Political Economy - A Beginner's Course
Political Economy - A Beginner's Course
Political Economy - A Beginner's Course
A Beginner’s Course
A. LEONTIEV
First Published by
Co-operative Publishing Society of Foreign Workers in the U.S.S.R.
in 1935
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. II, “Our Program,” p. 491, Russian ed.
7
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Marxism was the first to give a scientific approach to the study of the
history of mankind. Bourgeois scientists are powerless to explain the laws of
development of society. They represent the history of society as a continu-
ous chain of pure accidents in which it is impossible to find any definite law
connecting them. Marx was the first to show that social development like
natural development follows definite internal laws. However, unlike the laws
of nature, the laws of development of human society are realized, not inde-
pendently of the will and acts of man, but, on the contrary, through the ac-
tion of the broad human masses. Marxism discovered that the capitalist sys-
tem, by virtue of the contradictions inherent in it, is unswervingly advancing
towards its own destruction. Marxism teaches, however, that the destruction
of capitalism will not come of itself, but only as the result of a bitter class
struggle of the proletariat against the bourgeoisie. The social-democratic
theory that, since society presumably develops according to definite laws,
the working class can sit down with folded hands and wait for these laws to
bring about socialism in place of capitalism is a crass distortion of Marxism.
The laws of social development do not realize themselves automatically.
They forge their way through the class struggle taking place in society.
The proletariat, armed with the Marxist-Leninist teaching, carries on the
struggle for socialism with certainty. It knows the laws of social develop-
ment: with its struggle, its work, its activity, it follows these laws, which
lead to the inevitable destruction of capitalism and the triumph of socialism.
Marxism-Leninism teaches one to lay bare the class struggle of the dis-
inherited against their oppressors. Marxism-Leninism teaches that the only
road to socialism leads through the determined class struggle of the proletar-
iat for the overthrow of the power of the bourgeoisie and the establishment
of its own dictatorship.
Class differences under capitalism
Let us take any capitalist country. Whether it is an advanced or a back-
ward country, the first thing that strikes one is class differences. In splendid
mansions on streets lined with lawns and trees – a few rich people live. In
dirty, smoky houses, squalid tenements or rickety shacks on joyless streets –
live the workers, the creators of the tremendous incomes of the rich.
Under capitalism society is divided into two great enemy camps, into
two opposed classes – the bourgeoisie and the proletariat. The bourgeoisie
has all the wealth and all the power in its hands; it has all the plants, facto-
ries, mines, the land, the banks, the railroads; the bourgeoisie is the ruling
class. The proletariat has all the oppression and poverty. The contrast be-
tween the bourgeoisie and the proletariat – that is the most important dis-
tinction in any capitalist country. The struggle between the working class
and the bourgeoisie – that is what takes precedence over everything else.
The gulf between these two classes grows ever deeper, ever wider. With the
8
WHAT IS POLITICAL ECONOMY
growth of class contradictions the indignation of the masses of the working
class grows, their will to struggle grows, as do their revolutionary con-
sciousness, their faith in their own strength and in their final victory over
capitalism.
The crisis brought untold suffering to the proletariat. Mass unemploy-
ment, lower wages, thousands of suicides of people brought to desperation,
death from starvation, increased mortality of children – these are the joys of
capitalism for the workers. At the same time, the bourgeoisie gets its tre-
mendous incomes as usual.
Thus, for instance, according to German newspapers, 43 directors of the
dye trust get 145,000 marks a year each; 4 directors of the Schubert and
Saltzer Firm – 145,000 each; 2 directors of the Ilse Corporation – 130,000
each; 7 directors of the Mannesmann Corporation – 135.000 each; 22 direc-
tors of the Alliance Insurance Co. – 80,000 each.
Millions of people go hungry so that a handful of parasites may live in
luxury and idleness. This is the picture which capitalism presents, this is the
picture of the class contradictions, sharpened to the extreme by the unprece-
dented crisis.
The interests of the bourgeoisie and the proletariat are opposed to each
other. The bourgeoisie tries to hold on to its rule by all the devices of vio-
lence and deceit. The proletariat tries, in proportion to the growth of its class
consciousness, to do away with capitalist slavery and to substitute the social-
ist order for it.
The bourgeoisie and the proletariat are the basic classes in capitalist
countries. Their inter-relations, their struggle – these are what determine the
fate of capitalist society. However, in capitalist countries, together with the
bourgeoisie and the proletariat, there are other, intermediate strata. In many
countries these intermediate strata are fairly numerous.
The intermediate strata consist of the small and middle peasants (farm-
ers), artisans, and handicraftsmen. These strata we call the petty bourgeoisie.
What makes them kin to the bourgeoisie is that they own land, instruments
and tools. But at the same time they are toilers, and this makes them kin to
the proletariat. Capitalism inevitably leads to the pauperization of the inter-
mediate strata. They are being squeezed out under capitalism. Insignificant
numbers break through into the ranks of the exploiters, great masses are im-
poverished and sink down into the ranks of the proletariat. Hence, in its
struggle against capitalism, the proletariat finds allies in the broad masses of
the toiling peasants.
What are classes?
The bourgeoisie and the proletariat – these are the two main classes in
every capitalist country. The bourgeoisie rules. But the bourgeoisie cannot
exist without the working class. The capitalist cannot prosper if hundreds
9
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
and thousands of workers will not bend their backs and be drenched in sweat
at his plants and factories. The blood and sweat of the workers are converted
into jingling coin to fill the pockets of the rich. The growth and strengthen-
ing of bourgeois rule inevitably call forth the growth of the working class, an
increase in its numbers and in its solidarity. Thus the bourgeoisie prepares its
own grave-digger. As the capitalist system develops, the forces of the new,
socialist society ripen at its core. Classes, their struggle, the contradictions of
class interests – this is what constitutes the life of capitalist society. But what
are classes? Lenin answered this question as follows:
“What is meant by classes in general? It is what permits one
part of society to appropriate the labour of another. If one part of
society appropriates all the land, we have the classes of landlords
and peasants. If one part of society owns the plants and factories,
shares and capital, while the other part works for them, we have the
classes of capitalists and proletarians.”*
What is the secret, however, which renders it possible for one part of so-
ciety to appropriate the labour of another part of that society? And what are
the reasons for the appearance of whole groups of people that “sow not, but
reap”?
In order to understand this it is necessary to look into how production is
organized in society. Every worker, every toiling farmer knows very well
what production means. People must have food, clothing and shelter in order
to exist. Every toiler knows very well what work it takes to build houses,
cultivate land, produce bread, do the work in plants and factories to produce
the things man needs – because every worker, every toiling farmer, himself
takes part in this work.
By means of labour, people change objects found in nature, adapt them
for their use and for the satisfaction of their wants. In the bowels of the earth
people find coal, iron ore, oil. By their labour they extract these useful ob-
jects and bring them to the surface of the earth. Here the iron ore is smelted
and made into iron. The iron is in turn converted into the most diverse things
– from a locomotive to a pocket knife or needle.
Everyone knows that people do not work singly but together. What
could one man, by himself, do with a coal mine, an iron mine, a plant or a
factory? And first of all, could there be such undertakings altogether without
the united effort of thousands and tens of thousands of people? However, it
is not only on large undertakings that individual effort is unthinkable. Even
the individual peasant working a small plot of land with the help of his old
* Ibid., Vol. XXV, “Speech at the Third Congress of the Russian Young
Communist League,” p. 391, Russian ed.
10
WHAT IS POLITICAL ECONOMY
mare could not do so if other people would not furnish him with a whole
number of necessary things. The handicraftsman and artisan who works by
himself could not get very far either without the instruments and materials
which are the product of the labour of others.
We thus see that production proceeds in society. Production is social,
but it is organized in various ways.
In order to produce, land, factory buildings, machinery and raw material
are needed. All these are called the means of production. But the means of
production are dead without human labour, without live labour power. Only
when labour power is applied to the means of production does the process of
production begin. The place and significance in human society of different
classes are determined by the relation of each of these classes to the means
of production. For instance, under the feudal system the principal means of
production – the land – is owned by the landlord. By means of his ownership
of the land, the landlord exploits the peasants. Under the capitalist system all
enterprises, all the means of production, are in the hands of the bourgeoisie.
The working class has no means of production. This is the basis for the ex-
ploitation of the proletariat by the bourgeoisie.
Capitalism was not the creator of classes and class differences. Classes
existed before capitalism, under the feudal system and even earlier. But capi-
talism substituted new classes for the old. Capitalism created new methods
of class oppression and class struggle.
“Classes are large groups of persons, differing according to
their places in the historically established system of social produc-
tion, according to their relations (mostly fixed and formulated in
laws) to the means of production, according to their roles in the so-
cial organization of labour and consequently according to their
methods of obtaining and the size of the share of social wealth over
which they dispose. Classes are groups of persons, of which one
group is able to appropriate the labour of another, owing to a differ-
ence in their respective positions in a definite order of social econ-
omy.”*
Productive forces and production relations
Marxism was the first to disclose the laws of development of human so-
ciety. Marx showed that economics lies at the basis of social development
and that the mainspring of social development is the class struggle. The
struggle of the oppressed classes against their oppressors – this is the fun-
damental motive force of history.
We have already seen that classes differ according to the place they oc-
* Marx, Critique of Political Economy, Preface, p. 12, Charles H. Kerr & Co.,
Chicago, 1908.
13
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
At the present time we are living in such a period of social revolution.
The production relations of capitalist society have turned into chains ham-
pering the further development of productive forces. Overthrowing the
power of capital, the proletariat breaks these chains. The proletarian revolu-
tion frees the productive forces from the chains of capitalism and opens up
an unlimited scope for their development.
The scope of study of political economy
The capitalist system, resting as it does on the brutal exploitation of the
toiling masses, will not get off the stage of its own accord. Only the heroic
revolutionary struggle of the working class, relying upon its alliance with
the basic mass of peasants and toilers in the colonies, will bring about the
overthrow of capitalism and triumph of socialism the world over.
How is capitalism organized, how is the apparatus organized by means
of which a handful of capitalists enslave the working masses? It is important
to know this in order to take a conscious and active part in the great struggle
which is now going on all over the world between capitalism and socialism.
The development of capitalism leads to the victory of the proletarian
revolution, the triumph of the new, socialist system. This was established by
Marx many years ago. Marx came to this conclusion through a thorough
study of the capitalist system of production, through discovering the laws of
its development and decline.
From this it is clear what tremendous significance there is in political
economy, which, in the words of Lenin, is “the science of the developing
historical systems of social production.” This science occupies a very impor-
tant place in all the teachings of Marx and Lenin.
In his introduction to Capital, Marx says:
“….it is the ultimate aim of this work to lay bare the economic
law of motion of modern society,” i.e., capitalist society.
Marx set himself the task of discovering the law of development of capi-
talist society in order to guide the proletariat in its struggle for freedom.
“The study of the production relationships in a given, histori-
cally determined society, in their genesis, their development, and
their decay – such is the content of Marx’s economic teaching,”*
says Lenin.
The servants of the bourgeoisie try to “prove” that the capitalist system,
capitalist relations, are eternal and immutable. Their purpose is perfectly
evident. They would like to convince the workers that there can be no ques-
tion of the overthrow of capitalism. The fall of capitalism, they say, is the
17
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
struction in four years. At the present time, the U.S.S.R. is triumphantly car-
rying out the even greater task of the Second Five-Year Plan – the building
of classless socialist society.
The U.S.S.R. has laid the foundation of socialist economy during the
years of the First Five-Year Plan. Socialist large-scale industry – the funda-
mental base of socialism – has grown enormously. Dozens of new industries
have been created that had never before existed in Russia. In particular,
heavy industry, which is the backbone of the entire national economy, has
made great strides forward.
During the period of the First Five-Year Plan, the U.S.S.R. has also ac-
complished the tremendous task of reorganizing agriculture on socialist
principles. The new system of collective farms (kolkhozes), that opened the
door to a well-to-do and cultured life for the millions of peasants, has tri-
umphed in the village. The basic masses of the peasantry, the collective
farmers, have become staunch supporters of the Soviet power, and the last
bulwark of capitalism – the kulak (the rich, exploiting farmer) – has been
routed.
The working class has grown enormously. The living conditions of the
broad masses of workers have improved. The Soviet Union has been trans-
formed into a land of advanced culture. Universal education has been intro-
duced and the illiteracy of tens of millions of people has been done away
with. Millions of children and adults are studying at various schools. Tre-
mendous success has been achieved in the inculcation of socialist labour
discipline. The energy and activity, the enthusiasm of the millions of build-
ers of socialism, have grown tremendously.
“As a result of the First Five-Year Plan, the possibility of build-
ing socialism in one country was for the first time in the history of
mankind demonstrated before hundreds of millions of toilers of the
whole world.” In the Soviet Union “the worker and collective
farmer have become fully confident of the morrow, and the con-
stantly rising level of the material and cultural living standards de-
pend solely upon the quality and quantity of the labour expended by
them. Gone is the menace of unemployment, poverty and starvation
for the toiler of the U.S.S.R. Confidently and joyfully each worker
and collective farmer looks into his future, and presents constantly
rising demands for knowledge and culture.”*
At the same time, in the lands of capital the masses of toilers suffer un-
told and unprecedented privations. The army of unemployed grew with each
* J. Stalin, Report on the Work of the Central Committee of the C.P.S.U. to She
Seventeenth Congress of the C.P.S.U., p. 8, Moscow, 1934.
19
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
worlds are facing each other: the world of labour, the world of the workers’
government, the world of socialism – in the Soviet Union; the world of the
bourgeoisie, the world of profit hunting, the world of unemployment and
hunger – in all other countries. The banner of the workers of the U.S.S.R.
carries the slogan: “Those who do not work shall not eat.” On the banner of
the bourgeoisie could be written: “The worker shall not eat.” It is clear that
the conscious workers of the entire world consider the Soviet Union their
socialist fatherland.
But the capitalist system of violence and oppression will not vanish by
itself. It will perish only as a result of the struggle of the working class. Only
the revolutionary struggle of the conscious proletariat will push capitalism,
which has become unbearable to the great masses of workers, into the grave.
Capitalism or socialism? With the establishment of the Soviet Union
this question arose in its full import. Capitalism or socialism? This question
becomes more acute with the growing successes of the U.S.S.R. and the
growing disintegration of capitalism.
The road to socialism lies through the dictatorship or the proletariat
In all capitalist countries power is in the hands of the bourgeoisie.
Whatever the form of government, it invariably covers the dictatorship of
the bourgeoisie. The purpose of the bourgeois state is to safeguard capitalist
exploitation, safeguard the private ownership of the plants and factories by
the bourgeoisie, the private ownership of the land by the landlords and rich
farmers.
For socialism to triumph, the rule of the bourgeoisie must be over-
thrown, the bourgeois state must be destroyed and the dictatorship of the
proletariat must be substituted in its place. The transition from capitalism to
socialism is possible only by means of an unremitting class struggle of the
proletariat against the capitalists, by means of a proletarian revolution and
the establishment of a proletarian state. Only by establishing its own state
can the working class proceed with the building of socialism and create a
socialist society.
The Social-Democrats claim that socialism can be attained without a
revolution, without establishing the dictatorship of the proletariat, that so-
cialism can be “introduced” democratically, through parliament, that by get-
ting a majority the workers can legislate socialism. But the bourgeoisie hav-
ing in its hands all the machinery of force (the police, the army, etc.) will
never allow real representatives of labour to get to power. So far as the So-
cial-Democrats are concerned, they could get the power – and in fact they
were allowed to assume power in a number of capitalist countries – just be-
cause they have defended and defend not the interests of the proletariat but
those of the bourgeoisie. While in power they not only passed no laws “in-
troducing socialism” but did not even try in the least to improve the condi-
20
WHAT IS POLITICAL ECONOMY
tions of the workers. Quite the contrary, they supported the bourgeoisie in
attempts to lower wages, reduce unemployment doles, etc.
Despite the hypocritical assertions of the Social-Democrats, the road to
socialism does not lead through parliament nor through bourgeois democ-
racy. There is only one road from capitalism to' socialism – and that is the
one pointed out by the Communists – the road of proletarian revolution, of
the destruction of the bourgeois state machinery, of the dictatorship of the
proletariat.
“Between capitalist and communist society,” says Marx, “lies a
period of revolutionary transformation from one to the other. There
corresponds also to this a political transition period during which
the state can be nothing else than the revolutionary dictatorship of
the proletariat.” *
It was this road, the only correct, the only possible road to socialism,
that the proletariat of Russia took in 1917.
In the Soviet Union the working class won political power for itself. The
October Revolution established the rule of the proletariat, the dictatorship of
the working class. The working class strives to capture state power not
merely for power’s sake. State power in the hands of the proletariat is a
means for building the new, socialist society.
“Its purpose is to create socialism, to do away with the division
of society into classes, to make all members of society workers, to
take away the basis for the exploitation of man by man. This pur-
pose cannot be realized at once, it requires a fairly long transition
period from capitalism to socialism, because the reorganization of
production is a difficult matter, because time is required for all the
radical changes in every field of life, and because the enormous
force of petty-bourgeois and bourgeois habits in economic man-
agement can be overcome only by a long, persistent struggle. That
is why Marx speaks of the entire period of the dictatorship of the
proletariat as the period of transition from capitalism to socialism.Ӡ
The transformation from capitalism to socialism cannot be accom-
plished at once. A fairly long transition period is unavoidable. During this
period state power is in the hands, of the working; class, which is building
socialism.
25
CHAPTER II
How Did Society Develop to Capitalism?
Our goal – a classless socialist society
The Russian revolution of October (November) 1917 opened up a new
chapter in the history of mankind. It set as its aim the building of socialism.
Under socialism, the exploitation of man by man is done away The task of
the second five-year period, upon which the U.S.S.R. entered in 1933, is the
building of a classless, socialist society.
In his speech to the congress of collective farm shock brigade workers
in February 1933, Comrade Stalin said:
“The history of nations knows not a few revolutions. But these
revolutions differ from the October Revolution in that they were
one-sided revolutions. One form of exploitation of the toilers made
way for another form of exploitation, but exploitation, as such,
remained. Certain exploiters and oppressors made way for other
exploiters and oppressors, but exploitation and oppression, as such,
remained. The October Revolution alone set itself the aim – of
abolishing all exploitation and of liquidating all exploiters and
oppressors.”*
In order to understand thoroughly the full significance of the struggle for
a classless, socialist society, it is necessary to know the essence of class so-
ciety. It is necessary to remember of what classes society is constituted un-
der capitalism. One must keep in mind what classes are and clarify the ques-
tion as to whether classes have always existed. One must understand in just
what way capitalist society differs from all other forms of class rule. Finally,
one must thoroughly master the questions as to what course the struggle of
the working class must follow in order to destroy capitalist slavery, and as to
what the laws of development and decay of the capitalist system are.
Have there always been classes?
