Jiang Kim-CorporateGovernance in China-A Survey 2020
Jiang Kim-CorporateGovernance in China-A Survey 2020
Jiang Kim-CorporateGovernance in China-A Survey 2020
doi: 10.1093/rof/rfaa012
Advance Access Publication Date: 13 May 2020
Abstract
This article surveys corporate governance in China, as described in a growing litera-
ture published in top journals. Unlike the classical vertical agency problems in
Western countries, the dominant agency problem in China is the horizontal agency
conflict between controlling and minority shareholders arising from concentrated
ownership structure; thus one cannot automatically apply what is known about the
USA to China. As these features are also prevalent in many other countries, insights
from this survey can also be applied to countries far beyond China. We start by
describing controlling shareholder and agency problems in China, and then discuss
how law and institutions are particularly important for China, where controlling
shareholders have great power. As state-owned enterprises have their own features,
we separately discuss their corporate governance. We also briefly discuss corporate
social responsibility in China. Finally, we provide an agenda for future research.
1. Introduction
Corporate governance has received increasing attention in recent decades, particularly since
the 1997 Asian financial crisis and the early 2000s corporate scandals (e.g., Worldcom and
* We thank Alex Edmans, Zhan Jiang, and two anonymous referees for excellent comments on this
article. Wenjing Cai, Xinni Cai, Yiqian Cai, Yajie Chen, Jin Feng, Haozheng Huang, Yanyan Shen,
Ying Wang, Xiaoxue Xia, and Xiaotong Yang provided superb research assistance. We thank all
participants of a workshop on corporate governance in China at Renmin University of China for
their valuable comments, especially the editors and former editors of several top journals in eco-
nomics, finance, and accounting in China, including Dongsheng Jiang, Hongkui Liu, Zhigang Song,
and Qian Xie. Finally, we are especially indebted to Alex Edmans for encouraging us to write this
article. Fuxiu Jiang acknowledges financial support from the China National Natural Science
Foundation (No. 71432008).
C The Author(s) 2020. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the European Finance Association.
V
All rights reserved. For permissions, please email: [email protected]
734 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
Enron in the USA, and other firms globally). Since it was in the early 1990s that China
launched its stock market and began to establish modern enterprises, corporate governance
practices in China have grown alongside this global trend. In the meantime, China has
experienced spectacular economic growth and given rise to a large number of influential
corporations operating worldwide. Hence, the underlying governance mechanisms and
problems of Chinese corporations have garnered significant interest from researchers, and
top journals have published a large body of work on this topic in recent years. In this art-
icle, we survey this growing literature with the aim of providing a clear and thorough pic-
ture of the current findings and future research implications.
1 The CSMAR database, developed by GTA Information Technology, covers Chinese publicly listed
firms and has been used in studies published in leading journals (Fang, Lerner, and Wu, 2017).
Corporate Governance in China 735
discuss circumstances under which a controlling shareholder can solve problems rather
than cause them—that is, the bright side of having a controlling shareholder.
Shleifer and Vishny (1997) argue that legal protection of investor rights is one essential
element of corporate governance. Given the existence of dominant controlling sharehold-
ers, legal protection seems to be the most important, albeit imperfect, solution to agency
problems in China. When controlling shareholders take full control of corporate boards
and management teams, it is difficult for internal corporate governance to work effectively,
as is also the case in the USA, where managers dominate corporate decisions and reduce the
effectiveness of internal corporate governance (Allen and Gale, 2000). Meanwhile, external
2 In saying that takeovers are rare, we refer to listed firms; mergers and acquisitions involving non-
listed firms and overseas firms are quite active (see Section 6).
736 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
effective market for corporate control (outsiders cannot obtain enough shares to seize con-
trol, nor can they seize control of an SOE). That is, the ways to resolve the agency problem
in China are limited.
3 Bertrand, Mehta, and Mullainathan (2002) and Bae, Kang, and Kim (2002) provide some of the ear-
liest empirical evidence on tunneling in their study of Indian firms and Korean firms, respectively.
4 Cheung, Rau, and Stouraitis (2010) measure the wealth effect as the ratio of the total value change
to the announced size of the related party transaction, where the total value change is the abnor-
mal announcement return multiplied by the firm’s market capitalization.
