Topic 5 - Uncertainty
Topic 5 - Uncertainty
Topic 5 - Uncertainty
El Colegio de México
Dr. Stephen McKnight
• The volatility of U.S. output declined significantly starting in the early 1980s
• This phenomenon has become known as the Great Moderation
• The next slide illustrates this point by depicting the quarterly growth rate of real per
capita GDP in the United States over the period 1947:Q2 to 2017:Q4
• It shows that output growth has been much smoother in the post-1984 subsample
than it was in the pre-1984 subsample
• A commonly used measure of volatility in macroeconomic data is the standard
deviation
• According to this statistic, postwar U.S. output growth became half as volatile after
1983
• The standard deviation of quarter-to-quarter real per capita output growth was
1.2% over the period 1947Q1 to 1983Q4 and only 0.6% over the period 1984Q1 to
2017Q4
Causes of the Great Moderation?
• Economists have put forward three alternative explanations of the Great Moderation
1. Good luck
2. Good policy
3. Structural change
Intuition:
• Facing an uncertain income in period 2, households are likely to engage in
precautionary saving in period 1
• This would allow them to hedge against a bad income realization in period 2
• Thus, consumption should fall in period 1
• Since the period 1 endowment is unchanged, the trade balance must improve
Implication:
• If this intuition is right, the decline in income uncertainty observed during the
Great Moderation should lead to an elevation in current account deficits
Baseline: The Economy without Uncertainty
• For simplicity we assume that the world interest rate is zero (𝑟 ∗ = 0) and initial asset
holdings in the economy are zero (i.e., 𝐵0 = 0) so that the current account equals the
trade balance. These assumptions simplify the budget constraints of the household
• The period 1 budget constraint is given by:
𝐶1 + 𝐵1 − 𝐵0 = 𝑟0 𝐵0 + 𝑄1
⇒ 𝐶1 + 𝐵1 = 𝑄
max ln 𝐶1 + ln 2𝑄 − 𝐶1 .
𝐶1
• The F.O.C for this unconstrained optimization problem yields the consumption Euler
equation:
𝜕𝑈 1 1
= − = 0,
𝜕𝐶1 𝐶1 2𝑄 − 𝐶1
⇒ 𝐶1 = 𝑄
• The trade balance is zero: 𝑇𝐵1 = 𝑄 − 𝐶1 = 0
• and the current account is in balance: 𝐶𝐴1 = 𝑇𝐵1 = 0
• No need for households to use the current account to smooth consumption over
time because the endowment stream is already perfectly smooth
Introducing Uncertainty
• Suppose now that the period 1 endowment continues to be 𝑄, but that the period
2 endowment 𝑄2 is not known with certainty in period 1
• Specifically, we assume that with probability 1/2 the household receives a positive
endowment shock in period 2 equal to 𝜎 > 0, and that with equal probability the
household receives a negative endowment shock in the amount of −𝜎
• Thus:
𝑄 + 𝜎 𝑤𝑖𝑡ℎ 𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑏𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦 1/2
𝑄2 = ቊ
𝑄 − 𝜎 𝑤𝑖𝑡ℎ 𝑝𝑟𝑜𝑏𝑎𝑏𝑖𝑙𝑖𝑡𝑦 1/2
• equals the endowment that the household receives in period 2 in the economy
without uncertainty
