Interest Rate Model Selection - Levin
Interest Rate Model Selection - Levin
Interest Rate Model Selection - Levin
Alexander Levin
EXHIBIT 1
Daily Volatility versus Level for 10-Year Treasury Rate
Observations Annualized
deviations, bp
1400 300
00-03
95-99
1200 90-94 250
85-89
80-84
1000
200
800
150
600
100
400
50
200
0 0
4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14
rate level, %
100
400
80
300
60
200
40
100 20
0 0
4 4.5 5 5.5 6 6.5 7 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 10
rate level, %
implied volatility skew, i.e., the dependence of the implied selected drift term), such as Black, Derman, and Toy (BDT)
Black volatility on the strike level. If market participants [1990] or Black and Karasinski (BK) [1991]. For g = 0, the
believe in lognormality, there would be little reason for absolute volatility is rate-independent and can lead to a nor-
the implied volatility to change with the option’s strike. mal model, such as Hull and White (HW) [1990]. If g =
A volatility skew testifies against lognormality by the very 0.5, we may have a popular family of square root models,
fact of its existence. such as the squared Gaussian model (SG) (see James and
To discuss a simple skew measurement method, let Webber [2000]), or the model of Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross
us first introduce a setup that generalizes many known and (CIR) [1985]. Any unnamed values for the CEV are cer-
popular single-factor models, a constant elasticity of vari- tainly possible, including negative values (hypernormality)
ance (CEV) model: and values exceeding 1 (hyperlognormality).
Blyth and Uglum [1999] propose a simple method
dr = ( Drift )dt + sr g dz (1) of recovering the most suitable CEV constant by just
looking at the observed swaption volatility skew. They
argue that, if a swap forward rate satisfies the random pro-
where r is some modeled rate, s is the volatility coeffi- cess (1), the skew should have the approximate form:
cient, and g is the CEV constant. As usual, t is time, z(t)
is the Brownian motion that disturbs the market, and the 1-g
18
Lognormal (CEV = 1)
17
Square-root (CEV = 0.5)
Normal (CEV = 0)
16 Optimal fit (CEV = 0.23)
Actual
Volatility
15
14
13
12
-250 -200 -150 -100 -50 ATM 50 100 150 200 250
Strike
*Source for actual volatility history: Bank of America; volatility for 200 ITM/OTM was not quoted.
Let us analyze the same set of CEV special values, options are traded with a square root volatility. This phe-
0, 1.0, and 0.5. If g = 1.0, there will be no skew at all: nomenon may be a combination of a slight theoretical
sK ∫ sF for any strike K. This is the Black-Scholes case. smile and the broker commission demand.
For g = 0, the skew has a functional form of inverse Exhibit 4 illustrates historical month-by-month
square root. For g = 0.5, it will have the shape of an inverse skew, suggesting that the normalization effect (g ª 0) has
fourth-degree root. It is worth mentioning here that each been observed since the beginning of 2001.
inverse root function is a convex one, so the theoretical This CEV analysis unambiguously rejects lognor-
skew should not be deemed a straight line (except when mality and reveals a more suitable model. Although the
g = 1). In fact, it should not be confused with a more best-fit CEV constant varies somewhat, any volatility
aggressive convex volatility smile that may or may not be model between the normal one and the square root seems
present in addition to the skew.2 to be a decent choice. Because of its analytical tractabil-
The object of our study—the five-year into ten-year ity and the recent CEV trend, we focus on the HW
swaption (5-into-10)—was selected with modeling volatil- model as the chief alternative to the BDT or BK models.
ity of mortgage rates and valuation of the prepayment
option in mind. Exhibit 3 depicts five skew lines plotted VOLATILITY INDEX
for three named CEVs, the actual volatility observations
averaged from January 1998 through May 2002, and the It is useful to design a market volatility index—a sin-
optimal fit line (g = 0.23) for the same period. The best gle number reflecting the overall level of swaption volatil-
CEV is therefore found to be generally between the nor- ity deemed relevant to the mortgage market. This gives us
mal case (HW model) and the square root case (SG or CIR a convenient way to communicate with practitioners and
models). It is also seen that low-struck options are traded compare models; it can also serve as a risk assessment tool.
