentes, Un Río. In Poderes Emergentes y
Cooperación Sur-Sur: Perspectivas desde el Sur Global, ed. G. Lechini and
C. Giaccaglia, 193–210. Rosario: UNR Editora.
96 S. CHRISTENSEN
———. 2015b. Preliminary Overview of the Economies of Latin America and the
Caribbean. Santiago: Economic Commission for Latin America and the
Caribbean.
———. 2016a. Panorama de la Inserción Internacional de América Latina y el
Caribe: La región frente a las tensiones de la globalzación. Santiago: Economic
Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean.
———. 2016b. Actualización de proyecciones de crecimiento de América Latina y el
Caribe en 2016 y 2017. Downloaded December 8, 2016 from http://www.
cepal.org/sites/default/files/pr/files/tabla_proyecciones_octubre2016.pdf.
Santiago: Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean.
Economist. 2011. Waging the Currency War, January 13. Available at: www.econ-
omist.com/node/17906027.
———. 2016a. Economic and Financial Indicators, September 17.
———. 2016b. Economic and Financial Indicators, October 29.
Ellis, R.E. 2016. Chinese Engagement in Bolivia, May 20. Available at: http://
latinamericagoesglobal.org/2016/05/chinese-engagement-bolivia/.
Fiori, J.L. 2013. O Brasil e seu “Entorno Estratégico” na Primeira Década do
Século XXI. In 10 anos de governos Pós-neoliberais no Brasil: Lula e Dilma, orga-
nized by E. Sader, 13–51. São Paulo: Biotempo Editorial .
Fleischer, D. 2010. Brazil Focus, July 24–30 (weekly report), 30 July, Contacted at:
[email protected].
———. 2016a. Brazil Focus, October 1–7 (weekly report), 7 October, Contacted
at: [email protected].
———. 2016b. Brazil Focus, October 15–21 (weekly report), 21 October,
Contacted at: [email protected].
———. 2016c. Brazil Focus, October 22–28 (weekly report), 28 October,
Contacted at: [email protected].
Frecchero, J.I. 2012. The Return of the Dragon: China’s Transformation and Its
New International Role and Expansion in Latin America. In The Rise of China:
The Impact on Semi-Pheriphery and Periphery Countries, ed. X. Li X and
S.F. Christensen, 133–152. Aalborg: Aalborg University Press.
Gallagher, K.P., and M. Myers. 2016. China Latin America Finance Database.
Washington: Inter-American Dialogue. Available at: http://www.thedialogue.
org/agenda/programs/china/.
García Agustín, O. 2016. Venezuela and China: Independency and Dependency in
the Context of Interdependent Hegemony. In Journal of China and
International Relations, Special Edition: China-Latin America Relations in an
Era of Changing World Order, ed. S.F. Christensen and D.R.S. Becard,
104–127. Aalborg: Journal of China and International Relations.
Giacalone, R., and J. Briceño Rui. 2013. The Chinese-Venezuelan Oil Agreements:
Material and Nonmaterial Goals. Latin American Policy 4 (1): 76–92.
Guilhon-Albuquerque, J.A. 2014. Brazil, China, US: A Triangular Relation?
Revista Brasileira de Política Internacional, Special Edition 57: 108–120.
98 S. CHRISTENSEN
Leonardo E. Stanley and José M. Fernández Alonso
Introduction
Defined as the complex of resources assigned to the enhancing of socio-
economic structures and dynamics within a specific political entity,—
usually a State, but not exclusively—development financing comprises
both public and private funds and actors. On the one hand, funds could
be obtained from national or supra-national (public funded) institutions
or from private sources (bonds, banks, etc.)1 On the other hand, funds
could be directed to finance private agents´ projects (corporate financing)
or they go to finance public projects (public debt). The mobilization of
domestic resources in LA has historically been limited. In this context,
political-economic authorities in the region were compelled to rely on
foreign funds in order to forge development projects, frequently associ-
ated with infrastructure necessities: the construction of railways and ports
in the late nineteenth century, the expansion of roads and basic facilities
for the provision of public services during the twientieth century, or the
generation of wind farms, or rapid transit systems in present days.
In spite of being a constant, this need for external financing did not
always have equal importance. Likewise, the amounts and mechanisms
regarding the need for capital varied in the course of time, together with
the adjustments in the international financial system and LA development
strategies.
Without the purpose to display a detailed historical approach, the argu-
ment merely note that, in recent decades, the access of South American
countries to development financing has gone through substantial changes.
In this respect, it could be stated that, in spite of the low savings to
GDP ratio traditionally observed in the region, this problem became par-
ticularly significant in the 70s, when governments decided to phase out
the ISI policies and disarticulate the so-called financial “repressed model”.
In this regard, it should be noted that after the liberalization of the capital
account, savings were no longer required to match investment necessities.
At the same time, the post WWII financial architecture suddenly collapsed,
transforming development financing with it. Cross-border funds began to
increase, alongside the likelihood of financial crisis on a global scale as we
have repeatedly observed since then.
In order to obtain funds, sovereign nations were somewhat forced to
go into the markets, whose conditions and institutions would cyclically
challenge them, as observed after 1982 when the LA debt saga erupted. A
decade later, international debt markets experienced a “revolution”, as
transnational bank loans lost their prominence, and bond financing
bloomed. Most LA bonds were issued under New York jurisdiction, with
sovereign nations unaware of the legal conditions the market was impos-
ing on them.
The role of multilateral lending agencies also changed during these
years, particularly after the collapse of the Bretton Woods order.
Historically, development financing came from traditional IFIs, namely,
globally funded agencies as the World Bank or from institutions estab-
lished on a regional level such as the IADB and the CAF, among others.
After the turn of the century, the financial development setting became
more complex when other international agents gained presence: the PRC,
in particular, followed by other members of the BRICS coalition (Brazil,
Russia, India, and South Africa). In this context, it should be noted that
the decision of the Chinese authorities to compete globally—under the
so-called “go global” strategy—and to internationalize the Renminbi
THE CHANGING PROBLEM OF REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE... 103
When the Chinese economic reforms were launched in the early 80s, its
economy, measured by GDP, was almost a quarter of the total GDP of
LAC. Nowadays, it is twice the size and increasing. Only in a few decades,
the PRC has become a leading world-factory producer, a giant global
trader, and a leading innovative country. In fact, China now ranks second
worldwide just behind the US economy, although it remains categorized
as a middle income country. Likewise, and after decades of being ranked
amongst the largest recipients of foreign direct investments, its go out pol-
icy and a fierce appetite first for resources and recently for technology
transformed China in a net capital exporter.
Due to the structural characteristics of its political system, the Chinese
authorities have always maintained a leading role in the process of direct-
ing outward capital flows. Notwithstanding the foregoing, an important
number of Chinese private firms have recently begun to establish invest-
ments abroad.
The go out policy was managed by governmental financing sources
since the launch and implementation of the aforementioned strategy,
involving a variety of public agencies and political actors, initially aimed at
financing infrastructure projects abroad. As we will see, infrastructure
projects were mainly financed by two banking institutions: the China
ExIm bank and the CDB.
THE CHANGING PROBLEM OF REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE... 107
transforming their old lending practices. For example, they are becoming
forced to take environmental assessments into account or to include trans-
parency clauses in their credits.
Historically, their function as a donor was free from non-economic
assessments: Chinese credits were basically benefiting sovereign countries
in the South not really interested in governance related issues. However,
funds are no longer confined to developing partners, but are now becom-
ing global.
As a matter of fact, China is increasingly involved in financing develop-
ment projects all around the world. Development financing aid can be
traced back to the early years of communism in government, in the form
of donations directed to “friendly” regimes around the world with one
main conditionality: the recognition of the One China principle. To this
we should add the principle of non-interference and mutual benefit. In
summary, China’s development financing within the South-South coop-
eration framework initiated by Mao Zedong in the middle 50s (Xu and
Carey 2015a, b). Modern era (and widely dispersed) financing recognizes
its roots in Africa (Brautigam 2011; Cheng-Hin 2015),8 as China main-
tained deeper political and economic relations with the region since the
early 50s (Avendaño 2013).9
China’s financial aid continued after Deng Xiaoping’s reforms, although
the country now also benefitted from multilateral lending and external aid
packages.10 This second phase would embrace a strong orientation towards
economic development— mainly limited to the African continent.11
Furthermore, and in contrast to old development packages where political
interests predominate new loans, objectives become wider in scope
although economically driven and basically directed to boost Chinese eco-
nomic presence abroad.12
During both stages, Chinese financing was tied to governmental sources
and bilateral negotiations. After the financial reforms were passed, devel-
opmental funds began to be mediated by the China ExIm Bank and the
CDB, financial entities that were both created during the mid-90s and
cataloged as policy (financial) entities.13 As such, credits remain subordi-
nate to the approval of the MOFCOM, in both cases. Although some of
the credits granted by China’s policy banks are concessional, most of
the loans qualify as non-concessional, in the sense that they are tied to
market-based interest rates.14 Furthermore, Chinese credits have often
profited from sovereign guarantees, basically associated to earnings from
the export of natural resources—a practise originally introduced by Japan
THE CHANGING PROBLEM OF REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE... 109
$40,00,000.00
$30,00,000.00
$20,00,000.00
$10,00,000.00
$0.00
1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010 2014
18.0%
12.0%
6.0%
0.0%
2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Year
GDP (%) OFDI
a third stage of financing, now expanding the scope of their credits and
borrowers.
China launched a series of dialogs with their counterparts, first in the
African continent and more recently in the region, followed by a series of
initiatives for cooperation that later induced the creation of particular
financial schemes (for instance, the CADF).28 As for the region, Chinese
lending gained relevance after the global financial crisis (Gallagher et al.
2012). In 2009, China decided to join the IADB, after contributing
US$350 million in funding. Later, this bank received funds from the Bank
of China and the ExIm Bank of China (Pérez Roldán et al. 2016). More
recently, Chinese authorities decided to sign a cooperation package with
the CELAC, aimed to increase the dragon’s financial assistance in the
region.29
Conclusions
Development financing might be considered as one of the recurrent prob-
lems faced by LA countries since their independence. Short of funds, gov-
ernments in the region had periodically turned to foreign capital in order
to advance with their investments projects. During their time as indepen-
dent States, they have made use of different sources and mechanisms in
order to finance its developmental needs. Each of these financing mecha-
nisms has been consistent with a specific international order and a particu-
lar model of development adopted in the region.
At first, LA countries—especially the South Americans ones— resorted
to bank loans and the bond market. These resources allowed them not
only to build their own States during their first years of independence but
also to define an international economic insertion based on an agro-export
model. However, the structural changes reported during the first decades
of twentieth century altered the aforementioned financial logic and the
international economic strategy. As a consequence of this new context, LA
governments decided to articulate an ISI model. This model was funded
mainly with their own resources, but also with external ones. In this
regard, it must be emphasized that since their institutionalization after
WWII, IFI’s—development Banks, in particular—have traditionally
focused on mobilizing long-term funds towards strategic sectors under
this new developmental model. Infrastructure was, of course, one of those
critical sectors. Nevertheless, these financial development mechanisms
eroded concurrently with the erosion of the Bretton Woods’ agreement.
THE CHANGING PROBLEM OF REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE... 115
After the arrival of the Debt Crisis in the first half of the 80s, the funds
provided by IFI were conditioned to the implementation of political and
economic reforms in order to create a neoliberal model under the
“Washington Consensus” paradigm.
During the boom in commodity prices, public funding constraints were
lifted and developmental financing problems faded. However, once the
boom transformed into a burst, policy-makers began to realize the chal-
lenges imposed by foreign lending and the insufficient funds maintained
to foster economic development, including largely forgotten infrastruc-
ture needs. Once again, the government of the region proved incapable to
meet development necessities with long term financing. Such dynamics in
financing, although autonomous, demonstrated a lack of sustainability
over time.
Regardless of the cycle, long-term development financing is still rele-
vant. Infrastructure is now considered to be, as in the past, key to eco-
nomic growth and development. Although relevant during the aftermath
of WWII, financial institutions located in Washington have forgotten this
premise. Nowadays, China seems to have become a critical agent of
change, called upon to fill the gap. In recent years, the PRC’s ascent
induced a revival of bilateralism, first benefiting Africa but recently expand-
ing to other latitudes. Afterwards, a South-South pattern emerged, which
made the availability of funds affordable and somewhat lifted political con-
straints. After years of conditionalities of the IMF, and structural reform
packages from the World Bank, the arrival of China was seen as a panacea
for developing countries’ rulers. In spite of the criticism that this funding
could cause, Chinese financing came to fill the gap left by traditional
donors and multilateralism.
Regardless of the sources, financing collateral obligations start to
recurrently constrain the region’s growth ambitions, when funds are
exogenous and long-term developmental objectives remain unclear.
When lenders are called upon to fill this gap, they will try to impose
their conditions, as IFIs have done in the past, and China might do right
now. Whether this would change in future would depend on ourselves,
by making our economies more resilient to external shocks, by improv-
ing our institutions, and overall, by beginning to think of long-term
development.
In light of the above considerations, South American countries– should
strengthen their savings in order to avoid external (political and economic)
conditionalities and construct a sustainable development model.
116 L.E. STANLEY AND J.M. FERNÁNDEZ ALONSO
Notes
1. We do not consider donor funds, as benefited countries are not entitled to
their repayment.
2. Helleiner (2014) describes Harry D. White’s efforts to addressing this
topic at Bretton Woods meetings. Interestingly, US involvement in the
Latin American region during the late 30s and early 40s becomes crucial to
embrace this vision—missions in which White himself and Robert Triffin
were especially involved. These initiatives, in turn, were part of the famous
Good Neighbor policy toward the region installed by US President
F.D. Roosevelt in the 30s.
3. The 1998 Asian financial crisis was a significant event, signaling the begin-
ning of a worldwide movement to condemn the challenges imposed by
unchartered capital flows—including massive support for re-introducing
capital controls. In any case, industrialized countries led by the USA con-
tinued to push for market deregulation and capital account openness.
4. Currency swaps can be viewed as a credit line that both sides can draw
upon at a pre-determined exchange rate. US Fed liquidity swaps lines are
essentially repo transactions based on prevailing exchange rates, whereas
China’s bilateral currency swap agreements are designed to facilitate settle-
ments in renminbi.
5. The swap was initially supposed to last three years and allowed Argentina
to pay Chinese imports with RMB, but Argentina used up most of it in the
first two years, bringing in RMBs to boost the country’s foreign-currency
reserves, which had been on the decline (Buenos Aires Herald, Wednesday
25 December 2015).
6. Previously, the CDB issued an RMB bond in London (RMB 2 billion), the
first by a quasi-sovereign outside of China. The UK government issued a
landmark RMB bond (RMB 3 billion), the first non-Chinese issuance of
sovereignRMBdebthttps://www.gov.uk/government/news/china-chooses-
london-for-its-first-ever-sovereign-renminbi-rmb-bond-issued-outside-of-
china
7. “China’s Xi woos Latin America with $250 bln investments” Reuters.
January 8, 2015.
8. The role of China’s development finance in the “Africa rising” history is
certainly crucial. Guinea, a newly independent socialist government in the
early 60s, obtained an interest free loan from the PRC, a practise that
expanded to other newly-decolonized African states. Years later, China par-
ticipated in the TanZam railway between Tanzania and Zambia, which
involved the participation of Chinese public works companies but also
public funds from China.
9. Chinese (financial development) involvement in the region, on the other
hand, remained weak as most LA governments preferred to side with the
THE CHANGING PROBLEM OF REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE... 117
Bibliography
Avendaño, L. 2013. Lending Money: Latin America and China’s New Engagement.
In African East—Asian Affairs—The China Monitor. Western Cape:
Stellenbosch University, Centre for Chinese Studies.
Bautrigam, D., and K. Gallagher. 2014. Bartering Globalization: China’s
Commodity Backed Finance in Africa and Latin America. Global Policy 5 (3):
346–352.
Brautigam, D. 2011. Chinese Aid in Africa: What, Where, Why, and How Much?
In Rising China: Global Challenges and Opportunities, ed. J. Golley and
L. Song. Canberra: Australia National University Press.
Cheng-Hin, A. 2015. Africa and China’s 21st Century Maritime Silk Road. The
Asia – Pacific Journal 13 (11).
Chwieroth, J.M. 2010. Capital Ideas: The IMF and the Rise of Financial
Liberalization. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Coehlo, J.C. 2012. Reformando as instituições financeiras multilaterais (passado
presente): Banco Mundial e Fundo Monetário Internacional. In As
Transformações do Sistema Financeiro Internacional, organized by M.A. Macedo
Cintra and K. Da Rocha Gomes, vol. 2, 605–648. Brasília: Instituto de Pesquisa
Econômica Aplicada
THE CHANGING PROBLEM OF REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE... 119
Dreher, A., A. Fuchs, B. Parks, A.M. Strange, and M.J. Tierney. 2015. Apples and
Dragon Fruits: The Determinants of Aid and Other Forms of State Financing
from China to Africa. AidData. Available at: http://china.aiddata.org/
publications
Gallagher, K., A. Irwin, and K. Koleski. 2012. New Banks in Town: Chinese Finance
in Latin America. Washington, DC: Inter-American Dialogue. Available at:
http://archive.thedialogue.org/PublicationFiles/TheNewBanksinTown-
FullTextnewversion.pdf.
Helleiner, E. 2014. Forgotten Foundations of Bretton Woods: International
Development and the Making of the Postwar Order. Ithaca: Cornell University
Press.
———. 2016. Legacies of the 2008 Crisis for Global Financial Governance. Global
Summitry 2 (1): 1–12. Available at.: https://academic.oup.com/globalsum-
mitry/article/2/1/1/2355287/Legacies-of-the-2008-Crisis-for-Global-
Financial
IDS. 2015. China’s Development Finance: Ambition, Impact and Transparency.
IDS Policy Brief. www.ids.ac.uk
Liao, S., and D. McDowell. 2014. Redback Rising: China’s Bilateral Swap
Agreements and Renminbi Internationalization. International Studies
Quarterly 59 (3): 1–20.
Lin, J., and Y. Wang. 2015. China´s Contribution to Development Cooperation:
Ideas, Opportunities and Finances. Foundation Pour Les Etudes et Recherches
Sur le Developpment International, Working Paper 119. Available at: http://
www.ferdi.fr/en/publication/p119-china%E2%80%99s-contribution-
development-cooperation
Pérez Roldán, A., et al. 2016. La presencia de China en América Latina: comercio,
inversión y cooperación económica. Medellín: Centro de Estudios Asia Pacifico—
Universidad EAFIT, SOPLA—Konrad Adenauer Stiftüng.
Ruggie, J. 1982. International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded
Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order. International Organization 36
(2): 379–415.
Sanderson, H., and M. Forsythe. 2013. China’s Superbank: Debt, Oil and
Influence—How China Development Bank Is Rewriting the Rules of Finance.
Singapur: Bloomberg Press.
Stanley, L. 2014. El creciente protagonismo de la RPC, la autoridad monetaria y
el “florecer” del RMB. In Economía, Comercio e Inversiones, coordinated by
Enrique Dussel Peters. México: UNAM, Centro de Estudios China—México,
Unión de Universidades de América Latina y el Caribe, Red Académica América
Latina y el Caribe sobre China. Available at: http://www19.iadb.org/intal/
intalcdi/PE/2015/15845.pdf
The Economist. 2016. Non Where to Hide: China’s Newest Export it is Financial
System, for Good and for Ill. May 7th.
120 L.E. STANLEY AND J.M. FERNÁNDEZ ALONSO
Xu, J., and R. Carey. 2015a. China’s International Development Finance. United
Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research,
UNU-WIDER. Available at: https://www.wider.unu.edu/sites/default/files/
WP2015-130-.pdf
———. 2015b. China’s Development Finance: Ambition, Impact and Transparency.
IDS Policy Brief. Available at: https://opendocs.ids.ac.uk/opendocs/
bitstream/handle/123456789/5996/P92_AGID353_ChinaDevFinance_
Online.pdf?sequence=1
Yang, J. 2016. China’s New Development Bank and Infrastructure Led Growth.
Norwegian Institute of International Affairs, Policy Brief 18. Available at:
https://brage.bibsys.no/xmlui/bitstream/id/432913/NUPI_Policy_
Brief_18_16_Jiang.pdf
Yu, Q. 2013. Relocating China’s Foreign Reserves. Brookings, 21 November.
CHAPTER 6
Wilson Pérez-Oviedo, John Cajas-Guijarro,
and María Cristina Vallejo
Introduction
From 1992 to 2014, the international trade network suffered important
structural changes. These changes included the strengthening of the
USA’s economic power after the fall of the Soviet Union in 1991, as well
as China’s (and the Asia-Pacific region in general) higher commercial
expansion and gravitational force, especially after China joined the WTO
in 2001. When it comes to the consequences of this for South America,
changes were felt in two different ways. The first included a favorable
“commodities boom” from 2000 to 2014, and a relative increase in the
exportation of primary goods, exacerbated by their high prices and
Chinese competition with manufactured products that used cheap labor.
From 1992 to 2014, the global trade network suffered substantial changes.
We particularly observe the strengthening of the USA as a central eco-
nomic power after the fall of the Berlin Wall and the commercial rise of
China since 2001. On account of this, we looked at the evolution of the
global trade core, its two members, USA and China, and the relevance to
countries in South America.
In 2014, the USA had the highest relevance index (0.081). If this
country had grown (decreased) by 1%, the rest of the global economy
would have grown (decreased) by 0.081% (see Fig. 6.1). During the 90s,
this relevance increased, probably due to the extraordinary growth in pro-
ductivity that the USA experienced since 1994. For some, that growth was
based on computer science and information technology developments
124 W. PÉREZ-OVIEDO ET AL.
0.10
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
that took place in this country and helped launch a “New Economy”
based on knowledge and information (Castells 2009). This increasing rel-
evance of the USA ended in 2000, which coincided with the burst of the
so-called “bubble of the dot coms” in March of that same year.
On the other hand, the Chinese pro-market reforms, led by Deng
Xiaoping since 1992, allowed China to reach yearly growth rates of
approximately 9% from 1992 to 2000. In addition to its impressive growth
during the 2000s, China increased its relevance in international trade, par-
ticularly since 2001 when it joined the WTO. In 2001, its relevance index
was only 0.013 but, by 2013, it reached 0.057, positioning itself as the
second most important country in the international trade network.