• The parameter 𝜎 measures the degree of uncertainty (i.e., the standard deviation
of the period 2 endowment)
• To see this, first note that the variance is the expected value of squared deviations
of output from its mean
• In the good state of nature H, the deviation of output from its mean (𝑄) is:
𝑄+𝜎−𝑄 =𝜎
• In the bad state of nature L, the deviation of output from its mean is:
𝑄 − 𝜎 − 𝑄 = −𝜎
• Therefore, the variance is:
1 1
𝑉𝑎𝑟 𝑄2 = 𝐸 𝑄2 − 𝐸(𝑄2 ) = 𝑄 + 𝜎 − 𝑄 + 𝑄 − 𝜎 − 𝑄 2
2 2
2 2
𝜎 2 (−𝜎) 2
= + = 𝜎2
2 2
• The standard deviation is the square root of the variance. Therefore, the standard
deviation of 𝑄2 is
𝑉𝑎𝑟(𝑄2 ) = 𝜎2 = 𝜎
1 1
𝑈1 = ln 𝐶1 + ln 𝐶2 (𝐻) + ln 𝐶1 + ln 𝐶2 (𝐿)
2 2
1 1
⇒ 𝑈1 = ln 𝐶1 + ln 𝐶2 (𝐻) + ln 𝐶2 (𝐿)
2 2
⇒ 𝑈1 = ln 𝐶1 + 𝐸 ln 𝐶2
𝐶1 + 𝐵1 = 𝑄
• However, now we have TWO period 2 budget constraints (one for each state of
nature)
• For the good state of nature H, the period 2 budget constraint is:
𝐶2 (𝐻) + 𝐵2 − 𝐵1 = 𝑄2 (𝐻)
⇒ 𝐶2 (𝐻) − 𝐵1 = 𝑄 + 𝜎
𝐶2 𝐿 + 𝐵2 − 𝐵1 = 𝑄2 (𝐿)
⇒ 𝐶2 𝐿 − 𝐵1 = 𝑄 − 𝜎
• after setting 𝐵2 = 0
• Combining the period 1 budget constraint with each period 2 budget constraint,
yields the intertemporal budget constraint for each state of nature:
𝐶1 + 𝐶2 𝐻 = 2𝑄 + 𝜎
𝐶1 + 𝐶2 𝐿 = 2𝑄 − 𝜎
• Using each intertemporal budget constraint to eliminate 𝐶2 (𝐻) and 𝐶2 (𝐿) from the
lifetime utility function, then expected lifetime utility is given by:
1 1
𝑈1 = ln 𝐶1 + ln 𝐶2 (𝐻) + ln 𝐶2 (𝐿)
2 2
1 1
⇒ 𝑈1 = ln 𝐶1 + ln 2𝑄 + 𝜎 − 𝐶1 + ln 2𝑄 − 𝜎 − 𝐶1
2 2
1 1 1 1
⇒ = + (2)
𝐶1 2 2𝑄 + 𝜎 − 𝐶1 2𝑄 − 𝜎 − 𝐶1
1 1 1 1
⇒ = +
𝑄 2 𝑄+𝜎 𝑄−𝜎
𝑄2
⇒1= 2
𝑄 − 𝜎2
• which is impossible, given that 𝜎 > 0
• We have thus shown that 𝐶1 ≠ 𝑄
• That is, a mean preserving increase in uncertainty induces households to choose a
different level of period 1 consumption than the one they would choose under
certainty
• The next Figure provides a graphical representation of this result
• It plots with a solid line the marginal utility of period 1 consumption as a function
of 𝐶1 i.e., the LHS of the Euler equation (2)
• Suppose 𝐶1 = 𝑄. Then the marginal utility of period 1 consumption is equal to 1/𝑄
(point A in the figure)
• In this case consumption in period 2 is either (𝑄 − 𝜎) or (𝑄 + 𝜎) and the marginal
utility in period 2 is either at point B, where 1/(𝑄 − 𝜎), or point C, where 1/(𝑄 + 𝜎)
• The expected marginal utility in period 2 is then given by point D, where:
1 1
+
2(𝑄 − 𝜎) 2(𝑄 + 𝜎)
• Point D is above point A (because the marginal utility is convex), therefore when 𝐶1 = 𝑄
the marginal utility of period 1 consumption is below the expected marginal utility of
period 2 consumption
• Therefore, we have shown that if we set 𝐶1 = 𝑄, then the LHS of the Euler equation (2)
is less than the RHS:
1 1 1 1 1 1 1
< + = +
𝐶1 2 2𝑄 + 𝜎 − 𝐶1 2𝑄 − 𝜎 − 𝐶1 2 𝑄+𝜎 𝑄−𝜎
• In other words, if the consumer chose 𝐶1 = 𝑄, then the marginal utility of consumption
in period 1 would be smaller than the expected marginal utility of consumption in period
2
• The household would be better off consuming less in period 1 and more in period
2!