738 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
Controlling shareholders have incentives to hold excessive amounts of cash for their pri-
vate benefit, as Jensen’s (1986) free cash flow hypothesis suggests for managers. Cash pro-
vides more tunneling opportunities because it can be more conveniently transformed into
private benefits than other assets (Myers and Rajan, 1998). Providing indirect evidence of
this agency problem, Chen et al. (2012) find that firms held significantly less cash after the
split-share structure reform aligned incentives between controlling and minority
shareholders.5
Controlling shareholders may also manipulate information disclosure to hide their self-
dealings. When they withhold information, the firm’s stock price movements will mimic
5 The split share structure reform converted nontradable shares owned by controlling shareholders
into tradable shares. We discuss this reform in more detail in a later section.
6 Normally a firm receives ST status if it experiences two consecutive annual losses. If it experien-
ces another annual loss, then trading is suspended; a fourth annual loss leads to delisting.
Corporate Governance in China 739
legal means for controlling shareholders to realize returns from their NTSs was dividends,
but these have to be shared with all other investors. They thus have strong incentives to
realize returns through expropriation.
Several studies provide empirical evidence for this argument, using the 2005 split-share
structure reform, which converted all NTSs into tradable shares (TS) and thus allowed the
controlling shareholders to obtain returns through capital gains rather than expropriation.
For example, Chen et al. (2012) find that average cash holdings and the average corporate
savings rate were significantly larger before the reform, indicating self-serving cash holding
due to poor liquidity of shares. Campello, Ribas, and Wang (2014) find that real corporate
7 We obtain pyramid ownership structure data from CSMAR. Fan and Wong (2002) find that one-
quarter of the seven East Asian firms display cash-vote divergence, and the mean ratio of cash
flow right to voting right (the CV ratio) is 0.85. In our data, the mean CV ratio of Chinese listed firms
is 0.83.
740 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
efficient allocation of capital in the economy. For example, Faccio, Masulis, and
McConnell (2006) find that politically connected firms are more likely to receive bailouts
than matched unconnected firms, but they underperform after bailouts. In China, many
controlling shareholders also have political connections. While controlling shareholders of
SOEs, that is, the government, are naturally politically connected, it is also common for
controlling shareholders of non-SOEs to build connections with the government through
connected CEOs, top managers, or directors. For example, Fan, Wong, and Zhang (2007)
find that almost 27% of the CEOs in their non-SOE sample are former or current govern-
ment bureaucrats.
8 This is similar to Bertrand et al.’s (2018) finding that French firms maintain high employment and
plant creation rates to help regional politicians in their re-election efforts.
9 As an important component of the anticorruption campaign, in October 2013, the Organization
Department of the Central Committee of the CPC issued Rule 18, to prohibit party and government
officials from serving as directors for publicly listed firms.
Corporate Governance in China 741
provide indirect evidence. On December 4 2012, the Chinese Communist Party unexpected-
ly announced its “Eight-point Policy”.10 In general, the policy prohibits government offi-
cials and top executives of SOEs from demanding or accepting extravagant perks. Lin et al.
(2018) find that the Chinese stock market experienced 3–4% return over the 3-day and 5-
day windows surrounding the announcement date, suggesting that political connections,
and corruption in general, can destroy firm value. On May 17 2013, the Central
Commission for Discipline Inspection (CCDI) announced that it would conduct inspections
of provincial governments.11 This surprise announcement meant the government’s anticor-
ruption campaign was not just talk. Ding et al. (2020) find an overall positive return
directors were likely nominated and appointed by controlling shareholders. Third, even if
independent directors are active, they represent the minority on most boards.13
Nevertheless, some types of directors still conduct partially effective monitoring. Jiang,
Wan, and Zhao (2016) study the voting behavior of independent directors of listed firms in
China. Their sample includes 609 board meetings, in which voting takes place on 859 pro-
posals, with at least one independent director voting “abstain” or “against”. The study
finds that only 6% of independent directors dissent even once, particularly those who are
career cautious and highly reputed—and most of these dissents occur during the independ-
ent directors’ second terms (there is a two-term limit for directors in China), when they are
13 In our own check of the data on CSMAR, in 2018, 4.27% of the listed firms have boards with at
least 50% independent directors, and 1.51% of listed firms have boards with >50% independent
directors. Since June 30 2003, one-third of listed firms’ boards must be independent (CSRC board
regulations can be found here (in Chinese): http://www.cninfo.com.cn/finalpage/2001-08-22/
605382.html). Since 2003, the annual median ratio of independent directors to total directors is
0.333, with mean ratios being slightly higher (see Jiang and Kim, 2015). While some boards have
extra independent directors, another reason why mean ratios are slightly >0.333 is because
boards with five, seven, and ten members cannot have an independence ratio <0.4.