However, several elements will change the role of this country in that net-
work in the future as its lower economic growth, its reduced demand for
primary products, and Chinese leaders assigning more importance to
internal demand.
Russia and India also increased their relevance in the world trade net-
work during this period, but far behind the relevance of China and the
USA (global centers). In the case of South America, Brazil’s relevance
grew from 0.001 to 0.006 from 1992 to 2014. This shows that its
growth was far behind that of global centers, but, as presented below,
this growth was enough to consolidate Brazilian commercial unipolarity
in South America.
SOUTH AMERICA: TRADE AND INTEGRATION IN THE NEW GLOBAL TRADE... 125
140
130
120
110
100
90
80
100
80
60
40
20
Fig. 6.2 Centrality in the global and regional trade networks. (a) Central econo-
mies. (b) Brazil, a sub-center in the South American periphery
SOUTH AMERICA: TRADE AND INTEGRATION IN THE NEW GLOBAL TRADE... 127
Map 6.1 Trade relevance of the USA and China on South America (2013)
(Note: Nodes are proportional to the centrality level of each country, while links
are proportional to the relevance of one country to another)
Map 6.2 Trade relevance among South American countries (2013) (Note:
Nodes are proportional to the GDP of each country in current US$, while links are
proportional to the relevance of one country to another)
SOUTH AMERICA: TRADE AND INTEGRATION IN THE NEW GLOBAL TRADE... 129
0.0140
0.0120
0.0100
0.0080
0.0060
0.0040
0.0020
0.0900
0.0800
0.0700
0.0600
0.0500
0.0400
0.0300
0.0200
0.0100
Fig. 6.3 Regional blocks and the rest of the world. (a) Average relevance of
blocks on the rest of the world. (b) Average relevance of the rest of the world on
the blocks
0.3000
0.2500
0.2000
0.1500
0.1000
0.0500
0.0600
0.0500
0.0400
0.0300
0.0200
0.0100
Fig. 6.4 Influence of global centers on the South American blocks (a) the USA
(b) China
USA rhetoric of this group, since the relevance of the ALBA on shocks in
the USA income was higher than that vulnerability suffered by the world
(which was just 0.0778 in that year) and even higher than the vulnerabil-
ity of the CAN.
134 W. PÉREZ-OVIEDO ET AL.
On the other hand, the average influence of China on the rest of the
world, as well as on all South American trading blocks, has increased expo-
nentially (see Fig. 6.4b). From 2000 to 2013, the Chinese relevance grew for
all South American blocks: the UNASUR (0.006–0.046), the MERCOSUR
(0.005–0.040), the CAN (0.005–0.041), and the ALBA (0.004–0.038).
The continuously growing trend of this indicator with regard to all South
American trading blocks, and even with regard to the AP, shows that these
blocks are increasingly vulnerable to a China’s hypothetical crisis, although
the relevance of the Asian giant on these blocks is below its world average.
0.140
0.120
0.100
0.080
0.060
0.040
0.020
It is possible that the MERCOSUR had more strength to push the entire
region to greater internal cohesion, especially due to the consolidation of
Brazil’s trade relations with the rest of South America. Since 2012, how-
ever, the regional cohesion seems to be decreasing again (see Fig. 6.5).
Figure 6.6 presents regional block cohesion indexes together with the
percentage of primary products in total exports. It can be seen that the
ALBA and the CAN show similar positions to the African Union. For
instance, both the ALBA and the CAN have low internal cohesion and
more than 50% of their exports are primary goods. The MERCOSUR
90%
80%
PERCENTAGE OF PRIMARY EXPORTS
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
0.000 0.000 0.001 0.010 0.100 1.000
INTRA-BLOCK COHESION (LOGARITHMIC SCALE)
AP NAFTA European Union African Union ASEAN MERCOSUR CAN UNASUR ALBA
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
AP NAFTA European Union African Union ASEAN MERCOSUR CAN UNASUR ALBA World (average)
shows a similar cohesion index to the NAFTA but has higher primary
goods participation when it comes to exports. On the other hand, the
UNASUR shows a position similar to that of the MERCOSUR, revealing
once again the importance of the latter in the international trade of the
former. Figure 6.6 shows a negative correlation between the group’s share
of primary exports and its level of internal cohesion, which could signify
that, in the blocks that are specialized in the export of primary products,
members tend to interact more strongly with countries outside of the
group. This occurs particularly with manufacturing countries, which
reduces internal cohesion levels. Meanwhile, when it comes to industrial-
ized groups, members have more opportunities to strongly interact with
one another and exchange manufactured products.
Figure 6.7 shows the relevance of each trading block on the rest of the
world (interpreted as a measurement of the block’s importance in the
global trade network) and the share of primary products in the block total
exports. As in the case of block-cohesion, there is also a negative c orrelation
between the group’s relevance index and the group’s share of primary
exports. In South America, the ALBA and the CAN are less relevant on the
90%
80%
70%
PERCENTAGE OF PRIMARY EXPORTS
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
0.000 0.001 0.010 0.100 1.000
AVERAGE RELEVANCE ON THE REST OF THE WORLD (LOGARITHMIC SCALE)
Fig. 6.7 Average relevance of the block on the rest of the world vs. percentage
of primary exports
SOUTH AMERICA: TRADE AND INTEGRATION IN THE NEW GLOBAL TRADE... 137
1.00
0.90
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
note that the ALBA was created to serve mainly political purposes rather
than commercial goals.
The CAN and the MERCOSUR show better trajectories (which seem
to explain the UNASUR dynamics). Although there is still a gap regarding
the balance achieved by trade groups such as the NAFTA or the EU, their
integration processes generate similar benefits for all of its members in
terms of industrialization incentives (see Fig. 6.8).
Figure 6.9 shows the interaction between the blocks’ industrial trade
balance and the percentage of export of primary products, noting that
90%
80%
PERCENTAGE OF PRIMARY EXPORTS
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
- 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00
INTRA BLOCK INDUSTRIAL TRADE
AP NAFTA European Union African Union ASEAN MERCOSUR CAN UNASUR ALBA
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0
1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
AP NAFTA European Union African Union ASEAN MERCOSUR CAN UNASUR ALBA World (average)
Conclusions
This document analyzes the position and links of the South American
countries in the global trade network for the period 1992–2014. It showed
the relevance, cohesion, and balance of intra-block industrial trade of the
South American integration and trading blocks. For this purpose, a set of
new, and more appropriate, network indicators was developed. Using our
140 W. PÉREZ-OVIEDO ET AL.
1.000
INTRA-BLOCK COHESION (LOGARITHMIC SCALE)
0.100
0.010
0.001
0.000
0.000
- 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80 0.90 1.00
INTRA BLOCK INDUSTRIAL TRADE
AP NAFTA European Union African Union ASEAN MERCOSUR CAN UNASUR ALBA
0.14
0.12
0.1
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
indexes we found that the core of the global economy consist of the USA
and China, as the main actors, followed by Germany, in a stable position,
and France, the UK, Italy, Japan, and the Netherlands, losing their central
status but still part of the core.
None of the South American countries can be considered part of the
core of the global trade network. These countries show strong and depen-
dent links towards core countries and relatively weak links between them-
selves. This is true even for Brazil which, however, plays a “sub-core” role
in the region. Specifically, the South American countries have a lower
SOUTH AMERICA: TRADE AND INTEGRATION IN THE NEW GLOBAL TRADE... 141
Notes
1. The maximum value this index could reach is 144 (the number of all the
countries that are part of the network minus one). A country can have, at a
minimum, the first highest relevance spot (145–144=1).
2. At the time these calculations were made, 2014 data for Venezuela was not
available.
3. NAFTA includes Canada, the USA, and Mexico. The free trade agreement
between these countries became valid in 1994.
4. The ASEAN was created in 1967 and is comprised of ten member coun-
tries: Malaysia, Indonesia, Brunei, Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos, Myanmar,
Singapore, Thailand, and the Philippines.
5. The African Union was formed by 54 African countries and has been func-
tioning since 2001. It includes almost all of the countries of the African
continent, excluding Morocco.
6. For the CAN indicators, Venezuela is considered until 2006, when it with-
drew from the group.
7. Current members include Antigua and Barbuda, Bolivia, Cuba, Dominica,
Ecuador, Grenada, Nicaragua, Saint Kitts and Nevis, Saint Lucia, Saint
Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname, and Venezuela.
8. www.alba-tcp.org.
9. Although Mexico is not a South American country, it is part of the AP and,
as such, is part of the analysis for comparative purposes.
Bibliography
Aitken, N. 1973. The Effect of the EEC and EFTA on European Trade: A
Temporal Cross-Section Analysis. American Economic Review 63 (5): 881–892.
Amin, S. 1974. Accumulation on a World Scale: A Critique of the Theory of
Underdevelopment. Trans. Brian Pearce. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Backer, L., and A. Molina. 2010. Cuba and the Construction of Alternative Global
Trade Systems: Alba and Free Trade in the Americas. Journal of International
Law 31 (3): 679–752.
SOUTH AMERICA: TRADE AND INTEGRATION IN THE NEW GLOBAL TRADE... 143
Carolina Viola Reyes
Introduction
The end of the progressive and post-neoliberal era, that characterized the
South American politics and economy during the first decade of the
twenty-first century, brought profound changes of how the regional area
was perceived, and thus its regionalization processes. This event creates a
setting full of uncertainty regarding the direction that social, economic,
and political integration and stability will take in South America. However,
its cyclical link can provide clues about the direction to follow, considering
its close link with accumulation processes on a global scale. When we con-
sider the strategic character of the region, rich in natural resources, we can
see that it is impossible to understand the regional dynamics in an isolated
form and without contemplating the processes that occur amidst the geo-
politics of global capitalism.
Oil and gas have played a fundamental role in the regional integration
proposals since the past century. The energetic integration of the region
has been a central part of the agenda of South American and LA integra-
tion since the 90s, occupying a central position in the proposal of
at end 2015
at end 2013
at end 2004
at end 1994
Fig. 7.1 The evolution of the share of South American oil and gas reserves
(Source: BP 2016)
Sufficient gas fields are added to the significant crude oil reserves to
boost interregional trade. At the end of 2015, 3.9% of global natural gas
reserves was accounted for; growth was shown during the last two decades,
even though at a slower pace regarding oil, rising from 5.3 trillion m3 in
1994, to 7.4 trillion m3 in 2015 (BP 2016).
While these resources are abundant, they are located in concentrated
areas. On the one hand, 17.5% of global oil reserves is concentrated in
Venezuela, almost 92% of the regional total; its share in gas reserves is less:
2.7% of global reserves, equivalent to 78% of the reserves of the region.
Chile, Uruguay, and Paraguay are on the other side; net importers of
hydrocarbons (BP 2016). The asymmetry in the distribution of resources
determines the needs to consolidate an energy integration strategy that
would guarantee the stable and safe supply of energy, in the interest of
consolidating a regional development project.
In spite of its potential, the sub-region does not manage to be self-
sufficient. This is mainly due to tension and rivalry between countries that
have delayed the implementation of supply agreements and joint intercon-
nection projects, on various occasions.
The energy matrix of the region is intensive in hydrocarbon. In 2015,
energy consumption was 692.8 million tons equivalent of oil. Oil repre-
sented 48% of the total, followed by natural gas at 22%, biomasses at 3%,
and carbon at 4.6% (BP 2016). The level of oil and gas consumption has
increased during the last decade, in spite of the increase in the c onsumption
150 C.V. REYES
of hydroelectricity; the demand for oil and gas in South America is inelastic,
in other words, it does not respond to changes in the market price of these
products. This explains the subsidies, which have characterized the energy
policies of all the producing countries in South America. This policy has
remained in place during the neoliberal period, as well as during the post-
neoliberal phase of the first decade of twenty-first century. The huge risk that
it implies for a government to withdraw a subsidy that, in one form or the
other, alleviates other systematic inefficiencies—inherent to the countries
that depend on the export of energy—partly explains the persistence of a
non-focalized subsidy policy beyond the governments’ ideological symbol.
It should be emphasized that during the golden period of oil prices, no
significant improvement was registered in terms of the intensity of energy.
This data shows the persistence of a matrix that is rich in hydrocarbon, as
well as the intense reprimarization process that characterized the “pro-
gressive neo-development”. This implied that, regardless of institutional
design, a progressive increase in activities with a high use of energy and
other materials would occur, such as the extraction of natural resources
like oil, gas or others that are linked to agroindustry—for example, soy-
beans in the Southern Cone.
96,4
90,5
94,2
93,8
97,1
89,3
90,8
85,3
85,2
81,47
86,2
89,6
84,2
83,6
86,6
85,9
79,3
74,95
83,0
82,4
76,3
82
76,3
69,4
74,4
67,4
67,9
70,8
63,3
65,2
61,9
60,5
47,4
NA
IL
RU
LA
A
UA
UA
VI
IL
BI
IC
DO
AS
E
TI
PE
CH
LI
ER
ZU
G
UG
BR
UA
EN
BO
LO
RA
M
NE
UR
EC
G
CO
RA
PA
AR
VE
SU
Fig. 7.2 Share of primary exports in total exports (Source: http://interwp.
cepal.org/sisgen/ConsultaIntegradaFlashProc_HTML.asp)
120,00
100,00
80,00
60,00
40,00
20,00
0,00
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Dubai Brent
The demand for oil has contracted during recent years due to the eco-
nomic deceleration that affects emerging economies, mostly China, as well
as developed economies. This contraction of demand is confronted with a
sustained increase in supply, originated by the spectacular growth in the
production of shale oil and gas in the USA, as well as in the numerous
investments in exploration and development carried out during the period
of high prices, when the investment in the sector was highly profitable.
This investment flow, as well as the inclusion of energy in the hot points of
the security strategy of countries, regardless of their size, considerably
expanded extraction horizons. Geopolitical issues, such as the standardiza-
tion of relations with Iran and its return to the global oil and gas market,
or the progressive recovery of extraction in Iraq, may be added.
From the perspective of the producers, the OPEC has not managed to
prevent the drop in prices. On the one hand, there is Saudi Arabia’s refusal
to reduce the injection of oil on the market, interested in cornering the
production of shale in the USA, which would be considered unsustainable
at such low prices. Several analysts indicate that, in reality, the Saudi drive
would not give the desired results. While some small companies have gone
out of business, they have been absorbed by the larger companies special-
ized in extraction in complex conditions (US EIA 2014, 2015).
Hence, we would face a process of auto-purification of the shale sector,
more due to its failure than anything else. On the other hand, recent
ENERGY INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND GLOBAL GEOPOLITICS 155
Almost a decade later, while entering into a new economic, social, and
political context, we can evaluate how these strategies have evolved. We
find ourselves facing a turning point, defined by the structural weakness
from which both proposals suffer, in other words, the impossibility of
overcoming the extractivism and the economic, political, and social
pathologies generated.
The stagnation from which the Venezuelan proposal suffers, while fac-
ing increasing internal instability, and the profound economic crisis that
has submerged the oil giant into chaos since the death of Hugo Chavez,
puts its continuity in doubt. The weakness of the Venezuelan political class
is indicated by the drop in resources of oil profits, putting its incapacity to
overcome its condition of “Petrostate” on the table. Trade with Petrocaribe
has declined and will not be maintained during a change in the govern-
ment; in parallel, the ambitious binational projects such as the Abreu de
Lima Refinery in Brazil, and the Pacific Refinery in Ecuador. In both cases,
South American funding has been replaced by Chinese funders undermin-
ing projects of its potential integration.
In other cases, barriers for the intensification of the process have come
from the national interests of the South American countries, such as in the
case of the mega-construction of the Gas Pipeline of the South, which
aspired to coordinate the gas supply in the Southern Cone. Differences
regarding mapping, which reflected the Argentinian, Chilean, and
Brazilian geopolitical interests, added to Shell’s lobby, for whom the inter-
connection did not turn out to be good business, slowed down the project
driven with force by Hugo Chavez. This project aspired to be the emblem
of Petroamerica.
Meanwhile, the integration proposal in the framework of the
UNASUR also suffered a setback. The pivot of this strategy is currently
facing a profound political crisis that has led to the recent impeachment
of President Dilma Rosseuff. The difficulties and the crisis in politics
and its institutions are accompanied by the resurgence of a conservative
political class that could tend to isolate them from South America, los-
ing the regional projection gained during the last two decades. After a
decade of effervescence, due to the emergence of new leadership in
the region, that proclaimed to relaunch South America as a geopolitical
enabler, and at the same time, an area of synergies and partnerships,
the countries close themselves off, to defend their stability in the face
of increasing dissatisfaction generated by the economic crisis affecting
them today. Oil resources are sold once more to the highest bidder,
ENERGY INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND GLOBAL GEOPOLITICS 161
Notes
1. Renamed as Belt by Hugo Chávez in February 2014 by President Nicolás
Maduro (Reuters, 18 February 2014).
2. This is the case in Argentina and Brazil; changes are expected in Venezuela
and probably in Ecuador.
3. The IEA is the cartel of the oil importer countries. As a result of the two oil
conflicts, the countries of the IEA implemented a strategic re-service that
would enable them to combat price wars driven by the OPEC countries and
to face sudden shortages.
4. The WB launched its “Energy Strategy” in 1992, focused on private invest-
ment, commercial orientation of state-owned companies, and new regula-
tory frameworks (Arelovich 2012: 18).
5. In the project portfolio of IIRSA, there are projects, such as the extension
of the oil pipeline in Northern Peru, the gas pipeline in Northeastern
Argentina, the gas pipeline of URAPABOL trache 1 and 2, and the gas
pipeline Brazilian Aldea (Argentina) – Uruguaiana – Brazil, bordering US$5
billion (IIRSA, n/s).
6. The “Council” was formed during the 1st Energy Summit on Isla Margarita,
Venezuela in 2007. Data available on the official UNASUR website. http://
www.unasursg.org/es/node/251
7. In this context, we refer to the failure of highly important constructions
such as the gas pipelines of the South, prompted by the Petroamerica
Initiative.
ENERGY INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND GLOBAL GEOPOLITICS 163
Bibliography
Acosta, A. 2009. La Maldición de la Abundancia. Quito: Ediciones Abya Yala.
Arelovich, S., and P. Bertinat. 2012. Subvenciones Energéticas. Proyecto Regional de
Energía y Clima. Buenos Aires: ILDIS.
BP. 2016. Statistical Review 2016. London: British Petroleum. Available at:
https://www.bp.com/content/dam/bp/pdf/energy-economics/statistical-
review-2016/bp-statistical-review-of-world-energy-2016-full-report.pdf
Bunker, S. 1984. Modes of Extraction, Unequal Exchange, and the Progressive
Underdevelopment of an Extreme Periphery: The Brazilian Amazon,
1600–1980. The American Journal of Sociology 89 (5): 1017–1064.
Cairo Carou, G. 1993. Elementos para una geopolítica crítica: tradición y cambio
en una disciplina maldita. Revista Ería, 195–213. Available at: http://www.
unioviedo.es/reunido/index.php/RCG/article/view/1153
Cairo Carou, G., and J. Pastor Verdú. 2006. La construcción discursiva de los
conflictos la guerra global y las contiendas localizadas en el nuevo orden mun-
dial. In Geopolítica, guerras y resistencia, 11–26. Madrid: Editorial Trama.
CEPAL/ECLAC. 2016. Relaciones económicas entre América Latina y el Caribe y
China, Oportunidades y desafíos. Available at: http://www.cepal.org/es/
publicaciones/40743-relaciones-economicas-america-latina-caribe-china-
oportunidades-desafios
ECLAC/CEPAL. 2015. América Latina y El Caribe y China. Naciones Unidas.
Santiago, Chile. Disponible en: https://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/
38196-america-latina-y-el-caribe-y-china-hacia-una-nueva-era-de-coopera-
cion-economica
———. (2016) Relaciones económicas entre América Latina y el Caribe y China.
Oportunidades y desafíos. Naciones Unidad. Santiago, Chile. Disponible en:
http://repositorio.cepal.org/handle/11362/40743
El Financiero. 2015. Fondos buitre acechan inversiones de elevado riesgo y ren-
dimiento. 19 de julio, Available at: http://www.elfinanciero.com.mx/econo-
mia/fondos-buitre-acechan-inversiones-de-elevado-riesgo-y-rendimiento.html
El Universal. 2015. En reunión China-CELAC se acordó un Plan Quinquenal de
Cooperación. 09 de enero, Available at: http://www.eluniversal.com/nacional-
y-politica/150109/en-reunion-china-celac-se-acordo-un-plan-quinquenal-
de-cooperacion
El Universo. 2015. Brasil y China sueñan con un tren transoceánico que llegará a
puertos de Perú. 19 de mayo, Available at: http://www.eluniverso.com/noti-
cias/2015/05/19/nota/4891171/brasil-china-suenan-tren-transoceanico-
que-llegara-puertos-peru
164 C.V. REYES
Francisco, E. 2015. Petroleum Politics: China and Its National Oil Companies.
SciencesPo. Available at: www.sciencespo.fr/ceri/fr/content/dossiersduceri/
petroleum-politics-china-and-its-national-oil-companies
Gallagher, K.P., and M. Myers. 2014. China-Latin American Finance Database.
Washington: Inter-American Dialogue.
García Sanchez, I. 2014. El Auge de China y su Suministro Energético. In
Cuadernos de Estrategia: Energy and Geostrategy, 166, 221–288. Available at:
http://dialnet.unirioja.es/ejemplar/381443
Hameiri, S., and L. Jones. 2015. Rising Powers and State Transformation: The
Case of China. In European Journal of International Relations, 1–27. Available
at: www.ejt.sagepub.com
Harvey, D. 2003. El Nuevo Imperialismo. Madrid: Ediciones Akal.
Karl, T.L. 1997. The Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Klare, T.M. 2008. Planeta Sediento Recursos Menguantes. La nueva geopolítica de
la energía. Barcelona: Ediciones Urano.
La Nación. 2010. Millonaria capitalización de Petrobras. 24 de septiembre,
Available at: http://www.lanacion.com.ar/1307758-millonaria-capitalizacion-
de-petrobras
Lacoste, Y. 2010. Geopolítica. Madrid: Ediciones Akal.