with a close-to-normal volatility, while high-struck We designate a family of at-the-money swaptions
EXHIBIT 4
Historical CEV Values
1 lognormality level
0.9
0.8
0.7
0.6
square-root level
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
0 normality level
-0.1
-0.2
Jan-98 Jul-98 Jan-99 Jul-99 Jan-00 Jul-00 Jan-01 Jul-01 Jan-02
2.5
7-yr swap
BK sigma
HW sigma
2
SqG sigma
1.5
0.5
synchronized start
0
0
3
0
3
0
3
00
01
02
03
-0
-0
-0
-0
-0
-0
-0
-0
l-0
l-0
l-0
l-0
n-
n-
n-
n-
pr
pr
pr
pr
ct
ct
ct
ct
Ju
Ju
Ju
Ju
Ja
Ja
Ja
Ja
O
O
A
tractable. For example, a Monte Carlo simulation, or any who think a 20% short rate volatility plugged into the
other forward sampling method employed as the primary model results in a 20% swaption volatility. Therefore,
mortgage pricing tool will simulate only the short rate pro- model calibration to the mortgage-relevant options (not
cess on its own. Analytics that would map this process into the options on the short rate) can be complicated.
long rate dynamics (a mortgage rate) simply do not exist
and need time-consuming numerical replacements. THE HULL-WHITE MODEL: AN OVERVIEW
Relative (Black) volatility is used for quotation
only; it is merely a price-volatility conversion tool, not The short rate in the HW [1990] model is driven
requiring any acceptance of the Black-Scholes model. As by a linear stochastic differential equation, which is a spe-
we have seen, volatility changes drastically with the level cial case of the CEV Equation (1):
of rates, and therefore with the expiration of traded
options. One constant number cannot describe the entire dr = a(t )(q (t ) - r )dt + s (t )dz (3)
universe of swaptions deemed relevant for mortgage pric-
ing. The BK model with constant volatility cannot be rec- where a(t) denotes mean reversion, and s(t) stands for volatil-
ommended, in view of a steep yield curve and a sharply ity; both can be time-dependent. Function q(t) is sometimes
inverse proportional volatility term structure. referred to as arbitrage-free drift. That is, by selecting a
Contrary to common belief, long rates in the BDT proper q(t), we can match any observed yield curve.
and the BK models are not lognormal, and generally are Since (3) is a linear differential equation disturbed
less volatile than short rates, even in the absence of mean by normally distributed Brownian motion, its output,
reversion. This may be an unpleasant surprise for those the short rate process, will also be normally distributed.
EXHIBIT 6
Calibrated Volatility Term Structure—May 2002
150
vol on 2-yr swap
140 vol on 10-yr swap
the short-rate caplet vol
calibrated s(t)
130
120
absolute quote, bp
110
100
90
80
70
60
0 12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96 108 120
expiry, months
s(t) or a constant volatility parameter, s(t) ∫ s = const, it Although many market participants perceive that
can be optimized to approximate the volatility matrix of caps and swaptions trade in unison, they may overlook an
traded ATM swaptions. This calibration procedure important modeling difference—the jumps. Long swaps
includes finding the best mean-reversion parameter a in are chiefly diffusive, and a model disturbed by a Brown-
the sense discussed above. ian motion [like z(t) in Equation (1)] makes sense. Short
Exhibit 6 plots the calibration results using a series rates combine continuous diffusion (small day-after-day
of ATM options on the two-year swap and on the ten- changes) with sudden regulatory corrections.
year swap as the input. The bars for six different expira- It is mathematically not very difficult to add jumps
tions show known volatility quotes converted into the to diffusion (Merton did it in 1976), but the equivalent
absolute form (i.e., the relative quote multiplied by the volatility term structure will become hump-shaped. Under
forward rate).3 a jump or a jump-diffusion disturbance, the short-dated
The overall effective error of calibration is just 3.6 Black volatilities come up considerably suppressed.
basis points of absolute volatility, as measured across the Exhibit 9 compares market volatilities for traded
swaption matrix. The mean-reversion parameter was caps (solid bars) with volatilities of caps derived from the
restricted to be a constant; its best value is found as a = swaption-fitted HW [1990] model. The model drastically
2.05%. For some particular applications (like standardized overstates short-dated cap volatilities, in both absolute and
risk tests), one may prefer a zero mean reversion, or a con- relative terms. As the cap’s maturity extends, swaptions and
stant volatility parameter. These restrictions generally caps seem to converge. Can the cap (rather than the
reduce the calibration accuracy as shown in Exhibit 7. swaption) volatility structure be plugged into a mortgage
Calibrated s(t) in Exhibit 6 is rather responsive to the pricing system? Perhaps so, if the system’s interest rate
slope and the shape of the input volatility structure. It falls model maintains the jump-diffusion setting. As develop-
sharply beyond the six-year horizon, perhaps as a result of ers of mortgage analytical systems traditionally do not do
market perception about current versus long-term volatil- this, the blind use of caps will understate volatility and
ity. During the stormy market of the first half of 2002, therefore the prepayment option value.4
short-dated options were indeed traded at unprecedented We prefer using the swaption market for bench-
absolute volatility levels of 125-140 basis points, well above marking volatility, especially for fixed-rate mortgages.
their long-term averages. This was not the case in the calm Valuation of adjustable-rate mortgages may need additional
August of 1998, just prior to the Russian crisis (Exhibit 8). attention in view of embedded reset caps.
