Managerial Economics 1
Managerial Economics 1
Managerial Economics 1
Page 1 of 23
D21MBA11764
Assignment No. 2
Page 2 of 23
D21MBA11764
SECTION-A(10 MARKS)
Page 3 of 23
D21MBA11764
Lilly’s Indifference Curves. Lilly would receive equal utility from all points on a given
indifference curve. Any points on the highest indifference curve Uh, like F, provide greater
utility than any points like A, B, C, and D on the middle indifference curve Um. Similarly, any
points on the middle indifference curve Um provide greater utility than any points on the lowest
indifference curve Ul.
The schedule shows that the quantity of capital remains the same i.e. 2 machines throughout the
production process but the number of laborers is increased from time to time. The first laborer
has produced a total production (TP) of 10 meters of cloth. After applying the 2nd laborer total
production is increased to 22 meters. The marginal production (MP) of the second laborer is 12,
which goes on increasing. After the use of the 3rd, 4th and then the 5th laborer the total
production is increased from 36 to 70 meters and the M.P from 14 to 18 meters.
6. What is an iso-quant-curve?
Answer- An isoquant (derived from quantity and the Greek word iso, meaning equal),
in microeconomics, is a contour line drawn through the set of points at which the same quantity
of output is produced while changing the quantities of two or more inputs. The x and y axis on an
isoquant represent two relevant inputs, which are usually a factor of production such as labor,
capital, land, or organisation. An isoquant may also be known as an “Iso-Product Curve”, or an
“Equal Product Curve”.
Page 4 of 23
D21MBA11764
An isoquant map where production output Q3 > Q2 > Q1. Typically inputs X and Y would refer
to labor and capital respectively. More of input X, input Y, or both is required to move from
isoquant Q1 to Q2, or from Q2 to Q3.
A) Example of an isoquant map with two inputs that are perfect substitutes.
B) Example of an isoquant map with two inputs that are perfect complements.
Page 5 of 23
D21MBA11764
Long-run Average Cost (LAC) is the total cost divided by any level of output. It is ideally
derived by long-run average price from short-run average cost curve. In the short-run turn, a firm
or plant remains fixed, and the curve corresponds to a respective plant. Here the long average
cost curve is termed as planning or envelope curve due to its function in preparing plans for
enlarging production at a minimum cost.
A good example will be taking three sizes of plants where nothing else can be built. In the short-
run curve, this plant size remains fixed, which can increase or decrease the variables. However,
in the long term, a firm has the flexibility to choose the options of plants which can aid in the
highest output at minimum cost.
Page 6 of 23
D21MBA11764
Macroeconomics deals with the performance, structure, and behaviour of the entire economy, in
contrast to microeconomics, which is more focused on the choices made by individual actors in
the economy (like people, households, industries, etc.
Macroeconomics is the branch of economics that deals with the structure, performance,
behaviour, and decision-making of the whole, or aggregate, economy.
The two main areas of macroeconomic research are long-term economic growth and shorter-term
business cycles.
Macroeconomics in its modern form is often defined as starting with John Maynard Keynes and
his theories about market behavior and governmental policies in the 1930s; several schools of
thought have developed since.
In contrast to macroeconomics, microeconomics is more focused on the influences on and
choices made by individual actors in the economy (people, companies, industries, etc.
Page 7 of 23
D21MBA11764
In the beginning, the demand curve is DD. If there is a favorable change in the factors
determining the demand and the demand curve for the goods shift upward to D’D’, increase in
demand has occurred. It will be clear from the Figure 7. that when the demand curve for the
goods is DD, then the price OF, OM quantity of the goods is demanded, but with the demand
curve D’D’, at the same price OP, a greater quantity OH is demanded.Likewise, at other prices
also, at the demand curve D’D’, more quantity is demanded than at the demand curve DD. We
have explained above how the increase in demand takes place.
(i) The fashion for a goods increases or people’s tastes and preferences become more favourable
for the good;
(vi) Owing to the increase in population and as a result of expansion in market, the number of
consumers of the goods has increased.
If there is any above change, demand will increase and the demand curve will shift to an upward
position.Now, take the question of decrease in demand. Whereas the contraction in demand
implies the fall in quantity demanded as a result of rise in price, decrease in demand means the
whole demand curve shifts to a lower position. In other words, decrease in demand means that at
Page 8 of 23
D21MBA11764
various prices, less is demanded than before. The decrease in demand does not occur due to the
rise in price but due to the changes in other determinants of demand.
(iv) The prices of the complements of that commodity have risen and
(v) The propensity to consume of the people has declined. In other words, the propensity to save
has increased.