Lefebvre, H. 1974a. The Production of Space. Londres: Blackwell Publishing.
———. 1974b. La producción del espacio. Papers: revista de sociología 3: 219–229.
Norris, W. J. 2011. Chinese Grand Strategy. Decisión Making & Brazilian-Chinese
Petroleum Cooperation. Available at: http://www.thedialogue.org/uploads/
NorrisChineseGrandStrategydecision-makingand_China_Brazil_Economic_
Ties.pdf
OECD. 2014. Perspectivas económicas de América Latina 2015: Educación, compe-
tencias e innovación para el desarrollo. Paris: OECD Publishing. https://doi.
org/10.1787/leo-2015-es.
Smith, G.E. 1986. Geopolitics. In The Dictionary of Human Geography, ed.
R.J. Johnston, D. Gregory, and D.M. Smith, 178–189. Oxforf: Blackwell.
Taylor, J.P. 1985. Political Geography: World-Economy, Nation-State and Locality.
Londres: Longman.
US EIA. 2014. China Overview. Available at: https://www.eia.gov/beta/inter-
national/analysis.cfm?iso=CHN
———. 2015. Argentina and China Lead Shale Development Outside North
America in First Half 2015. Available at: http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/
detail.cfm?id=21832
Viola, C. 2015. El Petróleo y el Gas en la Geopolítica de la Integración Suramericana.
Tesis Maestría, FLACSO. Available at: http://repositorio.flacsoandes.edu.ec/
handle/10469/6945
———. 2016. El rol de China en la geopolítica de la energía en América Latina.
Available at: https://www.aldhea.org/el-rol-de-china-en-la-geopolitica-de-la-
energia-perspectivas-desde-america-latina/
CHAPTER 8
Uallace Moreira Lima
Introduction
In 2000, the inter-regional trade among Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile,
Colombia, Ecuador, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela totaled
US$71,242 billion. In 2014, the trade among these same countries
jumped to US$110,773 billion, a 205.5% rise representing an average
growth rate of 13.7% between 2000–2014 (CEPAL). Even though that
is a considerable growth for trade among South American countries, it
is interesting to notice that concealed behind those highly positive results
there are regional production structures directed to a notably low level
of integration, mostly resulting on a poor use of economies of scale and
specialization. It is also possible to notice certain difficulties on develop-
ment processes for new capacities and production of goods and/or
specific services with more advanced technology and added value. These
issues affect a proper and competitive international insertion of South
American countries into global trade.
Such issues become even more relevant when we understand that the
international trade is notably marked by a broad productive integration
process among countries from the same region so as to obtain, collectively,
a more competitive external insertion within GVCs logic. Productive inte-
gration is associated to developing the process of fragmenting production
into regional bases among international groups enabling an international
distribution of work within a certain production chain, where as a coun-
terpart intra-industrial trade fluxes are consolidated and parts, compo-
nents, and industrial processing are imported while more complex
components or final products are exported.
Productive integration represents one of the aspects of the productive
globalization process—production internationalization—which is associ-
ated to the expansion of FDI and to the contractual relations that contrib-
ute to a global production growth. These features are part of new strategies
for production internationalization, which consists on industries moving
from entities nationally limited to a fragmented business network globally
spread, leading companies to engage in the production of certain goods
and/or services from conception to final consumption. Such new strategy,
which grew stronger due to productive globalization concepts during the
90s, is best known as GVCs and is strictly connected to the process of
productive integration, i.e., production fragmentation and integration
walk side by side.
According to Estevadeordal et al. (2012) and Baldwin (2013), one of
the main features of GVCs is the fragmentation of production that leads
to the extinguishment of the need to acquire proper knowledge on every
level of any goods production and allows developing countries to associ-
ate with a cross-borders cooperative network, sharing production and
obtaining expertize in only one or few steps of the production activities
within the manufacturing process of final goods. The automotive indus-
try is clearly one of the main industries affected by the transformations
on production internationalization. Biesebroeck (2009) suggests that,
from a geographical point of view, the global automotive industry, as
many others, is in the middle of a deep transitioning process. Since the
early 80s, there has been a transitioning process from local national
industries, limited to a number of countries, to a fully integrated global
industry.
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION... 167
Table 8.1 World motor vehicle production—All types—Growth rate total and
by region—2000/2015
2000 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013 2014 2015 Average
rate
Total 3.6 −3.4 3.0 3.6 5.6 −12.5 2.8 3.7 2.9 1.1 1.1
Production
EU 1.0 0.5 6.0 −0.8 5.6 −17.2 3.4 −0.3 5.8 6.1 1.0
North 0.0 −10.5 −2.9 0.5 −2.7 −32.5 10.4 4.3 28.8 −1.2 −0.6
America
South 23.5 1.9 1.5 16.7 15.2 −4.1 −3.3 8.3 −17.1 −20.6 2.2
America
Asia-Oceania 6.0 −0.2 10.3 3.3 8.7 1.6 −0.8 4.8 3.6 0.8 3.8
Africa 5.0 23.9 38.5 23.8 −4.4 −28.5 12.9 8.5 13.1 16.2 10.9
Source: OICA
North America: USA, Canada, and Mexico
South America: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela
Asia-Oceania: Australia, China, India, Indonesia, Iran, Japan, Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines, South
Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam
174 U.M. LIMA
EU 29.4 30.6 29.6 27.3 27.0 24.7 22.1 18.5 19.1 20.0
North America 30.4 28.1 26.8 24.6 21.1 14.2 16.8 18.9 23.6 23.1
South America 3.6 3.7 3.4 4.5 5.0 6.1 5.4 5.3 4.2 3.3
Asia-Oceania 30.8 31.8 36.2 38.8 41.9 51.5 50.7 52.4 52.2 52.6
Africa 1.9 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.9
Total 95.9 94.9 96.7 96.1 95.7 97.2 95.7 95.9 100.0 100.0
participation
Source: OICA
North America: USA, Canada, and Mexico
South America: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela
Asia-Oceania: Australia, China, India, Indonesia, Iran, Japan, Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines, South
Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION... 175
negative growth rates observed during the economic crisis that hit the
region, participation fell back to 3.3%, lower than the values obtained in
2000. The highest participation gain in the total production of the auto-
motive industry was noticed in Asia-Oceania, climbing from 30.8% in
2000 to 52.0% in 2015. These figures are related to a loss of participation
of more traditional markets such as North America and the EU.
The decrease of participation in the global production of motor vehi-
cles of those two regions is not conjuntural but structural as we observe a
constant downward trend in the production growth rate in both regions
as well as in the total production participation. Furthermore, the decrease
of growth rates and participation are not associated with the drop on the
total world vehicle production but with a world vehicle production growth
dynamics, along with other non-traditional regions presenting higher pro-
duction growth rates and increasing evolution on their total production
participation. In addition, indicators presented so far suggest that the
highest production growth rates, in South America and Asia-Oceania,
resulted in a constant growth of their respective participation in all catego-
ries—when compared to Europe and North America, while the highest
growth rate in Africa, compared to the same markets, do not reflect a
considerable growth in its participation in the world vehicle production.
However, it is clear that countries from Asia-Oceania present a more solid
dynamics than any other region, indicating that such countries have
adapted and introduced themselves more dynamically into the automotive
industry global value chain than, for example, South American and African
countries.
As mentioned before, when analyzing the automotive industry produc-
tion dynamics individually, as shown on Table 8.3, it is possible to notice
that, except for Brazil and Argentina, countries such as Ecuador, Chile,
Colombia, and Venezuela presented average growth rates above the South
American and the world economy production average between 2000 and
2015. Nevertheless, the low average production growth rate of the auto-
motive industry in Brazil and Argentina, due to their economic crises
observed over the past few years, substantially impacted the productive
dynamics of the automotive industry in the region. This can be explained
by analyzing the productive activity of the sector in the region according
to the participation of these countries in the sector production in South
America.
Even though some countries such as Venezuela, Ecuador, and Chile
presented an average growth rate of vehicle production remarkably above
176
U.M. LIMA
South America 23.5 1.9 1.5 16.7 15.2 −4.1 −3.3 8.3 −17.1 −20.6 2.2
Argentina 11.4 −30.6 6.1 22.8 26.0 −14.1 15.7 3.5 −22.0 −13.5 0.5
Brazil 23.7 8.7 2.0 14.5 14.0 −1.2 −6.6 11.1 −15.3 −22.8 2.8
Chile 257.3 100.6 −60.6 −7.3 62.2 −26.2 * * * * 32.6
Colombia 209.2 6.1 −8.1 29.1 4.3 −26.4 −32.8 8.8 −7.5 9.7 19.2
Ecuador * 206.7 −9.5 603.5 3.4 −47.8 8.9 −37.4 −60.7 −19.8 64.7
Uruguay 23.8 −26.9 −97.8 * * * * * * * −10.1
Venezuela 313.9 −37.8 8.0 311.1 −1.7 −17.3 −1.9 −31.1 −72.5 −7.4 46.3
Source: OICA
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION... 177
South 2.9 3.6 3.4 4.5 4.6 6.1 5.3 5.3 4.2 3.3
America
Argentina 18.1 11.1 8.3 10.3 13.5 13.3 18.5 16.6 15.4 16.7
Brazil 80.3 85.9 89.7 83.5 80.0 83.0 78.0 80.2 82.1 80.1
Chile 0.1 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.1 * * * *
Colombia 0.5 1.2 1.0 1.6 2.0 0.7 0.6 1.5 1.9 2.4
Ecuador * 0.1 0.1 0.9 0.7 0.4 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.2
Uruguay 0.7 0.5 * * * * * * * *
Venezuela 0.3 0.6 0.6 3.5 3.5 2.5 2.4 1.4 0.5 0.6
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: OICA
178 U.M. LIMA
South American and Asia-Oceania economies are: (1) major market satu-
ration in existent European and North American markets, especially after
the 2008 crisis; (2) low growth rate of major traditional markets and rapid
growth expectations for great emerging markets, which draw vehicle man-
ufacturers to such promising markets, seeking an expansion on sales.
These two reasons can be verified and analyzed through the motor
vehicles sales indexes for the world economy. According to the data on
Table 8.5, South America and Asia-Oceania presented an average growth
rate above the world average growth rate for vehicles production. The
average growth rate in South America was 4.5% between 2006 and 2015
and it could have been even higher, if it was not for the drastic drop on
motor vehicles sales in 2014 (−10.7%) and 2015 (−19.8%). As previously
mentioned, the drop in recent years is due to an economic crisis Brazil and
Argentina are currently going through, which has significantly affects
regional sales.
As South America presented a higher average sales growth rate than the
world economy average, the region presented an increase of participation
percentage on motor vehicles sales in the world market. In 2006, the
South American Participation was 5.0%, in 2011 it reached 7.6%, in 2013
it dropped to 7.3%, and after the strong decrease on regional sales in 2014
and 2015, the South American participation on total motor vehicle sales
rose back to 5.0%, just as in 2006. As confirmed, the drop is a result of the
political and economic crises Brazil and Argentina are currently facing,
evidencing once again that the automotive industry in South America is
highly dependent on those two countries, which heavily weakens produc-
tive integration strategies in the region for creating too strong a relation
placed upon two countries alone (Table 8.6).
Such dependency upon Brazil and Argentina, on the sales market,
becomes even more evident when analyzing motor vehicle sales indexes
among South American countries only, as seen in Table 8.7. Although
countries such as Bolivia, Peru, and Paraguay presented average sales
growth rates considerably above the world and South American average
between 2006 and 2015—while Brazil and Argentina were just above
average—sales in South America did not increase sufficiently since the
region substantially depends on the growth dynamics of Brazil and
Argentina.
From a sales participation index standpoint, as shown on Table 8.8, in
2006 Brazil and Argentina represented 69.1% of the sales market in South
America and in 2015 both countries summed to 71.1%. Brazil is the main
Table 8.5 Vehicle sales motor—All types—Growth rate of total sales by region—2006/2015
Regions 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Average rate
Total sales 3.5 4.7 −4.6 −4.0 14.2 4.3 5.2 3.9 3.0 2.0 3.2
EU 1.6 1.9 −7.9 −6.4 −3.4 0.0 −8.3 −1.6 6.4 9.8 −0.8
North America −1.7 −3.0 −15.9 −20.8 10.5 9.8 12.4 7.1 4.2 6.2 0.9
South and Central America 10.6 25.1 8.4 0.0 17.7 8.5 3.4 1.5 −10.7 −19.8 4.5
Asia-Oceania-Middle East 6.5 8.1 2.7 16.5 24.3 0.6 8.2 5.8 5.1 3.2 8.1
Africa 15.1 0.9 −4.6 −7.6 7.9 15.6 8.6 3.3 2.8 −8.8 3.3
Source: OICA
North America: USA, Canada, and Mexico
South America: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela
Asia-Oceania: Australia, China, India, Indonesia, Iran, Japan, Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION...
179
180 U.M. LIMA
EU 26.9 26.2 25.3 24.7 20.9 20.0 17.4 16.5 17.1 18.4
North America 29.1 27.0 23.8 19.6 19.0 20.0 21.3 22.0 22.2 23.2
South and 5.0 6.0 6.8 7.1 7.3 7.6 7.5 7.3 6.3 5.0
Central America
Asia-Oceania- 32.0 33.0 35.5 43.1 46.9 45.3 46.5 47.4 48.3 48.9
Middle East
Africa 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.8 1.7 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.7
Total 95.0 94.1 93.3 96.2 95.7 94.7 94.7 95.1 95.9 97.1
participation
Source: OICA
North America: USA, Canada, and Mexico
South America: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela
Asia-Oceania: Australia, China, India, Indonesia, Iran, Japan, Malaysia, Pakistan, the Philippines, South
Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam
South America 11.6 24.6 8.5 −0.6 19.1 8.2 2.8 2.0 −11.1 −19.8 4.5
Argentina 14.4 22.7 8.3 −20.4 43.4 26.vd5 −6.0 16.1 −36.3 −1.3 6.7
Bolivia 25.0 0.0 5.7 −18.9 266.7 27.3 50.0 6.7 37.9 −30.7 37.0
Brazil 12.4 27.8 14.5 11.4 11.9 3.4 4.6 −0.9 −7.1 −26.6 5.1
Chile 0.0 15.0 9.9 −28.5 67.9 17.4 1.7 9.7 −11.1 −15.8 6.6
Colombia 36.7 14.6 −10.6 −7.1 46.2 3.5 −3.4 0.6 9.5 −13.3 7.7
Ecuador −3.8 2.5 22.8 −17.7 42.5 5.8 −13.2 −6.3 5.5 −31.2 0.7
Paraguay 0.0 37.5 90.9 −42.9 58.3 57.9 0.0 2.0 1.3 −9.0 19.6
Peru 40.8 55.2 81.4 −16.9 57.0 24.2 27.1 5.5 −7.1 −7.8 26.0
Uruguay 0.0 26.7 31.6 52.0 44.7 −0.1 2.7 8.1 −7.4 −10.1 14.8
Venezuela 19.7 52.3 −37.1 −31.9 −8.3 −3.6 8.2 −24.3 −76.0 −38.0 −13.9
Source: OICA
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION...
181
182 U.M. LIMA
Argentina 13.3 13.1 13.1 10.5 12.6 14.8 13.5 15.4 11.0 13.6
Bolivia 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.6 0.5
Brazil 55.8 57.2 60.4 67.7 63.6 60.7 61.8 60.1 62.8 57.5
Chile 5.8 5.3 5.4 3.9 5.5 6.0 5.9 6.3 6.3 6.7
Colombia 5.9 5.5 4.5 4.2 5.2 4.9 4.6 4.6 5.6 6.1
Ecuador 2.6 2.1 2.4 2.0 2.4 2.3 2.0 1.8 2.2 1.8
Paraguay 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.6
Peru 1.0 1.2 2.0 1.7 2.2 2.5 3.1 3.2 3.4 3.9
Uruguay 0.4 0.4 0.5 0.8 1.0 0.9 0.9 1.0 1.0 1.1
Venezuela 6.1 7.4 4.3 2.9 2.3 2.0 2.1 1.6 0.4 0.3
Total 91.3 92.7 93.2 94.0 95.3 94.9 94.8 94.8 93.8 92.1
participation
Source: OICA
that Europe is not the region with the highest exportation values in the
automotive products industry. Exportations from Europe to the world
rose from US$271 billion in 2000 to US$663.9 billion in 2012, a growth
of 133.9% in 12 years. It is also relevant to notice that European exporta-
tions are basically concentrated within Europe itself, i.e., it is mostly a
intra-regional foreign trade, indicating the high level of concentration of
automotive GVC formation within the company’s own region or country.
Such a scenario does not omit the growth of European exportations to
other regions during those years, such as exportations to Asia, North
America, Africa, the Middle East, or South and Central America.
The second leader of automotive products exportation is Asia. Asian
exportations of automotive products to the world rose from US$112.7
billion in 2000 to US$338.5 billion in 2012, a growth of 200.5%—higher
than the European growth percentage. Different from Europe, Asia does
not concentrate most of exportations within Asia itself, for there is a larger
distribution to other markets, such as North America and Europe. That is
a consequence of a stronger presence of Asian companies in world mar-
kets, especially in Europe and North America. It can be also observed that
there is trend in Asia of exportation growth to all regions, such as North
America, Europe, the Middle East, South and Central America, Africa,
and the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS).
North America occupies the third position on the world’s automotive
exportations leadership. North American exportations rose from
US$128.4 billion in 2000 to US$269.9 billion in 2013, a growth of
110.1% in 12 years. North American exportations are highly concentrated
within itself, with a low volume of exportations to other regions, such as
Asia, Europe, or South and Central America. This foreign trade character-
istic of the USA might be associated with a higher presence of American
companies in other markets distributing their production through several
other regions, influencing the foreign trade dynamics.
OMC data (Medeiros 2010) concerning LA is only available from 2000
to 2006 and there are no indexes for the region after 2006 since it does
not present relevant data for the world automotive industry figures, eco-
nomically speaking, for the countries in LA are not in the top 15 largest
exporters and importers of automotive products. Between 2000 and 2006,
LA participation in the foreign trade of products was not exactly relevant
but it was increasing from an exportation of US$571.3 million in 2000 to
US$1.015 billion in 2006, growing 77.9% in 6 years. These figures were
significantly below the growth of the global exportation of automotive
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION... 187
external tax promoted a fast expansion of the market chain among coun-
tries within the region (observant of the stagnation of external markets, a
high index of regional trading), especially for the automotive industry
and, most recently, a significant direct investment growth originated from
countries of the trade bloc. However, and opposite to what was estab-
lished in Asia, the great weakness of inducing structural mechanisms and
prevailing macroeconomic characteristics limited the possibilities of a
broader economic integration, which made the MERCOSUR an “incom-
plete” and “imperfect” customs union in which the needs imposed by
external crises had precedent over the long term arrangements directed
towards the bloc consolidation.
One of the mechanisms available to analyze the productive integration
among countries is the input-output model. The fragmented production
can be seen as a particular kind of input-output relation between imports
and exports that tends to increase the imported content of exports in rela-
tion to added value. This issue is especially important to the growth trajec-
tory of South American countries and their regional integration, thus
allowing us to analyze potentialities and synergies promoted by regional
and global trade for the growth of national economies, taking into
consideration that, even if there is a quid pro quo, there is no mechanical
and automatic determination between the growth of trade and the growth
of the economies (Medeiros 2010). Considering this perspective and the
indexes in Table 8.9 of automotive products input-output, one can state
that in South America there is only a single relevant integration process
between Brazil and Argentina, since Argentina consumes US$243 million
of sector products for their automotive industry production. In fact, with
that consumption, Argentina has Brazil as their main automotive products
suppliers, even being above the EU, the USA, Asia, and Russia.
As for Brazil, the automotive industry is supplied by a broad network of
suppliers established inside the country consuming US$11.558 billion.
The products arriving from Argentina total US$368 billion, which is
below the US$1.344 billion coming from the EU, US$912 million from
the USA, and US$421 million coming from Russia. That is to say, regard-
ing automotive products, Brazil demands more products from the EU,
the USA, and Russia than from Argentina, which does not mean there is
no integration between the two main manufacturers of the South American
automotive industry; it means Argentina depends much more in Brazil
than the reverse.
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION... 189
(continued)
190 U.M. LIMA
Table 8.9 (continued)
Conclusion
There has been in the past few decades a considerable growth of trade
among South American countries. However, the production structures of
the countries within the region indicate a low level of integration that
leads to a poor use of economies of scale and specialization, as well as dif-
ficulties in the process of developing new capacities of producing improved
goods and/or services with higher technological intensity and added
value, which affect a competitive international insertion of South American
countries into world trade.
Particularly regarding the acting dynamics of the automotive industry,
the debate on the automotive industry transformation in the world econ-
omy evidences that suppliers started to be fundamental to assembly com-
panies on their process of global expansion, especially because of the
capacity for meeting the requirements of the manufacturers. Among such
requirements, the need for investment on new productive plants placed
wherever the manufacturers establish new assembly lines has been consid-
erably frequent. The criteria used by the assembly companies to select
their suppliers involve, basically: pricing, technological quality, and capac-
ity. There are four levels of suppliers distinguished according to their
capacity to meet the assembly plants requirements: (1) major global sup-
pliers; (2) first level suppliers; (3) second level suppliers; (4) and third
level suppliers.