85
absolute quote, bp
80
75
70
65
60
0 12 24 36 48 60 72 84 96 108 120
expiry, months
normal model (curve g = 0 in Exhibit 3) is quite unlike under the three different term structure models. In each
the flat one for the lognormal model (g = 1). This means case the short rate volatility function is calibrated to ATM
the two models will value any option other than those swaptions.
employed for calibration differently. As one would expect, cuspy mortgages located at the
Since embedded mortgage options (prepayment, center of refinancing curve (“at-the-money” FNCL7)
ARM caps and floors, clean-up calls) are spread over time are valued in a very close OAS range by all three mod-
and instruments, changing from the BK model to the HW els. When the prepayment option is out of the money (the
model will generally result in a change of values. Even discount sector), this option will be triggered in a falling
more important, the interest rate sensitivity measures will rate environment. This sector therefore looks relatively rich
change visibly—as a direct result of different volatility spec- under the HW model, while the premium sector bene-
ifications. Under the BK model, every up move in rates fits from using this model. As one could expect, the SG
proportionally inflates the absolute volatility, thereby model produces valuation results that are between results
reducing the modeled value of the mortgage-backed of the HW and the BK models.
security. This can be considered an indirect (via volatil- Although most mortgage instruments will look
ity) interest rate effect, artificially extending the effective shorter under the HW model, there are some notable
duration of mortgages. exceptions. As we point out above, the primary divergence
Exhibit 10 shows a 0.4-year duration reduction of HW from BK is found in differing volatility models.
when moving from the BK model to the HW model, for Since mortgage interest-only (IO) classes and mortgage
the current-coupon agency MBS. This may considerably servicing rights (MSR) have drastically changing convexity
requantify the delta-hedging needs in secondary market- profiles, they will also have unsteady exposures to volatil-
ing and MBS portfolio management. ity, i.e., vega.
The table in Exhibit 10 summarizes comparative val- For example, vega is typically positive for an IO
uation results for 30-year fixed-rate agencies obtained taken from a premium pool (case 1), negative for that
82 INTEREST RATE MODEL SELECTION WINTER 2004
EXHIBIT 9
Implied Cap Pricing—May 2002
60 160
140
50
120
40
absolute volatililty, bp
100
relative volatility, %
Market quotes
Swaptions-fitted HW
30 80
60
20
40
10
20
0 0
12 24 36 60 84 120
maturity, months
stripped off a discount pool (case 2), and about zero when agement: one for the assets, and another for the hedge?
the pool’s rate is at the center of the refinancing curve Suppose a mortgage desk uses the BK model, while the
(cuspy premium, case 3). Therefore, the BK model will swaps desk trades with a skew. Unless the position is made
generally overstate the rate sensitivity for case 1, under- vega-neutral, differing volatility specifications in the mod-
state it for case 2, and be close to the HW model in case els may considerably reduce hedge efficiency.
3 (see Exhibit 11). Keep in mind that an IO value, con-
trary to a regular MBS, increases with rates. Curiously NEGATIVE RATES
enough, the value of an IO stripped off the current-
coupon pool is always found to be higher under the HW Knowing that interest rates have never been nega-
model than under the BK model, for all rate moves. tive in U.S. history, we should question what detrimen-
These interesting findings, although affecting valu- tal effects might occur upon use of the Hull-White [1990]
ation and delta-hedging, do not contradict what is well model. Some have tried to estimate the probability of get-
known; MBS stripped derivatives and MSRs are influ- ting negative rates in the model; this approach typically
enced greatly by prepayments and slightly by interest rate creates needless concern. Indeed, the odds of such an event
models, provided that models are calibrated to the same are far from infinitesimal, but how badly can that dam-
set of volatility benchmarks. The latter constraint is crit- age the value of an MBS?