Increase and decrease in demand is depicted in Figure 7. In this figure DD is the demand curve
for the goods in the beginning. If due to the above reasons the demand for the goods declines, the
whole demand curve will shift below. In figure 7 as a result of the decrease in demand, demand
curve has shifted below to the position D”D”.
It is now clear from the figure that when the demand curve shifts below from DD to D”D”, at
price OP, quantity demanded decreases from OM to OL. A glance at the demand curve D”D”
will reveal that at prices other than Op also, less quantity of the good is demanded at the demand
curve D”D” than at the demand curve DD.
Page 9 of 23
D21MBA11764
Where q refers to quantity demanded, p to price and ∆ to change. If Ep> 1, demand is elastic. If
Ep < 1, demand is inelastic, it Ep = 1 demand is unitary elastic.
A 6 0
В 5 ————-► 10
С 4 20
Page 10 of 23
D21MBA11764
D 3 ————-► 30
E 2 40
F 1 ————► 50
G 0 60
Page 11 of 23
D21MBA11764
:
The value of Ep again differs in this example than that given in example (iii) for the reason stated
above.
(2) The Point Method:
Prof. Marshall devised a geometrical method for measuring elasticity at a point on the demand
curve. Let RS be a straight line demand curve in Figure 11.2. If the price falls from PB(=OA) to
MD(=OC). the quantity demanded increases from OB to OD. Elasticity at point P on the RS
demand curve according to the formula is: Ep = ∆q/∆p x p/q
Where ∆ q represents changes in quantity demanded, ∆p changes in price level while p and q are
initial price and quantity levels.
From Figure 11.2
∆ q = BD = QM
ADVERTISEMENTS:
∆p = PQ
p = PB
q = OB
Substituting these values in the elasticity formula:
With the help of the point method, it is easy to point out the elasticity at any point along a
demand curve. Suppose that the straight line demand curve DC in Figure 11.3 is 6 centimetres.
Page 12 of 23
D21MBA11764
Five points L, M, N, P and Q are taken oh this demand curve. The elasticity of demand at each
point can be known with the help of the above method. Let point N be in the middle of the
demand curve. So elasticity of demand at point.
We arrive at the conclusion that at the mid-point on the demand curve the elasticity of demand is
unity. Moving up the demand curve from the mid-point, elasticity becomes greater. When the
demand curve touches the Y-axis, elasticity is infinity. Ipso facto, any point below the mid-point
towards the X-axis will show elastic demand.
Elasticity becomes zero when the demand curve touches the X-axis.
(3) The Arc Method:
We have studied the measurement of elasticity at a point on a demand curve. But when elasticity
is measured between two points on the same demand curve, it is known as arc elasticity. In the
words of Prof. Baumol, “Arc elasticity is a measure of the average responsiveness to price
change exhibited by a demand curve over some finite stretch of the curve.”
Any two points on a demand curve make an arc. The area between P and M on the DD curve in
Figure 11.4 is an arc which measures elasticity over a certain range of price and quantities. On
any two points of a demand curve the elasticity coefficients are likely to be different depending
upon the method of computation. Consider the price-quantity combinations P and M as given in
Table 11.2.
Page 13 of 23
D21MBA11764
P 8 10
M 6 12
Thus the point method of measuring elasticity at two points on a demand curve gives different
elasticity coefficients because we used a different base in computing the percentage change in
each case.
To avoid this discrepancy, elasticity for the arc (PM in Figure 11.4) is calculated by taking the
average of the two prices [(p1, + p2 1/2] and the average of the two quantities [(p1, + q2) 1/2].
The formula for price elasticity of demand at the mid-point (C in Figure 11.4) of the arc on the
demand curve is
On the basis of this formula, we can measure arc elasticity of demand when there is a movement
either from point P to M or from M to P.
From P to M at P, p1 = 8, q1, =10, and at M, P2 = 6, q2 = 12
Applying these values, we get
Page 14 of 23
D21MBA11764
Thus whether we move from M to P or P to M on the arc PM of the DD curve, the formula for
arc elasticity of demand gives the same numerical value. The closer the two points P and M are,
the more accurate is the measure of elasticity on the basis of this formula. If the two points which
form the arc on the demand curve are so close that they almost merge into each other, the
numerical value of arc elasticity equals the numerical value of point elasticity.
(4) The Total Outlay Method:
Marshall evolved the total outlay, total revenue or total expenditure method as a measure of
elasticity. By comparing the total expenditure of a purchaser both before and after the change in
price, it can be known whether his demand for a good is elastic, unity or less elastic. Total outlay
is price multiplied by the quantity of a good purchased: Total Outlay = Price x Quantity
Demanded. This is explained with the help of the demand schedule in Table 11.3.