The menials of capitalism do their utmost to prove that the division of
society into classes is inevitable. It is important to the defenders of the mon-
eybags to depict things as if the existence of exploiters and exploited were
an eternal and necessary condition of the existence of any society. As far
back as in ancient Rome, when the exploited rebelled against their masters, a
certain defender of the ruling class told a fable in which he compared society
with the organism of an individual; just as in the individual, presumably,
27
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
with tremendous difficulty. Generation followed generation and social con-
ditions did not change noticeably. Very slowly indeed man learned to perfect
his tools and his methods of work.
What were the social relations under primitive communism? The primi-
tive community or clan was usually small in numbers: with the technical
development existing at the time a large clan could not hope to feed all its
members. Labour in such a community was organized more or less accord-
ing to a plan. All members of the community had definite occupations. The
men, for instance, hunted. The women stayed at home with the children and
also had to till the soil. Upon returning from the hunt the game was divided
according to established, time-honoured custom.
“The population was very small in numbers. It was collected
only on the territory of the tribe. Next to this territory was the hunt-
ing ground surrounding it in a wide circle. A neutral forest formed
the line of demarcation from other tribes. The division of labour
was quite primitive. The work was simply divided between the two
sexes. The men went to war, hunted, fished, provided the raw mate-
rial for food and the tools necessary for these pursuits. The women
cared for the house, and prepared food and clothing; they cooked,
wove and sewed. Each sex was master of its own field of activity:
the men in the forest, the women in the house. Each sex also owned
the tools made and used by it; the men were the owners of the
weapons, of the hunting and fishing tackle, the women of the
household goods and utensils. The household was communistic,
comprising several, and often many, families.* Whatever was pro-
duced and used collectively, was regarded as common property: the
house, the garden, the long boat.Ӡ
Under conditions of primitive communism there could be no place for
social groups living on unearned income. There was no exploitation of one
part of the community by another in the framework of primitive commu-
nism. At that stage of human development, the instruments of labour were
very simple, so that there could be no question of private property in tools:
everyone was able, without much labour, to prepare for himself a spear, a
stone, a bow and arrow, etc. At the same time there was no private property
29
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
of specialists to rule. History shows that the state is a special appa-
ratus for the coercion of people, coming into being only where and
when there has been a division of society into classes – that is, a di-
vision into such groups of people of which one can constantly ap-
propriate the labour of others, where one exploits the other.”*
We thus see that the division of society into a class of exploiters and a
class of exploited is not at all an eternal and inevitable feature of each and
every social system. On the contrary, we see that society existed for a very
long period of time without knowing anything of classes, or exploitation, or
private property.
The decay of primitive society
In primitive times man proceeded very slowly upon the road of devel-
opment, but nevertheless there was progress. Human society never remained
in a totally static condition. Tools slowly but surely were perfected. People
learned to use the previously incomprehensible forces of nature. The discov-
ery of fire played a tremendous role. Then the savages learned to make a
bow and arrow for hunting purposes. Having begun with a stick and a stone,
man gradually learned to make the stick into a spear and to grind the stone
so as to make it better adapted for hunting purposes. A new stage was
reached when the art of pottery making was achieved, when man learned to
make vessels from clay. The taming of the first domestic cattle and the culti-
vation of grain played a tremendous part. Thus cattle-raising and agriculture
began. With the discovery of how to smelt iron from the ore, and the inven-
tion of writing, the primitive period ends and the era of civilization begins.
In the Manifesto of the Communist Party, Marx and Engels have written that
beginning with this point the entire history of human society is the history of
class struggles.
How did classes originate? The appearance of classes is most closely
connected with the entire process of social development. The domestication
of cattle leads to the separation of cattle-raising tribes from the remaining
masses of the clan groups in primitive society. This is the first great social
division of labour. From this point on different communities have different
products. The cattle-herding tribes have the products of cattle-raising:
animals, wool, meat, hides, etc. A basis is established for the exchange of
products among the tribes. At first the exchange is conducted by the elders
of the clan communities; cattle is the main article of barter. Barter at first
takes place at points where various tribes meet; barter takes place, at first,
between different communities and not between separate members of the
communities.
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XXIV, “On the State,” pp. 365-66, Russian ed.
30
HOW DID SOCIETY DEVELOP TO CAPITALISM?
At the same time, with the growth of the population, the old methods of
work prove inadequate. The ever increasing number of people cannot feed
themselves by means of these methods. There is a beginning of plant cultiva-
tion – the first steps in agriculture. Tilling of the soil, under those circum-
stances, inevitably brings about a much closer connection of some families
with their part of the cultivated land. Thus the basis for private property is
laid.
“The increase of production in all branches – stock raising, ag-
riculture, domestic handicrafts – enabled human labour power to
produce more than was necessary for its maintenance. It increased
at the same time the amount of daily work that fell to the lot of
every member of a gens, a household or a single family. The addi-
tion of more labour power became desirable. It was furnished by
war; the captured enemies were transformed into slaves. Under the
given historical conditions, the first great social division of social
labour, by increasing the productivity of labour, adding to wealth,
and enlarging the field of productive activity, necessarily carried
slavery in its wake. Out of the first great division of social labour
arose the first great division of society into two classes – masters
and slaves, exploiters and exploited.”*
To the extent that man masters new forms and methods of labour, a fur-
ther development of the division of labour takes place. People learn to make
utensils, all kinds of tools, various kinds of weapons, etc. This gradually
brings about the separation of artisanship from agriculture. All this greatly
widens the basis for the development of exchange.
The dissolution of primitive communism leads to the transfer of cattle
from communal to private ownership. Land and tools also become private
property. With the inception of private ownership the basis is laid for the rise
and growth of inequality.
“The distinction between rich and poor was added to that be-
tween free men and slaves. This and the new division of labour con-
stitute a new division of society into classes.Ӡ
Pre-capitalist forms of exploitation
With the decay of primitive communism the division into exploiters and
exploited arises in society. People appear who live upon the labour of others.
The exploitation of one class by another – that is what characterizes the dif-
ferent stages of development of class society. The forms of exploitation,
* Ibid., p. 214.
32
HOW DID SOCIETY DEVELOP TO CAPITALISM?
every slave-owner made his slaves produce only the things needed within his
own estate. The life of the ruling classes under slavery was characterized by
an insensate luxury and waste. But however great the luxury, there were lim-
its to slave labour, as beyond a certain definite amount excess products could
not be utilized. Under slavery the growth of wealth is circumscribed within
comparatively narrow limits. This is what caused the dearth of technical de-
velopment under the system of slavery.
Together with class dominance the state comes into being as an appara-
tus of coercion, compelling the majority of society to work for the exploiting
minority. In the slave-owning society of old the state was confined in a nar-
rower frame than it is at the present time. Means of communication were
still little developed, mountains and seas presented obstacles which were
difficult to surmount. Various forms of the state – the monarchy, the repub-
lic, etc. – were already present under slavery. Nevertheless, whatever the
form of the state was, it still remained an organ of the dominance of the
slave-owners. Slaves in general were not regarded as members of society.
Slave-owning society, particularly in ancient Greece and ancient Rome,
reached a high level of scientific and artistic development. However, it was a
culture erected on the bones of countless masses of slaves.
During periods of frequent wars the number of people who were made
slaves often grew tremendously. The lives of the slaves were extremely
cheap and the exploiters made their conditions of life altogether intolerable.
The history of slavery is one of bloody struggle between the exploiters and
the exploited. Uprisings of slaves against their masters were suppressed with
merciless cruelty.
Slave revolts shook slave-owning society to its very foundations, particu-
larly in the last period of its existence. Having conquered a series of countries
in the most remote corners of the world as it was then known to the Romans,
the Roman Empire had attained to enormous power, when it began to totter
more and more under the stress of the contradictions that were rending the
whole fabric of the society of that time. Especially famous is the slave rebel-
lion which broke out in Rome about two thousand years ago under the leader-
ship of Spartacus, who mobilized a huge army against the regime of the slave-
owners. The revolts of the slaves could not bring victory to the exploited,
could not put an end to exploitation in general. The slaves were not in a posi-
tion to set themselves a clearly perceived goal. They could not create a strong
organization to lead their struggle. Frequently the slaves were mere pawns in
the hands of the various factions of the ruling class who were fighting among
themselves. Nevertheless, the civil war and the slaves’ revolts dealt a severe
blow to the slave-owning order of society and prepared the soil for its destruc-
tion. However, in place of slavery a new form of the exploitation of man by
man appeared. This form, which prevailed during the Middle Ages, was feu-
dalism, the last stage of whose development was serfdom. Feudalism under-
33
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
went a comparatively long process of development. Under feudalism the tre-
mendous mass of the peasantry was exploited by a small group of feudal bar-
ons. The barons took into their own hands the supreme power over the land
worked by the peasants. For the right of working the land, the peasants had to
submit to a host of feudal services for their lords.
So long as natural economy prevailed, i.e., production for direct use and
not for exchange, feudal exploitation was circumscribed by comparatively
narrow limits. The feudal lords took a certain amount of the agricultural
products from the peasants for their own use. The greater part of these prod-
ucts were used up by the lord and his armed guard, and only a small portion
went in exchange for arms, some overseas goods, etc. The development of
exchange, however, led to a gradual increase in the appetites of the feudal
lords. Now they not only squeezed from the peasant the tribute that went for
the use of the lord and his menials, but the amount of tribute exacted for
purposes of exchange for other goods continually grew. As the exchange of
goods developed, the possibilities for increased exploitation of the peasantry
by the feudal lord became greater. The growth of exchange destroyed the old
patriarchal relations between the feudal lord and the peasants dependent
upon him and led to the rise of serfdom.
Serfdom represents a form of the severest kind of exploitation of the
peasantry by the landlords. Under serfdom the basic means of production –
the land – is in the hands of the landlords. The landlords appropriate the land
which has been tilled by a number of generations of peasants. But they are
not content with this. Taking advantage of the powers of the state which is
also in the hands of the landlords, they turn the previously free peasants into
their serfs. The peasants are attached to the land and become practically the
property of the landlord.
Trying in every way to augment their income, the landlords increase the
exploitation of their serfs. Exchange is already fairly well developed at the
time of serfdom. Overseas trade takes on considerable proportions. Mer-
chants furnish the serf-owning landlords with all kinds of overseas goods.
Money becomes more and more important. In order to get more money the
serf-owner squeezes more and more labour out of his peasants. He takes
away land from the peasants, limits their allotments, and, in place of these,
sets up his own fields upon which he makes these same peasants work.
Corvée service is introduced: the peasant must work the lord’s field for three
to four days a week and can work his own allotment only on the other days.
In other cases the serf-owning landlords appropriate ever increasing parts of
the harvest from the peasants’ fields by the system of making the peasants
pay quit-rent.
The exploitation of the serfs evoked the bitterest struggles of the peas-
ants against their landlords. The history of every country shows a great
number of peasant rebellions. There were peasant uprisings in many coun-
34
HOW DID SOCIETY DEVELOP TO CAPITALISM?
tries during the period of serfdom (in Germany, France, England, Russia).
Some of these uprisings lasted for decades. For tens of years these countries
were in the throes of civil war. The uprisings were suppressed mercilessly by
the landlords and their governments. This struggle of the peasants against
the landlords was utilized by the rising bourgeoisie in order to hasten the fall
of serfdom and to substitute capitalist exploitation for serf exploitation.
Here is what Stalin says about the substitution of one social form for
another:
“'The revolution of the slaves liquidated slavery and abolished
the slave form of exploitation of the toilers. In its place it introduced
the feudal rulers and the serf form of exploitation of the toilers. One
set of exploiters took the place of another set of exploiters. Under
slavery the ‘law’ permitted the slave-owner to kill his slaves. Under
the serf system the ‘law’ permitted the serf-owner ‘only’ to sell his
serfs.
“The revolution of the serf peasants liquidated the serf-owners
and abolished the serf form of exploitation. But in place of these it
introduced the capitalists and landlords, the capitalist and landlord
form of exploitation of the toilers. One set of exploiters took the
place of another set of exploiters. Under the serf system the ‘law’
permitted the sale of serfs. Under the capitalist system the ‘law’
permits the toilers ‘only’ to be doomed to unemployment and pov-
erty, to ruin and death from starvation.
“It was only our Soviet revolution, only our October Revolution
that put the question, not of substituting one set of exploiters for an-
other, not of substituting one form of exploitation for another – but
of eradicating all exploitation, of eradicating all and every kind of
exploitation, all and every kind of rich man and oppressor, old and
new.”*
The rise and development of exchange
We have already seen that exchange originated in the very ancient times
of human history. Together with the first steps in the division of labour in
society, the foundation was laid for the rise of exchange. At first exchange
took place only between neighbouring communes; each exchanged its excess
products for those of the other. However, having originated at the border
between communes, exchange soon exerted a destructive influence upon
relations within the commune. Money appeared. At first those products
which were the principal objects of exchange served as money. Thus in
36
HOW DID SOCIETY DEVELOP TO CAPITALISM?
article was much better or very much cheaper.”*
Thus natural production prevails not only under slavery and in the Mid-
dle Ages, but also under new conditions. Commodity production is by no
means prevalent at the inception of capitalism. Only the development of
capitalism strikes a mortal blow at natural production. Only under capitalism
does commodity production, production for sale, become the decisive, the
predominant form of production.
Within pre-capitalist society, commodity production develops to an ever
greater extent together with an increase in the division of labour. Of particu-
lar significance is the separation of handicraftsmanship from agriculture.
Whereas the peasant agriculturist conducts his husbandry mainly as natural
production, the same cannot be said of the artisan. Handicraftsmanship is,
from the very beginning, clearly of a commodity-producing character. The
artisan producing a pair of boots or a set of harness, a plough or horseshoes,
clay or wooden vessels, works from the very start for the market, for sale.
But unlike commodity production under capitalism, the artisan works with
instruments of labour which are his own. As a rule he applies only his own
labour power. Only later, with the development of cities, does the artisan
begin to hire apprentices and journeymen. Finally, the artisan usually works
upon local raw material and sells his commodities in the local market. When
things are produced for sale on the market but without wage labour we have
simple commodity production as distinguished from capitalist commodity
production.
“Previous to capitalist production,” says Engels, “that is to say,
in the Middle Ages, small-scale production was general, on the ba-
sis of the private ownership by the workers of their means of pro-
duction: the agricultural industry of the small peasant, freeman or
serf, and the handicraft industry of -the towns. The instruments of
labour – land, agricultural implements, the workshop and tools –
were the instruments of labour of individuals, intended only for in-
dividual use, and therefore necessarily puny, dwarfish, restricted.Ӡ
Wherein lies the difference between simple commodity production arid
capitalism? The artisan, handicraftsman, small-scale farmer own their tools,
raw material and means of production. They work by themselves, producing
their goods with the aid of these means of production. Under capitalism it is
different. There the plants and factories belong to the capitalists and in them
work hired labourers who do not have their own means of production. Sim-
ple commodity production always precedes capitalism. The capitalist system
38
HOW DID SOCIETY DEVELOP TO CAPITALISM?
ety unflaggingly undermined and broke down the foundations of this society.
With the growth of commerce the exploitation of the serfs by the landlords
grew continually stronger. The excessive exploitation undermined the foun-
dations of serfdom – peasant economy. It was impoverished, the peasants
became paupers leading a hungry existence, incapable of giving a large in-
come to the landlord. At the same time usurer capital grasped the feudal es-
tate in its tentacles, squeezing the life out of it. The decay of serfdom pre-
pared the way for the rise of capitalist production.
Commercial capital at first engaged only in trade. Commerce was car-
ried on with the products furnished by artisans and serfs as well as with
products imported from distant countries. With the growth of commerce,
however, these sources of products become inadequate. Small-scale handi-
craft production could supply only a limited mass of commodities, sufficient
merely for the local market. When commerce began to operate in more dis-
tant markets the necessity arose for extending production.
But only capital could secure such an extension of production. Small-
scale commodity production was powerless here; its possibilities were nar-
rowly circumscribed. A transition then took place from small-scale to capi-
talist production, which destroyed the pre-capitalist forms of exploitation
only to substitute for them the last form of exploitation of man by man –
capitalist exploitation.
Here is how Lenin describes this transition from small-scale production
to capitalism:
“Under the old conditions almost all the wealth was produced
by small-scale husbandmen who constituted the overwhelming ma-
jority of the population. The population lived settled down in the
villages, producing the greater part of their products either for im-
mediate use or for the small markets of local settlements, scarcely
connected with neighbouring markets.
“These same petty husbandmen worked for the landlords, who
made them produce only the things needed for their own immediate
use. Domestic products were given to the artisans to be worked on,
and these also lived in the villages or journeyed in the neighbour-
hood to take on work.
“But with the liberation of the serfs these conditions of life of
the mass of the people underwent a complete change: instead of
small-scale artisans’ shops, large factories began to appear, which
grew very rapidly, pushing out the small-scale handicraftsmen, turn-
ing them into wage labourers and compelling thousands of work-
men to work together, producing tremendous quantities of com-
modities which were sold all over Russia.
“Small-scale production is replaced by large-scale production
39
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
everywhere and the masses of workmen are already simply hired
men working for wages for a capitalist who owns tremendous capi-
tal, builds tremendous workshops, purchases masses of materials
and pockets all the profits of this mass production of the united
workmen. Production has become capitalist and it presses relent-
lessly and mercilessly upon the small husbandmen, destroying their
settled life in the village, compelling them to wander over the coun-
try from end to end as simple labourers, selling their labour to capi-
tal. Ever greater and greater portions of the population are torn
away from the villages and from agriculture to collect in the cities,
factory and industrial towns and settlements, forming a distinct
class of people having nothing of their own, a class of wage labour-
ers, proletarians living only by the sale of their labour power.”*
REVIEW QUESTIONS
1. How did people live before the appearance of class society?
2. How did classes originate?
3. What are the basic historical forms of class exploitation?
4. What are the relations between the exploiters and the exploited under the
system of slavery?
5. What are the relations between the exploiters and the exploited under the
system of serfdom?
6. What is the distinguishing feature of capitalist exploitation?
7. How does exchange arise and develop?
8. Why does small-scale commodity production give rise to capitalism?
44
COMMODITY PRODUCTION
peasant sells his products and makes his purchases. Here also the
peasant knows not only the conditions under which the artisan
works but the latter knows also the conditions of peasant labour. For
he is himself still a peasant to a certain extent, he not only has a
kitchen garden and an orchard, but frequently also a strip of arable
land, one or two cows, pigs, poultry, etc.” *
A number of self-evident facts confirm the truth that commodities are
exchanged according to the labour incorporated in them. Very many com-
modities which were once very dear become fairly cheap, because with
modern technical development less labour is required to produce them.
Thus, for instance, aluminium, from which kitchenware and a number of
other things are now manufactured, was a few decades ago eight or ten times
as expensive as silver. It cost about $225 a kilogram then. But with the de-
velopment of electro-technical science it became possible to produce alu-
minium with much less labour so that before the war the price fell almost to
27 cents a kilogram, a thousand times cheaper. It became so cheap only be-
cause so much less labour is now required to produce it.