• By inspection of the Euler equation (2), we can observe that the LHS is decreasing
in 𝐶1 and the RHS increasing in 𝐶1 :
1 1 1 1
= +
𝐶1 2 2𝑄 + 𝜎 − 𝐶1 2𝑄 − 𝜎 − 𝐶1
• It follows that the that the optimal consumption choice in period 1 that satisfies the
Euler equation (2) is:
𝐶1 < 𝑄
• This means that an increase in uncertainty induces households to consume less and
save more
• By saving more in period 1, households avoid having to cut consumption by too
much in the bad state of nature of period 2
• This type of saving is known as precautionary saving
Uncertainty, the Trade Balance, and the Current Account
• Recall that under certainty the trade balance and current account are balanced with
𝐵0 = 0
• An increase in uncertainty causes an improvement in the trade balance and the
current account:
𝐶𝐴1 = 𝑇𝐵1 = 𝑄 − 𝐶1 > 0
• Viewed through the lens of this model, the reduction in output volatility that came
with the Great Moderation should have contributed to the observed deterioration
of the U.S. current account
5.4 Complete Asset Markets
• Suppose that in period 1 there exists the following two assets, known as state
contingent claims:
1. An asset 𝐵𝐻 that pays in period 2, one unit of goods in the good state H and zero
in the bad state of nature L. Its price is 𝑃𝐻
2. Another asset 𝐵𝐿 that pays one unit of goods in the bad state L and zero in the
good state of nature H. Its price is 𝑃𝐿
• This economy is said to have complete asset markets, because households can buy
asset portfolios with any payoff pattern across states in period 2
• If the household wishes to have a portfolio that pays 𝑥 units of goods in the good
state of nature and 𝑦 units in the bad state of nature, then it must simply purchase
𝑥 units of the asset that pays in the good state (𝐵𝐻 = 𝑥) and 𝑦 units of the asset
that pays in the bad state (𝐵𝐿 = 𝑦)
• This portfolio costs in period 1:
𝑃𝐻 𝑥 + 𝑃𝐿 𝑦
• This was not possible in the incomplete asset economy, because with a risk-free
bond, households are restricted to buy asset portfolios with the same payoff in
period 2 regardless of the state of nature that occurs
• The quantities 𝐵𝐻 and 𝐵𝐿 could be positive or negative
• For example, the household could sell contingent claims that pay in the good state
(𝐵𝐻 < 0) and buy contingent claims that pay in the bad state (𝐵𝐿 > 0)
• The existence in period 1 of one state contingent claim for each possible state of
nature in period 2, makes any other asset redundant, in the sense that its payoff can
be replicated by an appropriate portfolio of state contingent claims
• Consider, for example, a risk-free bond, that was available to households in the
incomplete asset market economy of the previous section
• A risk-free bond is an asset that costs one unit of good in period 1 and pays 1 + 𝑟1
units of good in every state of period 2, where 𝑟1 is the risk-free interest rate
• Consider now constructing a portfolio of contingent claims that has the same
payoff as the risk-free bond, i.e., a portfolio that pays 1 + 𝑟1 in each state of period
2
• This portfolio must contain 1 + 𝑟1 units of each of the two contingent claims
• The price of this portfolio in period 1 is:
(𝑃𝐻 +𝑃𝐿 )(1 + 𝑟1 )