:
(i) Elastic Demand:
Demand is elastic, when with the fall in price the total expenditure increases and with the rise in
price the total expenditure decreases. Table 11.3 shows that when the price falls from Rs. 9 to
Rs. 8, the total expenditure increases from Rs. 180 to Rs. 240 and when price rises from Rs. 7 to
Rs. 8, the total expenditure falls from Rs. 280 to Rs. 240. Demand is elastic (Ep > 1) in this case.
Page 15 of 23
D21MBA11764
Price ТЕ Ep
Rises Falls
Falls Unchanged =1
Rises Unchanged
Falls Falls
Figure 11.5 illustrates the relation between elasticity of demand and total expenditure. The
rectangles show total expenditure: Price x quantity demanded. The figure shows that at the
midpoint of the demand curve, total expenditure is maximum in the range of unitary elasticity,
i.e. Rs. 6, Rs. 5 and Rs. 4 with quantities 50 kgs., 60 kgs. and 75 kgs.
Total expenditure rises as price falls, in the elastic range of demand, i.e. Rs. 9, Rs. 8 and Rs. 7
with quantities 20 kgs., 30 kgs. and 40 kgs. Total expenditure falls as price falls in the elasticity
range, i.e. Rs.3, Rs. 2 and Re. 1 with quantities 80 kgs., 90 kgs. and 100 kgs. Thus elasticity of
demand is unitary in the AB range of DD, curve, elastic in the range AD above point A and less
elastic in the BD1 range below point B. The conclusion is that price elasticity of demand refers
to a movement along a specific demand curve.
Page 16 of 23
D21MBA11764
Diminishing Returns Graph The graph highlights the concept of diminishing returns by plotting
the curve of output against input. The areas of increasing, diminishing and negative returns are
identified at points along the curve. There is also a point of maximum yield which is the point on
the curve where producing another unit of output becomes inefficient and unproductive.
This idea can be understood outside of economics theory, for example, population. The
population size on Earth is growing rapidly, but this will not continue forever (exponentially).
Constraints such as resources will see the population growth stagnate at some point and begin to
Page 17 of 23
D21MBA11764
decline Similarly, it will begin to decline towards zero, but not actually become a negative value.
The same idea as in the diminishing rate of return inevitable to the production process.
Figure 2: Output vs. Input [top] & Output per unit Input vs. Input [bottom] Seen in [top], the
change in output by increasing output from L1 to L2 is equal to the change from L2 to L3. Seen
in [bottom], until an output of L1, the output per unit is increasing. After L1, the output per unit
decreases to zero at L3. Together, these demonstrate diminishing returns from L1.
Assumptions
There is short run in the market during which fixed factors of production cannot be changed.
Labour is the only variable factor while other factors are assumed constant.
All units of variable factors are homogeneous and equally efficient.
There is no change in the state of technology and techniques of production.
The reward of the factors of production should remain constant.
Explanation
The law can be explained with the help of the following schedule and diagram.
The Schedule shows that if one unit of labour is applied on 12 acres of land (which is fixed), it
will produce 20 mounds of wheat. When two units of labour are applied on the same quantity of
land, the total production will increase to 45 mounds. Thus marginal production (MP) of the
second variable factor is 25 mounds. It is clear that the given quantity of land cannot be fully
utilized by applying only one labour. Thus the units of labour are increased again and again. The
optimum level is achieved when the 6th unit is applied at which MP of labour is Zero and TP is
Maximum. After the optimum level the additional unit of labour results in negative marginal
production and decline in TP.
Page 18 of 23
D21MBA11764
In the Law of diminishing return graph the units of labour are measured along X-axis while the
Total and Marginal production is measured along Y-axis. The total production (TP) curve is
represented by NRS while NUL represents the, Marginal Production (MP) Curve
4. State and explain the law of equi-marginal utility.
Answer-Law of Equi-Marginal Utility explains the relation between the consumption of two or
more products and what combination of consumption these products will give optimum
satisfaction. Marginal Utility is the additional satisfaction gained by consuming one more unit of
a commodity. Let’s try and understand
Assumptions of Law of Equi-Marginal Utility
Units of goods are homogenous.
No time gap between the consumption of the different units.
Tastes, fashion, preferences, and priorities remain unchanged.
Consumer aims at maximum satisfaction.
Consumer’s income is fixed and limited.
Types of Marginal Utility
Based on the relationship between the total and the Marginal Utility, there are three types of
marginal utility.
Positive
The marginal utility is positive when the consumption of an additional unit of a product results in
the increase in the total utility. Getting a coupon of free hair spa is its example.
Negative
It is negative when the consumption of an additional unit of a product results in the decrease in
the total utility. Taking more vitamin supplements or overtake of some medicine is its example.