Corporate Governance in China 743
In addition to boards of directors, under China’s two-tier board structure listed firms
are also required to have a board of supervisors. Members of both boards are determined
by a cumulative voting system, where the number of votes per share is equal to the number
of directors or supervisors to be elected. However, there are different membership restric-
tions placed on each board. The regular board must have a minimum of five directors and a
maximum of nineteen. A senior manager can sit on the regular board, but at least one-third
of its members must be independent directors. The supervisory board must have at least
three members and must include representatives of shareholders, but at least one-third of
the supervisors must be employees. However, supervisors cannot include current directors
14 The primary responsibilities of regular boards in China are the same as those of boards in
Western countries. For example, boards in China convene meetings, implement shareholder reso-
lutions, make major operational and investment decisions (e.g., capital expenditures and acquisi-
tions), make major financial decisions (e.g., budgets and raising capital), and evaluate the firm’s
top managers.
15 Conventional thought is that financial companies, such as the Industrial and Commercial Bank of
China, have effective supervisory boards because their chairs are high-ranking government offi-
cials, like regular board chairs.
16 For regulations on institutional investor ownership, refer to (in Chinese): http://www.csrc.gov.cn/
pub/newsite/flb/flfg/bmgz/jjl/201505/t20150511_276612.html and http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/zjhpub
lic/zjh/200804/t20080418_14496.htm
17 According to the Guidelines for Articles of Association of Listed Companies launched by the CSRC
in 1997, when a shareholders’ general meeting deliberates on matters pertaining to related party
transactions, related shareholders should abstain from voting, and the total number of valid votes
744 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
horizons (Jiang and Kim, 2015) and, sometimes, to political pressures. For example, in the
split-share structure reform, in order to convert NTS to TS, NTS holders have to offer TS
holders a compensation plan, which needs approval from two-thirds of the total voting
shares as well as from two-thirds of total TS voting shares. As mutual funds are typically
the largest institutional investors in TS, they are supposed to negotiate fair compensation
for themselves and for other holders of TS. However, in the case of SOEs, the government
is the controlling shareholder as well as the largest owner of NTS. Firth, Lin, and Zou
(2010) find that mutual funds bow to political pressure to help these firms implement the
reform quickly and at relatively low cost. Therefore, the authors conclude that minority
should not include the shares with voting rights held by related shareholders. In such cases, insti-
tutional investors are supposed to be a powerful and influential party, since they are typically one
of the largest groups of unrelated shareholders. http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/csrc_en/laws/rfdm/
DepartmentRules/201904/P020190524606840462980.pdf
18 Having decreased substantially since 2002, loans from commercial banks in 2015 were 73.1% of
total new external financing, whereas equity financing was only 4.9% (Jiang, Jiang, and Kim,
2017).
19 Before 2009, the big four state-owned commercial banks (i.e., Bank of China, Agricultural Bank of
China, China Construction Bank, and Industrial and Commercial Bank of China) dominated China’s
banking system, while the twelve joint equity banks faced great limitations when opening new
branches. In April 2009, the China Banking Regulatory Commission partially lifted this entry barrier.
Corporate Governance in China 745
banks preferred to lend to inefficient SOEs over more productive private firms. To receive
bank loans from entrant banks, private firms have to provide more guarantees and higher
internal loan ratings to indicate their credit worthiness, while SOEs do not. Nevertheless,
the authors find that in the long run, entrant banks accumulate more information on local
private firms and eventually lend more to them, suggesting that some banks are starting to
use their inside information and stable relationships with borrowing firms to play a moni-
toring role.
Joint equity banks are allowed to open branches in cities in which they had already had
branches, and allowed to enter all cities in a province in which they already had branches in the
capital city.