It is also important to recognize that developing markets are drawing
more investments and most of the vehicles manufacturers place their pro-
192 U.M. LIMA
Notes
1. It is important to notice that the insertion of countries into different levels
of the GVC is connected to a set of functions performed by companies
through their supply and production contracts. Being that so, Cruz-Moreira
and Fleury (2003) systematized an industrial modernization typology where
it is possible to better understand the hierarchy of activities hired companies
can be responsible for within a value chain:
1. OEA (Original equipment assembly): Maquiladoras: (a) they receive
specifications about products and productive processes; (b) receive unfin-
ished input and components; (c) perform simples assembly activities; (d)
return the product to the client for other processing; 2. OEM (Original
equipment manufacturer): Full package suppliers: (a) they receive specifi-
cations about the product; (b) develop specifications about the production
process; (c) manage buying and logistics; (d) deliver finished products with
the client’s logo; 3. ODM (Original design manufacturer): Full package
suppliers with design capacity: (a) they perform design activities and product
specification; (b) either produce or outsource their production; (c) manage
the supplier’s chain; (d) eventually decide about commercialization;
4. OBM (Original brand manufacturer): Full package suppliers with their
own brand: (a) they perform creation and branding activities; (b) perform
design and product specification activities; (c) manage the supplier’s chain;
(d) decide about commercialization processes; 5. GB (Global buyers):
Global buyers: (a) they do not produce; (b) perform creation and branding
activities; (c) perform design activities and product specification; (d) out-
source production; (e) manage the supplier’s chain; (f) decide about com-
mercialization processes. According to Cruz-Moreira and Fleury (2003), in
order to reach superior levels, companies need to develop learning processes
that allows them to promote innovation and to strengthen their compe-
tences. Other researchers believe that upgrading, in this context, can be
achieved by improving (1) processes and (2) products, developing new
competences and functions—known as “functional upgrading” (3), or even
using acquired knowledge for sector diversification.
2. WTO. International Trade Statistics. (Several Years). International Trade
Statistics is a yearly journal published by OMC with indexes providing a
world trade panorama.
3. The definition of automotive industry products comes from the classifica-
tion Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) 781, 782, 783, 784
and 7132, including: 781—Passengers automobile and other vehicles mainly
created to transport people (except vehicles designed to public transporta-
tion), including trucks and race cars; 782—Automobile vehicles to transport
merchandise and for special uses; 783—Motor vehicles (n.e.p.); 784—Parts
PRODUCTIVE INTEGRATION IN SOUTH AMERICA AND ITS INSERTION... 195
Bibliography
Baldwin, R. 2013. Global Supply Chains: Why They Emerged, Why They Matter,
and Where They Are Going. In Global Value Chains in a Changing World, ed.
D. K. Elms and P. Low. World Trade Organization. Available at: http://www.
wto.org/engliss/res_e/booksp_e/aid4tradeglobalvalue13_e.pdf
Baldwin, R.E., and F. Robert-Nicoud. 2010. Trade-In-Goods and Trade-In-Tasks:
An Integrating Framework, Working Paper 15882. Cambridge: Bureau of
Economics Research. Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w15882
Colovic, A., and U. Mayrhofer. 2009. Optimising the Global Value Chain: Na
Analysis of the Automobile Industry. 10th Vaasa Conference on International
Business, University of Vaasa, Finland, August 23–25. Available at: http://hal.
archives-ouvertes.fr/docs/00/69/02/07/PDF/Vaasa2009Article.pdf
CRUZ-MOREIRA, J., and A, Fleury. 2003. Industrial Upgrading nas Cadeias
Produtivas Globais: Reflexões a partir das Indústrias Têxtil e do Vestuário de
Honduras e no Brasil. São Paulo, USP. Tese de Doutorado.
Estevadeordal, A., J. Blyde, and K. Suominen. 2012. Are Global Value Chains
Really Global? Policies to Accelerate Countries Access to International Production
Networks. Available at: http://e15initiative.org/wpcontent/uploads/2012/12/
web
Humphrey, J. 2013. The Global Automotive Industry Value Chain: What Prospects
for Upgrading. United Nations Industrial Development Organization:
Economy Environment Employment. Available at: http://www.unido.org/
fileadmin/user media/Publications/Pub free/Global automotive industry
value chain.pdf
Leite, M. 1999. O Trabalho Reestruturado. Competitividade e Trabalho na Cadeia
Automotiva Brasileira. Novos Cadernos NAEA 2 (1), Dezembro.
Machado Mesquita, J.B. 2010. Integração produtiva: referencial analítico, experiên-
cia europeia e lições para o Mercosul. In Integração Produtiva – Caminhos
para o Mercosul, Volume XVI. Brasília: Série Cadernos da Indústria
ABDI. Available at: http://www.abdi.com.br/Estudo/Integra%C3%A7%C3%
A3o%20Produtiva%20Caminhos%20para%20o%20Mercosul.pdf
Medeiros Aguilar de, C. 2010. Integração produtiva: a experiência asiática e
algumas referências para o Mercosul. In Integração Produtiva – Caminhos
196 U.M. LIMA
The chapter is divided into four sections. The first examines the develop-
ment structure of the so-called knowledge gaps in South American coun-
tries. The second analyzes the related international norms and regulations,
from a global agency point of view. The third introduces the economic
gaps in intensive research activities, regional invention, and innovation,
with a particular focus on energy consumption and efficiency gaps. Finally,
the conclusions are presented.
reality, given that they do not include the transaction and transportation
costs, or geopolitical factors, taking on the idea of perfect markets (Falconí
2013).
Beyond these limitations, the neotechnological approaches (Posner
1961; Hufbauer 1966) justify the comparative advantages that are created
based on the capacity of the countries to innovate.1 For Krugman and
Obstfeld (2001), for example, countries engage in international trade due
to convenience and necessity. Thus, it would be ideal to export goods
produced with high levels of productivity, and import goods with less
efficient production processes. According to the authors, what prevails is
an international division of labor, where rich countries must be the suppli-
ers of intensive goods in research and development (industrial and tech-
nology), while poor countries must keep supplying commodities, food,
and minerals.
Such form or structure of international insertion represents an obstacle
to reduce the knowledge gaps (KG), due to its limited endogenous pro-
cess in the assimilation and dissemination of knowledge that may boost
innovation. This topic was initially observed by Sunkel for whom “the
primary export sector becomes the critical component of the capacity of
accumulation and innovation” (Sunkel 1987: 45). Before, and in line
with the theoretical center periphery approach of Prebish (1959), Cardoso
and Faletto (1969) maintained that technological dependence is gener-
ated by the production processes concentrated in industrialized countries.
Consequently, the insertion pattern and specialization of the region in
abundance of natural resources and unqualified labor are perpetuated,
which ultimately does not stimulate productive diversification with greater
technological content, even during the boom in commodity prices
(Gudynas 2009).
Indeed, this segmentation creates more benefits in the countries of the
North than in the countries of the South due to the fact that this type of
industrialization brings about productive connections, facilitates special-
ization, and generates more opportunities to develop new products and
processes. Moreover, in the long term, the terms of trade deteriorate
(Prebish 1959, 1950; Singer 1950). In other words, the ratio between the
unit prices of the export of commodities and the import of industrialized
goods reduces. In this way, the aforesaid limitations have made it possible
to challenge the theory of comparative advantage proposed at the begin-
ning of the nineteenth century.
THE REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF KNOWLEDGE... 199
In this sense, in the middle of the last century, the ECLAC proposed
the concept of ISI (Prebish 1950, 1959), in other words, to substitute
imports by locally produced goods. However, the proposal did not man-
age to reduce the dependency of the LA countries, but it only industrial-
ized those countries that had already completed the first phase, or that
already had industries for the consumption of non-durable goods (Furtado
1970). Moreover, the policies of the neoliberal school based on commer-
cial liberalization, started in LA during the mid-70s, and, as a result, the
different multilateral, sub-regional, and bilateral agreements have progres-
sively led to an increase in economic primarization based on the export of
primary products.
Under the premise of rethinking the “international insertion pattern of
the region” (ECLAC 2009: 14), a pattern is searched for that would
enable a boost in knowledge creation, and at the same time make way for
innovation and the creation of new products and processes. This is a
greater regional relative autonomy where the LA thinking should prevail
as an alternative to a specific type of globalization that generates greater
opportunities for the rich countries.
In that regard, the accelerated growth of China, although it is not the
root cause, highlights the structural deindustrialization problem of the
region, making it necessary to prioritize “the management and quality of
innovation and, above all, its effects on environmental sustainability and
social integration” (Phillips 2007; ECLAC 2016a: 5).
Historical evidence shows that knowledge is boosted through endoge-
nous development (Romer 1986; Lucas 1988). The endogenous notion
suggests that growth is stimulated by improved technologies that origi-
nate from their internal potential and the international decisions of invest-
ment in R&D of the agents of each economy. The production of knowledge
responds to the resources and funds that facilitate R&D, while the supply
of ideas directly depends on the number of researchers (Romer 1990), and
the latter on R&D expenditure.
However, rich countries invest more in R&D than poor countries. This
situation facilitates the specialization of economies according to their
intensive use of knowledge. In poor countries, there is a higher share of
less intensive activities, as compared to technology, while in rich countries,
the opposite happens. Due to this dynamic, the knowledge spillover pro-
cess is accelerated in rich countries (ECLAC 2010). Therefore, there are
two problems: the deindustrialization and reprimarization.
200 P. CANGO ET AL.
24.0 198
Industrializaon, value added (% of GDP)
178
20.0
158
138
16.0
118
12.0 98
78
8.0
58
38
4.0
18
0.0 -2
1993
1995
1998
2000
2002
2005
2007
2009
2010
2012
2014
1992
1994
1996
1997
1999
2001
2003
2004
2006
2008
2011
2013
South America Lan America and Caribbean Commodity price index (2005=100, right axis)
Fig. 9.1 Industrialization (value added % of GDP) in LAC and South America,
1992–2014 (Data do not include Paraguay between 1994–2004 or Venezuela in
2013 and 2014; Source: World Bank and International Monetary Fund (2016))
THE REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF KNOWLEDGE... 201
256
224
192
160
128
96
64
32
0
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
Commodities Natural resource-based manufactures
High-technology manufactures Low-technology manufactures
Medium-technology manufactures Commodity price index (2005=100, right axis)
Fig. 9.2 The export structure of South America by technological intensity index
1992 = 100 (Data do not include Suriname in 1993, Guyana until 1996, and
Venezuela in 2014; Source: UN Comtrade-Database and International Monetary
Fund (2016))
the machines) or direct energy (fuel or electricity needed for their opera-
tion). The necessary energy for the generation and maintenance of knowl-
edge is added to this.
This result was already observed by Cottrell (1955), when he men-
tioned that productivity increases with an increase in the available energy
consumption per capita. The higher productivity of workers in the USA
compared to Europe was explained by their higher consumption of energy
per capita (Boretsky 1975). For the USA, it was also shown that labor
productivity of manufacture workers is related to the consumption of
energy per hour of work (Cleveland et al. 1984). These authors also
showed that when the oil price (in real terms) was lower than real salaries
(in relative terms), oil substituted work, and labor productivity increased,
and vice versa. This same result was found for countries as diverse as
Ecuador (Falconí 2001), Spain (Ramos-Martin 2001), China and India
(Velasco-Fernández et al. 2015), and countries of the EU 15 (Sorman and
Giampietro 2013).
The higher the productivity, the greater the economic growth of those
countries (World Bank 2016). As a consequence, data from the same
source (World Bank 2016), reveals that the average per capita income of
countries in the region in 1960 represented 36.2% of the income of the
USA, but for 2015 it fell to 27%. Similarly, the proportion of income com-
pared to Japan went from 43.5% to 21%, while compared to the USA it
decreased from 36.2% to 27%. On the contrary, South Korea’s income in
1960 represented 30.3% of the income of a LAC person. Today, the income
of a LAC person represents 37.2% of the income of a Korean person.
According to ECLAC (2016b), the persistence of gaps in economic
growth deepens the segmentation and falling behind from the developed
world, creating difficulties to finance other dimensions of development,
such as knowledge. Between 2000 and 2012, according to the indicators
of the World Bank (2016), the average growth rate in R&D in China was
6.6%, 5.3% in South Korea, 1.2% in the EU, 0.9% in Japan, and 0.6% in
the USA. LAC had a annual growth rate of 2.8%, which enabled a decrease
in distance with most countries, however there is no convergence with
countries such as South Korea and China, whose gap between 2000 and
2012 went from 3.9 to 5.3 and 1.6 to 2.5 times, respectively. In 2012, on
average, LAC invested 0.76% of their GDP in R&D, an amount that is
below the global average (2.2%) and the rich countries (2.5%).
As shown in Fig. 9.3, in spite of the prolonged boom in commodity
prices (2003–2011), the evolution of R&D expenditure of most South
206 P. CANGO ET AL.
1.2 198
Research and development expenditure (% of GDP)
176
1.0
0.8 132
110
0.6
88
0.4 66
44
0.2
22
0.0 0
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Argentina Bolivia
Brazil Chile
Colombia Ecuador
Paraguay Uruguay
Commodity price index (2005=100, right axis)
Fig. 9.3 Evolution of R&D expenditure (as % of GDP) in South American coun-
tries and the commodity price index, 2000–2012 (Source: World Bank and
International Monetary Fund 2016)
Conclusions
The analysis presented in this chapter shows that there are growing knowl-
edge gaps between rich countries of the North and poor countries of the
South. There are various convergent causes, of very different origins, that
explain these knowledge gaps. On the one hand, those causes arise from
the distinctive innovation system of the countries of the North. On the
other hand, the causes arise from the structural failures of the countries of
the South themselves, in particular of the LAC countries. Among the
structural failures, the following stand out: (1) the weak international
insertion of the countries of South, as suppliers of raw materials and food;
(2) a process of deindustrialization, resulting in weak productive connec-
tions and scarce linkage with the innovation system; and (3) an asymmet-
ric international order that establishes norms and regulations that favor
rich countries, and at the same time, does not recognize the supply of
knowledge of the natural wealth coming from the countries of the South.
Additionally, there is a lack of suitable public policies to promote the sys-
tem of science, technology, and innovation.
Knowledge and innovation gaps between rich countries and South
America, as well as LAC, show growth over time and have not decreased
in spite of the boom in prices of commodities and food. Nevertheless,
three possible scenarios prevail, that could mark the trajectory of gaps in
the future. First, to maintain the current trajectory that would imply the
deepening of the gaps. Second, to reduce the gaps by investing in educa-
tion and R&D, or provide a big boost. This implies injecting more
resources (public and private, the last are tax incentives) that aim to fulfill
basic needs (public health, energy, food).
However, the improvement of knowledge inevitably brings along an
increase in the consumption of energy and materials. It is not by coinci-
dence that the economies that are stronger in knowledge, such as the USA,
Japan, Germany, and recently Korea or China, are those which have higher
consumption levels, as well as more developed industrial sectors. This
unsustainable behavior drives a third scenario, which would not imply an
emulation of what these rich countries have done. One should not forget
THE REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF KNOWLEDGE... 211
Notes
1. The neo-technological approaches distinguish two models: theory of tech-
nological gap (Posner 1961; Hufbauer 1966), the topic of this research, and
the theory of the product lifecycle.
2. According to Correa (2004), the bilateral investment treaties with intellec-
tual property contents and intellectual property agreements were common
in the 80s.
3. According to Art. 27 of the TRIPS, member countries can exclude plants
and animals from patentability.
4. “If knowledge were a non-rival good, it would be distributed quickly, imita-
tion would be at almost zero cost, as a consequence less resources would be
invested in its production” (Velazco-Fernández et al. 2015: 84).
5. There is a similar difference in the investment in secondary education.
6. 10% of the countries with the most and least wealth had an income higher
and lower than 37,500 and 500 (US$), respectively.
7. Without China, the Gini coefficient decrease from 0.788 to 0.711 between
1986 and 2013.
8. In 2013, the proportion of China’s population represented 19% of the
world population.
212 P. CANGO ET AL.
Bibliography
ARWU. 2016. Academic Ranking of World Universities 2015. Available at: http://
www.shanghairanking.com/
Bayarçelik, E., and F. Taşel. 2012. Research and Development: Source of Economic
Growth. Social and Behavioral Sciences 58: 744–753.
Bell, D. 1973. The Coming of Post-Industrial Society. New York: Basic Books.
Boretsky, M. 1975. Views: Trends in U.S. Technology: A Political Economist’s
View: Decline in the Rate of Growth of Technological Innovation and Rapid
Dissemination Throughout the World of U.S. Technology in a “Naked” form
Are Having Dismal Repercussions on Our Economy. American Scientist 63:
70–82.
CAN. 2000. Decisión 486 de la Comunidad Andina – régimen común sobre
Propiedad Industrial. Lima. Available at: http://www.wipo.int/edocs/lex-
docs/laws/es/can/can012es.pdf
Cardoso, F., and E. Faletto. 1969. Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina.
México DF: Siglo Veintiuno Editores.
Carrillo, C. 2006. De patentes y derechos de los pueblos indígenas. Revista
Cultura Científica 83: 31–37.
CEPAL. 2009. Panorama de la inserción internacional de América Latina y el
Caribe, 2008–2009: crisis y espacios de cooperación regional. Santiago de Chile.
Available at: http://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/panorama-de-la-insercion-
internacional-de-america-latina-y-el-caribe-2008-2009-crisis
———. 2010. La hora de la igualdad. Brechas por cerrar, caminos por abrir.
Santiago de Chile. Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/han-
dle/11362/13309/S2010986_es.pdf
———. 2012. Panorama de la inserción internacional de América Latina y el
Caribe. Santiago de Chile. Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.org/bit-
stream/handle/11362/1186/S1200769_es.pdf?sequence=1
———. 2013. La Inversión Extranjera Directa en América Latina y el Caribe.
Santiago de Chile. Available at: http://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/
36805-la-inversion-extranjera-directa-en-america-latina-y-el-caribe-2013
———. 2016a. Ciencia, tecnología e innovación en la economía digital: La situ-
ación de América Latina y el Caribe. Santiago de Chile. Available at: http://
www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/40530-ciencia-tecnologia-innovacion-la-
economia-digital-la-situacion-america-latina
———. 2016b. El imperativo de la igualdad: por un desarrollo sostenible en América
Latina y el Caribe. Santiago de Chile. Available at: http://www.cepal.org/es/
publicaciones/40120-imperativo-la-igualdad-un-desarrollo-sostenible-amer-
ica-latina-caribe
Chang, H.-J. 2002. Kicking Away the Ladder – Development Strategy in Historial
Perspective. London: Anthem Press.
THE REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF KNOWLEDGE... 213
Cleveland, C.J., R. Costanza, A.S. Hall, and R. Kaufmann. 1984. Energy and the
United States Economy: A Biophysical Perspective. Science 80 (225): 890–897.
Correa, C. 2004. Tratados Bilaterales de Inversión: ¿agentes de normas mundiales
nuevas para la protección de los derechos de propiedad intelectual? Grain,
1–31.
Cottrell, W.F. 1955. Energy and Society: The Relation Between Energy, Social
Change, and Economic Development. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Falconí, F. 2001. Integrated Assessment of the Recent Economic History of
Ecuador. Population and Environment 22: 257–280.
———. 2013. En el Sur de las decisiones. Quito: El Cornejo.
Finetti, C. 2011. Traditional Knowledge and the Patent System: Two Worlds
Apart? World Patent Information 33: 58–66.
Furtado, C. 1970. Economic Development of Latin America. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press.
Gault, F. 2006. Measuring Knowledge and Its Economic Effects: The Role of
Official Statistics. In Advanced Knowledge and the Knowledge Economy, ed.
B. Kahin and D. Foray. London: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.
Gómez, M., M. López, and A. Araujo de la Mata. 2008. Los ADPIC Plus en los
actuales tratados bilaterales impulsados por los Estados Unidos y Consecuencias
en los países en desarrollo. Revista de Economía Mundial 20: 23–48.
Gudynas, E. 2009. Inserción internacional y desarrollo latinoamericano en tiem-
pos de crisis global: una crítica a la CEPAL. Observatiorio de la globalización 7:
1–12.
Heckscher, E. 1919. The Effect of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income.
Ekonomisk Tidskrift 21: 497–512.
Hufbauer, G. 1966. Synthetic Materials and the Theory of International Trade.
London: Buckworth.
Huň ady, J., and M. Orviská. 2014. The Impact of Research and Development
Expenditures on Innovation Performance and Economic Growth of the
Country – The Empirical Evidence. CBU International Conference on
Innovation, Technology Transfer and Education, pp. 119–125.
International Monetary Fund. 2016. IMF Primary Commodity Prices. Available at:
http://www.imf.org/external/np/res/commod/index.aspx
Jaffe, A., and R. Stavins. 1994. The Energy-Efficiency Gap. Energy Policy 22 (10):
804–810.
Krugman, P., and M. Obstfeld. 2001. Economía internacional: Teoría y Política.
Madrid: Addison Wesley.
Lall, S. 2000. The Technological Structure and Performance of Developing
Country Manufactured Exports, 1985–1998. Oxford Development Studies 28
(3): 337–369.
Lederman, D., and W. Maloney. 2003. Research and Development (R&D) and
Development. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 3024, 1–37.
214 P. CANGO ET AL.
Luis Fuentes and Gustavo Durán
Introduction
The city is where the results and contradictions of regional development
are depicted and observed; such as growth, wellbeing, inequality, and
informality within a determined global position. The protagonism acquired
by urban settlements has once again driven the debate about the impor-
tance of urban policies and the management of metropolitan areas in many
places in the world. As indicated by Harding (2005), the study of city gov-
ernments, especially of the connections between the local, regional,
national, and supranational levels of the public sector, becomes strategic,
This work was possible thanks to financial support of the Technological and
Scientific Research National Commission from Chile through the projects N°
1141157 and N° 15110020.
L. Fuentes (*)
Pontifica Universidad Católica, Santiago, Chile
G. Durán
Departamento de Asuntos Publicos, FLACSO Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
given that its governance is in the center of the relationship and the balance
between the urban competitiveness and social cohesion, principle objec-
tives of public action. Today, in LA, priorities have been linked to urban
policies that correspond to a “classic” development agenda (infrastructure,
services, education, health, etc.) as well as those that arise in a new context
of urban evolution (security, mobility, citizen participation, etc.).
South America is not an exception to this. It is one of the regions with
the highest level of urbanization in the world (80%), with almost one third
of its population residing in cities of more than one million inhabitants
(ECLAC 2014). These factors intensify the visibility and the importance
of the metropolitan government. Above all, if we consider that, in addi-
tion to the classic South American development problems (informality,
inequality, lack of infrastructure, wellbeing, among others), there are other
complexities, which are the product of the insertion of its countries in the
global stage (migration, organized crime, illegal trafficking, and others).
In relation to this, several experiments have been carried out since the 90s,
in terms of urban policies with important and positive effects on the public
sphere. Some of these are the cases of public transport policies in Lerner’s
Curitiba, citizen culture and public transport in Mockus’, and later
Peñalosa’s Bogota, and lastly, the interventions in the poor neighbor-
hoods of Fajardo’s Medellin.