Zero
It is zero when the consumption of an additional unit of a product results in no change in the total
utility. Getting two copies of the same novel is one of the examples of zero marginal utility.
Suppose we have data for the marginal and the total utility for different units of ice creams. Let
us see the relation between the two.
1 20 20
2 35 15
3 45 10
Page 19 of 23
D21MBA11764
4 52 7
5 55 3
6 55 0
7 52 -2
8 47 -5
9 36 -11
10 20 -16
This law is based on the principle of obtaining maximum satisfaction from a limited income. It
explains the behavior of a consumer when he consumes more than one commodity.
The law states that a consumer should spend his limited income on different commodities in such
a way that the last rupee spent on each commodity yield him equal marginal utility in order to get
maximum satisfaction.
Suppose there are different commodities like A, B, …, N. A consumer will get the maximum
satisfaction in the case of equilibrium i.e.,
MUA / PA = MUB / PB = … = MUN / PN
Page 20 of 23
D21MBA11764
Where MU’s are the marginal utilities for the commodities and P’s are the prices of the
commodities.
Assumptions of the Law
There is no change in the price of the goods or services.
The consumer has a fixed income.
The marginal utility of money is constant.
A consumer has perfect knowledge of utility.
Consumer tries to have maximum satisfaction.
The utility is measurable in cardinal terms.
There are substitutes for goods.
A consumer has many wants.
Limitation of the Law
There are some limitations to this law. They are
The law is not applicable in case of knowledge. Reading books provides more knowledge
and has more utility.
This law is not applicable in case of fashion and customs.
This law is not applicable for very low income.
There is no measurement of utility.
Not all consumer care for variety.
The law fails when there are no choices available for the good.
The law fails in case of frequent price change.
Importance of the Law
This law is helpful in the field of production. A producer has limited resources and tries to get
maximum profit.
This law is helpful in the field of exchange. The exchange is of anything like some goods,
wealth, trade, import, and export.
It is applicable to public finance.
The law is useful for workers in allocating the time between the work and rest.
It is useful in case of saving and spending.
It is useful to look for substitution in case of price rise.
Page 21 of 23
D21MBA11764
{\displaystyleu(A)=9,u(B)=8,u(C)=1}
But critics of cardinal utility claim the only meaningful message of this function is the order {\
{\displaystylev(A)=9,v(B)=2,v(C)=1}
The functions u and v are ordinally equivalent – they represent George's preferences equally
well.
Ordinal utility contrasts with cardinal utility theory: the latter assumes that the differences
between preferences are also important. In u the difference between A and B is much smaller
than between B and C, while in v the opposite is true. Hence, u and v are not cardinally
equivalent.
The ordinal utility concept was first introduced by Pareto in 1906
Cardinal vs. Marginal Utility
In economics, utility simply means the satisfaction that a consumer experiences from a product
or service. While the concept is considered an important factor in decision-making and product
choice, it presents a problem for economists trying to incorporate the concept
to microeconomics models because utility varies among consumers for the same product, and it
can be influenced by other factors, such as price and the availability of alternatives.
KEY TAKEAWAYS
Utility measures the amount of satisfaction that an individual receives from a product or service.
Utility comes in two types: cardinal and marginal.
Cardinal utility assigns a number to the utility, such as a basket of apples gives a utility of 10 and
a bushel of corn is 20.
Marginal utility is based on the idea utility functions diminish as quantities of products are
increased.
Cardinal utility is an attempt to quantify and abstract concept because it assigns a numerical
value to utility. Models that incorporate cardinal utility use the theoretical unit of utility, the util,
in the same way that any other measurable quantity is used. For example, a basket of bananas
might give a consumer a utility of 10, while a basket of mangoes might give a utility of 20.
The downside to cardinal utility is that there is no fixed scale to work from. The idea of 10 utils
is meaningless in and of itself, and the factors that influence the number might vary widely from
one consumer to the next. If another consumer gives bananas a util value of 15, it doesn't
necessarily mean that the individual likes bananas 50% than the first consumer. The implication
is that there is no way to compare utility between consumers.
One important concept related to cardinal utility is the law of diminishing marginal utility, which
states that at a certain point, every extra unit of a good provides less and less utility. While a
consumer might assign the first basket of bananas a value of 10 utils, after several baskets, the
additional utility of each new basket might decline significantly. The values that are assigned to
each additional basket can be used to find the point at which utility is maximized or to estimate a
customer's demand curve
An alternative way to measure utility is the concept of ordinal utility, which uses rankings
instead of values. The benefit of using rankings is that the subjective differences between
products and between consumers are eliminated, and all that remains are the ranked preferences.
One consumer might like mangoes more than bananas, and another might prefer bananas over
Page 22 of 23
D21MBA11764
Page 23 of 23