Thus the value of a commodity depends upon the amount of labour
spent in producing it. If we produce a greater quantity of commodities with
the same amount of labour, we speak of the increased productivity of labour;
on the other hand, when less is produced, we speak of a decrease in produc-
tivity. It is self-evident that increased labour productivity means a decrease
in the amount of labour that must be spent in order to produce a single one
of the given commodities. As a result there will be a decrease in the value,
each commodity of this particular kind will be cheaper. A decrease in pro-
ductivity would, on the contrary, bring about dearer commodities. It is there-
fore said that productivity of labour and the value of each unit of the com-
modities produced are in inverse proportion (i.e., when one rises the other
falls, and vice versa). That is why Marx says,
“The value of a commodity... varies... inversely as the produc-
tiveness of the labour incorporated in it.Ӡ
The value of a commodity is given to it by the labour spent in producing
it. The value of a commodity is nothing but a definite quantity of labour time
congealed (or incorporated) in the commodity. But value only manifests it-
self when one commodity is compared with another. Let us assume that the
same amount of labour is incorporated in one ton of iron as in one kilogram
of silver. Then a ton of iron will be equal in value to a kilogram of silver.
The value of a commodity expressed in comparison with the value of an-
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. II, “Articles on the Question of the Theory of
Markets,” p. 407, Russian ed.
50
COMMODITY PRODUCTION
The law of value appears as a blind force of the market. Every individ-
ual producer must submit to this blind force. As Marx expresses it, this force
acts like the falling of a house. This means that the individual producer can
never know beforehand what the all-powerful market will require of him.
The law of values acts behind the back of the individual producer. Commod-
ity production is characterized, as we have seen, by anarchy, i.e., by the ab-
sence of any order, any conscious plan for society as a whole. The law of
values acts as an impersonal, unconscious power in a society where anarchy
of production prevails.
The development of exchange and the forms of value
From the preceding chapters we already know that commodity produc-
tion did not come into existence at once in its developed form. On the con-
trary, exchange only gradually undermines and destroys the previous natural
economy. The change from natural economy to commodity economy is pro-
longed over many centuries.
Under developed commodity economy one commodity is not exchanged
directly for another. Commodities are bought and sold, they are converted
into money. The form in which their value is manifested is money. However,
in order to understand the monetary form of value, we must acquaint our-
selves with the less developed forms, corresponding to the earlier stages of
development of commodity production and exchange.
When production still has a primarily natural character, and the ex-
change is effected by chance, we have the elementary, single, or accidental
form of value. One commodity is exchanged for another: the skin of an ani-
mal, let us say, is exchanged for two spears. Those distinguishing features,
which become prominent when exchange and commodity production have
reached their utmost development and expansion, are already contained in
embryo in this still completely undeveloped form of value.
In the given instance, the simple form of value serves as an expression
of the value of the skin, receives its expression in the form of two spears. We
see that the value of the skin is not expressed directly, but only relatively, in
relation to the value of two spears. Two spears serve here as the equivalent
of one skin. The value of the skin is expressed by means of the use value of
two spears.
Thus we see here that the use value of one commodity (two spears)
serves as an expression of the value of another commodity (a skin). The
value and the use value are divided as it were, the value is separated from the
use value. Here the skin figures only as the value, the two spears only as the
use value. The value of the skin becomes, so to speak, separated from its use
value and is equated to another commodity. From this the conclusion can be
drawn that the value of a commodity cannot be expressed in terms of itself
alone, to express this value there must be the bodily form of another com-
51
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
modity, an equivalent.
Even in the simple form of value the distinguishing feature of the com-
modity equivalent is that the use value of this commodity serves as the ex-
pression of its opposite – value.
“The body of the commodity that serves as the equivalent figures as the
materialization of human labour in the abstract and is at the same time the
product of some specifically useful concrete labour.”*
Accordingly concrete labour serves here as the expression of abstract
labour, individual labour – as the expression of social labour.
The simple form of value exists only so long as exchange bears an abso-
lutely single, accidental character. As soon as exchange is somewhat more
widely developed, this form of value changes into the total or expanded
form of value in which not two commodities, but a much wider circle of
commodities, are equated to each other. In this form each commodity can be
exchanged not only for another commodity, but for a whole series of com-
modities. For example, the skin can be exchanged not only for two spears,
but for a pair of shoes, for an oar, for a piece of cloth, or for a sack of corn.
The total or expanded form of value will, therefore, appear as follows:
{
2 spears
1 pair of shoes
1 skin = 1 oar
1 piece of cloth
1 sack of corn, etc.
We have this form of value when some product of labour, cattle for in-
stance, is habitually exchanged for various other commodities, not as an ex-
ception but as a general rule.
The expanded form of value is a further stage in the development of the
form of value. The value of one commodity is expressed in different com-
modities, belonging to different owners of commodities. The division be-
tween value and use value is here made still more evident. The value of the
skin is here opposed to its use value as something common to a series of
other commodities.
However, even the expanded form of value does not satisfy the demand,
which grows with the development of exchange.
The development of exchange makes the shortcomings of this system of
exchange more and more manifest. These shortcomings are done away with
by the next, more developed form of value, namely, the general form. The
general form of value naturally grows out of the total, or expanded form. In
the expanded form of value one commodity is most frequently exchanged, and
}
1 boat
3 pairs of shoes
= 1 ox
3 sacks of corn
2 0 arrows, etc.
In the universal equivalent form of value, the value of all commodities
finds expression in one and the same commodity. The commodity which
expresses the value of the other commodities serves as the universal equiva-
lent. This commodity is readily taken in exchange for any other commodity.
Thus the inconvenience which accompanies the total or expanded form of
value is eliminated. Here the separation of value from use value becomes
still greater. All commodities express their value in a single commodity. It
becomes the function of one commodity to express the value of all other
commodities. The entire world of commodities is split into two opposite
groups: the universal equivalent by itself makes one group, and the other
group consists of all the other commodities.
The money form of value differs only slightly from the universal form.
When the precious metals – gold and silver – definitely become the fixed
universal equivalent, we have the transition from the universal form of value
to the money form. In the money form the particular social function, i.e., the
expression of the value of all commodities, is embodied in one particular
commodity. This commodity, gold or silver, is pre-eminent in the commod-
ity world. Before it becomes money, gold must first be a commodity. But,
having become money, gold acquires a number of new properties in connec-
tion with its role as money.
Value is a specific social relation between persons which is expressed as a
relation between things. The value of a commodity cannot be expressed in
terms of itself. It can only be expressed with the help of another commodity.
The exchange relation between one commodity and another, or its exchange
value, serves as the expression of its value. We have seen the development of
the form of value from the simple to the money form. The development of the
form of value is linked with the development of the contradictions which are
inherent in commodities. The contradictions between use value and value
emerge more and more clearly in the process of the development of exchange
and the corresponding forms of value. In money this contradiction is ex-
pressed most fully. Money becomes the one and universal means of the ex-
pression of value. All other commodities counterbalance money as use values.
53
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Commodity fetishism
Under planned socialist production it is clear to every worker that he is
part of an organized body. Under socialism the production relations between
people become clear and obvious. The connection between each individual
worker and enterprise and all other workers and enterprises is self-evident
and clearly understood.
It is not so in a society where commodity production prevails. With
commodity production the production relations between people appear as
relations between things. When a cobbler sells a pair of boots he has made
and with the money thus obtained buys bread at the baker’s for himself and
his family, we have a definite production relation, a definite connection be-
tween people according to production. The bread baked by the baker serves
the needs of the cobbler, and the boots made by the cobbler will perhaps go
to the baker. It follows, therefore, that the work of the baker is needed to
satisfy the needs of the cobbler; the work of the cobbler is needed to satisfy
the needs of the baker. Thus there is a definite connection between the cob-
bler and the baker, a definite relation according to production. But how is
this connection revealed? In what is it expressed? We have already seen. It
reveals itself in the process of exchange. Commodities are objects that
change hands from one producer to another. Bread goes from the baker to
the cobbler. Boots go from the cobbler to the merchant and from the mer-
chant to the same baker. However, commodities do not simply change
hands. Everyone knows that the cobbler gives up the boots he has made only
after he has received a corresponding amount of money for them – their
price. The baker acts in exactly the same way. Thus, under the system of
commodity production, production relations among people are revealed as
the movement of things – commodities.
Value is the relation between persons who produce commodities. But
this relation presents itself as a relation between things – commodities. This
production relation is concealed by a material cover, hidden behind the
movement of things. The value of a commodity seems just as natural a prop-
erty of the commodity as, say, its colour or weight; it is said, for instance:
this bread weighs half a pound and is worth five cents. A commodity be-
comes a very puzzling thing. The fate of the producer is closely tied up with
that of his product. If our cobbler cannot sell the boots he will stay without
bread. If the price of boots falls – he can buy so much less bread. Why can-
not the cobbler sell the boots, or why does he get less for them this time than
he got before? The cause lies in the changes which have taken place in the
economic life, in the production relations of people in capitalist society, say
a crisis has come, or the workers are buying boots more seldom because of a
reduction in wages. The real cause will, however, long remain unknown to
the cobbler and when he does find it out it will generally be in a distorted
way. For the connection between the cobbler and the rest of the producing
54
COMMODITY PRODUCTION
world is centred in his commodity – boots, in their value which is realized
on the market.
The fact that under commodity production the relations between persons
according to production acquire the appearance of relations between things –
commodities – and that commodities, hence, acquire peculiar social proper-
ties, we call commodity fetishism (fetishism generally is the worship of
imaginary, supernatural properties ascribed to an object – a fetish). Under
capitalism all production relations between persons in society are hidden
under a cover of things. All production relations between persons under
capitalism appear as relations between things, as relations connected with
things. This masks the real meaning of capitalist relations, veils them, hides
their real character, gives them an illusory appearance. That is why it is very
important to unmask, to understand, the puzzle of commodity fetishism that
permeates all relations under capitalism.
Marx was the first to solve the riddle of commodity fetishism. Marx was
the first to reveal the social relations between persons, where up to his time
only the mysterious properties of things had been seen. He was the first to
show that value is a social relation between people in the commodity pro-
duction system.
“Political economy begins with commodities, begins with the moment
when products are exchanged for one another – whether by individuals or by
primitive communities. The product that appears in exchange is a commod-
ity. It is, however, a commodity solely because a relation between two per-
sons or communities attaches to the thing, the product, the relation between
producer and consumer who are here no longer united in the same person.
Here we have an example of a peculiar fact, which runs through the whole of
economics and which has caused utter confusion in the minds of the bour-
geois economists: economics deals not with things but with relations be-
tween persons and in the last resort between classes; these relations are,
however, always attached to things and appear as things. This inter-
connection, which in isolated cases it is true has dawned upon particular
economists, was first discovered by Marx as obtaining for all political econ-
omy, whereby he made the most difficult questions so simple and clear that
now even the bourgeois economists will be able to grasp them.”*
The role of money in the system of commodity production
Nowadays it seldom happens that one commodity is directly exchanged
for another. The producer usually sells the commodities he produces for
money, and for the money realized buys the commodities he needs. Why
then do we speak of the exchange of commodities? The fact is that money
here really acts as an intermediary in the exchange of commodities. The
56
COMMODITY PRODUCTION
whom the market brings together.”*
Money plays an important part in the transition from small-scale com-
modity production to capitalism. The bosses who have grown rich, acquiring
their wealth by hook or by crook, amass it in the form of money. Capital first
originates in the form of money.
The functions of money
Money has a number of functions in commodity economy. Every com-
modity is sold for a definite sum of money. This sum of money is called the
price of the commodity. Thus, price is value expressed in terms of money.
The value of a commodity is measured by money. The measurement of the
value of a commodity in money is the premise of the exchange of the com-
modity, its purchase or sale. Before a commodity can be bought or sold, it is
essential to know its price. Thus money plays the role of a measure of value.
The value of a commodity is determined by the working time spent on
its production. However, value cannot be expressed by the socially neces-
sary working time. In buying or selling a pair of boots, for example, it is not
said that the boots cost twenty hours of labour but that they cost, let us say,
$10. We have explained this previously. The value of a commodity x can be
expressed only through the medium of another commodity. It is not known
beforehand whether the time spent on the production of the boots will actu-
ally be taken into account. Perhaps, if the market is flooded, the boots will
be sold not for $10, but only for $5. This would mean that the twenty work-
ing hours actually spent on the production of the boots would have to be
exchanged for a product of only ten working hours. The price of a commod-
ity is constantly fluctuating round its value, these fluctuations manifesting
themselves in the fact that the cost of a commodity may be first above, then
below the value, or vice versa.
To be a measure of value, money itself must be a commodity and pos-
sess value. One cannot, for example, measure weight by means of an object
which has no weight. But must money actually be present when the value is,
measured? Obviously not. We can evaluate an enormous number of com-
modities without having a cent in our pockets. Money fulfils its function as a
measure of value theoretically, as ideal money. From this it is clear that the
question of the amount of money also plays no part in this function.
The decisive moment for a commodity comes after it is priced in money.
It must be sold, i.e., exchanged for money. An exchange of goods accom-
plished by means of money is called the circulation of commodities. It is
clear that the circulation of commodities is inseparably linked up with the
circulation of money itself. When a commodity goes out of the hands of the
60
COMMODITY PRODUCTION
in capitalist commodity production are to be found in embryo in commodi-
ties, in their value, in the exchange of commodities.
“Marx, in his Capital, at first analyses the simplest, the most
ordinary, fundamental and commonplace thing, a relation that has a
mass appearance and is to be observed billions of times in bourgeois
(commodity) society: the exchange of commodities. In that simple
phenomenon (in that ‘cell’ of bourgeois society) the analysis reveals
all the contradictions (respectively the embryos of all contradic-
tions) of modern society. The subsequent exposition shows the de-
velopment (both growth and movement) of these contradictions and
of this society in the Σ* of its parts, from beginning to end.” †
The law of value is the law of motion of capitalist commodity produc-
tion. This motion appears in the form of a further development of the con-
tradictions, the germs of which are inherent in value. These contradictions
are manifested most sharply during crises. Anarchy of production, character-
istic of the capitalist commodity producing system, appears in its most naked
form during crises. The contemporary capitalist crisis bears the most elo-
quent evidence of this. During a crisis, the contradictions between the pro-
ductive forces and the production relations, contradictions which draw capi-
talism towards its inevitable doom, stand out sharply.
With the historical development of commodity production and its trans-
formation into capitalist production, as capitalism develops further, the con-
tradictions inherent in commodities and value grow and become more com-
plex. The growth of the contradictions inherent in commodities reflects a
gigantic historical stride of capitalist development.
“Marx traced the development of capitalism from the first
germs of commodity economy and simple exchange, to its highest
forms, to large-scale production.”‡
Showing how Marx traces this great historical process of development,
embracing many centuries, Lenin also shows how the contradictions origi-
nate, the germs of which already exist in commodities:
“Where the bourgeois economists saw a relation of things (the
exchange of one commodity for another) Marx revealed a relation
between men. The exchange of commodities expresses the connec-
tion between individual producers by means of the market. Money
signifies that this connection is becoming closer and closer, insepa-
*Lenin, Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism, Chap. IV, p. 59, Moscow,
1934.
63
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
duction are based upon the laws of commodity production and primarily
upon the law of value.
“Capitalist production is marked from the outset by two pecu-
liar traits,” says Marx. “1) It produces its products as commodities.
The fact that it produces commodities does not distinguish it from
other modes of production. Its peculiar mark is that the prevailing
and determining character of its products is that of being commodi-
ties. This implies, in the first place, that the labourer himself acts in
the role of a seller of commodities, as a free wage worker, so that
wage labour is the typical character of labour....
“2) The other specific mark of the capitalist mode of production
is the production of surplus value as the direct aim and determining
incentive of production. Capital produces essentially capital, and
does so only to the extent that it produces surplus value.”*
The framework of commodity production expands under capitalism. A
new commodity appears, which did not exist under the system of simple
commodity production – labour power. What sort of commodity is this?
Marx answers this question as follows:
“By labour power or capacity for labour is to be understood the
aggregate of those mental and physical capabilities existing in a
human being, which he exercises whenever he produces use value
of any description.Ӡ
In other words, labour power is man’s capacity for labour, his capacity
for productive activity.
Marx says:
“The capitalist buys labour power in order to use it; and labour
power in use is labour itself.”‡
Under capitalism labour power becomes a commodity. But is labour
power always a commodity? By far not always, of course. Take the petty
producer. He works on his own strip of land or in his own workshop himself.
He sells his produce, but he does not sell his labour power. He uses his la-
bour power himself. It is clear that he can do this only so long as he pos-
sesses his own strip of land or workshop. Take away his tools or bench from
the artisan, take away the strip of land from the petty farmer – and they can
no longer apply their labour power in their own undertaking.
* Marx, Capital, Vol. III, pp. 1025-26, Charles H. Kerr & Co., 1909.
† Ibid., Vol. I, p. 145
‡ Ibid.
64
THE ESSENCE OF CAPITALIST EXPLOITATION
What then remains for them to do? In order not to starve they are com-
pelled to apply for work to the capitalist who owns the factory, the land, the
plant or the railroad. But what does hiring out to a capitalist mean? It means
– selling one’s labour power.
We thus see that definite conditions or prerequisites are necessary for
the rise of capitalism. It is necessary, for some members of society to have in
their hands all the means of production (or sufficient money for the purchase
of these means) and on the other hand, it is necessary that there should be a
class of people who are forced to sell their labour power.
“The historical prerequisites to the genesis of capital are: first,
accumulation of a considerable sum of money in the hands of indi-
viduals under conditions of a comparatively high development of
commodity production in general, and second, the existence of
workers who are ‘free’ in a double sense of the term: free from any
constraint or restriction as regards the sale of their labour power;
free from the land or from the means of production in general, i.e.,
of propertyless workers, or ‘proletarians,’ who cannot maintain their
existence except by the sale of their labour power.”*
Primitive accumulation
Capitalism arises on the ruins of the preceding social order – the land-
lord (feudal) economy. Capitalism grows on the soil of petty commodity
production. Capitalism effects a radical transformation of the previously
existing social relations.
How did the capitalists really get rich? At the beginning of the capitalist
era, some three or four hundred years ago, the then foremost European coun-
tries (Spain and Portugal, Holland and England) had developed a wide over-
seas trade. Intrepid travellers discovered routes to the distant and rich coun-
tries of the East – India and China; America was discovered. The invention
of gunpowder made it easy for the Europeans to overcome the resistance of
the native populations of these countries. All America was turned into a se-
ries of colonies. The robbing of the richest overseas countries was one of the
most important sources of primitive accumulation of European capital, espe-
cially English. Another source was war among the countries of Europe itself,
and the pillage of the vanquished countries. Finally the robbing of the people
of their own country by means of usury, robbing by means of overseas trade
at usurious prices, and partly direct robbery (especially piracy) are not the
least important methods employed in the history of the birth of capital.
But the accumulation of wealth is only half the problem the solution of
which is necessary for the appearance of capitalist production. The second
66
THE ESSENCE OF CAPITALIST EXPLOITATION
At a certain stage of the development of commodity production money
is transformed into capital. The formula for commodity circulation used to
be C (commodity) – M (money) – C (commodity), i.e., the sale of one com-
modity for the purchase of another. The general formula for capital is the
reverse of this, M – C – M, i.e., buying for the purpose of selling (at a
profit).