746 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
newspapers,20 and find that the articles published in state-controlled newspapers are less
critical, less accurate, less comprehensive, and more subject to reporting delay. The authors
also find that the articles in market-oriented newspapers are followed by stronger stock
market reactions than those in state-controlled newspapers, and that market-oriented news-
papers are better at predicting firms’ future performance.
20 State-controlled financial newspapers include the China Securities Journal, Securities Daily,
Securities Times, and Shanghai Securities Journal, and market-oriented financial newspapers in-
clude the China Business Journal, First Financial Daily, Economic Observer, and 21st Century
Business Herald.
Corporate Governance in China 747
propping, cash is transferred back to the controlling shareholder. Therefore, propping may
benefit minority shareholders only in the short run.
Controlling shareholders may also benefit minority shareholders if the firm and the con-
trolling shareholder are part of a business group. The business group is a type of corporate
organization in which member firms are linked through cross-ownership and internal factor
markets, such as financial markets, and it can help to relax financial constraints and en-
hance investment (Hoshi, Kashyap, and Scharfstein, 1990, 1991). Business groups are com-
mon in emerging economies, perhaps because they substitute for weak institutions (Khanna
and Palepu, 2000). In China, it is well known that the state largely controls natural and fi-
21 According to our statistics, of all Chinese A-share listed firms from 2003 to 2018, 34.28% have at
least two blockholders that hold at least 10% of the firm’s outstanding shares (a threshold follow-
ing Faccio and Lang, 2002), and 56.65% of firms have at least two blockholders with an ownership
>5% (a threshold following Edmans and Manso, 2011 and Hope, Wu, and Zhao, 2017). The data
come from CSMAR, which specifies share ownership of the top ten largest shareholders for all
listed firms in each year. We manually group parties related to the controlling shareholder and
sum their shareholdings using the financial statement disclosures on related parties.
748 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
22 In China, a prefecture is an administrative division. It ranks below a province and above a county.
It comprises a main central urban area (such as a city) and its larger surrounding rural area, con-
taining smaller cities, towns, and villages.
750 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
while the Securities Law has been amended three times, in 2004, 2013, and 2014, and
revised once, in 2005. The Contract Law was promulgated in 1999. In 2007, the Property
Right Law was enacted to strengthen the protection of property rights, benefiting both
listed firms and their investors and creditors. In sum, in 20 years, China has set up an inte-
grated law system.
In addition to law, securities regulations and enforcement by the CSRC have also been
improving. A well-known CSRC regulation requires firms to show that they are profitable
before being allowed to issue new equity to existing shareholders. This regulation aims to
guide capital to more efficient sectors of the economy. During 1996–98, the CSRC required
decisions be separately approved by the owners of TSs who participated in the voting.
Chen, Ke, and Yang (2013) find that the passage of the segmented voting regulation
deterred corporate insiders from submitting value-decreasing proposals, and that the mean
announcement returns for submitted proposals were significantly negative before the regu-
lation but significantly positive after, which suggests that giving minority shareholders
more power can improve corporate decisions.
The CSRC continuously tries to improve the functioning and capabilities of financial
intermediaries and other institutions. For example, it has given investment banks more
power to identify and develop IPO candidates (Jiang and Kim, 2015). Another example is
revenues to the state and retain the residuals. With both control rights and claims on resid-
uals, local governments effectively own SOEs, and therefore should have incentives to
maximize their value.
At first, the gradual reforms increased SOEs’ productivity (Li, 1997), largely because
bonus schemes and other incentives motivated workers (Groves et al., 1994). However,
during the mid-1990s, >40% of SOEs were loss making (Lin, Cai, and Li, 1998) as strong
non-SOE competitors entered the market. Non-SOEs have to obtain financing and sell out-
put in a competitive environment, so they have to be excellent performers to survive.
Meanwhile, SOEs still carry heavy policy burdens and experience soft budget constraints.
24 Some studies provide evidence that SOEs continued to over-invest in later periods. Liu and Siu
(2011) study >36,000 Chinese firms during 2000–05 and find that SOEs used a much lower discount
rate to guide their investment decisions than non-SOEs. That is, SOEs overinvested. More recent-
ly, in the wake of the 2008 global financial crisis, the Chinese government ordered state-owned
banks to lend and ordered centrally controlled nonfinancial SOEs to invest. However, Cong et al.