• This portfolio price must equal the price of the risk-free bond, namely 1,
otherwise a pure arbitrage opportunity would exist
• Thus, we have that:
(𝑃𝐻 +𝑃𝐿 ) 1 + 𝑟1 = 1
1
⇒ 1 + 𝑟1 = 𝐻 (3)
𝑃 + 𝑃𝐿
• Thus, the gross risk-free interest rate is the inverse of the price of a portfolio that
pays one unit of good in every state of nature of period 2
Household’s Optimization Problem
𝐶1 + 𝑃𝐻 𝐵𝐻 + 𝑃𝐿 𝐵𝐿 = 𝑄
𝐶2 𝐻 = 𝑄 + 𝜎 + 𝐵𝐻
• For the bad state of nature, the period 2 budget constraint is:
𝐶2 𝐿 = 𝑄 − 𝜎 + 𝐵𝐿
• As before, each state of nature has the same probability of occurrence (i.e., 1/2 )
• Using the period 1 budget constraint to eliminate 𝐶1 and the period 2 budget constraints to
eliminate 𝐶2 (𝐻) and 𝐶2 (𝐿), the individual’s lifetime expected utility on date 1 is given by:
1 1
𝑈1 = ln 𝐶1 + ln 𝐶2 (𝐻) + ln 𝐶2 (𝐿)
2 2
1 1
⇒ 𝑈1 = ln 𝑄 − 𝑃 𝐵 − 𝑃 𝐵 + ln 𝑄 + 𝜎 + 𝐵 + ln 𝑄 − 𝜎 + 𝐵𝐿
𝐻 𝐻 𝐿 𝐿 𝐻
2 2
𝑃𝐿 1
= (5)
𝐶1 2𝐶2 (𝐿)
• Equations (4) and (5) are the intertemporal Euler equations relating to state contingent
claims rather than a risk-free bond
• The LHS of (4) is the welfare cost of purchasing in period 1 a state contingent claim that
pays one unit of consumption in the good state of nature in period 2
• Why? The price of such an asset is 𝑃 𝐻 units of period 1 consumption. In turn, each unit of
period 1 consumption yields 1/𝐶1 units of utility, because, with log preferences, 1/𝐶1 is the
marginal utility of consumption
• So the total utility cost in period 1 of a state contingent claim that pays one unit of
𝑃𝐻
consumption in the good state of nature in period 2 is
𝐶1
• The household equates this cost to the expected utility of an additional unit of
1
consumption in the good state of nature in period 2, given by
2𝐶2 (𝐻)
• The second optimality condition (5) has a similar interpretation
• We can rearrange equations (4) and (5):
𝐻
𝐶1
𝑃 =
2𝐶2 (𝐻)
𝐶1
𝑃𝐿 =
2𝐶2 (𝐿)
• where the marginal rate of substitution between consumption in period 1 and state-
contingent consumption in period 2 is equal to the relative price of goods in each
state in period 2 in terms of goods in period 1
Note
• Under incomplete asset markets, we had one optimality condition, the Euler
equation given by (2)
• Under complete asset markets, we have two optimality conditions (4) and (5)
• The reason is that under complete asset markets the household can buy as many
independent assets as there are states of nature (in our example two)
• Whereas with incomplete asset markets the household has access to fewer assets
than states (one asset in an environment with two states of nature)
Free International Capital Mobility
1
1 + 𝑟∗ = (6)
𝑃𝐻∗ + 𝑃𝐿∗
• Assuming for simplicity as we did in the economy with incomplete asset markets
that the world interest rate is zero (𝑟 ∗ = 0) gives:
𝑃𝐻∗ + 𝑃𝐿∗ = 1
Assumption: Foreign Investors Make Zero Expected Profits
𝐵𝐻 𝐵𝐿
⇒ 1+ 𝑟∗ 𝑃∗𝐻 𝐵𝐻 + 𝑃 ∗𝐿 𝐵𝐿 − −
2 2
• The assumption that the foreign investor makes zero expected profits on any portfolio
𝐵𝐻 , 𝐵𝐿 means:
𝐵 𝐻 𝐵 𝐿
1 + 𝑟 ∗ 𝑃∗𝐻 𝐵𝐻 + 𝑃 ∗𝐿 𝐵𝐿 − − =0
2 2
1 1
⇒ 1 + 𝑟 ∗ 𝑃∗𝐻 − 𝐵𝐻 + 1 + 𝑟 ∗ 𝑃∗𝐿 − 𝐵𝐿 = 0
2 2
• which implies:
1 1
1+ 𝑟∗ 𝑃∗𝐻 = ; 1+ 𝑟∗ 𝑃 ∗𝐿 =
2 2
• Finally, assuming as we did in the economy with incomplete asset markets that the world