Taking the context of the region-city ratio in South America and the
different metropolitan administration models that reflect this ratio into
consideration, and using this as a reference point, the objective is to analyze
the forms of administration and management of the metropolitan areas of
Bogota, Lima, Quito, and Santiago, while facing urban challenges. Through
this research, we aim to find similarities and differences in institutionalism
that operates in these geographic areas and their responsibilities in terms of
competitiveness and economic development, transportation and infrastruc-
ture, spatial planning, social development, and the environment.
Why these cities? The justification that makes the comparison between
these cities attractive is that they are the capitals located within South
America known as the Andean region. Historically, the South American
countries with earlier and more advanced urbanization processes were
those on the Atlantic coast, exposed to an intense exchange with Europe.
In the present day there is a globalizing shift that marks the region
converting the Pacific coast into a strategic zone in terms of global trade,
reflected in the relevance of the main cities of the region. Today, three
regional urban agglomerations of more than ten million inhabitants can be
CITIES IN THE SOUTH AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT: BOGOTA, LIMA, QUITO... 219
One of the main difficulties in analyzing the cities in this study relates to
their physical delimitation, an issue that is increasingly more complex
according to the specialized bibliography (Mongin 2006; Dematteis
1996). In spite of this, it is necessary to establish certain limits that define
what it is that we are referring to, when we speak of the metropolitan area
of Bogota, Lima, Quito, or Santiago. For this reason, and considering that
each of the countries to which these cities belong have distinct criteria to
define when we speak of a city or a metropolitan area, we have chosen to
consider delimitation from a legal point of view, facilitating analysis from
different perspectives.
In the case of Colombia, the metropolitan areas have legal recognition
from the highest legal body in the country. The PCC of 1991 recognizes
metropolitan areas as a need generated by urban growth, when it states:
Models
Supramunicipal Intermunicipal
Under the Autonomous
Characteristics authority of the linked with the Autonomous
Autonomous
central central Fragmented
government government
Immediate
It is part of the
power between
regional or Association or Association or
the central,
provincial cooperation of cooperation of
Links with other provincial and
government all some of the
areas of power regional
municipalities of municipalities of
government or
Local dependent an area an area
the
municipalities
municipalities
Different and
variable. It
Different and depends on the
Jurisdiction precise agreements and
jurisdiction coordination of
the
municipalities
CITIES IN THE SOUTH AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT: BOGOTA, LIMA, QUITO... 223
Besides this general regulation, the PCC defines a special regime for Santa
Fe de Bogota, the capital of the Republic, and of the Department of
Cundinamarca, organized as a District Capital (D.C) (Art. 332 of the
PCC). So, in the case of this research, the metropolitan area of Bogota is
territorially represented by 20 localities that jointly form the administra-
tive unit of Bogota, D.C. This territorial unit has a surface area of
177,598 hectares, representing 0.15% of the national territory, of which
approximately 25% (around 45,000 hectares) correspond to the urban
area with the rest categorized as rural area, according to the Higher
Mayor of Bogota D.C. According to the National Administrative
Department of Statistics, Bogota D.C. contributes around 22% to national
GDP. On the other hand, according to the 2015 census, the Colombian
capital has a population of 6,840,116, which represents 16% of the total
population of the country, being Colombia’s political, cultural, and eco-
nomic center.
Peru’s case is different from that of Colombia, given that the PCP of
1993 does not establish the possibility for the constitution of metropolitan
areas, However, Art. 198 establishes a special measure for the capital:
“The Capital of the Republic does not integrate any regions. It has a special
regime in decentralization laws and in the Organic Law of Municipalities.
The Metropolitan Municipality of Lima exercises its competencies within
the area of the Lima Province.”
In the other cases, the organic laws of the municipalities establish coordi-
nation mechanisms, integrated by the district mayors of the respective
jurisdictions, who coordinate the plans, programs, projects, and budgets
of the municipalities of the province.
In that sense, the metropolitan area of Lima comprises the large conur-
bation of Lima including the agglomeration of the Callao Province. This
means that administratively, it consists of 49 districts, 12% belonging to
Callao and the remainder to the Lima Province. The study area corresponds
224 L. FUENTES AND G. DURÁN
Political 4. Counties
Administrative
Divisions 3. Provinces 3. Departments 5. Parishes
3. Districts (10)
(53) (24) (1035)
visions for the municipalities, and by the Decree Law 1.421 of 1993
(Special Regime for Santa Fe de Bogota, D.C.). The administrative struc-
ture of the District Capital incorporates the central sector, the decentral-
ized sector, and the localities. The mayor of the locality is designated by
the Higher Mayor, as defined by Decree Law 1421 that establishes the
political, administrative, and fiscal regime under which the localities of the
cities operate.
Regarding the central government, the President of the Republic is the
Head of State, the Head of the government, and the highest administra-
tive authority. The national government is formed of the President of the
Republic, the Cabinet Ministers, and the Directors of the administrative
departments.
In Peru, according to Art. 189 of the Constitution, the territory of the
Republic consists of regions, departments, provinces, and districts, whose
boundaries are established and organized by the government on a national,
regional (regions and departments), and local (provinces and districts)
level. It is important to explain that two special territories exist in this
context: the Lima Province and the Callao Constitutional Province, which
are governed by a special statute. In the case of this research, they are the
most relevant since together, they form the metropolitan area of Lima.
The Metropolitan Municipality of Lima, the political-administrative
unit that has jurisdiction over the Lima Province, has a special regime,
granting it powers and competencies of a Regional Government (Art. 198
of the PCC, and 33 of the Law for the Decentralization of Bases). So
according to this, the Mayor of Metropolitan Lima exercises responsibili-
ties of the Regional President, as the executive body, and the Metropolitan
Assembly of Lima exercises competencies and functions of the Regional
Coordination Council as an entity for consulting and coordination. A spe-
cial legal regime is recognized for the Metropolitan Municipality of Lima,
whereby it takes on corresponding functions of regional governments in
the form of an exception, without creating its own region, producing an
integration of municipal functions (on a metropolitan level and on a local
government level) as well as a regional function, in the same entity, based
on different regulations (Municipality of Lima 2014).
On the other hand, the Callao Constitutional Province has a political-
administrative constituency of a special regime: being a province, it has
regional autonomy, with a Regional Government (the Callao Regional
Government). The Regional Government has political, economic, and
administrative autonomy regarding the issues of its jurisdiction and they
228 L. FUENTES AND G. DURÁN
Main
Type of
Responsibilities
Metropolitan
of the Funding
Administration
Metropolitan
Model
Institutionalism
Broad
responsibilities
in the areas of Own resources
economics, obtained by
BOGOTÁ Supramunicipal territorial means of taxes
planning, and possibility
infrastructure, to go into debt.
transport and
environment.
Exclusive and
mostly shared
responsibilities
Own resources
in the areas of
and transfers
economic
from the central
development,
government.
territorial
Intermediate Transfers by
planning,
model, means of
infrastructure
LIMA institutionally compensation
and
and spatially funds and
environment.
fragmented possibilities to
Several
go into debt,
authorities for
with control
the coordination
from the central
of decisions
government.
with limited
decision-making
power.
Own income
Exclusive and and transfers
shared in the from a central
Intermunicipal
areas of level. Mostly of
linked to the
SANTIAGO territorial the
central
planning, municipalities
government
education and depend on the
health Common
Municipal Fund
Own resources
Jurisdiction over
obtained from
the planning of
taxes, fees, and
Metropolitan land,
the possibility to
QUITO Municipal management of
go into debt
Model basic services,
with guarantees
transit and
from the central
transport
government
230 L. FUENTES AND G. DURÁN
From the perspective of the tax regime, the income of the Regional
Governments comes from moveable assets and real estate property, assig-
nations and transfers from the central government, economic rights that
are generated due to privatization or granted concessions, resources
assigned by the RCF, and resources that are a product of financial opera-
tions and loans and regional taxes. Additionally, Lima’s Metropolitan
Municipality possesses other tax sources, due to the Municipal Organic
Law, such as: urban property tax, “Alcabala” tax,4 vehicle property tax,
taxes on non-sports public spectacles, and gambling taxes. In addition to
these local taxes, the municipalities receive resources from the MCP.
Santiago de Chile’s case is different from all the previous cases.
According to the models reviewed in literature, in spite of having a regional
government, the responsibilities of this public entity are weak to the extent
that it is the representation of the President and its ministries in the region,
due to which its autonomy remains contingent upon the objectives of
politics. Moreover, this institutionalism can be characterized as a decen-
tralized or inter-municipal model, where the municipalities exercise
authority in matters related to urban development by means of responsi-
bilities and areas related to territorial planning and several other public
services.
From the point of view of funding of these institutions, in the first case,
the Regional Government of Santiago is funded by transfers from central
government, as it has neither its own income nor the possibility to go into
debt. Art. 69 of the Regional Administration and Government Law speci-
fies the wealth of these institutions.
In the case of the Municipalities, Art. 13 specifies the forms of funding
for these local institutions. Some of the most important ones are moveable
assets and real estate property; the contribution granted by the regional
government; income generated by the participation in the common
municipal fund; vehicle registration certificates, trade patents, among
others.
Regarding the responsibilities of regional governments, in terms of the
control of processes of territorial transformation, they are restricted, with
the exception of matters related to urban regulation on a regional and
intercommunal level. Specifically regarding the responsibilities in the area
of economic development and competitiveness, they do not have an exclu-
sively relevant responsibility; only a shared level.
From the point of view of territorial planning and development, the
municipalities have the instruments for the elaboration and application of
CITIES IN THE SOUTH AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT: BOGOTA, LIMA, QUITO... 233
Conclusions
In general terms, the four analyzed cities, reflect the different variants of
metropolitan administration models described here. Bogota’s case is simi-
lar to the model characterized as consolidated, metropolitan or supra
municipal, and Santiago is similar to the decentralized or inter-municipal
model. Lima would have an intermediate model between the two extremes
with an intermediate coordination entity; however, spatially and institu-
tionally fragmented, and the metropolitan district of Quito is similar to
CITIES IN THE SOUTH AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT: BOGOTA, LIMA, QUITO... 235
better with the new management objectives in this global area, than a
“subsidiary” institution, to the extent that it can respond better to that
expected from a city in a world where urban jurisdiction prevails.
This is not the case for the metropolitan management models of Lima
and Santiago. First, there is a convergence of different stakeholders, with
distinct interests, making it impossible to carry out a city project, and the
leadership is diluted among the different institutions that take action in the
city in an uncoordinated way. On the other hand, the disagreement between
the geographic space and the institutions that take action in the territory,
make integrated urban management of urban development impossible.
However, the four cities face the “difficulty of the scale”, since the terri-
torial transformation processes do not adapt themselves to the scale in which
the different forms of metropolitan administration are established. In many
cases, institutionalism remains “over” and “under” the scale of agglomera-
tion, which would generate conflicts between the different stakeholders that
intervene in the transformation processes, and it does not adapt to the urban
environment, as a dynamic process, and in constant physical and functional
transformation of the territory. This become complex, especially when con-
sidering the characteristics of LA cities, where urbanization (formal and
informal) advances at high speed, in many cases, faster than the public poli-
cies. This has intensified to the extent that these countries are strengthening
their insertion processes in international markets, generating economic
dynamics that intensify social inequality and spatial segregation, among
other issues that affect the region’s development models of the region.
While the four countries represent different development models with
different emphases, their (global) threats and (internal) weaknesses are
relatively similar. In spite of the fact that all of the cities present institu-
tional differences, it seems that the homogenization forces of globaliza-
tion and the market are stronger than the regulatory public actions, in any
form. Therefore, metropolitan institutionalism represents a factor of low
incidence, to generate conditions for the social-territorial balance in the
economic, physical, and social development and transformation of the cit-
ies in this study (Fuentes and Orellana 2013).
Notes
1. Metropolitan Governance of the UN (1995).
2. While the constitution recognizes Easter Island and the Juan Fernandez
Archipelago as special territories, for the purposes of this study, such a situ-
ation is not relevant.
238 L. FUENTES AND G. DURÁN
3. Aquellas que, conforme a Ley, son delegadas a una entidad pública distinta
de la titular de la responsabilidad con la finalidad que sean ejecutadas con
mayor eficiencia. La responsabilidad frente a los ciudadanos no se delega
(Ley N° 26922 Marco de Descentralización).
4. The Alcabala tax charges for the transfer of real estate property against pay-
ment or for free, whichever may be its form or method, including sales with
reservation of title. The taxable amount wll be the value of the real estate
property, determined for Urban Property Tax purposes. The applicable rate
is 3%, charged to the buyer. The following are exonerated from this Tax: the
tranfer to goods related to the concession of public infrastructure impove-
ment works and public services according to the terms of the concession; as
well as equity transfers as a result of mergers, divisions or any other type or
reorganization of state-owned companies, in the case of private investment
state-owned companies.
Bibliography
Allard, P., A. Orellana, and R. Néspolo. 2009. Indicadores de Gestión Urbana
Municipal. Santiago: Progress Report of the Fondecyt Project.
Arenas, F. 2008. Obstáculos para la Gobernanza de los espacios metropolitanos
chilenos: Fragmentación institucional, desarticulación instrumental, atom-
ización social. En Ciudad, Poder y Gobernanza, ed. G. Yáñez, A. Orellana,
O. Figueroa and F. Arenas, 67–76. Santiago de Chile: Eure Libros y Geo
Libros.
Ascher, F. 2001. Los Nuevos Principios del Urbanismo. Madrid: Alianza.
Barrena, X. 2010. La nueva área de BCN emerge como el contrapeso de Madrid.
El Periódico de Cataluña, January 02, 33.
Begg, I. 1999. Cities and Competitiveness. Urban Studies 36 (5–6): 795–809.
Benko, G. 1996. Economia, espaço e globalização: na aurora do século XXI. Sao
Paulo: Huicitec.
Borja, J., and M. Castells. 1997. Local y Global: La gestión de las ciudades en la era
de la información. Madrid: Santillana.
Bourne, L. 1999. Modelos alternativos para el manejo de las regiones Metropolitanas:
El desafío para las ciudades norteamericanas. Memoria del Foro Internacional
sobre metropolización. Available at: http://www.urbaninternational.utoronto.
ca/ NewDocs/metforum_2.pdf
Brenner, N. 2003. La formación de la ciudad global y el re-escalamiento del espa-
cio del Estado en la Europa occidental Post Fordista. EURE 29 (86): 5–35.
Buck, N., I. Gordon, A. Harding, and I. Turok. 2005. Changing Cities. Rethinking
Urban, Competitiveness, Cohesion and Governance. New York: Palgrave
Macmillan.
CITIES IN THE SOUTH AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT: BOGOTA, LIMA, QUITO... 239
Alejandro I. Canales
Introduction
Even though international migration forms part of the priority axes of the
social agenda and modern politics, its analysis and debate are defined and
restricted by a set of ideological and political preconceptions as well as by
theoretical methodological perspectives that skew and distort its under-
standing. One of these weaknesses corresponds to methodological nation-
alism, which is the underlying factor behind a large part of the social and
political thinking of our era. Consequently, the Nation State would restrict
its territorial borders, forming an entity of analysis, observation, and theo-
rization valid in itself, transferring this identification to all of the categories
of analysis of social reality. As such, the processes that go beyond the
national environment, in this case migrations, are conceptualized as inter-
national processes and relations, namely, between nations, and not as com-
ponents of a global process (Canales 2002).
The fact is that within globalization, the national social space has been
passed through and reconfigured by a complex system of networks and
the UK, Italy, and Spain, as well as in the USA, the senior adult population
has gone from representing less than 12% of the population in the 70s, to
almost 20% currently. As a result, the Ageing Index has almost doubled in
these countries, going from a ratio of at least 60 senior adults for every
100 children in the 80s, to a ratio of more than 120 senior adults for every
100 children currently.
This change in the structure of the age distribution of the population
generates a significant demographic deficit of young people, which creates
room for international migration that would fill these gaps caused by the
aging of the population in developed countries. In the case of the USA,
for example, between 2000 and 2013 the native population aged 15 to 49
reduced by 10.8 million people. On the contrary, the Hispanic population
of the same age range increased by 9.9 million people, while other minori-
ties did so by 5.8 million people. A similar situation occurred in Spain as
in the USA. While births in Spain reduced by almost 2.0 million people,
international immigrants of this age range increased by 3.7 million people
(Canales 2015b).
These data show how in the USA, Spain, and other developed countries
in Europe, migration from peripheral countries has contributed to filling
the demographic gap created by the dynamics of these populations.
However, this process has a consequence; that in the medium and long
term, a virtual demographic replacement of the population in these coun-
tries would take place, where the native population must share its current
privileges with the emerging ethnic and migratory minorities.
In the case of the USA, for example, in 1970, the demographic promi-
nence of non-Latin white people was undeniable, representing 84% of the
total population. By the year 2010, however, this prominence reduced,
representing less than 65% of the total population. Similarly, it is predicted
that by the year 2050, the number of non-Latin white people will reduce
to only 46.3% of the total population; no longer being the absolute major-
ity. On the contrary, the high volumes of LA migration, together with
their higher birth rate, pose an opposite situation. While in 1970, they
represented less than 5% of the total, by 2010, they reached 16% and the
prediction is that by 2050 they will represent at least 30% of the total
population (Canales 2015b).1
If these distinct growth dynamics continue, Latinos will no longer be
an ethnic minority, becoming the second relative majority, relativizing the
traditional demographic prominence of the non-Latin white population.
GLOBAL AND REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MIGRATION 247
90s, when it grew to around 3.1 million people per year, starting a quick
and sustained descent since then, to the extent that by 2040, a reverse
cycle of an absolute decrease in the population of active age will
commence.
In this context, maintaining the current rates and volume of emigration
in the medium term will negatively impact the dynamics of the population,
putting not only its growth at risk, but also its capacity for intergenera-
tional replacement.
analyze the revenue flow, and by those means, the conditions for growth
in economic activity, as well as the distribution between the different eco-
nomic agents (Samuelson and Nordhaus 2010).
From a structuralist perspective, we can use the same operating model
of the economic system to link the areas of consumptions on the one
hand, with the production areas on the other hand, classifying both of
them in the process of the reproduction and accumulation of capital. In
this sense, we can understand the functioning of the economy as the com-
plementarity of two different moments:
Graph 11.4 USA, 1995–2016. Accumulated deficit of labor force and coverage
by ethnic minorities
and occupations oriented towards taking care of sick people, children and
the elderly, food preparation, cleaning and maintenance, among others,
increasingly filled by migrant workers.
The commercialization of domestic services is not new in capitalist soci-
eties. The new part in the current situation is that, in developed countries,
the massive demand for these type of workers occurs in the context of
social and demographic changes that we have already indicated. The
demographic aging, the massive integration of women into the labor mar-
ket, the changes in the formation and structure of homes, the reduction in
fertility rates, among others, drive the increasing demand for workers who
dedicate themselves to these tasks. Similarly, native women who previously
dedicated themselves to these activities are decreasing in number, as they
increasingly opt for less compromising jobs and enjoy a higher valuation
and social prestige, and therefore better salaries and work conditions
(Parella Rubio 2003).
This situation manifests in a structural imbalance between demand and
supply in this labor market, creating space for immigrant women arriving
from peripheral countries to incorporate themselves into these types of
markets in the central countries, carrying out tougher domestic tasks, such
as cleaning, maintenance and taking care of people, among others (Escrivá
2000).
This growing demand for immigrants to work in the so-called repro-
ductive and personal services, leads to an emerging form of a social divi-
sion of work, that adopts a transnational form, and is based on a form of
“transfer of inequalities in class and ethnicity” (Parella Rubio 2003: 15).
In fact, the emancipation of native women from developed countries who
have freed themselves from chains that tied them to domestic chores and
reproduction environments, has actually transferred these conditions of
subordination and vulnerability to immigrant women who require this
income for their own social reproduction, and who are forced to disregard
their own liabilities and reproductive responsibilities of their families who
have stayed behind in their countries of origin.
In this context, it is not surprising that a process of ethno-stratification
arises (Catarino and Oso 2000), or a racialization of reproductive services
(Hondagneu-Sotelo 2007), i.e., of a socio-labor differentiation based
more on ethnic-migratory factors, than on the labor credentials of each
person. In this respect, the data for the USA allow us to illustrate these
processes of the racialization of occupations.
GLOBAL AND REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MIGRATION 263
On the one hand, we can see that the occupational structure is clearly
differentiated according to the ethic-migratory condition. While in occu-
pations at higher levels of the occupational hierarchy (directors, profes-
sionals, executives) the participation of white non-Latin workers
predominates (69%), in the occupations at the lower strata of the occupa-
tional structure (domestic service, caretaking, cleaning and maintenance,
food preparation, among others), the participation in this demographic
group drops to only 48%.
On the contrary, demographic minorities show an opposite labor inte-
gration. The case of the workers of Latino origin (first and second genera-
tion immigrants) stands out, who while representing 16% of the labor
force, only obtain 8% of the high position jobs of the occupational struc-
ture. However, they represent 33% of construction workers, and 25% of
workers in personal services and social reproduction activities of the native
population.
These data indicate that the occupational polarization in the case of the
USA, adopts the form of an ethnic differentiation, establishing differenti-
ated occupational segments for each demographic group according to its
ethnic and migratory condition.
It would seem that the occupational integration of each worker is deter-
mined more by their ethnic origin than by their merits and productive and
labor credentials.
This racialization of occupations also has its counterpart in the form
taken on by the social inequality and income distribution in the USA. While
white people represent 72% of the population in the highest social stratus,
Latinos only represent 7%. On the contrary, in the strata with lower
income the opposite occurs. In this case, the population of white origin
represents only 42% of the poor population and 47% of the population in
a vulnerable situation. However, Latinos and other ethnic minorities
(mainly Afro-Americans), represent 51% of the population in a situation of
poverty and 47% of the population in a situation of economic vulnerability
(Graph 11.5).
These data show how social inequality in the USA acquires a racialized
form, where the ethnical and migratory condition tends to be an essential
factor for determining the social and economic position of individuals in
class structure and in income distribution. It concerns a situation that
shows the level of ethnic and migratory discrimination that characterizes
the actual social structure of this country.