(2019) find that during the stimulus plan years (2009–10), more bank credit flowed to firms with
lower initial average capital productivity, and around 70% of this misallocation was driven by
credit reallocation from private firms to SOEs. This is similar to Duchin and Sosyura’s (2012) finding
that political connections led to inefficient government bailouts in the USA. Furthermore, Deng
et al. (2015) show that SOEs’ primary response to the increased funding was simply to make highly
leveraged purchases of real estate, even though they had no experience in property
development.
754 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
of 634 SIPs during 1994–98. Immediately after the exchange listings, SOEs’ earnings, real
sales, and employee productivity rose, but returns on sales and earnings on sales declined.
Therefore, the authors conclude that SIPs had “only limited success”.
Sale of shares by the state controlling shareholder to private investors is also a form of
privatization. From the mid-1990s, the state began to allow the controlling nontradable
ownership stake to be sold to private investors via negotiated transfer, marking a new stage
in the privatization of SOEs. Chen et al. (2008) study 156 control transfers that took place
during 1996–2000. In sixty-two cases, control was transferred from state entities to private
entities, while in ninety-four cases, control was merely transferred from state entities to
25 Chen et al. (2008) use many variables to measure performance, such as operating ROA, ratio of
operating cash flows to assets, return on sales, asset turnover, ratio of cost to sales, ratio of cap-
ital expenditure to fixed assets, employment, sales per employee, assets per employee, and sales
growth.
Corporate Governance in China 755
However, SOEs may be reluctant to be privatized. In China, the state can provide subsi-
dies, favorable tax treatment, industrial license approvals, and loans—what Shleifer and
Vishny (1998) call the government’s “helping hand”. Therefore, when firms lose their con-
nection to the government, they may find it difficult to generate sustainable profit. Offering
strong evidence for this view, Calomiris, Fisman, and Wang (2010) study a surprise an-
nouncement on July 24 2001, when four partially privatized SOEs announced that their
state shares would be sold in the A-share stock market. Because these sales could dilute the
value of A-shares, the authors study the announcement effect by considering B-share
returns. The China B-share index declined by 10.5% during a 3-day window surrounding
with training and experience only in the state sector, they have almost no outside opportu-
nities (Chen, Guan, and Ke, 2013). Thus, the incentive for doing a good job as a SOE man-
ager is to get promoted to a high-level government position (Jiang and Kim, 2015). Cao
et al. (2019) study the relationship between political promotion and firm performance of
Chinese SOEs during 2005–11. They find that the likelihood of an SOE manager’s receiving
a political promotion increases with firm performance. Furthermore, manager pay-for-
performance sensitivity is higher when the SOE manager has a lower likelihood of receiving
a political promotion—that is, incentives for political promotion substitute for explicit
compensation incentives. This is similar to Gibbons and Murphy’s (1992) finding of career
5. CSR in China
Above, our central concern has been outside investors. However, many people believe that
companies have a responsibility to all their stakeholders, including society at large, not only
26 Chinese SOEs are classified by administrative rank. Du, Tang, and Young (2012) use two criteria to
code the political rank of individual SOEs: whether an SOE is a “vice-ministerial level” firm and
whether the Organization Department of the CPC Central Committee assigns its CEO.
758 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
shareholders. Is CSR important in China? If so, then does it improve shareholder value, and
what are the factors leading to improved CSR?
Since managers, shareholders, and creditors do not suffer directly from negative exter-
nalities created by firms (e.g., environmental damage and poor labor conditions), it is usual-
ly ordinary citizens who call on government to regulate or tax such behavior. Is CSR
important to ordinary Chinese citizens? Given that China is still a developing economy,
they may not currently be in a position to make social concerns a high priority. Bartling,
Weber, and Yao (2014) experimented using college students in Zurich, Switzerland, and
Shanghai, China. Almost half of the Zurich students were willing to purchase a high-priced
27 http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/csrc_en/newsfacts/release/200708/t20070810_69223.html
Corporate Governance in China 759
28 http://www.csrc.gov.cn/pub/csrc_en/laws/rfdm/DepartmentRules/201904/P020190415336431477120.pdf
29 http://english.sse.com.cn/laws/framework/c/3978492.pdf
760 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
governance is more complicated, since they face conflict of interest between the state and
listed firms, as well as agency problems involving SOE managers. As to CSR, government is
likely the most important promoter in China.