What is the difference between these two formulae? The formula C – M
– C is characteristic of simple commodity production. Here one commodity
is exchanged for another. Money serves only as a medium of exchange. Here
the purpose of the exchange is clear – the shoemaker, let us say, exchanges
his boots for bread. One use value is exchanged for another. The commodity
producer hands over the commodity which he does not need and receives in
exchange another commodity which he needs.
The formula for the circulation of capital is of an entirely different char-
acter. The capitalist goes to the market in possession of a certain sum of
money. The point of departure here is not the commodity, but money. With
his money the capitalist buys certain commodities. However, the movement
of capital does not end with this. The commodity of the capitalist is con-
verted into money. Thus the starting point and the finishing point of the
movement of capital coincide: the capitalist had money in the beginning and
he has money in the end. But, as is well, known, money is always the same,
it does not differ qualitatively, it differs only quantitatively. Money is unlike
other commodities which are distinguished by their great qualitative diver-
siveness. Thus the entire movement of capital would be quite absurd if at the
end of the movement the capitalist had only as much as he had at first. The
whole reason for the existence of capital, the whole meaning of its move-
ment, is that at the end of this movement more money is withdrawn from
circulation than was put in at the beginning. The goal of capital is the extrac-
tion of profit. Its formula is not selling in order to buy again, as in the case of
the simple commodity producer, but buying in order to sell and extract
profit.
But in what way is this profit obtained? If the capitalist buys any ordi-
nary commodity with his money and then sells it above cost price, he en-
riches himself, but only at the expense of other capitalists – either at the ex-
pense of those whom he tricks by buying the commodity and not paying its
actual price, or at the expense of those to whom he sells the commodity for
more than its price, or at the expense of both. But the capitalist class cannot
prosper by cheating itself, by the mutual trickery of the individual capitalists.
Then how is profit obtained? Obviously, the capitalist who goes to the mar-
ket with his money must find a commodity of a special kind. It must be a
commodity that creates value while it is being used. And under capitalist
conditions there is such a commodity. This commodity is labour power.
67
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Buying and selling of labour power and its value
Under commodity economy every commodity is sold at its value. What
does the worker sell? He sells his labour power, which is essential for the
capitalist to conduct his enterprise.
But we know that every commodity has its value and that this value is de-
termined by the labour time necessary to produce this commodity. What is
the value of that commodity which the worker sells – the commodity, “la-
bour power”?
It is perfectly evident that a person can work only when he is able to
maintain his existence: feeds and clothes himself, and has a place to rest his
head. It is understood that a human being can perform work only when he
satisfies his wants, at any rate his most elemental needs. If a worker is hun-
gry, if he has no clothes, he becomes unfit for work, he loses his labour
power. It can therefore be considered that the production of labour power
consists in the satisfaction of the most elemental needs of the worker.
But we also know that all those things which go to satisfy the needs of
man (food, clothing and shelter) are commodities under capitalism and can-
not be obtained free of charge. A definite quantity of labour is spent in pro-
ducing them and this determines their value. Thus the value of the commod-
ity called “labour power” is equal to the value of those commodities the
worker must consume in order to maintain his existence and that of his fam-
ily, in order to recuperate his labour power and to secure future labour power
for the capitalists.
“The value of labour power is determined by the value of the
necessaries of life habitually required by the average labourer.”*
But the value of these commodities depends on the labour necessary to
produce them.
In other words, the value of the commodity called labour power is de-
termined by the quantity of labour necessary to produce this peculiar com-
modity, while this commodity, as we have already said, consists of the food,
clothing, etc., consumed by the worker. It is this value of the commodity
called “labour power” that is paid for by the capitalist in the form of wages.
The capitalist owns a plant: buildings in which there is machinery,
warehouses in which there are raw material and fuel, all kinds of auxiliary
material. All this is dead without human labour. Therefore a capitalist hires
workers. With this he buys the last commodity necessary. Now everything is
in order. Production can begin. The workers begin to work, the enterprise is
started, the machinery is in motion.
Having hired the labourer, bought his labour power for a definite time,
* Ibid., p. 174.
70
THE ESSENCE OF CAPITALIST EXPLOITATION
self and his family (wages), and the other part of the day he toils
without remuneration and creates surplus value for the capitalist
which is the source of profit, the source of wealth of the capitalist
class.
“The doctrine of surplus value is the corner-stone of the eco-
nomic theory of Marx.”*
The Marxian doctrine of surplus value discloses the secret of capitalist
exploitation. That is why this teaching is an invaluable weapon in the hands
of the proletariat struggling for the destruction of capitalism, for the creation
of the new communist society. That is why the bourgeoisie and its “learned”
henchmen rage against the Marxian doctrine of surplus value. That is why
they are continually trying to “refute” and to “destroy” this teaching.
The Marxian doctrine of surplus value is based, as we have seen, on his
teaching of value. That is why it is important to keep the Marxian teaching of
value free from all distortion, because the theory of exploitation is built on it.
We can now sum up our investigation of the sources of enrichment for
the capitalists. This summary can best be made by citing the concise and
clear exposition of the teaching on surplus value which we find in the works
of Lenin:
“Surplus value cannot arise out of the circulation of commodi-
ties, for this represents only the exchange of equivalents; it cannot
arise out of an advance in price, for the mutual losses and gains of
buyers and sellers would equalize one another; and what we are
concerned with here is not the individual but the mass, average, so-
cial phenomenon. In order that he may be able to receive surplus
value, ‘Moneybags must... find... in the market a commodity whose
use value possesses the peculiar property of being a source of
value’† – a commodity, the actual process of whose use is at the
same time the process of the creation of value. Such a commodity
exists. It is human labour power. Its use is labour, and labour creates
value. The owner of money buys labour power at its value, which is
determined, like the value of every other commodity, by the socially
necessary labour time requisite for its production (that is to say, the
cost of maintaining the worker and his family). Having bought la-
bour power, the owner of money is entitled to use it, that is, to set it
to work for the whole day, twelve hours, let us suppose. Meanwhile
in the course of six hours (‘necessary’ labour time) the labourer
77
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
It is perfectly evident that every capitalist tries to get as much surplus
value as he possibly can. How does he achieve his purpose?
The simplest way would be to hire more workmen and expand produc-
tion. If 100 workers produce surplus value amounting to $250, 200 will net
the capitalist $500. But to double production, additional capital is necessary.
If the capitalist has such additional money, or means in general, he will natu-
rally do so. This is very clear and simple.
The question is, however, how to increase surplus value without increas-
ing the amount of capital outlay. Here the capitalist has two ways.
We have seen that the working day consists of two parts – paid, neces-
sary labour and unpaid, surplus labour. Let us assume that the working day
is 12 hours, of which 6 hours are the paid part, and of which the other 6
hours consist of surplus labour. Let us represent this working day by a line
divided into 12 parts, every division representing an hour, thus:
12 hours
6 hours 6 hours
6 hours 8 hours
78
THE ESSENCE OF CAPITALIST EXPLOITATION
ume of surplus value increases because of an absolute increase of the work-
ing day as a whole.
There is also another way of increasing the amount of surplus value.
What will our working day look like if the capitalist finds some way of re-
ducing the amount of necessary labour? It is easy to answer this. Let us as-
sume that the necessary labour has been reduced to 4 hours. Then the work-
ing day will look like this:
12 hours
4 hours 8 hours
In this case we have an increase of the relative surplus value: the vol-
ume of surplus value increases exclusively by changing the ratio of neces-
sary to surplus labour while the working day as a whole remains unchanged.
Formerly we had the ratio 6:6, and now we have 4:8 – a result of reducing
the necessary labour time.
But how is this reduction of necessary labour time achieved?
The development of technical improvements leads to enhanced labour
productivity. Less labour is expended on the production of the means of sub-
sistence of the worker. The value of these means is reduced. By the same
token, the value of labour power is reduced, decreasing the amount of neces-
sary labour and increasing the relative amount of surplus value.
In order to reduce the amount of necessary labour the capitalist employs
the wives and children of the workers. Then the entire family receives in
wages approximately as much as was previously received only by the head
of the family. When, with increased technical development, the role of the
worker is reduced to watching the machine and performing merely very
simple operations, male labour can very well be replaced by children or
women. The capitalists prefer this kind of labour because it is cheaper: a
woman worker is generally paid only half as much as a man whose place she
takes; the pay for the work of children is even less.
Excess surplus value
The following method of augmenting the relative surplus value should
be especially noted. Every capitalist tries in all ways to increase his profits.
79
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
For this purpose he introduces all kinds of improvements which lower the
cost of production. For this purpose he buys new machinery, introduces new
technique to increase the productivity of labour. So long as these technical
innovations introduced by the capitalist remain unknown to other enterprises
of the same field he receives super-profits, excess surplus value. The com-
modities cost him less, whereas he sells them at the same price as before or
only slightly under this price.
An individual enterprise usually keeps such an advantage for only a very
short time. Other enterprises also introduce technical improvements. Since
the value of commodities is determined by the average socially necessary
labour contained in them, the general introduction of technical improve-
ments leads to a fall in the value of each commodity unit and thus the indi-
vidual enterprise is deprived of its special advantage.
Under capitalism, the main driving force of technical progress is the
possibility of getting super-profits. The race for excess surplus value pro-
duces an increase in relative surplus value, as it brings about a reduction in
the amount of labour needed to produce the workers’ means of subsistence.
Excess surplus value is only another form of relative surplus value.
The struggle around the working day
It is perfectly clear that for the capitalist, the simplest way to augment his
profits is to increase absolute surplus value. No new technical improvements
are needed for this, it is only necessary to lengthen the working day. And in
fact the capitalists always try to extend the working day to the utmost. If they
could do so, they would make the worker labour more than twenty-four hours
a day. Lengthening of the working day, however, has its natural physical lim-
its. Moreover, this incurs the ever more determined opposition of the workers.
That is why the capitalists cannot limit themselves to attempts at increasing
absolute surplus value. Together with this they also struggle for relative sur-
plus value, which promises them unlimited possibilities.
At the dawn of the capitalist era an extremely long working day pre-
vailed in all countries. Technical development was still weak, and, most im-
portant of all, the working class was scattered and not prepared for battle,
hence the production of absolute surplus value predominated everywhere.
In some cases the working day consisted of almost the entire twenty-
four hours. The worker only got a few hours for sleep, the rest of the time
belonged to the capitalist. It is easy to imagine what an effect such murder-
ous exploitation had upon the life of the workers.
A long working day is still common in many countries. In China, for in-
stance, the working day in many factories is sixteen to eighteen hours long;
even in underground work, in the coal mines, the working day is as exorbi-
tantly long. And such a long working day prevails not only for men but also
for women and young children.
80
THE ESSENCE OF CAPITALIST EXPLOITATION
In capitalist society, says Marx, the free time of one class is obtained by
turning the entire life of the masses into working time.
As soon as the proletarian begins to struggle for better conditions he ad-
vances the demand for limiting the working day as one of his first demands.
Laws limiting child labour and the length of the working day appeared in the
older capitalist countries (in England and then in France) only in the forties
of the last century. Labour legislation everywhere appeared only after the
severest struggles on the part of the working class, The bourgeois govern-
ment, defending the (interests of its capitalist class as a whole, consents to
the enactment of such laws only under pressure of the labour movement on
the one hand and from consideration of the necessity of preserving the lives
of the working population on the other hand, as without workers there would
be no profits for the capitalists.
In most of the highly developed countries the ten-hour day prevailed
prior to the World War; the working day was shorter only in some cases of
underground work (in coal and metal mines). There were some limitations of
child labour and the work of women (the limitation of night work).
After the World War, when the sweep of the labour movement threat-
ened the very existence of capitalism, the bourgeoisie in many countries
made concessions. In 1919 a special proposal was even drawn up in Wash-
ington to introduce the eight-hour day on a world scale, but nothing came of
this. In the following years, when capital took the offensive, most of the
concessions were withdrawn. A general onslaught against the eight-hour day
was made by the capitalists everywhere and in most countries the eight-hour
day does not exist any longer.
Intensity of labour
One of the favourite methods of squeezing more surplus value out of the
workers is by increasing the intensity of labour. It can be arranged that the
worker shall spend more labour, spend more energy in the same interval of
time. In such a case he will produce more value; hence the surplus value
falling to the capitalist will also increase.
With machinery the intensity of labour is often increased by speeding up
the machine. The worker must make an effort to keep up with the machine.
If he fails to do so he loses his job. In other cases the capitalists try to get the
workers to work more and more intensively by means of special methods of
payment.
Excessive intensity of labour is just as injurious to the health and life of
the worker as an excessively long working day. When the length of the
working day is limited by law, the capitalists find a “way out” for them-
selves by an unlimited increase in the intensity of labour. In most capitalist
enterprises the intensity of labour is so great that the worker prematurely
loses his ability to work, ages too soon, is subject to various diseases. For
81
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
the capitalists, intensification of labour is a well-tried method of augmenting
the exploitation of the worker, of increasing the degree of his enslavement.
Capitalism and technical development
At the present time the decaying capitalist system, finding itself in the
grip of a severe and protracted crisis, manifests itself as the foe of technical
progress. The capitalists and their learned servants often try to represent ma-
chinery as being the cause of all the trouble. Too many machines, they say,
too many steel monsters robbing honest people of work. Too many products
produced by these machines, which then find no market. The workers know,
however, that it is not the machine in itself which brings unemployment,
crises, etc. The reason for these evils is the capitalist system with its deep-
rooted contradictions. It is not the machine that robs the worker of bread, but
the capitalist application of the machine as a means of exploitation.
Under the conditions of the present crisis, the bourgeoisie evince a
predilection for returning from machine production to hand labour. And it is
not a rare thing for them to put into practice these mad schemes so inimical
to progress. In America, while many steam shovels and dredges stand idle,
thousands of people are made to labour with the pick and shovel on public
works. Under these conditions the U.S.S.R. is the only country in the world
today which continually progresses towards the adoption of the newest and
most advanced technique in all fields. The country where socialism is being
built holds high the flag of technical progress.
Modern technical engineering increases the productivity of labour hun-
dreds and thousands of times.
A worker can make 450 bricks a day by hand. A modern brick-making
machine turns out about 400,000 bricks a day for every worker employed on
it, i.e., about 1,000 times as many.
A hand-power flour mill turns out 450-650 pounds of low grade flour. A
modern flour mill in Minneapolis (U.S.A.) turns out 13,000,000 pounds of
the best grade flour a day to every worker employed, or about 20,000 times
as much.
A modern shoe factory can produce 83 pairs of shoes per worker every 6
days, as against 1 pair which could be produced by a worker working by
himself.
Modern moribund capitalism, however, is incapable of utilizing these
possibilities. Even before the present crisis the application of the newest
technical developments met with tremendous difficulties even in the richest
capitalist country – the United States of America.
In 1929 there were 2,730 brick-making plants employing 39,000 work-
ers and making 8,000,000,000 bricks, whereas 6 to 7 modern plants with
only 100 workers each could completely satisfy the U.S.A. market.
In 1929 there was a total of 6,500,000,000 pounds of flour produced in
82
THE ESSENCE OF CAPITALIST EXPLOITATION
the United States. In order to produce this quantity of flour, with the normal
production capacity of the Minneapolis flour mill mentioned above, only 17
workers would be needed. As a matter of fact, however, there were not 17
workers but 27,028 employed in the flour-mill industry of the United States.
In the shoe industry, even in 1929, that is, in the period of greatest pros-
perity, 205,640 workers produced 365,000,000 pairs of shoes which gives,
not 83 pairs, but approximately 35 pairs a week per worker.
An almost infinite number of such examples could be enumerated.
It is important to keep in mind that in its period of youth and prosperity
capitalism brought with itself a tremendous growth of the productive forces
of human society. Until the rise of capitalism no one even dreamed of mod-
ern large-scale industry, its high technical development, modern means of
transport and communication. It was capitalism that brought with it machine
production. It called to life the tremendous wealth that lay buried in the
bowels of the earth. It evolved a tremendous advanced technique, lightening
human labour considerably and increasing its power over nature.
However, capitalism places all this development of the productive
forces of society at the service of the murderous exploitation of one class by
another. The most perfect means of production is used by the capitalist sys-
tem as the most perfect means of squeezing surplus value out of the working
class. The race for gain, the race for profit – this is the motive power of capi-
talist industry. An increase in profit – this is the purpose for which the capi-
talist introduces new technical achievements.
That is why the further development of productive forces under capital-
ism means the further intensification of the exploitation of the working class,
the further enrichment of a handful of capitalists at the expense of the im-
poverishment of the great masses of the people. But at the same time, by
creating gigantic enterprises of a high technical order, by greatly increasing
the technical powers of human labour, capitalism prepares the material basis
for socialism, prepares the material conditions and the prerequisites for the
realization of the aims for which the proletariat is struggling. It is in this, in
the preparation of the necessary prerequisites for the triumph of the proletar-
ian revolution, that the historical role of capitalism lies.
Wage slavery
There is nothing more disgusting than the hypocrisy of the bourgeoisie
who assert the “equality” of rich and poor, the well-fed and the hungry, the
drone and the over-worked labourer. In reality the bony hand of hunger
drives the worker into bondage to the capitalist more effectively than the
severest legislation. Capitalism leads to a continual worsening of the condi-
tions of life of the proletariat. Capitalism leads to ever greater poverty
among the broad masses of workers. Hunger becomes an ever more frequent
guest in working class quarters.
83
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Marx says:
“The Roman slave was held by fetters; the wage labourer is
bound to his owner by invisible threads. The appearance of inde-
pendence is kept up by means of a constant change of employers,
and by the fictio juris [legal fiction] of a contract.”*
And in fact, the .worker is free to leave his employment at one capitalist
enterprise only to get to another one belonging to another capitalist.
Under the pretence of fighting against forced labour the capitalists con-
ducted a campaign against the Soviet Union. It is hard to imagine anything
more base than this outburst of modern slave-drivers against the only free
socialist country in the world, under the slogan of fighting for the freedom of
labour. The Soviet Union is the only country in the world where wage slav-
ery has been put to an end, where tremendous masses of .workers have, for
the first time in human history, acquired the opportunity of sane and free
labour for themselves, for the benefit of a socialist system where there are no
exploiters and no exploited.
Throughout the entire capitalist world the working masses are chained
with invisible fetters to exhausting, hateful labour the fruit of which only
serves to further their enslavement, to intensify capitalist bondage. Creating
untold wealth for a handful of drones, the workers themselves suffer more
and more from hunger and privation. “The place of the slave-driver’s lash is
taken by the overlooker’s book of penalties,”† said Marx about capitalist
enterprises. Without doubt, the fine-book of the foreman – the eternal threat
of losing one’s job and dying of hunger – affects the present-day worker no
less than the lash of the slave-driver.
But even the lash of a foreman is by no means a rarity in modern capi-
talist countries. In a number of countries, especially in the colonies, the most
authentic slave labour exists for the benefit of the capitalist. Capital makes
sufficient profits from “free” wage labour. But where circumstances permit,
it is not averse to utilizing slave labour.
Even in the most highly developed capitalist countries we may find con-
ditions similar to slave conditions.