264 A.I. CANALES
Graph 11.5 USA, 2016. Occupational and social class structure, by ethnic
minorities
Conclusions
In this text, we have presented an analytical model based on three axes
from where we can understand and theorize the role of migration in the
reproduction of modern society. We refer to migration as a structuring
factor of (i) the reproduction of populations, (ii) the reproduction of capi-
tal, and (iii) the reproduction of class structure and social inequality.
From a demographic perspective, migration creates a system of comple-
mentarity that connects the patterns of demographic reproduction in the
origin and destination places. In the countries of origin, migration repre-
sents an escape valve, while facing a demographic bonus that the local
economy is not able to fulfil. In the destination countries, migration
enables the demographic gaps to be filled, that are left by the ageing of the
population and the reduction in births resulting from the advancement of
the second demographic transition.
From an economic perspective, we understand the role of migration
from three complementary points of view: (i) on the one hand, migration
is essentially labor, and therefore, a mechanism for the supply of labor
force for capital; (ii) similarly, it is not simply the migration of one single
worker, but of a group of workers that are socially vulnerable and inserted
into precarious, flexible, and unstable jobs; (iii) finally, the remittances that
GLOBAL AND REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MIGRATION 265
are sent by the migrants, are salary transfers that enable the reproduction
of their families. In this way, migration contributes to closing the circle of
the reproduction of capital, sustaining the connection between the local
reproductive moment (the labor force in local environments) with the
global productive moments (work and labor insertion in the destination
economy).
Finally, the role of migration in the reproduction of class structure and
social inequality is seen as a connection between the two moments. On the
one hand, by means of insertion in occupations of the social reproduction
environment in destination places, migrants contribute to maintaining the
reproduction of the population of the middle and higher class in these
societies. On the other hand, remittances and social networks activated
with migration represent a reproduction strategy of these migrants, their
families and their communities.
The integrated vision of these three moments (demography, econom-
ics, social classes), allows us to reach a higher level of understanding of
international migration, understanding it as a component and author of
the reproduction of modern global society.
However, this same model for the understanding of migration allows us
to identify the risks and tensions that accompany it and imprint it with a
substantial level of uncertainty. Specifically, we can indicate at least three
dynamics that can come into existence in its limits and risk areas that need
to considered and theorized.
On the one hand, migration from peripheral countries, in particular
from LA countries, is based on the conditions of the generation of a popu-
lation surplus resulting from the incapacity of the local economic dynam-
ics to absorb the population growth in active ages that generates the
demographic bonus. However, as we have seen, the Demographic Bonus,
as with any bonus, has an expiration and collection date, which in the case
of the South American countries is about to expire within a few decades.
In this context, the risk for our societies is that by maintaining the current
rates and volumes of migration, the reproduction of our own populations
will be seriously compromised.
On the other hand, the demographic situation in the destination coun-
tries also creates substantial tension with regard to the implications and
consequences of migration. Considering the high degree of advancement
in the level of aging and the low birth rates, it is highly probable that
migration would end up being the basis of an ethnic replacement process,
where the current condition of demographic improvement of the native
266 A.I. CANALES
Notes
1. Coleman documents similar tendencies (2006) in the case of seven European
countries (Austria, England, Denmark, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway,
and Sweden), where by 2050, the population of migrant origin will repre-
sent between 24% and 36% of the population.
2. The other 27% divides among Afro-Americans, Asians, Aboriginals, and
other minorities. Data from the Current Population Survey, March
Supplement of 2015.
3. It worth mentioning that the most recent data of demographic projections
of the US Census Bureau indicate that this current situation of demographic
replacement and replacement and age distribution that is currently occur-
ring in California, will extend to the entire country during the next decades
(Canales 2015b).
4. CEPALstat, http://estadisticas.cepal.org/cepalstat/WEB_CEPALSTAT/
Portada.asp
GLOBAL AND REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MIGRATION 267
Bibliography
Appadurai, A. 1990. Disjuncture and Difference in the Global Cultural
Economy. Theory, Culture and Society 7: 295–310. https://doi.
org/10.1177/026327690007002017.
BBVA. 2015. Yearbook of Migration and Remittances Mexico 2016. México:
Fundación BBVA. Available at: https://www.gob.mx/cms/uploads/attach-
ment/file/109457/Anuario_Migracion_y_Remesas_2016.pdf
Beck, U. 2000. What Is Globalization? Cambridge: Oxford Polity Press.
Bongaarts, J. 2001. Fertility and Reproductive Preferences in Post-Transitional
Societies. In Global Fertility Transition, Supplement to Population and
Development Review, ed. R.A. Bulatao and J.B. Casterline, vol. 27, 260–282.
New York: Population Council.
Canales, A. 2002. El concepto de globalización en las ciencias sociales. Alcances y
significados. In El norte de todos. Migración y trabajo en tiempos de globalización,
Compiled by A. Canales, J. Arroyo y P. Vargas, 23–64. México: Universidad de
Guadalajara, UCLA, PROFMEX y Juan Pablos Editores.
———. 2008. Vivir del norte. Remesas, desarrollo y pobreza en México. México:
National Population Council (CONAPO). Available at: http://www.omi.gob.
mx/work/models/OMI/Resource/472/canales2008.pdf
———. 2011. Hacia una visión comprehensiva del nexo entre Migración,
Desarrollo y Derechos Humanos. In Migración y Desarrollo, 16 (9): 43–78.
Available at: http://rimd.reduaz.mx/revista/rev16/2.pdf
———. 2015a. E Pur Si Muove. Elementos para una teoría de las migraciones en el
capitalismo global. México: M.A. Porrúa. Available at: https://www.academia.
edu/28272877
———. 2015b. El papel de la migración en el sistema global de reproducción
demográfica. Notas de Población. Santiago de Chile: CELADE, Año XLII, 100:
91–123. Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/han-
dle/11362/38514/S1500199_es.pdf?sequence=1
Castells, M. 1996. The Rise of the Network Society. The Information Age: Economy,
Society, and Culture. Vol. I. Cambridge: Blackwell Publishers.
Catarino, C., and L. Oso. 2000. La inmigración femenina en Madrid y Lisboa:
hacia una etnización del servicio doméstico y de las empresas de limpieza. In
PAPERS, Revista de Sociología. Barcelona: Universidad Autónoma de
Barcelona, 60: 183–207. Available at: http://www.raco.cat/index.php/
papers/article/viewFile/25572/25406
Coleman, D. 2006. Immigration and Ethnic Change in Low-Fertility Countries:
A Third Demographic Transition. In Population and Development Review,
32 (3): 401–446. Available at: http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/
j.1728-4457.2006.00131.x/pdf
Cooke, M. 2003. Population and Labour Force Ageing in Six Countries. In
Workforce Aging in the New Economy, Working Paper. Canada: University of
Western Ontario, 4: 49.
268 A.I. CANALES
Ehrenteich, B., and A. Russel Hochschild. 2004. Global Woman. Nannies, Maids
and Sex Workers in the New Economy. New York: Henry Holt and Company.
Escrivá, A.M. 2000. ¿Empleadas de por vida? Peruanas en el servicio doméstico en
Barcelona. In PAPERS, Revista de Sociología. Barcelona: Universidad Autónoma
de Barcelona, 60: 327–342. Available at: http://papers.uab.cat/article/view/
v60-escriva/pdf-es
FOMIN. 2015. Las remesas a América Latina y el Caribe superan su máximo valor
histórico en 2014. Washington DC: Fondo Multilateral de Inversiones, FOMIN,
Banco Mundial. Available at: http://idbdocs.iadb.org/wsdocs/getDocument.
aspx?DOCNUM=39619559
Guzmán, J.M. 2002. Envejecimiento y desarrollo en América Latina y el Caribe. In
Serie Población y Desarrollo. Santiago de Chile: Centro Latinoamericano y Caribeño
de Demografía (CELADE) – División de Población, 28: 47. Available at: http://
repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/7166/1/S025388_es.pdf
Herrera, G. 2005. Mujeres ecuatorianas en las cadenas globales del cuidado. In La
migración ecuatoriana. Transnacionalismo, redes e identidades, ed. G. Herrera
et al. Quito: Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales.
Herrera Ponce, M.S. 2007. Individualización social y cambios demográficos:
¿hacia una segunda transición demográfica? Colección monografías. Madrid:
Centro de Investigaciones Sociológicas, no. 232.
Hondagneu-Sotelo, P. 2007. Doméstica: Immigrant Workers Cleaning and Caring
in the Shadows of Affluence. Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Massey, D. 1990. Social Structure, Household Strategies, and Cumulative
Causation of Migration. Population Index 56 (1): 3–26.
Parella Rubio, S. 2003. Mujer, inmigrante y trabajadora: la triple discriminación.
España: Editorial Anthropos.
Redondo, N., and S. Garay. 2012. El envejecimiento en América Latina. Evidencia
empírica y cuestiones metodológicas. Serie Investigaciones. Río de Janeiro:
Asociación Latinoamericana de Población, no. 13. Available at: http://www.
alapop.org/alap/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1112&It
emid=437
Samuelson, P., and W. Nordhaus. 2010. Economics, 19/e. New York: Tata McGraw-
Hill Education.
Sassen, S. 1995. Immigration and Labor Market. In The Economic Sociology of
Immigration, ed. A. Portes, 87–127. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
———. 2007. Sociology of Globalization. New York: W.W. Norton.
UN. 2001. Replacement Migration: Is It a Solution to Declining and Ageing
Populations? United Nations, Population Division. United Nations Publication,
ST/ESA/SER.A/206. Available at: http://www.un.org/esa/population/
publications/migration/migration.htm
GLOBAL AND REGIONAL POLITICAL ECONOMY OF MIGRATION 269
Daniel Pontón and Tomás Guayasamín
Introduction
The emergence of TOC as a new global threat has generally been the
scope of international security studies, a result of the connotations that
this phenomenon has for world peace. Illegal trafficking of drugs, weap-
ons, persons, and money laundering form part of a strongly interrelated
clandestine world. This setting has enabled the creation of a regional func-
tional agenda that has prompted the progressive integration of sub-
regional and regional mechanisms aimed at fostering cooperation and
exchange of police information focused on the prevention and repression
of crime, especially on a strategic level. This basis has supported interna-
tional governance against TOC (Andreas and Nadelmann 2005), whose
purpose, amongst other things, is to contribute to the protection of liberal
peace and the development of nations (Duffield 2007).
D. Pontón (*)
Instituto de Altos Estudios Nacionales del Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
T. Guayasamín
Department of International Studies, FLACSO Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
elements for the study of formal structures of the fight against crime.
Thus, for this study, we identify the AMERIPOL; the SISME; and, on a
bilateral level depending on the participating countries, the areas of coop-
eration named: COMBIFRON, Security Committees, or Defense and
External Relations Commissions, as the most relevant experiences in terms
of cooperation and exchange of information of the police in LA.
On a hemispheric level, AMERIPOL was created as a mechanism to
overcome asymmetries through the education and promotion of technical
scientific assistance, the exchange of information, criminal investigation,
and legal assistance (AMERIPOL 2012: 2). Its organic structure consists
of 29 police forces from 26 countries and 21 permanent observing agen-
cies. They have a Center of Hemispheric Prospective and Security that
monitors crimes on a regional scope and a System of Exchange of Police
Information, which enabled the execution of the operation “Without
Borders” against organized crime in June 2016 as a joint enterprise in 13
countries of the region (AMERIPOL 2016).
Meanwhile, the cooperation in terms of police and public security in
the framework of MERCOSUR and Associated States was institutional-
ized through different meetings of Ministers of Internal Affairs. In 2004,
this forum established SISME, inspired by its European counterpart of the
Schengen Agreements (Ugarte 2005). Since then, the tool has been per-
fected for the exchange of information through “national nodes” that
operate via telematics and that can be used to detect police incidents,
consultations of vehicles, weapons, or individuals with charges or warrant
for arrest or prison (Ugarte 2009). Currently, SISME interconnects
national databases of 10 countries, which has made it possible, for exam-
ple, to carry out operation “SPARTACUS” in 2012, an initiative against
human trafficking that led to the rescue of 365 victims and the arrest of
197 individuals (INTERPOL 2013).
On a bilateral level, binational mechanisms for the exchange of infor-
mation facilitate mutual trust through a joint analysis of the issue in com-
mon border areas. This has enabled the existence of instructions,
operational procedures, security passbooks, and communication systems
in case of possible border security incidents, in order to establish actions
for quick solutions at borders. In general, the composition of members
mostly consists of the highest authorities of the Communication,
Intelligence and Military, and Police Counterintelligence Units.
An important point, in any case, is that this bureaucratic instrument for
the fight against TOC suffers from a weakness for international studies: its
276 D. PONTÓN AND T. GUAYASAMÍN
analysis lies in the state sphere as a basic and homogenous police entity,
based on power relations. Furthermore, it supports research in a structure
of an international system that is close to positivist epistemology, material-
ism, and methodological rationalism (Buzan 2014). As a consequence,
TOC has been interpreted as a type of “low intensity war” in which power
ends up adapting itself to face the conflicts generated by TOC or other-
wise, and that this practice enables the recreation of these conflicts for
specific political or geopolitical purposes.
Based on these coordinates, while there is no majority consensus yet,
advanced academic debates maintain that studies regarding police gover-
nance against TOC should differ from classic security and defense studies
that are only centered around the state. On the contrary, the analysis
should focus on the philosophy of “social defense” (Baratta 2004: 37), in
other words, as a natural response of international society to unwanted
behavior and activities, where the regulations and institutions are of uni-
versal application to guarantee essential conditions for the existence of the
entire society (Buzan 2014). With this in view, and following Deflem
(2000: 748), police agencies should maintain relative autonomy regarding
the police centers of their states, so that the international police system can
operate beyond certain interests and political needs of one single state, and
eventually even influence the appreciation of the states regarding the issue.
In this regard, and while it has been said that police action is function-
ally carried out through regulations and procedures established with prior
political concurrence included some cases of undercover intelligence oper-
ations; the fact remains that there is a degree of informality and discretion
as a part of the habitus of this world. In effect, the use of this underground
system by the players forms part of a complex “gray area” that ends up also
being an active element in the management, dynamics, and configuration
of a clandestine world with limited access to civil society.
system; meaning that on the one hand, it contributes to the regulation and
control of TOC in an adaptive way, and on the other hand, it favors the
morphology, escalation, and reproduction of TOC in LA and its political
interpretation. In other words, from a constructivist perspective, it is an
informal system molded and molds this complex criminal world.
This “gray governance” can be found on the one hand, in the effective
materialization of a system of “criminal governance” that aims to mediate
between the tactical and strategic interests of the states, and the interests
of criminal groups (Arias 2006 quoted by Schultze-Kraft 2016). An exam-
ple of this relates to the network of alliances and disputes among illegal
actors that operate in the TOC economies, when at the end of the 80s,
Colombia found itself in a fratricidal struggle between the Medellin and
Cali cartels. The police and the Colombian military, together with various
intelligence agencies from the USA, joined forces to stop the violence
whose genesis goes back to competition in the cocaine market in the main
capital cities of the world. As such, while the Orejuela brothers, the drug
lords of the Cali cartel, had around 3000 people working for them around
the world, in the form of “sleeper cells”, in charge of opening legal busi-
nesses and living the most normal possible lives, Escobar, the head of the
Medellin cartel, negotiated with high level state officials, such as members
of parliament and judges (Salazar 2012). Both cartels had spy and counter-
spy offensives, which over time led to betrayals on both sides. In this
regard, according to an interview published in a report of the BBC news-
paper regarding William Rodríguez, one of the heirs of the Cali cartel, it
was publicly stated that the cartel managed by his father was helping the
authorities for a long time, financially as well as with information, and that
“they were an important bastion of the fall of Escobar.” (BBC 2014)
Likewise, there are other enigmatic cases, such as those specified in the
research of the journalist Anabel Hernández in her book Los Señores del
Narco [The Narcos] (2010). Through her book, she reveals how the
Mexican cartels managed to count on the support of high-level federal
agents, such as the Judicial Police, the Prosecutor’s Office, and the
AFI. The Zetas, for example, took advantage of the relationship that they
had with several officers of the Mexican military and the Prosecutor’s
Office to detect the position of their enemy, Osiel Cardneas, ex-leader of
the Golfo cartel. A persecution and war provoked by the possession of
land was also the liberation between the criminal organization “La
Federación” [The Federation] with the cartels of the Golfo and the Zetas;
in this case, the ex-leader of La Federación, “El Chapo Guzmán”, while he
280 D. PONTÓN AND T. GUAYASAMÍN
Bibliography
Adler, E., and P. Greve. 2009. When Security Community Meets Balance of
Power: Overlapping Regional Mechanisms of Security Governance. Review of
International Studies 35 (1): 59–84.
AMERIPOL. 2012. Estatuto Ameripol, Reunión de Consejo de Directores,
November 29.
———. 2016. Tras Operación SIFCO III se logra el decomiso de más 1 tonelada de
droga en el continente. July, Available at: http://www.ameripol.org/portalAm-
eripol/appmanager/portal/desk?_nfpb=true&_pageLabel=portals_portal_
page_m2p1p2&content_id=70001&folderNode1=66002
286 D. PONTÓN AND T. GUAYASAMÍN
Cintia Quiliconi and Raúl Salgado Espinoza
Introduction
Regionalism in South America in the twenty-first century has been
observed in various forms and it has been academically developed into a
great variety of approaches. This investigation proposes that the fact that
there are many types of regionalism in the region demonstrates that we
can mainly speak of a regionalism à la carte in a world of various regional-
isms and uncertainty of the “benefits” of globalization.
In the context of a regionalism à la carte, international actors of region-
alism behave selectively and, according to their preferences, they choose
the type of regionalism required for their action in an behavior of “forum
shopping” (Hofmann and Mérand 2012). In the same way as political
international actors look for their appropriate field for action, researchers
tend to choose one appropriate approach according to their topic of inter-
est and the objectives of their investigation.
First, LA states see in the proliferation of regionalism an expanding
menu of opportunities for the representation and positioning of their
interest (Quiliconi and Salgado 2017). Second, there is no homogeneity
Table 13.1 Regional organizations created in the twenty-first century and their
diversity of aims
Regional Organizations & full Some differences in their explicit objectives
members
ALBA: 11 member states To unify members’ capabilities and strengths in order
from the Caribbean and to produce structural transformations and the
South America, including necessary system-network for an integral development
Bolivia, Ecuador, and To defend the independence, self-determination, and
Venezuela identity of their members
UNASUR: all 12 South To create a space for integration and a cultural, social,
American states economic, and political union among the peoples,
prioritizing political dialogue, as well as social and
educational policies.
To promote the political dialogue, the South American
integration, and its world projection
To support social and human development, eradicate
poverty, and overcome inequalities in the region
To consolidate a South American identity
To protect biodiversity, water resources, and ecosystems
To promote cultural diversity
To cooperate in the area of human security and exchange
information and experiences in the field of defense
CELAC: 33 member states To promote and project a harmonized voice of LAC in
from LAC, including all 12 the political discussion about the big topics and the
South American states relevant events, regionally and globally
To become the regional interlocutor in international
conferences and meetings
To become a mechanism of dialog and agreement for
the strengthening of the social, economic, and political
links among its members
AP: Chile, Colombia, Mexico, To promote the free movement of goods, services,
and Peru capital, and people
To boost the growth, development, and
competitiveness of their economies
To become a platform of economic integration and
world projection with emphasis on the Asian Pacific
Source: Own elaboration on the basis of the foundational treaties and declarations of the ALBA, the
UNASUR, the CELAC, and the AP
296 C. QUILICONI AND R.S. ESPINOZA
already shows a fundamental basis for the explicit objectives (those being
in the Treaties, Agreements, or Foundational Declarations). At the same
time, it allows us to infer further implicit objectives. However, here only
the main differences in their explicit objectives will be explored, in order
to understand the presence of a regionalism à la carte in South America.
These explicit objectives differ particularly between the AP and the
three other regional organizations. As shown in the following table,
whereas the aims of the AP focus on the economic mechanism of integra-
tion and economic development, the other three regional organizations
place emphasis on the political dialog, as well as, social and human
development.
Although the ALBA, the UNASUR and the CELAC place emphasis on
political dialog as a mechanism for international projection, all three
endeavors play a diverse role in extra-regional politics. For example, the
ALBA has as an aim to influence the change of international structures and
establishes anti-capitalist aims, the UNASUR aims to construct a South
American identity, and the CELAC aims to become a regional interlocutor
for its members with extra-regional international actors.
Moreover, this table shows that none of these regional organizations
contains all possible aims of the four organizations referred. Hence, the
South American regionalism of the present decade cannot be considered
as a single project, despite the fact that the Treaty of the UNASUR sug-
gests using the experiences of the CAN and the MERCOSUR, implying a
convergence of these two, but the organization has systematically avoided
the task of combining both trade agreements. It also includes a variety of
further areas for cooperation based on positive integration. Namely a new
regional integration based on political issues, promotion of regional inter-
dependencies, and cooperation in various sectoral areas such as infrastruc-
ture, finance, security, education, and democratic stability, among others
(Sanahuja 2010) but avoiding the topic of consolidating trade integration
between the CAN and the MERCOSUR. In contrast to the economically
driven regionalism of the AP, the three other new initiatives are embedded
in a “re-politicization” (Dabène 2012) of LA in which the overlapping
existence of economically and politically driven regional initiatives reflects
the alternative ideologies that have prevailed in the region and that ended
up creating a complex geopolitical map of variable geometry in which vari-
ous alternative projects coexist (Sanahuja 2014).
This variety of regional organizations with different aims has also
opened up a new menu of alternatives and complementary fora to pursue
THE SOUTH AMERICAN REGIONALISMS: A SHIFT OR THE RETURN... 297
The current regional situation appears uncertain due to two main trends
at the regional and hemispheric level. On one hand, at the domestic politi-
cal level the end of the political cycle of left-wing governments in key
South American countries, i.e., Argentina and Brazil, poses big questions
of which country will lead regionalism in the subsequent years. In this
sense, the change from a left-wing to a right-wing government in Argentina
poses impairments on South American Regionalism given that the new
president has so far avoided attending any summits of the UNASUR or
the CELAC and has publicly declared intention to join the AP and sign
preferential agreements with the EU and the USA. In a similar vein, Brazil,
THE SOUTH AMERICAN REGIONALISMS: A SHIFT OR THE RETURN... 299
Brazil is not yet positioned for a strong recovery from its recession and
faces a weak political situation.