interest rate is zero (𝑟 ∗ = 0) gives:
1
𝑃 ∗𝐻 = 𝑃 ∗𝐿 =
2
Equilibrium in the Complete Asset Market Economy
𝑃𝐻 1 𝑃𝐿 1
= ; =
𝐶1 2𝐶2 (𝐻) 𝐶1 2𝐶2 (𝐿)
1
• We impose 𝑃 ∗𝐻 = 𝑃 ∗𝐿 = to get:
2
𝐶1 = 𝐶2 𝐻 = 𝐶2 𝐿 (7)
• Thus, complete asset markets allow households to completely smooth consumption across
time and across states of nature!
• Combining (7) with the period 2 budget constraints gives:
𝐵𝐻 = 𝐶1 − 𝑄 − 𝜎 (8)
𝐵𝐿 = 𝐶1 − 𝑄 + 𝜎 (9)
• Inserting (8) and (9) into the period 1 budget constraint yields 𝐶1 = 𝑄
• Thus, it follows from (7):
𝐶1 = 𝐶2 𝐻 = 𝐶2 𝐿 = 𝑄
• And inserting 𝐶1 = 𝑄 into (8) and (9) yields:
𝐵𝐻 = −𝜎
𝐵𝐿 = 𝜎
• Thus, the household takes a short position (borrows) in contingent claims that pay
in the good state of nature and a long position (saves) in claims that pay in the bad
state of nature
• In this way, households can transfer resources from the good state to the bad state
of nature in period 2, which allows them to smooth consumption across states
• Notice the difference compared to incomplete asset markets
• With a risk-free bond, households cannot transfer resources across states, because
the financial instruments to do so are unavailable
• Instead, to self-insure, households in period 1 must engage in precautionary saving
to transfer resources to both states in period 2 through the single bond traded in
the market
• This is an inferior option because it forces households to transfer resources from
period 1 to the good state in period 2, where they are not needed
• The trade balance and current account are balanced
𝐶𝐴1 = 𝑇𝐵1 = 𝑄 − 𝐶1 = 0
• Thus, under complete financial markets precautionary saving is zero and the link
between the level of uncertainty and the current account disappears
• Thus, the main result of the previous section, namely, that a decrease in uncertainty
leads to a deterioration in the current account relies on the assumption that
financial markets are incomplete
• It is therefore natural to ask whether reality is better approximated by the
assumption of complete asset markets or by the assumption of incomplete
markets?
• Domestic financial markets could be incomplete for various reasons
• As we will discuss later in the course, there may exist moral hazard and incomplete
contracts that make it impossible for any country to fully insure itself against all the
risks it faces
• Although with complete asset markets the current account is zero independently
of the degree of uncertainty 𝜎, there can be significant amount of international
borrowing and lending in this economy
• Specifically, even though the country’s net international asset position is zero:
𝐵𝐻 + 𝐵𝐿 = 0
(b) Suppose the economy is initially an equilibrium where the current account is
zero. Discuss what happens to saving, investment, the equilibrium interest rate,
and the current account in response to a temporary increase in productivity 𝐴1 .
Illustrate your answer.
(c) Explain how your answer to part (b) would differ under a closed economy.
Illustrate your answer.
(d) Explain how your answer to part (b) would differ if instead of a temporary
increase in productivity, there was a temporary increase in the terms of trade.