Under the conditions of the economic crisis the bourgeoisie gladly em-
ploys the-most genuine forced labour in various forms of “labour service,”
primarily unemployed youth. In the German “labour service” camps, hun-
dreds of thousands of young workers live in conditions of an army barracks
regime; they receive a miserable pittance for the most arduous labour. At the
same time, German fascism forces the camp inmates to go through military
86
CHAPTER V
Wages and the Impoverishment of the Working Class Under Capitalism
Value of labour power and its price
Under capitalism the worker sells his labour power to the capitalist. The
capitalist hires the worker and makes him work for him. The worker receives
wages. This constitutes the purchase and sale of labour power.
But labour power is a commodity of a special kind. The purchase and
sale of labour power characterizes a relation between capitalist and worker –
between the two basic classes of capitalist society. The value of labour
power, as we already know, is determined by the value of the means of sub-
sistence necessary for the maintenance of the worker. It must however be
kept in mind that the capitalists always try to reduce wages below this limit.
Under capitalism no one is concerned with how the worker lives. He often
remains unemployed and starves to death. But even when he obtains em-
ployment his wages are not always sufficient to satisfy his most elementary
needs.
The value of labour power is determined by the value of the means of
subsistence of the worker. But how are the necessary means of subsistence
determined? It is quite clear that the means of subsistence of the worker,
their amount, their nature, depend upon a number of circumstances. Marx
points out that
“...the value of labour is in every country determined by a tradi-
tional standard of life. It is not mere physical life, but it is the satis-
faction of certain wants springing from social conditions in which
people are placed and reared up.”*
Unlike other commodities the determination of the value of labour
power includes a historical or social element. The normal living standard of
the worker is not something that is fixed and established forever. On the
contrary, this standard changes with the course of historical development,
and is different in different countries depending upon the historical devel-
opment of the particular country. Capitalism, however, always tends to bring
the living standard of the working class down to an extremely low level. The
value of a commodity expressed in terms of money is its price. The price of
a commodity, as we have already seen, continually fluctuates above or be-
low its value. Wages are a special form of price for the commodity, “labour
power.” It is evident that the level of wages varies above and below the
value of labour power. But in contradistinction to other commodities the
variations here are mainly below the value.
88
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
and unpaid labour. All labour appears as paid labour. In the corvée,
the labour of the worker for himself, and his compulsory labour for
his lord, differ in space and time in the clearest possible way. In
slave labour, even that part of the working day in which the slave is
only replacing the value of his own means of existence, in which,
therefore, in fact, he works for himself alone, appears as labour for
his master. All the slave’s labour appears as unpaid labour. In wage
labour, on the contrary, even surplus labour, or unpaid labour, ap-
pears as paid.”*
Wages and the struggle of the working class
Workers began quite early to organize into trade unions, which con-
ducted a struggle to improve working conditions and to curb unlimited ex-
ploitation.
Wages, as we have seen, are determined by the value of labour power.
But, in the first place, wages fluctuate considerably, particularly below the
value of labour power and, secondly, the value of labour power itself
changes considerably dependent on a number of circumstances.
A constant struggle rages between the bourgeoisie and the working class
concerning the level of wages; in this struggle much depends upon the de-
gree of organization and unity of each side.
So long as the workers had not organized trade unions, each capitalist
dealt with a scattered mass. The capitalist in such a case is in an advanta-
geous position in the struggle about wages: if any worker does not agree to
the bad conditions of employment he is discharged and the employer quickly
finds someone to take his place.
Matters change when there is a trade union movement. Under such cir-
cumstances the capitalist is not opposed by a scattered mass of unorganized
workers, but now has to deal with a union of all (or of the majority) of the
workers, which presents uniform demands and calls for-uniform conditions.
Formerly the capitalist came to an agreement with individuals, now he has to
come to a collective agreement with a trade union. Wages of the workers are
usually determined by special rate agreements.
The capitalists, of course, find many ways of struggling against the
workers even when there is a trade union. In their turn they unite in “em-
ployers’ associations.” To help the capitalists, those betrayers of the working
class, the Social-Democrats, come forward. The trade unions under their
leadership disrupt the struggle of the workers, act as strike-breakers during
revolutionary strikes.
It is perfectly clear that by means of only an economic struggle on the
part of trade unions the working class cannot free itself from the ever grow-
91
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Piecework
On the other hand, various methods of piecework are employed in all
cases where the capitalist wants to interest the worker in producing as great a
quantity of commodities as possible.
Piecework saves the employer the necessity of supervising the work of
his employees; making the wages depend on the quantity produced, piece-
work assures the most intensive labour on the part of the workers. As a rule,
piecework is possible in those industries where it is easy to calculate or
measure (by piece, weight, volume or length) the quantity of commodities
produced.
Piecework, under capitalism, is the favourite method of increasing the
exploitation of workers by increasing the intensity of their labour. Piecework
rates are usually set according to the earnings of the most capable and the
fastest workers. In order to make the necessary minimum wage the other
workers must strain their energies to the utmost. When the employer sees
that a majority of the workers have increased their pay, he reduces the rate.
The workers must then work even more intensively in order to earn their
former wages.
The piecework form of remuneration has an entirely different signifi-
cance in the conditions obtaining in the U.S.S.R. There the worker does not
sell his work to a class of exploiters, but uses it in enterprises which are the
property of the proletarian state. The wage which the worker receives in the
U.S.S.R. is a social allowance for labour, and is in proportion to the quantity
and quality of the labour expended. Piecework remuneration in the socialist
economy of the Soviet Union is the best means of establishing conformity
between the quantity and quality of the labour expended and the remunera-
tion of the individual workman, it is a powerful lever in raising the produc-
tivity of labour and in addition the well-being of the working class. There-
fore, it is entirely different from piecework under capitalism.
Bonuses and profit-sharing
Sometimes the capitalists pay out part of the wages in the form of a bo-
nus. They figure that the bonus will stimulate special exertion on the part of
the workers and make them work with the utmost intensity.
An even greater deception is so-called profit-sharing. The capitalist
lowers the basic wage with the excuse that the worker is supposedly also
interested in having the business profitable. Then under the guise of “a share
in the profits” only a part of the wages previously deducted is returned to the
worker. In the end the worker “sharing in the profits” often receives less
than the one working simply for wages.
By this method not only does the employer try to raise the intensity of
labour to a high degree – but sometimes it induces a certain stratum of the
more ignorant workers to keep away from the class movement of the prole-
92
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
tariat and thus to serve as a support of capital.
The sweating system
On the basis of piecework the so-called “sweating system” exists, par-
ticularly in the needle trades industry in England and America. Work is
given out to be done at home at exceedingly low rates. The tailor working
under such a “sweating system” must work literally day and night to avoid
starvation.
Scientific organization of labour. The Taylor and Ford systems
Having bought the labour power of the proletarian, the employer tries to
derive the utmost possible from it for himself. Of late the cleverer and more
able employers have begun to introduce the so-called “scientific organiza-
tion” of labour, which amounts to the following.
Every kind of work done at the plant is studied in detail by experts who,
after long observation and research, establish the most rational methods of
doing this work. Methods of work are thus established which save the
worker unnecessary motion and effort, all his tools are rationally arranged,
etc., so that the worker is not distracted from his main work. Under these
circumstances all the energy of the worker, all the effort spent by him goes
towards useful work without any loss, is spent entirely on the operations
which he has to perform. Thus the industry gets the greatest benefit from his
work and the productivity of labour is greatly increased.
The scientific organization of labour is a great achievement in the ra-
tional utilization of human effort. After the overthrow of capitalism, under
conditions of a proletarian government, great possibilities are opened up for
the scientific organization of labour. But under the capitalist regime, the sci-
entific organization of labour, like all scientific achievements, is used by the
capitalists in their own narrow class interests. Scientific organization of la-
bour is turned by the capitalists into one of the means of squeezing more
surplus value out of the workers.
One of the first to advocate the scientific organization of labour was an
American engineer, Taylor. His system, called the Taylor system, is used in
many capitalist plants, .increasing the surplus value. Greatly raising the pro-
ductivity of labour, turning the workers into machines executing strictly cal-
culated motions, the Taylor system leads to the squeezing of the last ounce
of strength out of the workers, making invalids of them after a few years.
The lowering of the piecework rates following the introduction of the Taylor
system makes the workers labour much harder for the same, and at times
lower, wages.
During post-war years, the subtle methods of exploitation used by the
American automobile king, Henry Ford, became especially famous. His
methods of exploitation began to spread rapidly not only in America, but
also in the capitalist countries of Europe. The basic feature of the Ford sys-
93
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
tem is production in a .steady stream – along a conveyor. By speeding up the
conveyor, the work is speeded up and the intensity of labour increased.
Whoever cannot keep up with the conveyor loses his job in the capitalist
plant. Thus the capitalist turns every technical improvement into an instru-
ment for the further impoverishment and enslavement of the proletariat, into
an instrument for squeezing the very life out of the workers.
Payment in kind or in money
Formerly, when a worker was hired in the village, he was seldom paid in
money for his work. This was done in the following way: the worker was
boarded by his employer and, in addition, at the end of the summer, he re-
ceived a little grain. Here the worker is paid in kind: he gets the necessary
means of subsistence directly, in exchange for his labour power. Such a sim-
ple transaction is similar to the barter of products – say, an axe for bread.
When trade assumes such a simple character it is perfectly evident that the
value of the necessary means of subsistence is at the basis of the value of
labour power.
Payment exclusively in kind is very rare in capitalist industry. But even
here part of the wages is occasionally paid out in kind. This method of pay-
ment is usually only a convenient method for the capitalist to increase his
profits at the expense of the workers. The company store belonging to the
employer furnishes the worker with all kinds of shoddy goods at triple
prices. The workers’ real wages are thus greatly reduced. Workers’ organi-
zations therefore always struggle against such a practice. Sometimes the
capitalists try to achieve the same end – a decrease in the wages of the work-
ers by making them buy goods at high prices – in a more subtle way. They
assume control of all the stores in the workers’ settlement or district and the
workers, getting their wages in money, are compelled to buy things at high
prices just the same. Workers try to struggle against such exploitation by
means of organizing consumers’ co-operatives.
Nominal and real wages
In developed capitalist industry, except in rare cases, wages are paid in
money. The worker sells his labour power and, as with the sale of any other
commodity, gets its price in the form of a definite sum of money.
However, the worker does not need the money for itself, but only as a
means of getting the things he requires. Receiving his definite wages, the
worker buys the things he needs; he pays the prices for them that prevail on
the market at the time.
But we know that the level of commodity prices does not remain un-
changed. The purchasing power of money changes under the influence of
various causes. If a gold standard exists in the country, the prices may rise
because gold becomes cheaper; with a decrease in the value of gold, the pur-
chasing power of money falls. When paper currency is issued in great quan-
94
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
tities the prices of commodities suffer great and rapid changes, following the
fall in the purchasing power of money which almost always accompanies the
circulation of paper currency.
Hence, if we wish to compare the wages of workers in several cases, it
is not enough to know only how much money they receive in each case. It is
also necessary to know how much goods can be bought with the money in
each case. We must not merely compare the nominal rates of wages (by the
nominal rate of wages we mean the amount of money received by the
worker), we must also take into consideration the purchasing power of the
money received. Only then can we establish exactly the real wages, which
can be measured by the quantity of use values that can be purchased for the
given sum of money in the given place.
Wages of skilled workers
Everyone knows that workers in different trades receive different rates
of wages. Highly skilled workers receive much higher wages than unskilled
workers who have no special technical training. Usually, the greater the
skill, the higher the wages.
Different branches of industry require workers of different skill. Hence
the wages of workers in different industries are not the same.
Besides the difference in the rates of pay for workers in different indus-
tries there is the difference in the rates of pay for workers of different skill in
the same industry. The skilled worker is paid more than the semi-skilled, the
semi-skilled worker more than the common labourer.
What is the reason for such differences in the rates of wages of workers
according to skill? It is not difficult to understand this. Anyone can perform
unskilled labour, but the skilled worker must go through a definite period of
learning the trade, must spend much time and effort to obtain this skill. If
there were no differences in the rates of pay no one would want to spend the
time and energy to learn a trade, no one would try to obtain a definite degree
of skill.
However, no amount of skill saves a worker from inhuman, incessant
exploitation under capitalism.
The introduction of new machinery generally makes great numbers of
highly skilled workers superfluous. What was previously done by a highly
skilled master, who had spent many years in acquiring his skill, is now done
by a machine. Considerable sections of skilled workers become superfluous
and are thrown out of employment. In order not to starve to death they are
compelled to do unskilled labour at much lower pay.
The level of wages in the various capitalist countries
The level of wages in the various capitalist countries is not the same.
There are very great differences in this among the various countries. These
differences are due to many causes.
95
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
It would be ridiculous to think that capitalists in one country are kinder
in their relations to the workers than those in others. As a matter of fact capi-
talists everywhere try to lower wages to the lowest possible limits. But con-
ditions in different capitalist countries vary considerably. Different countries
have different histories. In America, for instance, capitalism developed un-
der circumstances where a shortage of labour was experienced rather than a
superfluity of it: an abundance of free land for some time gave emigrants
from European countries the opportunity of settling on the land. In older
capitalist countries the working class organized earlier to offer resistance to
the capitalists. In the more advanced capitalist countries the intensity of la-
bour, as well as the degree of average skill of the workers, is very high.
All these circumstances gave rise to the different levels of wages in dif-
ferent capitalist countries.
Thus, for instance, if we take wages in England as 100, the wages (the
average hourly rate) in other advanced capitalist countries on the eve of the
imperialist war were as follows:
England 100 France 64
Germany 75 U.S.A. 240
According to other calculations the average yearly wages of workers in
various countries (in 1900-07, in dollars) were:
U.S.A. 463 Austria 167
England 258 Russia 97
Germany 237 Japan 55
In post-war years we also see considerably different rates of wages in
the various capitalist countries. Here are figures showing the differences in
real wages in various large cities of the most important countries. The fol-
lowing figures show the conditions existing in January 1929 and are based
on the level of real wages in London in 1924 which is taken as 100:
Philadelphia 206 Berlin 77
Dublin 106 Madrid 57
London 105 Brussels 52
Stockholm 93 Milan 50
Amsterdam 88 Rome 44
It is understood that wages are particularly low in those countries where
capitalism has only recently begun to develop. Primitive accumulation in
these countries ruins the peasantry and artisans, throwing them into the army
of those seeking employment. In the colonies the living standard of the pro-
letariat is extremely low. The workers in China especially are subject to the
most brutal exploitation. The Chinese coolie, feeding himself on a handful of
rice, often sleeping on the streets or in the parks and clothing himself in rags,
96
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
is, in the eyes of the capitalists, the most exemplary worker in the world. The
more brazen capitalists tell the European workers to take an example from
the Chinese coolie, to live as “economically” as he does. This kind of advice
has been heard particularly often during the present times.
Growth of capitalist exploitation
As capitalism develops, the exploitation of the working class grows. The
conditions under which the workers conduct their struggle about wages with
the capitalists continually become more disadvantageous to the workers. As
it develops, capitalism brings with it both a relative and an absolute impover-
ishment of the working class.
The share of the capitalists grows bigger, the share of the workers
smaller. The figures for several capitalist countries show this clearly. Let us
take England. If we take the total values created in the country (the so-called
national income) as 100, then the share that fell to the workers changed as
follows:
Year Amount of national Amount of Workers’ share of
income in million wages in national income
pounds sterling million pounds (in per cent)
sterling
1843 515 235 45.6
1860 832 392 47.1
1884 1,274 521 41.4
1903 1,710 655 38.3
1908 1,844 703 38.1
The share of the worker becomes steadily less.
At the same time, of course, the share of the national income of the en-
tire country, which goes to the capitalists, grows steadily greater. What the
working class loses, the capitalists gain.
In an article written before the World War, Lenin quotes the following
figures showing the impoverishment of the working class. In Germany, for
the period between 1880 and 1912, wages rose on an average of 25 per cent,
while the cost of living for the same period rose by at least 40 per cent.
Lenin notes particularly that this took place in such a rich and advanced
capitalist country as Germany, where the situation of the workers was in-
comparably better than that of the workers in pre-revolutionary Russia, be-
cause of the higher cultural level in Germany, the freedom to strike and form
trade unions and the comparative political freedom, where the membership
in labour unions amounted to millions and where there were millions of
readers of the labour press. Lenin drew the following conclusion from this:
“The worker is impoverished absolutely, i.e., grows actually
poorer than before, is compelled to live worse, eat more sparingly,
97
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
remain underfed, seek shelter in cellars and attics. The relative share
of the workers in capitalist society, which is rapidly growing richer,
becomes ever smaller, because the millionaires grow richer ever
more rapidly.... In capitalist society wealth grows with unbelievable
rapidity alongside the impoverishment of the working masses.”*
This is the situation in the richest capitalist countries of the world, where
the capitalists can make concessions to the workers, as they get tremendous
profits from the colonies. Of course in the more backward countries, in the
colonies to which capital goes for easy profits, the exploitation of the work-
ers proceeds even more rapidly.
We thus see that capitalist exploitation steadily increases, and that the
gulf between the working class and the bourgeoisie becomes ever deeper.
The opportunists in all countries continually talk of an abatement of the so-
cial contradictions, of the necessity for civil peace between the classes, of
the possibility for the working class to improve its conditions even under
capitalism. The working class, however, grows poorer not only relatively (in
comparison with the boundless growth of the profits of the bourgeoisie), but
absolutely. Even in the richest capitalist countries the food of the workers
becomes continually worse, they live in still more crowded quarters, experi-
ence ever greater want. At the same time the intensity of labour of the work-
ers increases steadily. The worker has to spend more energy for each hour of
work than he had to spend formerly. The excessive intensity of labour, the
continual whipping up, rapidly exhausts the organism of the worker. There
can therefore not only be no talk about an abatement of class contradictions,
but, on the contrary, there is a constant sharpening of these contradictions,
they grow inevitably.
Unemployment and the reserve army of labour
With the growth of capitalism, unemployment increases and the so-
called “reserve army of labour” grows, furnishing hands to the capitalists in
times when industry needs to be expanded, or when the older workers refuse
to work under the old conditions any longer. Let us see how this takes place.
In its inception capitalism finds a sufficient supply of potential wage la-
bourers on the market. This supply is composed of ruined farmers, artisans
and handicraftsmen, who have lost their means of production. They are
ready to work for the capitalist if he will only give them the means of con-
tinuing their existence. There must always be a definite reserve of free
hands. Only on this condition can capitalist industry, based on the exploita-
tion of wage labour, arise.
99
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
thousands of workers who have been supplanted by machines with the pro-
gress of capitalist technical improvements.
The general law of capitalist accumulation
This constant replacement of workers by machinery, which is a result of
capitalist development, creates what is known as a “relative surplus popula-
tion” in capitalist countries. Hundreds of thousands of people yearly are
compelled to emigrate from their countries as they become superfluous and
are left without the faintest hope of obtaining employment. During the post-
war years this situation has grown still worse. The countries to which these
emigrants flowed have closed their doors and refuse admission.