While research to date has provided much insight on corporate governance in China,
there are still many potential topics for future research, especially as China continues to
transition from a control economy to a market economy, and as corporate governance in
China continues to evolve. Here, we provide a brief agenda.
First, the effect of the political system should be emphasized. Corporate governance
mechanisms that prove effective in capitalist countries may differ from those in China. The
investor is permitted to own >10% of a listed firm’s shares, the shares institutional invest-
ors hold allow them to place directors on the board, and this is currently happening, as
shares held by controlling shareholders gradually decrease. Exit is another important way
for shareholders to monitor in addition to voice, and institutional investors may govern
through exit. We need to know more about these questions to deepen understanding of the
role of institutional investors.
Fourth, we need to learn more about the role that legal protection plays in corporate
governance. China has long been criticized for its weak investor protection (Allen, Qian,
and Qian, 2005), though legal protection is one of the most important solutions for agency
31 In 2019, there were 129 Chinese firms and 121 US firms in the list. https://enapp.chinadaily.com.cn/
a/201907/24/AP5d376510a3106b83cdbf8a27.html
762 F. Jiang and K. A. Kim
changes eventually spill over to other listed firms? More importantly, would underperform-
ance increase the likelihood of takeover? Do takeovers create value, and how does corpor-
ate governance affect the returns to takeovers? Sophisticated analyses of these takeovers
could at least provide some insights for the market for corporate control in China.
Seventh, more research is needed to understand the role of banks. In China, banks are
the dominant providers of capital to firms (Jiang, Jiang, and Kim, 2017) and therefore have
the potential to be effective monitors. Surprisingly, little research has been conducted on
the governance role of banks in China. Bailey, Huang, and Yang (2011) find that the
Chinese banking system is subject to political goals, so that poorly performing firms are
32 A major feature of shadow banking is the entrusted loan, in which a privileged nonbank firm (such
as a large industrial SOE) with access to cheap capital lends to a less privileged nonbank firm
(such as a small or medium sized non-SOE). A bank plays the role of a servicing agent, in ex-
change for a fee, but does not bear the investment risk. See Allen et al. (2019) for an overview of
China’s shadow banking system.
Corporate Governance in China 763
researchers to address endogeneity problems. Already, many studies have exploited China’s
privatizations of SOEs (Fang, Lerner, and Wu, 2017; Bradshaw, Liao, and Ma, 2019)
and split-share structure reform (Chen et al., 2012; Campello, Ribas, and Wang, 2014) as
identification methods. While most studies in corporate governance suffer from serious
endogeneity issues and many early studies do not take these issues seriously, new opportu-
nities for identification deserve more attention.
Last, there should be more attention to how corporate governance has contributed posi-
tively to the prosperity of Chinese corporations and the Chinese economy in the past several
decades. Some studies have found that improvement of law and regulations has positively
冑
Giannetti et al. (2017) DID: Launch of the Chinese anti-corruption campaign – 冑 – – – – 冑
in 2012
Giannetti, Liao, and Yu (2015) (1) IV: Staggered provincial policies to attract highly 冑 – – 冑 – – 冑
skilled emigrants; (2) FE: Firm/province level
Groves et al. (1994) (1) IV: 1 or 2-year lagged bonus payments and contract 冑 – – 冑 – – 冑
workers; (2) FE: Firm level
Guan et al. (2016) (1) IV: Sum of percentile ranks of a firm’s executive 冑 – – 冑 冑 – 冑
team, where the rank for each executive is based on
the number of managers and auditors graduating
from his/her school; (2) FE: Firm level; (3) MM: PSM
Gul, Kim, and Qiu (2010) IV: Likelihood of Big 4 auditor choice 冑 – – – – – –
Hope, Wu, and Zhao (2017) (1) DID: Split share structure reform; (2) FE: Firm/year/ – 冑 – 冑 冑 – –
industry level; (3) MM: PSM
Hope, Yue, and Zhong (2019) (1) DID: Rule 18 issued by the CPC; (2) MM: PSM; (3) – 冑 – 冑 冑 – 冑
FE: Firm/year level
Huang and Ke (2018) DID: Regulatory reform (single difference) – 冑 – – – – –
Huyghebaert and Xu (2016) DID: Investment banks become fully responsible for fix- – 冑 – – – – –
ing IPO offer prices
(continued)
765
References
Adams, R. B., Hermalin, B. E., and Weisbach, M. S. (2010): The role of boards of directors in cor-
porate governance: a conceptual framework and survey, Journal of Economic Literature 48,
58–107.
