The Evolution of Modern States

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 3

International Studies Review (2012) 14, 463–465

The Evolution of Modern States

Review by Chris Thornhill


Politics Department, University of Glasgow

The Evolution of Modern States. Sweden, Japan, and the United States. By Sven Steinmo.

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/isr/article/14/3/463/1793439 by guest on 28 October 2021


Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2010. 264 pp., $28.30 (ISBN 978-0-521-
19670-3 (hb); 978-0-521-14546-6).

Evolutionary theory currently occupies a somewhat marginal yet also discretely


influential methodological position in the social sciences, and it often crosses
the divides between sociology, political science, and even law. The book under
review here, The Evolution of Modern States. Sweden, Japan, and the United States,
utilizes evolutionary theory to assess the implications of the bundle of processes
classified together as globalization for the welfare-state structures of advanced
democracies, and it compares ways in which different institutional systems gener-
ate different (variably successfully) reactions to these processes. Globalization is
construed as an aggregate of objective circumstances posing risks both for the
domestic cohesion and the international competitiveness of particular societies
(or particular political economies), exemplified here by Sweden, Japan, and the
USA.
The specific evolutionary dimension of this inquiry resides, first, in the fact
that the book analyzes institutions in different societies as expressions of selective
variation, which facilitate societal reactions to broader problematic constellations.
Indeed, the book perceives ‘‘human agency’’ itself, defined as the volitional sub-
strate of different institutions, as a complex aggregate of ‘‘intentional variation’’
(220), which makes it possible for a society incrementally to adapt to systemic
pressures. Underlying this approach is a systemic-evolutionary sociology of politi-
cal institutions. This approach accords a ‘‘structuring’’ role to institutions (xvii),
which are defined as mechanisms for reproducing and consolidating variations
that have obtained demonstrable adaptive success. Institutions are ‘‘systems of
rules,’’ akin to biological rules governing cell behavior, and human agency gen-
erates mutations within these rules (220). The image of societal order emerging
from this analysis is based in an interplay between institutional structure and var-
iational agency: These elements of society act together to stimulate the adaptive
and co-evolutionary interaction between different parts of the societal whole. Sec-
ond, the evolutionary focus of the book resides in the claim that each human
society as a whole forms a system, integrating the parallel evolutionary trajecto-
ries of a number of (sub-)systems. Indeed, Steinmo argues that all territorially
delineated societies or countries represent ‘‘quite different systems,’’ in which
problems of institutional balance, cohesion, and adaptivity are posed and
resolved from different preconditions (206). This is an interesting and rather dis-
tinctive argument, and it contains a rather unusual use of evolutionary theory.
The equation of a national society with a sui generis system has been increasingly
abandoned in more contemporary evolutionary theory in favor of a conception
of transnational or world society in its entirety as a social system. In this respect,
Steinmo’s analysis appears to look back to earlier models of systemic functional-
ism—that is, to those of a Parsonian orientation—which were widespread in the

Thornhill, Chris. (2012) The Evolution of Modern States. International Studies Review, doi: 10.1111/j.1468-2486.2012.01138.x
 2012 International Studies Association
464 The Evolution of Modern States

era of late nationalism. Nonetheless, this approach has clear merits, and it allows
the author to articulate the diverse and cultural-specific constitutional conjunc-
tures of the societies examined.
The substance of the book can be divided into two parts. On the one hand,
the book contains the methodological claim that we need to see societies as
more or less successful adaptive systems, in which institutions play a leading role.
It adds to this point the claim that market-based systems ‘‘have come to domi-
nate the modern world precisely because they have more mechanisms for gener-
ating variation’’ and for ‘‘reproducing successful variations than any other
systems of economic organization’’ (227). An element of latitude is always apparent
here in the definition of a system: If a country is a system, how can this also be

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/isr/article/14/3/463/1793439 by guest on 28 October 2021


the case for an economy?
On the other hand, the book contains the more substantive claim that we
need to perceive the correlation between fiscal strategies, welfare arrangements,
and the social values supporting policies of redistribution as a key element in
the adaptive structure of a society. This correlation is vital, internally, for demo-
graphic stability and for the structurally sensitive consolidation of societies (sys-
tems). It is also vital, externally, for cementing the position or niche of one
society (system) within an international political economy, marked by an implicit
transnational division of labor. These starting positions lead Steinmo to the con-
clusions that (i) contemporary society is not driven by a unilinear rush to the
bottom with respect to revenue extraction and welfare provision (206), and
(ii) the pressures of globalization have not uniformly acted to ‘‘undermine the
welfare state’’ (3). On the contrary, he claims that different societies organize
taxation and welfare in different ways, as articulations of their wider adaptive
national and internal evolution, and the functions of states in channeling fiscal
resources play a vital role in creating variations to sustain a societal system in its
internal and in its external dimensions.
From this position, then, Steinmo concludes that some societies are marked by
a higher level of adaptive success than others. The USA is good at generating
‘‘innovation and variation.’’ Sweden is ‘‘accomplished at selecting successful vari-
ations.’’ Japan is ‘‘proficient in reproduction’’ but less effective in ‘‘generating
variation’’ (228). Overall, the observation that taxation is a central institutional
fulcrum in the adaptive structure of a society is of great importance, and, despite
taxonomic inconsistencies alluded to above, it is adequately substantiated by the
evolutionary frame of reference. The ability to extract and allocate taxation in
relatively consensual and efficient fashion is presented as a highly probable fea-
ture of an effectively adaptive political ⁄ economic system and so of an effectively
adaptive society. Likewise, the claim for the continuing robustness of state insti-
tutions as centers of macro-sociological direction is of great importance. The
association between strong state institutions, flexibly adaptive economies, and
effective fiscal extraction makes an important implicit claim about the functional
continuity between states in their current form and states in their original
consolidation in early modern Europe.
Alongside these overlying propositions, the book generates a series of insights
that are somewhat incidental to the broad analytical thread, but also deserve
affirmative mention. Central to Sweden’s success, Steinmo suggests in illuminat-
ing fashion, is the formation, dated to the 1930s, of a relatively ‘‘symbiotic rela-
tionship’’ between capital and labor (87). This, in the setting of a small and
traditionally homogenous society, has tended to produce legitimacy and selective
authority for a ‘‘powerful and confident state’’ (87). The comparison of Japanese
and US-American welfare systems is also useful, and the author, repeating an
increasingly common theme, queries the perception that American political
economy is based in weak provision for social welfare (152). The extent of public
programs for materially disadvantaged social sectors in the USA is shown as
Chris Thornhill 465

substantially exceeding that in Japan (104), which since 1945 has had the ‘‘small-
est tax burden of any rich country’’ and generates support structures through
private regulatory facilities (106). All this is very helpful and gives weight to the
more general arguments.
Overall, the book is recommendable. It is not always clear whether the evolu-
tionary method is necessary to make the arguments. The legal dimension of state
institutions is also played down, and it only comes into focus in the case of Swe-
den (221). Moreover, strict proponents of systems analysis will query the breadth
of meaning ascribed to the word ‘‘system.’’ However, the book contains impor-
tant explicit claims about fiscal extraction and welfare policies and important
implicit claims about the persistence of state structures (and the adaptive

Downloaded from https://academic.oup.com/isr/article/14/3/463/1793439 by guest on 28 October 2021


grounds for their persistence) in globalized societies.

You might also like