The existence and growth of an industrial reserve army have a tremen-
dous influence on the entire situation of the working class. Poverty in-
creases, the uncertainty of what the next day will bring is ever present, and
wages fall. The working class produces surplus value with its labour, but it
goes to the capitalist class. Part of the surplus value obtained from the work-
ing class the capitalists consume and thus destroy; the rest they add to their
original capital. If the capitalist originally had $100,000 and during the year
he has succeeded in squeezing out of the workers $20,000 in profits, he will
add about half this sum to his original capital for the next year. In this case
his capital for the next year will already be $110,000. He has increased his
capital, has accumulated $10,000. Accumulation of capital, therefore, is the
addition of surplus value to capital. The growth of capital as a result of ac-
cumulating surplus value is enormous. The mass of surplus value squeezed
out of the working class grows ever greater as capitalism develops. The mass
of surplus value accumulated by the capitalists and which goes to increase
their capital grows apace.
Thus accumulation of capital brings with it the growth of the wealth of a
handful of capitalists. The surplus value created by the labour of the working
class becomes a source of the increasing power of the exploiters. With the
accumulation of capital the degree of exploitation of the workers increases.
Thus, under capitalism, the working class with its own labour creates the
conditions for an ever greater degree of its own exploitation.
With the accumulation of capital the living conditions of the working
class become steadily worse, the degree of their exploitation increases.
All this is an inevitable result of capitalist accumulation. The more capi-
tal the capitalists accumulate, the more they expand production, introduce
new machines, the more poverty and unemployment spread among the
working class.
This is the general law of capitalist accumulation discovered by Marx,
and it is of immense significance for an understanding of capitalism, for an
understanding of the direction in which capitalism develops.
Marx defines the general law of capitalist accumulation as follows:
100
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
“The greater the social wealth, the functioning capital, the ex-
tent and energy of its growth, and, therefore, also the absolute mass
of the proletariat and the productiveness of its labour, the greater is
the industrial reserve army. The same causes which develop the ex-
pansive power of capital develop also the labour power at its dis-
posal. The relative mass of the industrial reserve army increases,
therefore, with the potential energy of wealth. But the greater this
reserve army in proportion to the active labour army, the greater is
the mass of a consolidated surplus population, whose misery is in
inverse ratio to its torment of labour. The more extensive, finally,
the lazarus-layers of the working class, and the industrial reserve
army, the greater is official pauperism. This is the absolute general
law of capitalist accumulation.”*
Marx further says about this law:
“...within the capitalist system all methods for raising the social
productiveness of labour are brought about at the cost of the
individual labourer; all means for the development of production
transform themselves into means of domination over, and
exploitation of, the producers; they mutilate the labourer into a
fragment of a man, degrade him to the level of an appendage of a
machine, destroy every remnant of charm in his work and turn it
into a hated toil; they estrange from him the intellectual
potentialities of the labour process in the same proportion as science
is incorporated in it as an independent power; they distort the
conditions under which he works, subject him during the labour
process to a despotism the more hateful for its meanness; they
transform his life time into working .time.... But all methods for the
production of surplus value are at the same time methods of
accumulation; and every extension of accumulation becomes again
a means for the development of those methods. It follows therefore
that in proportion as capital accumulates, the lot of the labourer, be
his payment high or low, must grow worse. The law, finally, that
always equilibrates the relative surplus population, or industrial
reserve army, to the extent and energy of accumulation, this law
rivets the labourer to capital.... It establishes an accumulation of
misery, corresponding with accumulation of capital. Accumulation
of wealth at one pole is, therefore, at the same time accumulation of
misery, agony of toil, slavery, ignorance, brutality, mental
degradation, at the opposite pole, i.e., on the side of the class that
103
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Years Wages
(In dollars)
1929 28.5
1930 25.8
1931 22.6
1932 17.1
1933 17.7
The year 1933 seems to show a certain increase in wages, but it is only
an apparent increase. In point of fact the increase in the cost of living in this
period was considerably higher than the increase in nominal wages. Accord-
ing to the greatly understated official figures, the cost of living rose by 7 per
cent in 1933 in comparison with 1932, but according to the figures of the
Labour Research Bureau food prices rose by 18 per cent in 1933. The noto-
rious “National Recovery Act” passed by the Roosevelt government brought
about a still further worsening in the conditions of life of the workers.
In fascist Germany the conditions of the workers are going from bad to
worse. Letters of German workers give an idea of the virtually penal condi-
tions which the fascists have introduced into the enterprises. This, for exam-
ple, is what one working girl writes from the factories of the famous interna-
tional firm of Siemens to a German paper abroad:
“In the press shop of the small factories of Siemensstadt the
working conditions are terrible. With five working days per week,
on piecework, wages reach fifteen marks at the very most. There are
instances where a girl is only on four days a week and in this time
draws 9 marks all told. Under such conditions there are in all only 2
marks left to live on, seeing that 5 marks go in rent and 2 marks for
fares. The speed of the work is frightful. The majority of the women
cannot keep up with the conditions of the piecework. The time
needed for bringing and sending back material, for figuring out the
work cards, for seeing to defects in the machine, for having break-
fast, etc., is not taken into account.”
The following figures show the degree of impoverishment of the work-
ing class in the United States during the crisis. The index numbers of those
employed for wages in industry and the total sum paid them in wages for the
years of the crisis (index number 1923-25=100) are given below.
104
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
105
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
spread of all kinds of diseases, innumerable cases of death from starvation –
these are the results of the inhuman living conditions into which capital
forces millions of people. Mortality and disease among the children proceed
especially rapidly.
But if such is the degree of impoverishment of the proletariat in the
richer capitalist countries, the conditions in the backward capitalist countries
are still worse. In this respect Poland offers a graphic example. Recently the
result of an investigation of 204 Warsaw families of unemployed was pub-
lished. This investigation was conducted by a bourgeois organization that is
far from sympathetic to communism. The families investigated were those of
skilled workers. The report of the investigation reads:
“It must be stated that in the vast majority of cases the food was
below starvation minimum. Here are examples: a moulder’s family
consisting of four people spends 12 zloti (about $1.50) a week on
food. They eat twice a day: potatoes, cabbage, bread. They do not
buy meat or milk at all. A tailor’s family consisting of six persons
had not eaten anything in three days at the time the commission vis-
ited it; there was also no fuel, no kerosene. In another case a family
of four persons had not had a cooked meal for a period of three
weeks. Their only food was bread and tea. A family of an unem-
ployed worker lives on the earnings of the wife who peddles pret-
zels on the street. Her earnings amount to 1-1.5 zloti (about 15
cents) a day, and this is the only source of income of a family con-
sisting of ten persons.”
Summing up, the report states:
“The principal food of the unemployed is potatoes and cabbage,
more rarely bread and tea, occasionally cereal, very rarely maca-
roni, etc., vegetables. Of the 204 families investigated, meat is eaten
only by 20 families once a week.”
Matters are even worse with respect to clothes. The report says:
“The greatest shortage is felt in shoes and outer clothing. For
instance, an unemployed baker’s family, consisting of six persons,
has no shoes whatever. When he leaves the house, the father ties a
pair of soles to his feet with string; the children do not leave the
house. In another case two children have one coat. The mother takes
the younger one to school, takes off his coat, runs home and dresses
the older boy. The same procedure is repeated when the children
have to come home from school.”
About the terrible housing conditions of the unemployed the report tells
the following:
106
WAGES AND THE IMPOVERISHMENT OF THE WORKING CLASS
“Most of the homes investigated do not satisfy the most ele-
mentary requirements of hygiene.”
Here are some characteristic examples:
“The home is in a cellar. Water drips down the walls. The floor
of the hallway leading to the home is always under three centime-
tres of water. Three adults and four children live in this room. In a
number of cases, more than ten persons occupy one room. Of 929
persons questioned, only 193 sleep in separate beds. This includes
eleven persons who sleep on the floor, fourteen children sleeping in
cribs, and nine children sleeping on trunks, benches or chairs. The
majority sleeps two, three and more persons in a bed. In nine cases
it was established that five persons sleep in one bed, and in three
cases even six in a bed.”
Despite certain increases in industrial production, the number of unem-
ployed in Poland in the present year is higher than in the previous year. In
January 1934, the number of unemployed on the register of the Labour Ex-
change was 410,000; in the spring of 1934 it was 350,000, but even accord-
ing to the evidence of the bourgeois newspapers, the actual number of un-
employed exceeded a million and a half. The total wages actually paid out to
the workers in big industry amounted (according to official data) to
1,645,937,000 zloti in 1929, and to only 737,830,000 zloti in 1932, a cur-
tailment of 55 per cent. (There are no official figures for the years 1933-34
as yet.) The eight-hour day has been abolished. A series of new fascist laws
have deprived the working class of its small gains in the field of unemploy-
ment and health insurance, accident and disablement benefits, etc.
Capitalist “rationalization,” that is, the ruthless sweating system, en-
couraged by the government and introduced by the employers in the facto-
ries and mines, has resulted in an unprecedented increase of accidents in
industry. It is sufficient to state that in the mining industry alone, in the years
1927 to 1932, according to official figures, 1,039 miners were killed, 7,471
seriously injured, and 97,331 sustained general injuries – out of a total num-
ber of slightly over 100,000 men working in the coal industry in these years.
In Japan in the coal industry the daily wage of a man in 1930 was 1.72
yen and in 1933, 1.11 yen; the wage of a woman in 1930 was 1.52 yen and
in 1933 0.73 yen. Children working as helpers receive from 5 to 10 yen per
month. In the textile industry of Japan, where girls often work as long as
fifteen hours a day, they receive from three to five shillings a week and a
place in the factory barracks.
The following eloquent item appeared in a Japanese newspaper in De-
cember 1933:
“A group of ten girls were detained by the police. In spite of the
107
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
cold they were wandering about in their summer apparel. At the ex-
amination it transpired that they had run away from a weaving mill,
as they could no longer endure the arduous regime of a working day
of fifteen hours without a break, and the bad conditions. When they
were advised to return to the mill, the girls replied they would rather
die.”
Similar news items in the Japanese papers are frequently seen.
REVIEW QUESTIONS
1. In what respect does the value of labour power differ from the value of
other commodities?
2. How does the form of wages help to mask capitalist exploitation?
3. What is the significance of the struggle of labour unions under capitalism?
4. Under what conditions is it more advantageous for the capitalist to pay on
the basis of timework and under what conditions on the basis of piece-
work?
5. How is the difference in the rates of wages in different countries to be
explained?
6. What gives rise to the existence of a reserve army of labour?
7. What is the effect of the general law of capitalist accumulation?
8. What causes the impoverishment of the working class under capitalism?
108
CHAPTER VI
Division of Surplus Value Among the Capitalists
Equalization of the rate of profit
We already know that surplus value is created only by the labour of
workers. But the various enterprises do not employ the same number of
workers. Moreover, the greatest number of men is not always employed by
the enterprise which has the greatest capital investments. Let us take two
capitalists, each having the same amount of capital – a million dollars. One
has built an electric power station equipped with all the latest improvements.
The other has opened up a stone quarry where much manual labour is re-
quired. Only fifty workers are employed at the electric power station
whereas five hundred are employed at the quarry. The question arises: will
the owner of the quarry get ten times more profit than the owner of the elec-
tric power station?
We know that for capitalism the aim of production is to make profit. If
operating quarries (with the same outlay of capital) were more profitable
than operating electric power stations, many fortune hunters would be found
who would go into the quarry business. On the other hand, few would care
to invest their capital in electric power stations. But we already know now
what this would lead to: the price of quarried stone would drop and the price
of electric power would rise. The question may, however, be asked, what are
the limits within which these prices may range?
Let us assume that prices have changed to the extent that both enter-
prises yield the same profits. Will prices still change? Obviously not. There-
fore no owner of an electric power station will find it more profitable to go
into the quarry business: both enterprises have the same advantages.
Capitalist industry consists not of one or two enterprises, however, but
of a tremendous number of plants, factories, etc. The amount of capital in-
vested in each one of them is, of course, different. But all these investments
differ among themselves in their organic composition, i.e., in the relation
between constant and variable capital. The greater the constant capital in
comparison with the variable capital, the higher the organic composition of
capital. On the contrary, one speaks of a low organic composition of capital
when the variable capital is greater in comparison with the constant capital.
We can therefore say that the electric power station is characterized by a
high organic composition of capital. In other enterprises we shall find, on the
contrary, a low organic composition of capital. In which cases will this be? It
is not difficult to answer this question. We find a low organic composition of
capital whenever many workers are employed while the cost of buildings,
machinery, etc., is not very great. Let us take, for example, a contractor mak-
ing embankments, etc., for a railroad construction job – his expenditure of
109
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
constant capital is not very great. He buys some wheel-barrows, picks and
shovels, and that is all. But he will employ many labourers: the greater part
of his capital will go for the hiring of labour power.
Since surplus value is created only by the labour of the workers, enter-
prises with a low organic composition of capital appear to be the most prof-
itable. But the struggle for profits among the capitalists leads to the equaliza-
tion of profits with the same amount of capital invested. The ratio of the
profits of the capitalist to the amount of capital invested is called the rate of
profit. For instance, if by investing a million in an enterprise the capitalist
gets profits to the amount of a hundred thousand, his rate of profit is one-
tenth, or 10 per cent. Competition among the capitalists leads to the law of
the general or average rate of profit. This law, like all the laws of the capi-
talist system, enforces itself amidst ceaseless fluctuations in the struggle of
all against all.
We shall show in an example how the rate of profit is equalized in capi-
talist society. For the sake of simplicity we shall assume that there are only
three capitals (or three groups of capital) in society, all of the same amount,
but differing in organic composition. Let us assume the amount of capital in
each to be 100 units. The first consists of 70 units of constant capital and 30
units of variable capital, the second of 80 constant and 20 variable, and the
third of 90 constant and 10 variable. Let the rate of surplus value in all three
enterprises or groups of enterprises be the same and equal 100 per cent. This
means that every worker works half a day to earn his wages and the other
half day for the capitalist. In this case the surplus value obtained by each
enterprise will equal the amount of variable capital, i.e., in the first – 30
units of surplus value, in the second – 20, in the third – 10. If commodities
produced in capitalist enterprises would sell at their value, then the first en-
terprise would get 30 units of profit, the second – 20, the third – 10. But the
amount of capital invested in each of the three is the same. Such a situation
would be very welcome to the first capitalist, but not at all so to the third. In
such a case it is more advantageous for the capitalist of the third group to
transfer to the first group. This leads to competition among the capitalists in
the first group which compels them to lower prices and at the same time
gives the capitalists in the third group the possibility of raising prices, so that
the profit in all three groups is the same.
This course of equalization in the rates of profit can be shown more
graphically in the following tabulation:
110
DIVISION OF SURPLUS VALUE AMONG THE CAPITALISTS
* Ibid., p. 22.
112
DIVISION OF SURPLUS VALUE AMONG THE CAPITALISTS
profit for himself. This is self-evident, otherwise he would not install ma-
chinery. But the development of technical improvements, expressing itself in
a higher organic composition of capital, calls forth consequences which are
beyond the power of the individual capitalist to remedy. This consequence is
the tendency towards a lower general (or average) rate of profit.
“An increase in the productivity of labour means a more rapid
growth of constant capital as compared with variable capital. Inas-
much as surplus value is a function of variable capital alone, it is
obvious that the rate of profit (the ratio of surplus value to the whole
capital, and not to its variable part alone) has a tendency to fall.
Marx makes a detailed analysis of this tendency and of the circum-
stances that incline to favour it or to counteract it.”*
Among the counteracting circumstances comes first of all the increase
in the rate of exploitation of the workers. It must further be kept in mind that
with the increase of the productivity of labour, the value of machinery and
equipment, etc., falls. If one worker used to operate two looms and now op-
erates sixteen, it is necessary to remember that now the value of the looms is
lower.
Sixteen looms do not cost eight times as much now as two did formerly,
but only five or perhaps four times as much. Hence, the fraction of constant
capital that falls to one worker is not eight times greater than it was, but only
five or four times greater. There are also other causes for the retardation of
the fall in the rate of profit.
It must also be understood that the reduction in the rate of profit does
not signify a decrease in the mass of profit, that is, in the full amount of sur-
plus value squeezed out of the working class. On the contrary, the mass of
capitalist profit grows steadily because capital continues to grow, the mass
of workers who are being exploited increases, the degree of exploitation be-
comes greater.
However, the tendency towards a lower rate of profit still exists and ex-
erts a powerful influence on the entire development of capitalism. This ten-
dency towards a decrease in the rate of profit greatly sharpens the contradic-
tions of capitalism. The capitalists try to counterbalance the falling off in the
rate of profit by increasing the exploitation of the workers, which leads to a
number of contradictions between the proletariat and the bourgeoisie. The
fall in the rate of profit sharpens the struggle within the camp of the capital-
ists. In order to save themselves from this tendency capitalists establish en-
terprises in backward countries, where hands are cheaper, the rate of exploi-
tation is higher and the organic composition of capital is lower than in the
* Ibid.
113
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
highly industrialized countries. In addition, the capitalists combine in all
kinds of unions (trusts, cartels, etc.) in order to keep prices at higher levels,
trying thus to increase their profits, to keep the rate of profit from falling.
During periods of crisis, when all the contradictions of capitalism grow
most acute, the contradictions caused by the tendency for the rate of profit to
fall become clearly apparent.
Commercial capital and its income
As we have already said, under capitalist economy things are produced
not for immediate use, but for sale. Hence the troubles of the entrepreneur
are not over when the commodities have been produced: they have yet to be
sold. The capitalist has to sell the commodities he has produced in order to
turn his capital into money again.
Under developed capitalist economy the producer does not wait for the
consumer to come to him for the commodities. As a rule, the manufacturer
sells his goods to an intermediary merchant (middleman) and the latter man-
ages the further movement of the commodities to the consumers, to whom
they will be sold.
Everyone knows that for trade, capital is necessary. Without means the
merchant cannot fulfil the function of bringing the commodities to the pur-
chaser, the consumer. If the industrialist had to sell his goods himself he
would have to expend a definite amount of capital on equipping a store, hir-
ing clerks, etc. Hence, the industrialist lets the merchant take care of this,
giving him a share of the profit.
The profit of commercial capital thus consists of part of the surplus
value which the industrialist concedes to the merchant. Expending a certain
amount of capital, the merchant must receive the usual rate of profit on his
capital. If his profit is less than the average it will be unprofitable to engage
in commerce and the merchant will transfer his capital to industry.
The merchant not only serves as an intermediary for commodities pro-
duced at capitalist plants and factories, he also buys commodities from peas-
ants, artisans and handicraftsmen.
In some village, say, the locksmith trade has flourished for ages. The
handicraftsmen themselves find it difficult to locate a market for their prod-
ucts; their immediate region already has a sufficient supply of looks. A
buyer comes, who purchases a big lot, takes it to another part of the country
where he sells it advantageously. In selling the locks the buyer receives their
value, while the price for which he purchased them from the handicraftsmen
was very low. Part of the difference between the sales prices and the pur-
chase price goes to pay various expenses: packing, transporting, etc. The
remainder constitutes his profit, the gain received from the trade. Thus
commercial capital exploits the small independent commodity producers,
gradually transforming them into its workmen, working at home. In this way
114
DIVISION OF SURPLUS VALUE AMONG THE CAPITALISTS
the merchant exacts his profit from simple commodity production.