ical. As Exhibit 11 shows, the static (zero-volatility) val- Answering this question may be simpler than it
uation profile differs considerably from the option-adjusted sounds. Consider a LIBOR floor struck at zero. This
one. Buetow, Hanke, and Fabozzi [2001] provide a good non-existent derivative will have a sure zero practical
reminder to practitioners who may underestimate the value, but not under the HW model. We have priced such
importance of model calibration. a hypothetical instrument using assumptions that inflate
Can two different rate models be used for risk man- its value: market as of May 2002 (low rates, high volatil-
35 Hull-White
6
Squared Gaussian
30
5
25
Duration 4
20
3
15
Libor OAS
2
10
1
5
0 0
FNCL5 FNCL5.5 FNCL6 FNCL6.5 (CC) FNCL7 FNCL7.5 FNCL8 FNCL8.5
6
Multiple
100
5
Black-Karasinski
Convexity 50
4 Hull-White
Static Valuation
3
0
-50
1
Duration
ity), with model mean reversion set to zero. The volatil- and from the insightful comments of James Barrett, Robert Lan-
ity function s(t) is calibrated and extrapolated beyond the dauer, and Yung Lim. The volatility skew data used in the anal-
ten-year expiration. ysis are courtesy of Craig Lindemann and Krystn Paternostro. The
The value of a zero-struck floor is found to be author thanks Jay DeLong and Steven Heller who incorporated
insignificant for the average life range relevant to mort- the new library of interest rate models into the OAS products.
Initial AD&Co. internal publication would not have been pos-
gage pricing (up to ten years). Thus, for the ten-year non-
sible without the diligent production efforts of Ilda Pozhegu.
amortizing floor, the value is 7 basis points, which is All interest rate models discussed in the paper are included
equivalent to a 0.8 basis point error in the OAS. The error in AD&Co’s VectorTM suite of analytical models. They can
grows with the horizon; the 30-year floor is priced at 35 operate with time-dependent or constant volatility calibrated to
basis points, which would lead to 2.5 basis points of spu- an arbitrary family of ATM swaptions.
rious OAS. 1
The CEV model is analyzed in many published sources,
We can conclude that the Hull-White [1990] model including Wilmott [1998] and James and Webber [2000].
2
is rather harmless. It will not lead to sizable mispricing even This smile can be explained by the jumpy nature of the
in the worst mortgage-irrelevant case. This conclusion, underlying rate. For example, LIBOR caps are traded with a
however, certainly merits periodic review. considerable volatility smile because these rates are subject to
regulatory interference. Swap rates are much more diffusive than
jumpy, so swaption smiles are much less pronounced.
ENDNOTES 3
This method of conversion is more accurate in match-
ing option values under the lognormal and normal versions of
This article comes from several Andrew Davidson Co.
Black-Scholes than the formal variance match.
publications. It has greatly benefited from joint research with 4
A recent complex three-factor jump-diffusion develop-
Andrew Davidson (many views are as much his as the author’s)
ment by Chan et al. [2003] is a rare exception.
Black, F., and P. Karasinski. “Bond and Option Pricing when James, J., and N. Webber. Interest Rate Modeling: Financial Engi-
Short-Term Rates are Lognormal.” Financial Analysts Journal, neering. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2000.
July/August 1991, pp. 52-59.
Levin, A. “Deriving Closed-Form Solutions for Gaussian Pric-
Blyth, S., and J. Uglum. “Rates of Skew.” Risk, July 1999, pp. ing Models: A Systematic Time-Domain Approach.” Interna-
61-63. tional Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 1 (1998), pp.
349-376.
Buetow, G., B. Hanke, and F. Fabozzi. “Impact of Different
Interest Rate Models on Bond Value Measures.” The Journal Merton, R. “Option Pricing when the Underlying Stock
of Fixed Income, December 2001, pp. 41-53. Returns are Discontinuous.” Journal of Financial Economics, 5
(1976), pp. 125-144.
Chan, Y. K., R. Bhattacharjee, R. Russell, and M. Teytel. “A
New Term-Structure Model Based on the Federal Funds Tar- Wilmott, P. Derivatives. New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1998.
get.” Mortgage Securities, Citigroup, May 2003.
Cox, J.C., J.E. Ingersoll, and S.A. Ross. “A Theory of the Term To order reprints of this article, please contact Ajani Malik at
Structure of Interest Rates.” Econometrica, 53 (March 1985), pp. [email protected] or 212-224-3205.
385-408.
Ho, T.S.Y., and S.-B. Lee. “Term Structure Movements and Reprinted with permission from the Winter 2004 issue of The
Pricing Interest Rate Contingent Claims.” Journal of Finance, 41 Journal of Portfolio Management. Copyright 2004 by Institutional
(December 1986), pp. 1011-1129. Investor Journals, Inc. All rights reserved. For more information
call (212) 224-3066. Visit our website at www.iijournals.com.