Admati, A. R. and Pfleiderer, P. (2009): The “Wall Street Walk” and shareholder activism: exit as
a form of voice, Review of Financial Studies 22, 2645–2685.
Allen, F. and Gale, D. (2000): Corporate governance and competition, in: X. Vives (ed.),
Corporate Governance: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
Chan, K. C., Jiang, X., Wu, D., Xu, N., and Zeng, H. (2019): When is the client king? Evidence
from affiliated-analyst recommendations in China’s split-share reform, Contemporary
Accounting Research, Forthcoming.
Chan, K. H., Lin, K. Z., and Mo, P. L. (2006): A political-economic analysis of auditor reporting
and auditor switches, Review of Accounting Studies 11, 21–48.
Chen, F., Peng, S., Xue, S., Yang, Z., and Ye, F. (2016): Do audit clients successfully engage in
opinion shopping? Partner-level evidence, Journal of Accounting Economics 54, 79–112.
Chen, G., Firth, M., Xin, Y., and Xu, L. (2008): Control transfers, privatization, and corporate
performance: efficiency gains in China’s listed companies, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Duan, T., Li, K., Rogo, R., and Zhan, R. (2018): The Myth About Public Versus Private
Enforcement of Securities Laws-evidence from Chinese Comment Letters. SSRN working paper,
SSRN.
Duchin, R. and Sosyura, D. (2012): The politics of government investment, Journal of Financial
Economics 106, 24–48.
Dyck, A., Volchkova, N., and Zingales, L. (2008): The corporate governance role of the media:
evidence from Russia, Journal of Finance 63, 1093–1135.
Dyck, A., Morse, A., and Zingales, L. (2010): Who blows the whistle on corporate fraud? Journal
of Finance 65, 2213–2253.
Groves, T., Hong, Y., McMillan, J., and Naughton, B. (1994): Autonomy and incentives in
Chinese state enterprises, Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, 183–209.
Guan, Y., Su, L., Wu, D., and Yang, A. (2016): Do school ties between auditors and client execu-
tives influence audit outcomes? Journal of Accounting Economics 61, 506–525.
Gul, F. A., Kim, J. B., and Qiu, A. A. (2010): Ownership concentration, foreign shareholding,
audit quality, and stock price synchronicity: evidence from China, Journal of Financial
Economics 95, 425–442.
He, J., Mao, X., Rui, O. M., and Zha, X. (2013): Business groups in China, Journal of Corporate
Finance 22, 166–192.
Khanna, T. and Palepu, K. (2000): Is group affiliation profitable in emerging markets? An analysis
of diversified Indian business groups, Journal of Finance 55, 867–891.
Khwaja, A. I. and Mian, A. (2005): Do lenders favor politically connected firms? Rent provision in
an emerging financial market, Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 1371–1411.
Laeven, L. and Levine, R. (2007): Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations,
Review of Financial Studies 21, 579–604.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1997): Legal determinants of exter-
nal finance, Journal of Finance 52, 1131–1150.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (1999): Corporate ownership around the
Michaely, R. and Womack, K. L. (1999): Conflict of interest and the credibility of underwriter
analyst recommendations, Review of Financial Studies 12, 653–686.
Morck, R., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1988): Management ownership and market valuation: an
empirical analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 20, 293–315.
Morck, R. and Yeung, B. (2014): Corporate governance in China, Journal of Applied Corporate
Finance 26, 20–41.
Myers, S. C. and Rajan, R. G. (1998): The paradox of liquidity, Quarterly Journal of Economics
113, 733–771.
Pagano, M. and Röell, A. (1998): The choice of stock ownership structure: agency costs, monitor-