On the other hand, Argentina is still fighting high inflation and fiscal
deficits. Finally, to complete the picture, Ecuador is in a delicate situation
due to falling oil revenues and the lack of a monetary policy due to its dol-
larized economy in a region where most countries have already depreciated
their currencies. Clearly, this situation directly affects the level of commit-
ment that South American countries have towards regionalism. As we
pointed out before, the lack of leadership in many of the regional initiatives
has become one of the most common characteristics in a regionalism à la
carte. In this context, Malamud (2017) suggests that regionalism has
receded and diversification or à la carte regionalism has not paid off in a
context in which US hegemony has receded. Paradoxically, China appears as
the only counter hegemon capable of exerting leadership in South America.
Summing up, it could be said that in a situation of a contested interna-
tional neoliberal order, poor regional leadership, lacking economic resources
and weakness of the instruments of regionalism and integration set up by
left-oriented regimes, the other options on the menu for cooperation,
trade, and integration can be reconsidered and revitalized in South America.
As part of the wave of globalization of the 90s, many PTAs between the
USA and countries from the South took place and continued to be
arranged in the first decade of the twenty-first century as a way of deepen-
ing the export-oriented strategies propelled by the neoliberal policies,
which were supported mainly by the USA and the EU. Those PTAs have
particularly intensified in the 2000s with the characteristic of crossing the
North-South divide. This is one of the factors of regionalism in the twenty-
first century and which was referred to in a previous investigation as neo-
liberal regionalism reloaded (Quiliconi and Salgado 2017). In LA this
particular development was crystallized by the creation of the AP that
gathers those countries that have active joined the trend of North-South
preferential trade agreements.
This development created the impression that globalization was still
spreading at the beginning of the present decade. However, this global-
izing development experienced two big backlashes in 2016. First, the UK
voted to abandon the EU through a close referendum, and most recently,
302 C. QUILICONI AND R.S. ESPINOZA
Conclusion
South American regionalism is experiencing a phase of uncertainty and
lack of homogeneity. The period of the boom of commodities and the
contrasting ideological factors of the governments in power have moti-
vated the creation of a variety of regional international organizations that
make up a menu of regionalism à la carte whereby political actor (states)
can behave as being in a “shopping forum”. Some states with right-wing
governments have maintained a close relationship with the USA and have
signed commercial treaties with it and with the EU enabling these actors
to play a more prominent role in the region in subsequent years. On the
other hand, regional organizations created during the domination of the
left-wing governments such as the ALBA and the UNASUR appear to be
in decline and are showing a tendency to play a back-seat role in the South
American regionalism due to a financial and political crisis affecting the
whole region and the return of right-wing governments. In this context,
304 C. QUILICONI AND R.S. ESPINOZA
Notes
1. RCEP is a proposed free trade agreement between the ten member states of
the ASEAN that gathers Brunei, Cambodia, Indonesia, Laos, Malaysia,
Myanmar, the Philippines, Singapore, Thailand, and Vietnam, and the six
states with which ASEAN has existing free trade agreements (Australia,
China, India, Japan, South Korea, and New Zealand). RCEP negotiations
were launched formally in November 2012 at the ASEAN Summit in
Cambodia.
Bibliography
Allard, R. 2013. Explorando nuevos caminos de regionalización e integración en
América Latina y El Caribe. Relaciones Internacionales 44: 115–145.
Briceño Ruíz, J. 2013. Ejes y Modelos en la Etapa Actual de la Integración
Económica Regional en América Latina. Estudios Internacionales 45 (175):
9–39. https://doi.org/10.5354/0719-3769.2013.27352.
———. 2017. Latin America Beyond the Continental Divide: Open Regionalism
and Post-Hegemonic Regionalism Co-Existence in a Changing Region. In
Post-Hegemonic Regionalism in the Americas. Toward a pacific-Atlantic Divide?
ed. J. Briceño Ruíz and I. Morales, 73–98. London: Routledge.
CEPAL. 2014. La Alianza del Pacífico y el MERCOSUR. Hacia la Convergencia
en la Diversidad. Available at: http://repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/han-
dle/11362/37304/S1420838_es.pdf?sequence=1
Dabène, O. 2009. The Politics of Regional Integration. Theoretical and Comparative
Explorations. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
———. 2012. Consistency and Resilience Through Cycles of Repoliticization. In
The Rise of Post-Hegemonic Regionalism: The Case of Latin America, ed.
P. Riggirozzi and D. Tussie, 41–64. London/New York: Springer.
Gardini, G.L. 2015. Towards Modular Regionalism: The Proliferation of Latin
American Cooperation. Revista Brasileira de Política Internacional 58 (1):
201–229.
Hofmann, S., and F. Mérand. 2012. Regional Organizations à la carte: The Effects
of Institutional Elasticity. In International Relations Theory and Regional
Transformation, ed. T.V. Paul, 133–157. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Jenne, N., and L. Schenoni. 2015. Latin American Declaratory Regionalism: An
Analysis of Presidential Discourse (1994–2014), EUI Working Paper RSCAS
2015/53.
Legler, T. 2013. Post-Hegemonic Regionalism and Sovereignty in Latin America:
Optimists, Skeptics and an Emerging Research Agenda. Contexto Internacional
35 (2): 325–352.
306 C. QUILICONI AND R.S. ESPINOZA
Leví Coral, M., and G. Reggiardo. 2016. La Alianza del Pacífico en el regional-
ismo sudamericano actual. Revista Mexicana de Política Exterior 106: 187–204.
Malamud, A. 2017. As a Meaningful Diplomatic and Economic Unit, Does South
America Still Make Sense? Available at: http://latinamericagoesglobal.
org/2017/01/6192/
Nolte, D., and N. Comini. 2016. UNASUR: Regional Pluralism as a Strategic
Outcome. Contexto Internacional 38 (2): 545–565.
Nolte, D., and L. Wehner. 2013. The Pacific Alliance Casts Its Cloud over Latin
America. GIGA Focus 8: 1–8. Available at: https://www.giga-hamburg.de/
en/system/files/publications/ gf_international_1308.pdf
Ocampo, J. A. 2017. Will Trump Block Latin America’s Recovery? Avaliable in:
https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/trump-latin-america-
economy-by-joseantonio-ocampo-2017-01.
Quiliconi, C. 2013. Modelos competitivos de integración en el Hemisferio
Occidental: ¿liderazgo competitivo o negación mutua? Revista CIDOB d’afers
internacionals 102–103: 147–168.
———. 2017. From Open Regionalism to Neo-Extractivism: A New Geography
of Trade in Latin America? In Post-Hegemonic Regionalism in the Americas.
Toward a Pacific-Atlantic Divide? ed. J. Briceño Ruíz and I. Morales, 57–72.
London: Routledge.
Quiliconi, C., and S. Kingah. 2016. Conclusion: Leadership of the BRICS and
Implications for the European Union. In Global and Regional Leadership of
BRICS Countries, ed. S. Kingah and C. Quiliconi. New York: Springer.
Quiliconi, C. and R. Salgado. 2017. Regionalism à la Carte in a Multipolar World.
Colombia Internacional, forthcoming.
Riggirozzi, P., and D. Tussie, eds. 2012. The Rise of Post-Hegemonic Regionalism.
London/New York: Springer.
———. 2016. The Shadow of Brexit: Delegating or Pooling Sovereignty? Available at:
https://sotonpolitics.org/2016/07/08/the-shadow-of-brexit-delegating-
or-pooling-sovereignty/
Rodrik, D. 2016. Don’t Cry Over Dead Trade Agreements. Avilable at: https://
www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/no-mourning-dead-trade-agreements-
by-dani-rodrik-2016-12
Saltalamacchia Ziccardi, N. 2014. The Rise of Latin American Multilateralism:
Something Old, Something New. Prepared for delivery at the 55th Annual
Convention of the International Studies Association, Canada. Available at:
https://www.academia.edu/10716353/ The_Rise_of_Latin_American_
Multilateralism_So mething_Old_Something_New
———. 2015. Regional Multilateralism in Latin America, UNASUR, ALBA and
CELAC. In Routledge Handbook of Latin America in the World, ed.
J. Domínguez and A. Covarrubias, 298–310. New York: Routledge.
THE SOUTH AMERICAN REGIONALISMS: A SHIFT OR THE RETURN... 307
Timothy M. Shaw
An earlier & shorter version of this paper appeared as the Preface to the revised
paperback edition of Cornelissen et al. (2015) published in the Palgrave
Macmillan IPE Series in Spring 2015, ix–xxi.
Emerging Worlds/Regimes?
Each proposed grouping of, or acronym for, EMs & FMs embodies
slightly different sets of assumptions/directions/implications; PWC
expanded the “Next-11” of Goldman Sachs (i.e., 15 without South Africa)
to 17 significant EMs by 2050 (Hawkesworth and Cookson 2008): what
implications for transnational governance? Also, Laura Carsten Mahrenbach
(2013) put EM and EP together for her case studies of Brazil and India
(2/3 of the IBSA (Stuenkel 2015)), combining their roles in both inter-
national economy and global diplomacy.
Symptomatically, the initial iconic acronym was proposed at the start of
the new century by a leading economist working for a global financial
corporation—Jim O’Neill (2011) of Goldman Sachs (www2.goldma-
nsachs.com) —who marked and reinforced his initial coup with celebra-
tion of its first decade. As he noted at the start of the second decade,
global restructuring has been accelerated by the simultaneous decline, of
not only the USA and UK, but also the southern members of the Eurozone.
Many now predict China to become the largest economy by 2025, having
overtaken the USA in purchasing power parity (PPP) terms by 2015, with
India to catch-up with the USA by 2050 (Hawkesworth and Cookson
2008: 3). PWC (2013: 6 and 8) suggests that:
“By 2050, China, the USA, and India are likely to be the three largest econ-
omies in the world …”
AFRICA: CLUES ABOUT THE TENDENCIES OF THE GLOBAL SOUTH 315
But, Stuart Brown (2013: 168–170) notes that there are competing
prophecies about the cross-over date when China trumps the USA, start-
ing with the IMF advancing such a transition (transformation?) to 2016
(cf. Kiely 2015).
As the G8 morphed into the G20 (Cooper and Antkiwicz 2008) a vari-
ety of analysts/agencies attempted to map the emerging world, including
Parag Khanna’s (2009) “second world” and Fareed Zacharia’s (2011)
“rest”: for example:
Emerging Economies/States/Societies?
Africa’s economy is growing steadily. Last year average growth was 3.9% and
it is set to accelerate this year … FDI is helping to spur growth. It is expected
to reach US$55 billion in 2015, 20% higher than in 2010. Inflows of capital
are increasingly focused on less resource-rich countries as investors target
the continent’s booming middle classes. The amount of investment into
technology, retail, and business services increased by 17% between 2007 and
2013. FDI is also becoming a two-way affair. Last year, Africa’s outward
investment hit US$11.4 billion, up nearly two-fifths since 2011–2012.
(“Investment in Africa” box The Economist 2015b)
The salience of “emerging markets”, especially the BRICS and other politi-
cal economies in the second world, has led to debates about the similarities
and differences among emerging economies/middle classes/multinational
companies/states/societies, etc., informed by different disciplinary can-
nons; e.g., by contrast to Andrea Goldstein (2007) on EMNCs, Pieterse
(2011) privileges sociologically-informed emerging societies. In turn,
especially in IR, there are burgeoning analyses of emerging powers/
regional and otherwise (Flemes 2010; Jordaan 2003), some of which
might inform new regionalist perspectives, especially as these are increas-
ingly impacted by the divergence between BRICS and PIIGS. In turn, they
inform and advance alternative definitions of, and directions for, develop-
ment post-2015 (Grant et al. 2014).
Despite the US subprime and EU euro crises at the start of the twenty-
first century, FDI in Africa continues to grow, reaching US$50 billion in
2013, more than double ODA, primarily from outside the OECD: China,
India, and Malaysia, and myriad SWFs and SOEs. The drivers are increas-
ingly services for the burgeoning middle class (e.g., banking, real estate,
retail, telecoms, tourism, etc.) plus food and energy (www.un.org/africa/
osaa). The Globe & Mail (2015) suggested that “Africa’s clicking”.
However, the continent’s ranking in the latest Global Competitiveness
Report/Index from the WEF (www.weforum.org) is not overly impressive
or reassuring, at least compared to the BRICS: the top ten is led by
Mauritius (#39 globally), followed by South Africa (#56), Rwanda (#62),
and Botswana (#74), with #10 being Lesotho (#107 globally); by con-
trast, the top of the BRICS listing is China (#28) and the lowest India
(#71), with the remaining trio being in the fifties (as above, South Africa
# 56). The bottom of the competitiveness index, like that for fragile states,
318 T.M. SHAW
Varieties of Development
“Development” was a notion related to post-war decolonization and bipo-
larity. It was popularized in the “Third World” in the 60s, often in relation
to “state socialism”—an official euphemism for one party even one man
rule—but superseded by neoliberalism and the Washington Consensus.
Yet the NICs then BRICs pointed to another way, by contrast to those in
decline, like fragile states (Brock et al. 2012); such “developmentalism”
(Kyung-Sup et al. 2012) has now even reached Africa (Hanson et al. 2014,
UNECA 2011, 2012). However, while the “global” middle class grows in
the South (Dayton-Johnson 2015), increasingly, major cruise-line compa-
nies—such as Carnival, Royal Caribbean, and Norwegian—sail out of
Shanghai and Singapore, as well as Miami, so do inequalities along with
NCDs such as cancers, heart disease, and diabetes.
Nevertheless, Africa has advanced as well as benefitted from mobile
technologies, from cell phones to mobile finance such as M-Pesa, devel-
oped in Nairobi at its iHub, its mini-MIT, Waterloo or Cambridge (UK).
IBM opened a research lab in Kenya’s capital mid-decade and now, in
2015, a trio of Kenya’s major universities is to build a basic laptop com-
puter, for over one million schoolchildren, with an initial US$ 170 million
from the government.
Given the elusiveness as well as limitations of the MDGs (Wilkinson
and Hulme 2012), the UN has been debating and anticipating post-2015
development desiderata (www.un.org/millenniumgoals/beyond2015)
including appropriate innovative forms of governance (Campbell 2013) as
AFRICA: CLUES ABOUT THE TENDENCIES OF THE GLOBAL SOUTH 319
Varieties of Capitalisms
The world of capitalisms has never been more diverse: from old trans-
Atlantic and trans-Pacific to new—the Global South with its own diversi-
ties, such as Brazilian, Chinese, Indian, and South African “varieties of
capitalisms”. Andrea Goldstein (2007) introduced emerging market
MNCs in the IPE Series, including a distinctive second index—five pages
of company names of EMNCs (see next paragraph)—and Andreas Nolke
(2014) has developed such comparative analysis of EMNCs in the middle
of the second decade. And, in the post-neoliberal era, SOEs, especially
NOCs (Xu 2012), are burgeoning. Both US/UK neoliberal, continental/
Scandinavian corporatist, and Japanese/East Asian developmentalist “par-
adigms” are having to rethink and reflect changing state-economy/society
relations beyond ubiquitous “partnerships” (Overbeek and van Apeldoorn
2011). Furthermore, if we go beyond the formal and legal, then myriad
informal sectors and TOC/money-laundering/OFCs are ubiquitous
(Findley et al. 2014).
For the first time, in the “Global Fortune 500” of (July) 2012, MNC
HQs were more numerous in Asia than in either Europe or North America.
There were 73 Chinese MNCs so ranked (up from 11 a decade ago, in
2002) along with 13 in South Korea, and eight each in Brazil and India.
Each of the BRICS/EMs hosted some global brands: Geely, Huawei and
Lenovo (China), Hyundai, Kia and Samsung (Korea); Embraer and Vale
(Brazil); Infosys, Reliance, and Tata (India); Anglo American, De Beers,
and SABMiller (South Africa), etc. On 20 June 2015, The Economist based
on Boston Consulting Group data reported that, “private wealth in Asia
overtook that in western Europe in 2014 and is set to overtake North
America by 2016”. It also noted that, “by 2021 it (China) will overtake
America as the world’s wealthiest nation”. And, in the August 2015
320 T.M. SHAW
Fortune Global 500 listing, China had almost 100 companies identified
(98 actually) (www.fortune.com/fortune500)!
Reflective of African growth prospects, as already noted in (i) above, by
2013, there were over 20 ETFs on sale at the JSE. Market Vectors’ Africa
ETF invested most in Egypt, South Africa, Nigeria, and Morocco, espe-
cially in: banking, breweries, and cement (www.vaneck.com). Many of its
largest investments are Nigerian: First, Guaranty Trust, United and Zenith
banks, and Nigerian Breweries. Meanwhile, the increasingly diversified (in
both products and locations, let alone markets) Nigerian Dangote Group
cement empire, owned by the continent’s richest man (at US$25 billion),
is expanding into a dozen African economies, from Senegal to Ethiopia,
into pastas, salt, and sugar, from cement, logistics, and real estate (www.
dangote.com), just as global cement giants, Lafarge and Holcim, agreed a
proposed merger. Also, in the first half of 2014, Nigeria announced that it
had recalculated its GDP—now almost double the previous level (to over
US$500 billion), so, leap-frogging South Africa—but the supposedly
ubiquitous energy sector is now down to 14% GDP, less than half of previ-
ous estimate. This reflects growth sectors such as mobile telecoms and
Nollywood (1.4% GDP from nothing) plus manufacturing (7%). The main
sectors leading to this recalibration were telecoms and trading.
The pair of dominant economies in SSA is unquestionably Nigeria and
South Africa yet, despite being increasingly connected, they display strik-
ingly different forms of “African” capitalisms and governance. Nigeria,
including its mega-cities, Lagos and Ibadan, is a highly informal political
economy with a small formal sector (beer, consumer goods such as soft
drinks and soaps, energy, finance, telecommunications, etc.). By contrast,
despite its ubiquitous shanty-towns, South Africa is based on a well-
established formal economy centered on mining, manufacturing, farming,
finance, services, etc. Both have significant diasporas in the Global North,
especially the UK and the USA, including Nigeria’s in South Africa, espe-
cially Jo’burg, remitting funds back home. Since majority democratic rule,
South African companies and supply-chains, brands, and franchises have
penetrated the continent; initially into Eastern from Southern Africa, but
now increasingly into West Africa and Angola. Transnational relations in
Africa, as elsewhere, are increasingly subject to transnational regulation,
including fair trade, by multi-stakeholder groups and supermarkets to
MNCs, including SOEs in agriculture, energy, mining, and telecommuni-
cations (Mukherjee-Reed et al. 2012).
AFRICA: CLUES ABOUT THE TENDENCIES OF THE GLOBAL SOUTH 321
New Regionalisms
The proliferation of states along with capitalisms post-bipolarity has led to a
parallel proliferation of regions (Haastrup and Eun 2014), especially if
diversities of non-state, informal even illegal regions are so considered rather
than just traditional inter-state organizations. Also, the eurozone crisis con-
centrated in the PIIGS has eroded the salience of the EU as a model
(Dosenrode 2015), leading to a recognition of a variety of “new” regional-
isms (Flemes 2010). In turn, inter-regionalisms have proliferated from those
around the EU and the ASEAN towards novel multi-lateralisms around
emerging donors—e.g., China-African FOCAC (www.focac.org), Japan’s
parallel TICAD (www.mofa.go.jp)—and a proliferations of focused arrange-
ments ex-China, such as the AIIB, (www.aiibank.org) Chang-Mai Initiative
(CMI) and CMI Multilateralization, SCO (www.sectsco.org), and now the
BRICS’ Bank (wwwbrics6.itamaraty.gov.br; www.thebricspost.com).
These can now be claimed to include instances of “African agency”
(Brown and Harman 2013) like South African franchises and supply chains
reaching to West Africa and the recently formalized Trilateral FTA among
the COMESA, the EAC, and the SADC (T-FTA) (Hartzenberg et al.
2012) along with older/newer regional conflicts such as the GLR plus the
regional as well as global dimensions of, say, piracy off the coast of Somalia
(ACBF 2014). Such piracy has proliferated and intensified off West Africa
too, as oil generates illegal as well as legal supply chains; so-called “bun-
kering”. In addition, Africa is installing pipelines as well as broadband
cables in the Sahara, coast of West Africa, and, soon, East African oilfields
(Hicks 2015). As climate change increases, the continent is likely to need
water pipelines too. Together these erode any claims to Africa hosting
“gatekeeper states”: GVCs, hubs, logistics, etc., all part of “development”
in 2015, are largely defined by “private” interests and rules.
ACBF published a formal evaluation of African regionalism in 2004 but
was limited to inter-state arrangements. With the AfDB, it is undertaking
a more comprehensive evaluation mid-decade (details to be added from
ACBF draft and consultation in mid-2015). Moreover, Chatham House
in London is organizing a conference on “Advancing Inclusive Insurance
in Africa” in late-September, in Nairobi (www.chathamhouse.org)
Also, mid-decade, emulating China and its AIIB, AfDB, donors, and
African companies have established “Africa 50” for the continent to
finance its own infrastructure through indigenous developers and inves-
tors. (www.africa50.com) …
322 T.M. SHAW
Emerging out of an increasingly wired world with its very visible and ubiq-
uitous mobile “poles” and underground/undersea broadband wires, pro-
liferating mobile technologies increasingly facilitate the informal and
324 T.M. SHAW
Africa’s natural resources for all”, then “Grain, Fish, Money: financing
Africa’s green and blue revolutions”, and in mid-2015, on how Africa
can turn climate challenges into opportunities. In brief, Africa has some
of its ideas about post-2015, such as the AMV, reflecting is own desid-
erata and possibilities after a decade of more of sustained growth.
Some of the global INGOs are now based in Africa as well as elsewhere
in the global South (e.g., CIVICUS (www.civicus.org), which generates is
own civil society index and produces is own annual report on the sector
(2014). In addition, almost all of them work on the continent, now
including some from elsewhere in the Global South, such as BRAC from
Bangladesh now in five states in Africa: Liberia, Sierra Leone, South
Sudan, Uganda, and Tanzania (www.brac.net). Yet, CIVICUS (2014) still
ponders whether such changes really advance global governance in a sus-
tainable way (www.civicus.org).