Forms of commerce, speculation
Under modern capitalist economy trade is not carried on only with arti-
cles of consumption. On the contrary, a tremendous number of commercial
deals are transacted with commodities which are needed for further produc-
tion or for transport:
A textile mill buys cotton, coal, machinery, looms, dyes. A machine-
building plant buys coal, iron and machinery. Railroads buy vast quantities
of rails, ties, railroad-cars and locomotives.
It is necessary to distinguish between wholesale and retail trade. The
manufacturer customarily sells his goods to a wholesaler. The wholesaler
resells the goods to smaller tradesmen who, in their turn, sell them retail to
the consumer.
The structure of the trade apparatus in capitalist countries is very com-
plex. Big deals are transacted at produce exchanges. Some commodities pass
through a number of hands before coming to the ultimate consumer. The
participants in these deals and resales often do not even see the commodi-
ties: usually only warehouse receipts are sold which merely confirm the
presence of the commodities and confer the right to receive them. It is clear
that not all goods can be dealt with in this way; for this it is necessary that
the goods be of strict uniformity, that the quality be easily established and
noted in the corresponding warehouse documents.
Frequently, merchants buy goods at the produce exchange not for the
purpose of selling them to the consumer but only because they expect a rise
in the market price so that it will be possible for them to exact a profit on the
resale of these goods. Actually, prices fluctuate, dependent upon a number
of causes, which it is difficult or simply impossible to foresee. Let us say
that at the beginning of the summer a good harvest is expected and the price
of grain falls; if later the harvest suddenly seems to be worse than was ex-
pected, there is usually a sharp rise in grain prices.
This creates the opportunity for speculation. Speculation is inseparably
bound up with the whole nature of capitalist commerce. The gain which falls
to the share of the speculator is the loss of hundreds and thousands of people
who take part in the production of or in trade with the commodities which
are the subject of speculation.
Loan-capital and credit
In capitalist society it is not only the capitalist who owns an industrial or
commercial enterprise who receives an unearned income. Under capitalism a
continually increasing number of parasites crop up, who receive tremendous
incomes without doing any work whatsoever, merely because they are in
possession of an enormous capital, possess a great amount of money.
How does the money of these capitalists increase?
115
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
The owners of money capital usually keep their money in a bank. The
bank pays a definite rate of interest on deposits.
But where does the bank get the means with which to pay out this inter-
est? Money that lies in the vaults of the bank in the: form of gold or bills
does not increase of itself.
Capitalism knows only one source for the increase of capital; this source
lies in production: in the plant, in the factory, the mine, the agricultural en-
terprise, etc.
Therefore, a modern bank does not hide away and hold on to the money
which is deposited with it. It leaves only enough money in the vaults to meet
the usual demands of the depositors. Experience has shown that in ordinary
times only a small proportion of the depositors call for the return of their
money daily. The money which they withdraw is usually covered by new
incoming deposits. Of course, things take a different turn in case of any
unusual event, as in times of crisis, war, etc. Then the entire mass of
depositors suddenly, all together, demand the return of their money. If the
bank cannot make adequate preparations for this attack and gather into its
vaults a sufficient amount of money by means of borrowing from other
banks, from the government, etc., and if it does not succeed in abating the
“run” on the bank, it “fails.” This means that it declares itself unable to pay
back its depositors. A bank failure means the ruin of many capitalists, the
wiping out of the savings of the petty bourgeoisie, etc. A bank failure thus
only aggravates the crisis.
Under ordinary circumstances, however, the bank can keep compara-
tively little money in its vaults and yet be able to satisfy the demands of all
the depositors who wish to withdraw their money. The bank lends the re-
maining money to capitalists who are in need of funds.
We already know for what purposes the capitalist needs money. He
needs it to use as capital, to be used for production. It makes; no difference
that he does not get the money permanently, but only for a definite period of
time. In the production and sale of his commodities, he realizes various sums
of money at various times. From the money thus received the capitalist can
repay the bank loan. It must also be remembered that, under developed capi-
talism, banks not only grant loans to capitalists for more or less short terms,
but that they also invest vast sums of money in industry for very long terms.
The industrial capitalist uses the money received from the bank as capi-
tal. With the help of his capital he expands production on a much wider scale
than he could have done if he had not obtained the loan. The distinguishing
feature of loan capital thus consists in the fact that it is applied in production
not by the capitalist to whom it belongs, but by another. By using the loan
obtained from the bank in his enterprise the industrial capitalist who re-
ceived the loan can hire more workers: hence obtain more surplus value.
The industrial capitalist has to pay part of this surplus value to the bank,
116
DIVISION OF SURPLUS VALUE AMONG THE CAPITALISTS
for the capital it put at his disposal. If he borrowed $1,000 and must repay
$1,070 at the end of a year, it is said that the bank charges 7 per cent on
money loaned.
In this case the bank will pay its depositors a somewhat smaller interest
– say, 5 per cent – on money deposited. This means that of the $70 that the
bank received from the industrialist, the bank must pay $50 to the people
who deposited the $1,000. The bank’s profit will amount to $20 on this deal.
Anyone can see that this transaction is very similar to any other ordinary
commercial transaction. If a merchant bought a horse for $50 and sold it for
$70, he made $20. The bank also paid $50 and received $70, making $20
profit. The only difference is that the commodity which the bank dealt with
was not a horse nor an ordinary commodity generally, but a commodity of a
very special nature, What this commodity is we have already seen: $1,000
converted into capital and used as capital for the period of one year. The
banks trade in capital; a bank is a merchant dealing in capital.
Rate of interest
Capital is thus converted into a commodity with which transactions are
carried on in various ways. In these transactions the price of capital is estab-
lished. In our case $70 was the price paid by the industrialist for the use of
$1,000 worth of capital for a period of one year. This price was paid by the
entrepreneur to the merchant of capital – the bank. In its turn the bank paid
the owners of this capital $50 for the right to use it for one year.
The question now arises, what does this price depend on, what deter-
mines the rate of interest paid for capital?
This rate is subject to frequent change. Capitalists often say: money is
cheap now, or: money is dear now. In the first case this means that money
can be borrowed at low rates of interest, in the second case, on the contrary,
a high rate of interest must be paid. As in every commercial transaction, the
price in this case is ultimately determined by supply and demand. If in a
given month very many capitalists need additional money and determine to
get it at any cost, then the demand on money for loans is great. Let us see,
however, to what extent this cost can become greater.
In our example the industrial capitalist paid the bank $70 for the use of
capital amounting to $1,000 for one year. Why was such a transaction ad-
vantageous to him? Because he very probably made 15-16 per cent profit on
the capital invested in his enterprise. This means that on every $1,000 in-
vested, the entrepreneur realized $150-160 in profit. After paying the bank
$70 he still had $80-90 left. This is the difference between the rate of profit
obtained in industry and the rate of interest paid to the bank.'
Should the rate of interest rise because of the demand for loans, this rise
evidently has its limits. The bank may demand $80-90 instead of $70. It will
still be of advantage to the industrialist to take the loan. But if the bank will
117
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
demand $150-160 he will refuse. Under these terms he would get no profit
but only much trouble.
Thus, in rising, the rate of interest is limited by the average rate of profit
of the entrepreneur. It is usually considerably less than the average profit.
Only in rare cases (during crises) does it reach this level. On the other hand,
with an increase in the supply of money over the demand the rate of interest
paid for its use will fall.
Depending on circumstances, the rate of interest in this case may fall
exceedingly low, although, of course, no one will lend money gratis.
REVIEW QUESTIONS
1. How is the difference in the organic composition of capital in various
branches of industry to be explained?
2. How is the rate of profit equalized?
3. What determines the price of production?
4. Does the sale of commodities at the price of production contradict Marx’s
teaching on value?
5. What are the causes of the tendency for the fall in the rate of profit?
6. Where does the profit of commercial capitalists come from?
7. How does a bank trade in capital?
118
CHAPTER VII
Capitalism in Agriculture
Antithesis between city and village
Until capitalism became widespread there was no such thing as modern
industry. There were no gigantic metallurgical plants employing thousands
of workers, there were no oil derricks, no textile mills with their hundreds of
thousands of humming looms and shuttles. Before capitalism there were no
railroads or steamships. Large-scale industry was created by capitalism: pre-
vious to large-scale industry there were only artisans and handicraftsmen in
its place.
It is different with agriculture. Long before capitalism, people occupied
themselves with tilling the soil, cattle-breeding, raising all kinds of animals
and plants useful to man. When capitalism arose agriculture was in the state
of feudalism. The development of capitalism rapidly began to destroy the
mainstays of agriculture, but in many countries, nevertheless, remnants of
the feudal system proved very vital and survived even after the triumph of
capitalism. The most important survival is the retention of land in the hands
of landlords, in the hands of private owners generally.
Capitalism effects the separation of industry from agriculture. Under
the former pre-capitalist relations, clothes, shoes, and a number of other
articles for everyday use were produced within the peasant family or by
peasant artisans. Capitalism creates textile and shoe industries, which
because of the low cost and superior quality of their production supplant
peasant production.
But capitalism not only separates all new branches of industry from ag-
riculture. Capitalism creates a gulf between city and village, creates and con-
tinually deepens the antithesis between industry and agriculture. In industry
the development of capitalism brings with it a rapid growth of technical im-
provement; every decade, sometimes every year, brings new methods of
production, new improvements, new machinery. Agriculture, even in the
most advanced capitalist countries, lags behind this tempestuous growth of
industry. Dragging agriculture out of its previous narrow limits of natural
economy and freeing it from the trammels of serfdom, capitalism at the same
time brings with it the ever-growing oppression of exploitation for the broad
masses of the village, condemning them to ignorance, backwardness and
poverty. The many millions of the village population, the peasants, even in
the most advanced countries, are cut off from city civilization, live in a state
of ignorance and backwardness.
The rapid growth of industry and the extreme backwardness of agricul-
ture – this is one of the deepest contradictions of the capitalist system, giv-
ing rise to all kinds of upheavals and crises, foreshadowing and preparing
119
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
the inevitable downfall of capitalism.
“Agriculture lags behind industry in its development – this is a
phenomenon inherent in all capitalist countries and is one of the
most deep-seated reasons for upsetting the proportion among the
different branches of the national economy, for crises and high
prices.
“Capital has freed agriculture from feudalism, dragged it into
the commercial whirlpool and together with this into the economic
development of the world, it has torn it away from stagnation, the
barbarism of the Middle Ages and patriarchalism. Nevertheless,
capitalism has not only failed to remove the oppression, exploitation
and poverty of the masses, but, on the contrary, it creates these mis-
eries in a new form and re-establishes their old forms on a ‘modern’
basis. Not only is the contradiction between industry and agriculture
not removed by capitalism, but, on the contrary, it is widened and
sharpened to an ever greater extent. The pressure of capital, which
grows principally in the spheres of commerce and industry, falls
more and more heavily upon agriculture.”*
Ground rent
The prime prerequisite for production in agriculture is land. In all capi-
talist countries land is the private property of individual landowners. In al-
most all of these countries tremendous tracts of land are in the hands of the
landlords – large-scale owners who do not work the land themselves, but
rent it out. The landlords have retained their large estates from the days of
serfdom. They live as before on the fat of the land at the expense of the la-
bour of others. Merely the form in which they exploit the peasants, squeeze
out their income, has changed. Only in the Soviet Union has the land been
nationalized, i.e., taken away from the landlords and all other private own-
ers, and ownership has been vested in the proletarian state which turns part
over to the toiling peasantry, giving land to all toiling peasants without
charge, and employing part for the organization of large-scale state farms
which raise produce for supplying the workers and to satisfy the require-
ments of state industries serving these same workers.
Under capitalism the owner of the land receives rent. Anyone who
wants to engage in agriculture and has the necessary capital for it must first
of all rent a piece of land, at a definite rental and for a definite period of
time, from the one who owns this land. The owner of the land exercises his
rights of ownership to collect tribute from all those who need land. This
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XVII, “New Data on the Laws of the
Development of Capitalism in Agriculture,” p. 639, Russian ed.
120
CAPITALISM IN AGRICULTURE
tribute received by the landowner is called ground rent.
It is necessary to discriminate between differential rent and absolute
rent. First, let us take differential rent. We know that in industry the value of
commodities and their cost of .production are determined by the average
conditions of production. This is not so in agriculture. Land area is limited
and cannot be increased as needed. Different pieces of land are not of the
same fertility. An important role is also played by the distance of the land
from large cities, rivers and oceans or the railroads. From better soil with the
same expenditure of capital a better harvest is obtained. Land which is ad-
vantageously located saves the husbandman expenses which are required to
transport products when the land is located in isolated districts. The cost of
production of agricultural products is determined by the conditions of pro-
duction on the worst soil, otherwise capitalist entrepreneurs would not work
the worst soil but would transfer their capital to industry. But if such is the
case those working the better soil realize an excess income. Who gets this
income? It is clear that it falls into the hands of the landowner.
But besides this differential rent the landowner also gets absolute rent.
The land is a monopoly of private owners. This monopoly of land ownership
prevents the free transition of capital from industry to agriculture. In order to
work the land, the permission of the landowner must be obtained. Techni-
cally, agriculture is on a lower level than industry. Therefore the organic
composition of capital in agriculture is lower than in industry. This means
that with the same capital invested, more surplus value is produced in agri-
culture than in industry. If there were a free flow of capital between agricul-
ture and industry the rate of profit would be equalized by means of competi-
tion. But such freedom does not exist because of the private ownership of
land. Hence agricultural products are sold at prices above the price of pro-
duction. The excess thus obtained goes into the pockets of the landowner
and is called absolute ground rent. Marx says that absolute ground rent is
tribute paid to the landowner.
Lenin gives the following concise characterization of the conditions
which give rise to differential and absolute rent.
“...in the first place, we have the monopoly of the use (capital-
ist) of the land. This monopoly originates in the limitedness of land,
and is therefore inevitable in any capitalist society. This monopoly
leads to the price of grain being determined by the conditions of
production on the worst land; the surplus profit, obtained by the in-
vestment of capital on the best land, or by a more productive in-
vestment of capital, forms differential rent. This rent arises quite in-
dependently of private property in land, which simply enables the
landowner to collect it from the farmer. In the second place, we
have the monopoly of private property in land. Neither logically nor
121
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
historically is this monopoly inseparably linked up with the previ-
ous monopoly.
“This kind of monopoly is not essential for capitalist society
and for capitalist organization of agriculture. On the one hand, we
can quite easily imagine capitalist agriculture without private prop-
erty in land, and many consistent bourgeois economists demanded
the nationalization of land. On the other hand, even in practice we
have capitalist organization of agriculture without private ownership
in land, for example, on state and communal lands. Consequently, it
is absolutely essential to draw a distinction between these two kinds
of monopolies, and consequently, it is also necessary to recognize
that absolute rent, which is created by private property in land, ex-
ists side by side with differential rent.”*
Source of ground rent
The Marxian theory of rent, explained above, issues from the following
premises. The landowner leases his land. The lessee is a capitalist who
works his land by means of wage labour. In such a case it is not difficult to
understand the source of the ground rent that goes to the pockets of the land-
owner. The wage workers produce surplus value with their unpaid labour.
This surplus value first gets to the capitalist-lessee who divides it into two
parts: one part he keeps – this is his entrepreneur’s profit, the profit on his
invested capital – and the other part, a definite excess over and above this
profit, he is forced to give to the landowner. This part of the surplus value is
the rent. It is perfectly evident that absolute and differential rent, like any
other income derived without labour under capitalism, can have only one
source – surplus value produced by the labour of the working class.
“All ground rent is surplus value, the product of surplus la-
bour,Ӡ says Marx.
“The theory of rent presupposes that the entire agricultural
population has been split up completely into landowners, capitalists
and wage labourers. This is an ideal of capitalism but by no means
its reality,”‡ says Lenin.
In reality matters are much more complicated. Nevertheless the theory
of rent maintains its full force even under the more complicated circum-
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XVII, “New Data on the Laws of the
Development of Capitalism in Agriculture,” p. 619, Russian ed.
127
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
when they assert the advantages of small-scale over large-scale farming.
They praise the patience and endurance of the small farm owners to the
skies. But they consciously avoid all reference to the privations which fall to
his lot.
Distribution of land and the conditions of
farmers in capitalist countries
We have already mentioned that in capitalist countries by far the great-
est part of the land is in the hands of a small group of large landlords and
capitalists. In capitalist countries, the vast majority of small farmers taken
together have less land than the handful of large landowners. Most is con-
centrated in the hands of the large landowners.
In Germany, according to the census of 1925, 60 per cent of the farms
having an area of up to 2 hectares each constitute only 6.5 per cent of all the
land, while 11.5 per cent of estates of over 10 hectares each constitute 67 per
cent of all the land. This means that a handful of large estates (about one-
tenth of all the farms) have two-thirds of the entire land while the over-
whelming majority of small farmers have only one-sixteenth part of all the
land. In France, in 1908, farms of less than 1 hectare constituted 38 per cent
of all the farms; their total landholdings amounted to only 2.5 per cent of all
the land. Thus two-fifths of the farmers had only one-fortieth of the land.
But estates of over 10 hectares constituting 16 per cent of all the farms had
74.5 per cent of the land, that is, approximately three-quarters of all the land.
In Poland, in 1921, farms of less than 2 hectares made up 34 per cent of all
the farms; these had only 3.5 per cent of the land. But estates of over 100
hectares each, making up only 0.5 per cent of all the farms, owned almost
half (44 per cent) of the land. In Hungary half the land is owned by 99 per
cent of all the farms (small and middle-sized farms) while the other half is
owned by only 1 per cent – large landowners. In other words 10,000 land-
lords have as much land as almost 1,000,000 small farmers.
Before the revolution in Russia the greater part of the land was also in
the hands of landlords, the royal family, the monasteries and the kulaks
(rich, exploiting peasants). Thirty thousand of the largest landowners of pre-
revolutionary Russia held 70,000,000 dessiatins* of land. Ten million of the
poorest peasant farms also held about 70,000,000 dessiatins of land, thus
making a proportion of about 324 poor peasant farms to each large estate
owned by a landlord. A large landlord’s estate consisted of 2,300 dessiatins
on the average, a peasant farm – of 7 dessiatins of land. Insufficient land or
no land at all – that was the lot of the village poor. Only the October
Revolution drove the parasites off the land and turned it over to the working
peasantry.
132
CHAPTER VIII
Reproduction and Crises under Capitalism
Means of production and means of consumption
If we take any country we can see that from year to year definite quanti-
ties of the most diverse products are produced: bread, calico, locomotives,
ploughs, dwelling houses; Coal, machinery, sugar, rubbers, etc.
