International Trade Theory
International Trade Theory
International Trade Theory
Contents
Ricardian model[edit]
Main article: David Ricardo
Heckscher–Ohlin model[edit]
Main article: Heckscher–Ohlin model
In the early 1900s, a theory of international trade was developed by
two Swedish economists, Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin. This theory has
subsequently become known as the Heckscher–Ohlin model (H–O model). The
results of the H–O model are that the pattern of international trade is determined by
differences in factor endowments. It predicts that countries
will export those goods that make intensive use of locally abundant factors and will
import goods that make intensive use of factors that are locally scarce.
The H–O model makes the following core assumptions:
Gravity model[edit]
Main article: Gravity model of trade
The Gravity model of trade presents a more empirical analysis of trading patterns.
The gravity model, in its basic form, predicts trade based on the distance between
countries and the interaction of the countries' economic sizes. The model mimics the
Newtonian law of gravity which also considers distance and physical size between
two objects. The model has been shown to have significant empirical validity. [12]
Second phase: Ricardo's idea was even expanded to the case of continuum of
goods by Dornbusch, Fischer, and Samuelson (1977) [21] This model is restricted to
two country case. It is employed for example by Matsuyama [22] and others. These
theories use a special property that is applicable only for the two-country case. They
normally assume fixed expenditure coefficients. Eaton and Kortum (2002) [23] inherited
Ricardian model with a continuum of goodsl from Dorbusch, Fischer, and Samuelson
(1977). It has succeeded to incorporate trade of intermediate products. Countries
have different access to technology. The bundle of inputs is assumed as the same
across commodities within a country. This means that all industries of a country
consume the same bundle of inputs and there is no distinction between petrol-
consuming and iron-consuming industries. This is the major reason why Eaton and
Kortum (2002) cannot be used as framework for analyzing global value chains. The
paper has gotten a big success as giving theoretical foundation for gravity model.
Third phase: Shiozawa [24] succeeded to construct a Ricardian theory with many-
country, many-commodity model which permits choice of production techniques and
trade of input goods. All countries have their own set of production techniques. Major
difference with H-O model that this Ricardian model assumes different technologies.
Wages determined in this model are different according to the productivity of
countries. The model is therefore more suitable than H-O models in analyzing
relations between developing and developed countries. Shiozawa's theory is now
extended as "the new theory of international values." [25]
Traded intermediate goods[edit]
Ricardian trade theory ordinarily assumes that the labor is the unique input. This has
been thought to be a significant deficiency for Ricardian trade theory since
intermediate goods comprise a major part of world international trade. [26][27]
McKenzie[28] and Jones[29] emphasized the necessity to expand the Ricardian theory to
the cases of traded inputs. McKenzie (1954, p. 179) pointed that "A moment's
consideration will convince one that Lancashire would be unlikely to produce cotton
cloth if the cotton had to be grown in England." [30] Paul Samuelson[31] coined a
term Sraffa bonus to name the gains from trade of inputs.
John S. Chipman observed in his survey that McKenzie stumbled upon the questions
of intermediate products and postulated that "introduction of trade in intermediate
product necessitates a fundamental alteration in classical analysis". [32] It took many
years until Shiozawa succeeded in removing this deficiency. The new theory of
international values is now the unique theory that can deal with input trade in a
general form. [33]
Based on an idea of Takahiro Fujimoto,[34] who is a specialist in automobile industry
and a philosopher of the international competitiveness, Fujimoto and Shiozawa
developed a discussion in which how the factories of the same multi-national firms
compete between them across borders.[35] International intra-firm competition reflects
a really new aspect of international competition in the age of so-called global
competition.
Global value chains[edit]
Main article: Global value chain
Revolutionary change in communication and information techniques and drastic
downs of transport costs have enabled an historic breakup of production process.
Networks of fragmented productions across countries are now called global value
chains.[36] The emergence of global production has changed the way we understand
the trade and international economy. [37] Still the core of international trade theory
continues to be dominated by theories which assume trade of complete goods. As
Grossman and Rossi-Hansberg put it, it needs a new paradigm to better understand
the implication of these trends.[38] Extended Ricardian trade model provides a new
theory that can treat trade of input goods and the emergence of global value chains.
[39]