Bibliography
ACBF. 2014. Africa Capacity Report 2014: Capacity Building for Regionalism in
Africa. Harare. Available at: http://www.acbf-pact.org/sites/default/files/
ACR%20Web%202014%2023122014_0.pdf
Acharya, A. 2009. Whose Ideas Matter? Agency & power in Asian regionalism.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Adejumobi, S., and Z. Kreiter. 2016. The Theory & Discourse of Developmental
Regionalism. New York: SADC, SSRC-APN & UNECA.
Akinola, O. 2015. Boko Haram Insurgency in Nigeria: Between Islamic
Fundamentalism Politics & Poverty. African Security 8 (1): 1–29.
Armijo, L.E., and S. Katada, eds. 2014. The Financial Statecraft of Emerging
Powers: Shield & Sword in Asia & Latin America. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Bergamaschi, I., P. Moore, and A.B. Tickner (eds). 2017. South-South Cooperation
Beyond the Myths – Rising Powers, New Aid Practices? London: Palgrave
Macmillan, forthcoming.
Bernstein, S., and B. Cashore. 2008. The Two-Level Logic of Non-state Market
Driven Global Governance. In Authority in the Global Political Economy, ed.
V. Rittberger and M. Nettesheim, 276–313. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Besada, H., and S. Kindornay, eds. 2013. The Future of Multilateral Development
Cooperation in a Changing Global Order. London: Palgrave Macmillan for
NSI.
Bevir, M. 2011. Sage Handbook of Governance. London: Sage.
Brock, L., H.H. Holm, G. Sorensen, and M. Stohl. 2012. Fragile States.
Cambridge: Polity.
Brown, S., ed. 2011. Transnational Transfers and Global Development. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
———. 2013. The Future of US Global Power: Delusions of Decline. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Brown, W., and S. Harman, eds. 2013. African Agency & International Relations.
Abingdon: Routledge.
Caliari, A. 2015. UN Financing for Development: The Fund & Bank’s Role &
Influence. London, At Issue: BW Project. Available at: www.brettonwoodspro-
ject.org
Campbell, B., ed. 2013. Modes of Governance & Revenue Flows in African Mining.
London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Carrier, N. 2015. Little Mogadishu: Eastleigh, Nairobi’s global Somali hub. London:
Hurst.
Chin, G., and F. Quadir (eds). 2012. Rising States, Rising Donors and the Global
Aid Regime. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 25 (4): 493–649.
Christensen, S.F., and Li Xing, eds. 2016. Emerging Powers, Emerging Markets,
Emerging States: Global Responses. London: Palgrave Macmillan, forthcoming.
328 T.M. SHAW
Cilliers, J., and T.D. Sisk. 2013. Assessing Long-term State Fragility in Africa:
Prospects for “More Fragile” Countries. Johannesburg: ISS, Monograph #188.
CIVICUS www.civicus.org
CIVICUS www.civicus.org
Cooper, A., and B. Momani. 2011. Qatar and Expanded Contours of South –
South Diplomacy. International Spectator 46 (3): 113–128.
Cooper, A.F., and A. Antkiewicz, eds. 2008. Emerging Powers in Global Governance:
Lessons from the Heiligendamm Process. Waterloo: WLU Press for CIGI.
Cornelissen, S., F. Cheru, and T.M. Shaw, eds. 2015. Africa & International Relations
in the 21st Century. London: Palgrave Macmillan. Revised paperback edition.
Daianu, D., C. Dadda, G. Basevi, and R. Kumar. 2014. The Eurozone Crisis and
the Future of Europe: The Political Economy of Further Integration and
Governance. Basingstok: Palgrave Macmillan.
Dayton-Johnson, J., ed. 2015. Latin America’s Emerging Middle Class: Economic
Perspectives. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
De Waal, A., ed. 2015. Advocacy in Conflict: Critical Perspectives on Transnational
Activism. London: Zed.
Dingwerth, K. 2008. Private Transnational Governance and the Developing
World. International Studies Quarterly 52 (3): 607–634.
Dosenrode, S., ed. 2015. Limits to Regional Integration. Farnham: Ashgate.
Dunn, K.C., and T.M. Shaw, eds. 2013. Africa’s Challenge to International
Relations Theory. London: Palgrave. Revised Classics pb edition.
Fanta, E., T.M. Shaw, and V. Tang, eds. 2013. Comparative Regionalism for
Development in the Twenty-First Century: Insights from the Global South.
Farnham: Ashgate for NETRIS.
Farah, A.O., and S. Dini. 2014. Transnational NGOs: Creative Insecurity &
Volatile Environment. Aalborg: AUP.
Feinstein, A. 2012. The Shadow World: Inside the Global Arms Trade. London:
Penguin.
Financial Times. 2015. This Is Africa: Special Report from the Financial Times.
Building Inclusive Economies: Can Africa Bridge the Development Divide? FT &
Rockefeller Foundation. Available at: www.thisisafricaonline.com
Findley, M.G., D.L. Nielson, and J.C. Sharman. 2014. Global Shell Games:
Experiments in Transnational Relations, Crime & Terrorism. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press. Available at: www.globalshellgames.com
Flemes, D., ed. 2010. Regional Leadership in the Global System. Farnham: Ashgate.
Friman, H.R., ed. 2009. Crime and the Global Political Economy. Boulder:
LRP. IPE Yearbook #16.
Globe & Mail. 2015. Report on Business Weekend, 11 July 2015 (B4).
Goldstein, A. 2007. Multinational Companies from Emerging Economies. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Grant, J.A., W.R. Nadege Compaore, and M.I. Mitchell, eds. 2014. New Approaches
to the Governance of Natural Resources. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
AFRICA: CLUES ABOUT THE TENDENCIES OF THE GLOBAL SOUTH 329
Haastrup, T., and Yong-Soo Eun, eds. 2014. Regionalising Global Crises: The
Financial Crisis & New Frontiers in Regional Governance. London: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Hanson, K.T., C. D’Alessandro, and F. Owusu, eds. 2014. Managing Africa’s
Natural Resources: Capacities for Development. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Harman, S., and D. Williams. 2013. Governing the World? Cases in Globbal
Governance. London: Routledge.
Harman, S.A. 2014. Terror & Insurgency in the Sahara-Sahel Region. Farnham:
Ashgate.
Hartzenberg, T., et al. 2012. The Trilateral Free Trade Area: Towards a New
African Integration Paradigm? Stellenbosch: Tralac.
Hawksworth, J., and G. Cookson. 2008. The World in 2050: Beyond the BRICs: A
Broader Look at Emerging Market Growth. London: PWC.
Henley, D. 2015. Asia-Africa Development Divergence: A Question of Intent.
London: Zed.
Hentz, J.J., ed. 2014. Routledge Handbook of African Security. Abingdon:
Routledge.
Hicks, C. 2015. Africa’s New Oil: Power, Pipelines & Future Fortunes. London: Zed.
Hirschfield, K. 2015. Gangster States: Organised Crime, Kleptocracy & Political
Collapse. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Hudson, I., M. Hudson, and M. Fridell. 2013. Fair Trade, Sustainability & Social
Change. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Jensen, S. 2015. The Making of International Human Rights: The 1960s,
Decolonization, and the Reconstruction of Global Values, Human Rights in
History. Berkeley: University of California.
Jerven, M. 2015. Africa: Why Economists Get It Wrong. London: Zed Books.
Johnston, D., and M. Jerven, eds. 2015. Statistical Tragedy in Africa. Journal of
Development Studies 51 (2): 111–115.
Jordaan, E. 2003. The Concept of Middle Power in IR: Distinguishing Between
Emerging and Traditional Middle Powers. Politikon 30 (2): 165–181.
Kararach, G., H. Besada, and T.M. Shaw, eds. 2015. Development in Africa:
Refocusing the Lens After the MDGs. Bristol: Policy Press, forthcoming.
Keohane, R.O., and J.S. Nye, eds. 1972. Transnational Relations and World
Politics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Khanna, P. 2009. The Second World: How Emerging Powers Are Redefining Global
Competition in the Twenty-First Century. New York: Random House.
Kiely, R. 2015. The BRICS, US ‘Decline’ & Global Transformations. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Klare, M. 2012. The Race for What’s Left: The Global Scramble for the World’s Last
Resources. New York: Picador.
Kliman, D.M., and R. Fontaine. 2012. Global Swing States: Brazil, India, Indonesia,
Turkey and the Future of International Order. Washington, DC: GMF.
330 T.M. SHAW
Kliman, D.M., J.W. Walker, and W. Inboden. 2013. Promising Partnerships:
Emerging & Established Powers in the 21st Century. Washington, DC: GMF.
Knight, W.A., and T. Keating. 2010. Global Politics. Toronto: OUP.
Kshetri, N. 2013. Cybercrime and Cybersecurity in the Global South. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Kyung-Sup, C., B. Fine, and L. Weiss, eds. 2012. Developmental Politics in
Transition: The Neoliberal Era and Beyond. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Lee, B., et al. 2012. Resources Futures. London: Chatham House. Available at:
www.chathamhouse.org/resourcesfutures.
Mahrenbach, L.C. 2013. The Trade Policy of Emerging Powers: Strategic Choices of
Brazil & India. London: Palgrave.
Mbabazi, P.K. 2013. The Oil Industry in Uganda: A Blessing in Disguise or an All
Too Familiar Curse? Uppsala: NAI, 2012 Claude Ake Memorial Lecture.
Available at: www.nai.diva-portal.org, www.isn.ethz.ch
Modi, R., ed. 2011. South-South Cooperation: Africa in the Centre Stage. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Moran, M. 2013. Private Foundations & Development Partnerships: American
Philanthropy & Global Development Agencies. Abingdon: Routledge.
Mukherjee-Reed, A., D. Reed, and P. Utting, eds. 2012. Regulation & Non-state
Actors: Whose Standards, Whose Development? Abingdon: Routledge for
UNRISD.
Nolke, A., ed. 2014. Multinational Corporations from Emerging Markets. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
O’Neill, J. 2011. The Growth Map: Economic Opportunity in the BRICs and
Beyond. New York: Portfolio/Penguin.
Obadare, E., ed. 2014. Handbook of Civil Society in Africa. New York: Springer.
Overbeek, H., and B. Van Apeldoorn, eds. 2011. Neoliberalism in Crisis. London:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Peter, M. 2014. Emerging Powers & Peace Operations: An Agenda for Research.
Oslo: NUPI Policy Brief #10.
Pieterse J. 2012. Twenty-First Century Globalization: A New Development Era.
Vol. 39, No. 3, 11, 367–385.
Pieterse, J.N. 2011. Global Rebalancing: Crisis and the East-South Turn.
Development and Change 42 (1): 22–48.
PWC. 2013. World in 2050: The BRICs and Beyond: Prospects, Challenges and
Opportunities. London. Available at: http://www.pwc.com/my/en/
press/130116-world_in_2050.html
Ritchey, L.A., and S. Ponte, eds. 2014. New Actors & Alliances in Development.
Third World Quarterly 35 (1): 1–195.
Roger, C., and P. Dauvergene. 2016. The Rise of Transnational Governance as
Field of Study. International Studies Review 18: 415–437.
Shaw, T.M. 2012. Africa’s Quest for Developmental States: “Renaissance” for
Whom? Third World Quarterly 33 (5): 837–851.
AFRICA: CLUES ABOUT THE TENDENCIES OF THE GLOBAL SOUTH 331
Conclusions
Ernesto Vivares
This concluding chapter extends and assesses the critical theoretical and
methodological discussion taken up in the introduction, in light of the
collective works presented by the authors of this collection. Accordingly,
the quest for this collective edition has focused on how a South American
IPE and regionalism may attempt to account for the orientations of
national and regional development in a time of uncertainty about the con-
flictive change of the post-1945 liberal world order.
We started this journey discussing where the major findings of LA IPE
end, including research on the historical structures of inequality, unsteady
regional development, and international insertions in the current unset-
tled post-war Neoliberal Order. The collective endeavor demanded under-
taking a multidisciplinary and eclectical, theoretical, and empirical study
about South America in order to evaluate, adapt, and adjust regional
knowledge for the new realities of change, in relation to the regional his-
torical caveats or major regional features mentioned. This involves focus-
ing on existent theoretical and methodological tools concerning regional
structural issues, identifying and deconstructing conceptual cages as well
as adjusting regional knowledge as a critical aggiornamento via a critical
and constructive dialog with Western and non-Western approaches. This
E. Vivares (*)
Department of International Studies, FLACSO Ecuador, Quito, Ecuador
chapter continues the analytical discussion of the introduction and sets out
key related findings.
the region with the world order and hegemon, where each one of these
LA regions present configurations and structures of development that
shape rather different regional identities. They are socio-historical config-
urations, different capitalisms, different underworlds, and varied struc-
tures for shaping different political economic settings and borders. The
LA regions are constructed, deconstructed, and re-constructed around
different axes of development by states and one state actor, defining a
formal and an informal region, regionalism as well as regionalization. To
think of the condition of a region as homogeneous, in terms of institu-
tional convergence, is a rational conceptual cage that can only lead to
sophisms.
diverse disciplinary approach, has taken that notion within their specific
disciplinary perspective, aiming at studying the domestic implications
and international links, creating a mosaic of IPE multidisciplinary South
American insights.
The book has departed from the hypothesis that what explains the dif-
ferent and diverse orientations of national and regional, as well as the set-
backs of development, rests on the resilience of the different historical,
unequal, and unsteady structures of the region. We define them as mate-
rial, institutional, and ideational configurations that work across the for-
mal and informal domestic development with their own settings of
international insertion. Oil and gas, knowledge, organised crime, trade,
and finance have their own singular international links; they overlap and
coexist and they define a unique regional configuration functional to an
order of things.
Historically, LA has been a region of peace but not of democracy and
citizen security, where development cuts across regional security, in
geopolitical economic terms. Security, for instance, is and has been for
decades, the first major structural continental issue for the North
American hegemon. LA can appreciate the fact that the US Southern
Command (SOUTHCOM) operated exclusively for the region, dedi-
cated to building partner capacities and fighting organized crime.
Security can be studied as an unique dimension but also in relation to
regional disequilibrium such as inequality, political instability, and inter-
national position. Security can be also be approached in relation to the
role of cities and metropoles in the region, to the environment and even
development finance.
Development finance is another example of a key structural regional
issue, although these days, by large, is more dependent of Washington.
Historically, regional development finance has shifted from one order to
the next, and the same in terms of economic sources. The structure has
been demonstrated by the significant contributions from LA scholars such
as Stephany Griffith-Jones (1984) and Leonardo Stanley and Jose
Fernandez, Chap. 5 in this book. This structural issue is the case of why
economics or politics, isolated and domestically focused, cannot provide
the answers to major structural configurations that frame the apparently
contradictory developments and orientations of the region.
To sum up, LA’s structures of development exist and have proved to be
powerfully resilient, despite decades of neoliberal and developmentalist
changes and reforms. Nonetheless, the resilience of these structures of
340 E. VIVARES
Bibliography
Acharya, A. 2011. Dialogue and Discovery: In Search of International Relations
Theories Beyond the West. Millennium: Journal of International Studies 39
(3): 619–637.
Acharya, A. 2014. Global International Relations (IR) and Regional Worlds. A
New Agenda for International Studies. International Studies Quarterly 58 (4):
647–659.
Bøås, M., M. Marchand, and T. Shaw, eds. 2005. The Political Economy of Regions
and Regionalism. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Bonilla, A., and G. Long. 2010. Un nuevo regionalismo sudamericano. Íconos:
revista de Ciencias Sociales 38: 23–28.
Braudel, F. 1979. Afterthoughts on Material Civilization and Capitalism.
Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Pres.
Griffith-Jones, S. 1984. International Finance and Latin America. New York: St.
Martin Press.
Ikenberry, J. 2011. Liberal Leviathan: The Origins, Crisis, and Transformation of
the American World Order. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Katzenstein, P. 2005. A World of Regions: Asia and Europe in the American
Imperium. Cornell: Cornell University Press.
Katzenstein P. 2009. Civilizations in World Politics: Plural and Pluralist
Perspectives. New York: Routledge.
Saguier, M., and Z. Brent. 2015. Regionalismo y Economía Social y Solidaria en
Suramérica. Estudios Internacionales 48: 133–154.
Söderbaum, F. 2003. Introduction: Theories of New Regionalism. In Theories of
New Regionalism, ed. F. Söderbaum and T. Shaw, 1–21. Houndmills: Palgrave
Macmillan.
———. 2012. Conceptualizing Region, Regionalism and Regionalization.
Unpublished.
———. 2013. What’s Wrong with Regional Integration? The Problem of
Eurocentrism. Working Papers N64: RSCAS.
Thorp, R. 2012. A Historical Perspective on the Political Economy of Inequality
in Latin America. In Latin American Political Economy, ed. J. Santiso and
J. Dayton-Johnson, 149–167. New York: Oxford University Press.
Index1
Competitiveness, 150, 172, 218, 230, 151, 152, 155–157, 160, 165,
232, 236, 295, 317 173–177, 179–182, 202, 205,
Conceptual cages, 3, 8, 11, 13–17, 206, 209, 224, 225, 228, 235,
333–335, 337 236, 249, 281–283, 295, 297, 301
Consumer goods, 91, 320 Education, 5, 26, 31, 41, 43, 59, 202,
Core suppliers, 171 206, 207, 209, 210, 218, 233,
Crime, 271, 275, 278, 283, 324 275, 296, 297, 324, 325
Criminal governance, 279, 284 Emerging economies, 44, 150, 154,
Criminal group, 272, 273, 279 158, 312, 317
Employment, 26, 29, 31–33, 40–43,
89, 90, 261, 297
D Energy, 17, 59, 79, 86, 87, 105, 109,
DEA, see Drug Enforcement 110, 112, 147–163, 204, 205,
Administration 209, 210, 292, 313, 315, 317,
Decision-making process, 219 318, 320, 322, 323, 336
Defense, 59, 276, 295 Energy integration, 147
Deindustrialization, 10, 67n12, 90, Environment, 4, 104, 157, 197–211,
199, 200, 210 218, 219, 230, 233, 237, 243,
Demographic bonus, 247, 249, 250, 244, 257, 258, 262, 265, 273,
264, 265 280, 324, 339
Demographic replacement, 245, 246, Epistemic community, 8, 16, 336
250, 266, 266n3 Epistemology, 14, 276
Demographic surplus, 249, 250 EU, see European Union
Demography, 244, 265 Eurocentric, vi, 8, 14–17
Developmentalism, 318 Eurocentric regionalism, 14, 16, 17
Development finance, 6, 10, 101, 339 European integration, 48
Development structures, 5, 12, European Union (EU), 4, 16, 17, 59,
197–201, 219–221, 244 65, 81, 130, 131, 138, 142,
Diasporas, 313, 316, 320, 322, 323, 173–175, 177, 179, 180, 182,
325 188, 204–208, 292, 298,
Distribution of income, 33 301–304, 317, 321, 334
Dollarized economy, 30, 131, 301 Eurozone, 310, 313, 314, 321
Drug Enforcement Administration Exportations, 121, 184–187, 193
(DEA), 274, 280, 281, 283, 284
Drug trafficking, 273, 274, 278,
280–285 F
Dutch Disease, 81, 91, 95 FDI, see Foreign direct investment
Fertility, 245, 262
Follow sourcing, 170
E Foreign direct investment (FDI), 79,
Ecology, 10, 18, 316, 326 82, 90, 92, 94, 105, 106, 109,
Ecuador, 25, 58, 61, 106, 112, 117n20, 110, 117n16, 117n17, 166, 172,
125, 129, 131, 141, 142n7, 148, 200, 310, 313, 317, 319
344 INDEX
PIIGS, see Portugal, Italy, Ireland, Regional government, 224, 227, 228,
Greece, Spain 231–233
Pink Tide, 2, 5, 16, 304 Regional integration, vi, 14, 17, 50,
Population, 3, 5, 10, 25–28, 35, 36, 51, 54–63, 129–132, 134, 137,
39, 40, 218, 223, 224, 228, 233, 139, 147, 148, 157–159, 162,
236, 244–247, 250, 255, 167, 185, 188, 296, 298–300,
258–261, 263–266, 266n1, 285, 302, 338
336 Regionalism, vi, 1, 2, 5–8, 11, 12,
Population reproduction, 244, 245, 14–17, 47–63, 271–285,
250, 258–261, 263–265 291–304, 311, 321, 333–335,
Populism, 8, 105 337, 338
Portugal, Italy, Ireland, Greece, Spain Regionalization, xxv, xxvii, 2, 147,
(PIIGS), 313, 317, 321 335, 338
Poverty, 3, 11, 25, 26, 28, 29, 32–37, Region-city, 218
39, 42, 59, 81, 263, 285, 295 Reprimarization, 5, 18, 47, 150, 161,
PRC, see People’s Republic of China 199, 200, 300
Primarization, 199 Reproduction of capital, 244,
Primary export, 32, 39, 43, 61, 63, 253–255, 258, 264, 265
135, 136, 138, 141, 153 Right-wing, 6, 8, 88, 95, 292, 294,
Primary export sector, 198 298, 299, 303
Primary product, 47, 60–62, 64, 65, Russia, 59, 118n26, 124, 125, 188
67n12, 124, 135–139, 141, 161,
199
Production, 5, 9, 10, 15, 43, 61, 82, S
83, 87, 92–94, 148, 151, 152, Santiago, 217–238
154, 156, 165–191, 193, 194n1, SCO, see Shanghai Cooperation
198, 199, 204, 209, 253, 272, Organization
284, 299, 300, 322, 338 Security, 10, 12, 17, 18, 32, 33, 40,
Productivity, 41–43, 123, 150, 198, 42, 59, 154, 159, 161, 218,
200, 204, 205, 209, 220, 281, 271–285, 295, 296, 310, 312,
285 322, 326, 335, 339
Shadow world, 324
Shanghai Cooperation Organization
Q (SCO), 113, 118n26, 321
Quito, 217–238 Skilled work, 40
Social force, 10, 14, 335–337
Socialism, 85, 318
R Social reproduction, 252, 254,
Refugees, 4, 220 256–265
Regional development finance, South Africa, 90, 91, 167, 207,
101–118, 339 313–315, 317, 319, 320
348 INDEX