The ultimate destination of these products of human labour is also dif-
ferent. Bread, sugar and meat are consumed by people, cloth serves to clothe
people, houses are used to live in. A host of other products of human labour
have an entirely different fate: the plough goes to the agriculturist for tilling
the soil, machines and factory buildings serve for the further production of
commodities; locomotives and railroad cars serve to transport goods and
people.
Those products of human labour which serve for the immediate satisfac-
tion of human wants, the personal needs of food, clothing, amusement, shel-
ter, etc., are called means of consumption; those products of human labour
which serve for the further production of goods are called means of produc-
tion. It is important to remember that ultimately all products of human la-
bour are called upon to satisfy one or another want of an individual or of a
social group. The only difference is that some things serve this purpose di-
rectly – these are objects of personal use – whereas other things serve only
for the production of the things that go for direct use – to this category be-
long the means of production.
There are also a number of things that can serve both as objects of direct
consumption and as means of production. The simplest example of this is
coal, which is used in the steam boilers at plants and electric power stations
as a means of production, and in fireplaces in homes as an object of con-
sumption. Everyone can easily think of a number of other things that serve
both purposes.
Under capitalism the management of production is in the hands of indi-
vidual entrepreneurs or groups of them. The manufacturer conducts his enter-
prise, as we have already seen, with only one end in view – profit, personal
gain. It is therefore a matter of complete indifference to him whether he pro-
duces locomotives or cigar-lighters, plain calico or fine perfumes. He is after
only one thing: more profit. It is perfectly evident that capitalists do not make
any distinction between the production of objects of consumption and means
of production. Whether the manufacturer will produce rubbers or rubber belt-
ing depends only on one thing – which will be more profitable to him?
What is reproduction?
The mass of goods produced in any country is in continual motion. Ob-
jects of consumption move from the manufacturer to the consumer. There
133
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
they disappear: some serve for a comparatively long time in satisfying hu-
man needs (as clothing or books, for example), others disappear fairly rap-
idly (as food). Means of production produced at plants and factories or ob-
tained from the bowels of the earth are also put to use. Some of these prod-
ucts are also short-lived (coal or oil, for instance), others, on the contrary,
are used up very slowly and need to be replaced only after a long period of
time (machinery, for example).
One thing is clear. In order for society to exist, for the economic system
to be preserved, it is necessary that definite quantities of goods be produced
not only once, but continuously, over and over again. This everyone knows
to be a fact.
Shirts are worn out, but new shirts are produced at factories. Bread is
consumed, but at the same time fresh grain is ripening in the fields. Coal is
burned, but all the time new coal is being mined. Locomotives wear out,
machines become antiquated, but human labour is constantly busy making
new ones.
In all these cases, despite the big differences between these products one
can observe one thing which they all have in common. Various kinds of
commodities are produced, used and produced again. There is a constant
reproduction of things.
“Whatever the form of the process of production in a society, it
must be a continuous process, must continue to go periodically
through the same phases. A society can no more cease to produce
than it can cease to consume. When viewed, therefore, as a
connected whole, and as flowing on with incessant renewal, every
social process of production is, at the same time, a process of
reproduction.”*
Simple and extended reproduction
We must distinguish between simple and extended reproduction. If the
same quantity of a product is produced in a society year in and year out – we
have simple reproduction. In this case, everything that is produced in a year
is consumed. But the development of capitalism implies a rapid growth of
production. A greater quantity of all kinds of products is being produced
from year to year. We have extended production; reproduction takes place
on an extended basis. Capitalism brings about a change from the old stag-
nant conditions of society to its tempestuous development. Hence extended
reproduction is a characteristic of capitalism.
Reproduction under capitalism
Reproduction takes place in any society, regardless of the social system.
* Ibid., p. 578.
135
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
private property of the capitalist class. In a previous chapter, when we
studied primitive accumulation, we learned that capitalist private property
originates in robbery, violence and lawlessness. But once it has arisen
capitalist ownership of the means of production is maintained and extended
from year to year.
Capital brings surplus value to its owner. We have already studied the
source of surplus value. We have also seen in what forms and how this sur-
plus value is distributed among the different sections of the ruling classes.
It may seem at first as if the entrepreneur were free to do as he pleased
with his profit. And in fact capitalism knows no proscriptions in this respect.
If a textile manufacturer has made $100,000 in profit in a year he can do
whatever he wishes with this money. If he is a glutton – he can spend it on
food; if he is a drunkard – spend it on drink. And there are many people
among the capitalist class who actually spend their profits on such things.
However, this is not the essence of the matter.
Notwithstanding the absence of any written laws the capitalist, with very
rare exceptions, uses part of his profits to expand his enterprise. We call this
addition of part of the surplus value to the original capital capitalist
accumulation.
Of his $100,000 profit for the year our manufacturer will put $60-80,000
back into his business to expand his factory, buy new and improved machin-
ery. Two forces compel him to do this: the desire for gain and the fear of
competition. Capitalism is distinguished by just this feature – that the desire
for gain knows no limits. No matter how big the capital of the entrepreneur,
and no matter how enormous his profits, he will steadily try to increase his
wealth and his profits. And there is only one way to achieve this: to accumu-
late capital by adding to it from his profits. Watching his competitors our
manufacturer cannot calmly employ his entire profits for his personal use,
for all kinds of unproductive expenditures. He sees his competitors exerting
every effort in an attempt to improve their business, expand, improve the
technical processes, in order to produce commodities more cheaply and of
better qualify and thus crush competition. If our manufacturer does not wish
to be crushed, he must reinvest a large part of his profits in his business.
Thus, even though there are no laws compelling accumulation under
capitalism, elemental forces effect this compulsion and make the majority of
capitalists accumulate a part of their profits. The accumulation of surplus
value produced by the proletariat is a necessary condition for extended re-
production.
Concentration and centralization of capital
Accumulating a part of his profits annually the manufacturer becomes
the owner of ever more capital. If his enterprise was previously valued at
$1,000,000, with the gradual accumulation of profits to the amount of say
136
REPRODUCTION AND CRISES UNDER CAPITALISM
$50-70,000 a year, at the end of some ten years our manufacturer will have
$1,500,000 to $1,700,000, i.e., will increase his capital one and a half or
more times. The expansion of capital through the accumulation of surplus
value is called the concentration of capital.
There is yet another method by means of which the capital of individual
capitalists grows. We have already seen how the stronger enterprise crushes
the weaker, the big capitalist swallows up his smaller and weaker competi-
tors. Buying up the properties of his ruined competitors considerably below
their value, or joining them to his own enterprise by some other means (in
payment of debts, for instance) the big manufacturer increases his capital.
Such cases of merging several capitals is the result of a struggle which
brings the ruin of some and the victory of others. Often, however, the merg-
ing of capital proceeds peacefully: by the organization of stock companies,
corporations, etc. Of this phase we shall speak more in detail later. Centrali-
zation of capital is the term given to all cases of the merging of capital by
the joining of several enterprises into one.
Concentration and centralization of capital bring about the accumulation
of capital in the hands of a continually smaller number of rich men. A hand-
ful of billionaires, owners of tremendous fortunes, control untold wealth.
The fate of tens and hundreds of thousands of people is in their hands. Con-
centration and: centralization of capital thus lead to a sharpening of class
contradictions, to a more marked division of capitalist society into two op-
posed classes: a handful of the biggest capitalists and the mass of exploited
proletarians.
Concentration and centralization of capital, concentrating tremendous
wealth in the hands of a few persons, open the way for the creation of tre-
mendous enterprises. As we have already seen, large-scale industry is much
more advantageous than small. It is no wonder then that capitalism puts to
the fore ever larger and larger enterprises in which tremendous numbers of
workers are employed. Here, for instance, are the comparative figures show-
ing the changes in the size of enterprises in the U.S.A. over a period of thirty
years (average per enterprise):
1889 1899 1909 1919
Workers 8.1 13.8 24.1 38.0
Capital (in thousands of dollars) 6.7 19.0 68.7 154.1
Production (in thousands of 13.4 28.1 77.2 216.9
dollars)
Even more characteristic of the rapid growth of large-scale enterprises is
the case of pre-revolutionary Russia, where the distribution of workers per
enterprise according to size was as follows:
137
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Enterprise* 1895 1915
(Percentage) (Percentage)
Large (employing more than 500 workers) 45.2 61.2
Medium (employing from 50-500 workers) 38.9 30.6
Small (employing from 10-50 workers) 15.9 8.2
In 1895 the average number of workers employed in an enterprise was
98.5, in 1915 this figure had grown to 173.4.
Here is a more detailed table showing the process of concentration of
industry in Russia for the ten years from 1901 to 1910 (inclusive):
Group of enterprises Number of enterprises Number of workers
(in thousands)
1901 1910 1901 1910
Employing up to 50 work- 12,740 9,909 244 220
ers
Employing from 51 to 100 2,428 2,201 171 159
workers
Employing from 101 to 500 2,288 2,213 492 508
workers
Employing from 501 to 403 433 269 303
1,000 workers
Employing over 1,000 243 324 526 713
workers
Total 18,102 15,080 1,702 1,903
* Smaller enterprises, employing less than ten workers, are not taken into
account.
138
REPRODUCTION AND CRISES UNDER CAPITALISM
trate production to an ever greater extent. Ever greater numbers of
workers are gathered in a smaller number of enterprises, and the en-
tire profit from the labour of united millions of workers is pocketed
by a handful of millionaires.”
Historical tendency of capitalist accumulation
Capitalism in its development leads to an ever greater socialization of
labour. All kinds of connections between separate enterprises, regions and
entire countries are established to an unprecedented degree. Individual
spheres of industry, previously more or less independent, are broken up,
subdivided into a host of connected and mutually interdependent branches.
Capitalism unites the work of different people, tying them together with
invisible bonds. But socialization of production under capitalism does not
proceed in the interests of society as a whole, nor in the interests of the
working masses – it proceeds only in the interests of a small group of
capitalists, who are trying to increase their gains. Simultaneously with the
growth of the socialization of labour, the subdivision of labour among
enterprises, and the struggle and competition between capitalists also
increase. Only the abolition of the private ownership of the means of
production (and the transfer of this ownership to society as a whole, only the
expropriation of the bourgeoisie and the organization of socialist production
will do away with this contradiction.
The enlargement of enterprises proceeding apace with the concentration
and centralization of capital prepares all the conditions for the socialization
of the means of production, for the reconstruction of economic life on social-
ist principles. A large enterprise, where thousands of workers are employed,
is something quite different from an artisan’s workshop. Whereas society
would find it difficult to take over countless numbers of small workshops, it
is fully possible to socialize production when it is concentrated in a few huge
plants and factories.
Marx defines the historical tendency of capitalist accumulation as
follows:
“Self-earned private property, that is based, so to say, on the
fusing together of the isolated, independent labouring individual
with the conditions of his labour, is supplanted by capitalistic pri-
vate property, which rests on exploitation of the nominally free la-
bour of others, i.e., on wage labour.
“As soon as this process of transformation has sufficiently de-
composed the old society from top to bottom, as soon as the labour-
ers are turned into proletarians, their means of labour into capital, as
soon as the capitalist mode of production stands on its own feet,
then the further socialization of labour and further transformation of
the land and other means of production into socially exploited and,
139
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
therefore, common means of production, as well as the further ex-
propriation of private proprietors, takes a new form. That which is
now to be expropriated is no longer the labourer working for him-
self, but the capitalist exploiting many labourers. This expropriation
is accomplished by the action of the immanent laws of capitalistic
production itself, by the centralization of capital. One capitalist al-
ways kills many. Hand in hand with this centralization, or this ex-
propriation of many capitalists by few, develop, on an ever extend-
ing scale, the co-operative form of the labour process, the conscious
technical application of science, the methodical cultivation of the
soil, the transformation of the instruments of labour into instruments
of labour only usable in common, the economizing of all means of
production by their use as the means of production of combined, so-
cialized labour, the entanglement of all peoples in the net of the
world market, and with this, the international character of the capi-
talistic regime. Along with the constantly diminishing number of
the magnates of capital, who usurp and monopolize all advantages
of this process of transformation, grows the mass of misery, oppres-
sion, slavery, degradation, exploitation; but with this too grows the
revolt of the working class, a class always increasing in numbers,
and disciplined, united, organized by the very mechanism of the
process of capitalist production itself. The monopoly of capital be-
comes a fetter upon the mode of production, which has sprung up
and flourished along with, and under it. Centralization of the means
of production and socialization of labour at last reach a point where
they become incompatible with their capitalist integument. This in-
tegument is burst asunder. The knell of capitalist private property
sounds. The expropriators are expropriated.”*
Reproduction and sale of commodities
We have seen that every capitalist, on starting production, buys the means
of production (raw material, fuel) on the market and hires workers (i.e., buys
labour power). But now the capitalist has completed his annual production.
The raw material and fuel have been spent, the workers have expended their
year’s labour, a great amount of finished commodities, shoes, let us say, lies in
the manufacturer’s warehouse. What is needed for the renewal of production?
What is needed in order to continue the production of shoes?
It is perfectly evident that it is necessary for the manufacturer to pur-
chase a new lot of raw material and fuel, to hire his workers again for the
next year. But for this purpose he needs money. Where will the manufac-
turer obtain money? He may borrow it, but this only means that he will fi-
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. II, “Once More on the Problem of Realization,”
p. 415, Russian ed.
141
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Conditions of realization under simple and extended reproduction
Let us examine more closely the conditions in which realization of
commodities takes place under capitalist reproduction. The value of the en-
tire output of a capitalist country, like that of a single commodity, is made
up of the following three parts: 1) constant capital; 2) variable capital; 3)
surplus value. We know further that the entire mass of the various enter-
prises can be divided into two large groups: 1) enterprises producing means
of production (machinery, raw material, fuel, etc.), and 2) enterprises pro-
ducing articles of consumption.
“The problem of realization consists in finding on the market
for every part of the capitalist product another part of the product
that will be an equivalent of it, in terms of value (constant capital,
variable capital and surplus value) and in terms of its material form
(means of production, articles of consumption, particularly articles
of necessity and objects of luxury).”*
For the sake of simplicity we may assume that the entire economy of the
country is conducted on capitalist principles. In reality this is not true for any
part of the world; even in the most developed capitalist countries a certain
degree of artisan and peasant production, which is not of a capitalist nature,
persists. However, if we take such an unmixed or, as it is called, pure capi-
talist: economy, we shall have the following situation under simple repro-
duction. The entire mass of products made at the first group of enterprises
must be equal to that used up by both groups during the year. For example, if
during the year 20,000,000 tons of coal were consumed, then the annual out-
put of the mines must also equal 20,000,000 tons. If during the year 100,000
looms were used up, then the production of new looms must equal this num-
ber. As for the second group of enterprises, the entire mass of commodities
produced by them, articles of consumption, must be equal in value to the
combined income of all the workers and capitalists of both groups of enter-
prises. And in fact, since according to our assumption there are no other
classes in this society, all the articles of consumption produced must be used
up by the workers and capitalists. But the workers and capitalists can buy
only as much as their combined income will allow: the workers to the extent
of their wages, the capitalists to the extent of the surplus value.
How are the component parts of the annual product realized? The con-
stant capital of the first group will be realized within the group since it exists
in the form of means of production. The variable capital and surplus value of
the second group can also be realized within the same group since they exist
144
REPRODUCTION AND CRISES UNDER CAPITALISM
capitalism stands out – the contradiction between the social character of
production and the private-capitalist character of appropriation. Capitalist
enterprises unite many thousands of workers. The work of each enterprise is
vitally necessary to society as a whole. These enterprises employ all the
forces of social development, all the forces of technical science, the forces of
the united social labour of many hundreds and thousands of people. And
they belong to a small handful of capitalists who conduct them for their own
gain, chasing after the greatest profits.
The development of capitalism leads to a growth in the contradictions
between the bourgeoisie and the proletariat. Reproduction and accumulation
of capital lead, as we have seen, on the one hand, to the growth of the untold
wealth which belongs to a small group of capitalists and, on the other hand,
to an increase in the exploitation, oppression, misery and, at the same time,
the indignation and the will to struggle of the broad masses of the proletariat.
The basic contradiction of capitalism – the contradiction between the
social character of production and the private character of appropriation –
clearly betrays itself in the anarchy of production (i.e., in its planlessness).
This anarchy of social production peculiar to capitalism is thus characterized
by Engels:
“…every society based on commodity production has the pecu-
liarity that in it the producers have lost control of their own social
relationships. Each produces for himself, with the means of produc-
tion which happen to be at his disposal and in order to satisfy his
individual needs through the medium of exchange. No one knows
how much of the article he produces is coming onto the market, or
how much demand there is for it; no one knows whether his indi-
vidual product will meet a real need, whether he will cover his costs
or even be able to sell it at all. Anarchy reigns in social production.
But commodity production, like all other forms of production, has
its own laws, which are inherent in and inseparable from it; and
these laws assert themselves in spite of anarchy, in and through an-
archy. These laws are manifested in the sole form of social relation-
ship which continues to exist, in exchange, and enforce themselves
on the individual producers as compulsory laws of competition. At
first, therefore, they are unknown even to these producers, and have
to be discovered by them gradually, only through long experience.
They assert themselves therefore apart from the producers and
against the producers, as the natural laws of their form of produc-
tion, working blindly. The product dominates the producers.”*
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. I, “What the ‘Friends of the People’ Are and
How They Fight Against the Social-Democrats,” p. 92, Russian ed.
148
REPRODUCTION AND CRISES UNDER CAPITALISM
modities produced find no market. It is not because no one is in need of food
or clothing that they find no market; on the contrary, under capitalism the
number of those in desperate need of the bare necessities of life is tremendous.
The trouble is that the masses of the workers who stand in need of these ne-
cessities have no means of obtaining them. The market is curtailed, plants and
factories cannot get rid of their products, overproduction overtakes one branch
of industry after another. The warehouses are full of finished products, the
factories cut down production, many enterprises close altogether, the workers
are thrown out onto the streets. The growth of unemployment cuts down the
consumption of goods by the working class even more, cuts down the demand
for commodities. Tremendous masses of workers starving while the ware-
houses are full – this is the picture of capitalist crises.
Describing the devastating crisis of 1901, Lenin wrote about capitalist
crises as follows:
“Capitalist production cannot develop otherwise than in leaps –
two steps forward and one step (and sometimes two) back. As we
have already observed, capitalist production is production for sale,
the production of commodities for the market. Production is carried
on by individual capitalists, each producing on his own, and none of
them can say exactly what kind of commodities, and in what quanti-
ties, are required on the market. Production is carried on haphaz-
ardly; each producer is concerned only in excelling the others. Quite
naturally, therefore, the quantity of commodities produced may not
correspond to the demand on the market. The probability of this be-
ing the case becomes particularly great when an enormous market is
suddenly opened up in new unexplored and extensive territories.”*
Seeking their own gain, the bourgeoisie develops the production of the
most diverse commodities in a frenzied haste. To the capitalist one kind of
commodity is as good as another, so long as it gives him more profit. Every
entrepreneur tries to expand production: a greater scope promises greater
profits. It is perfectly clear that in this race for profits, in this struggle of all
against all, those complex conditions which are required for maintaining a
balance between diverse branches are not adhered to.
“Gigantic crashes have become possible and inevitable, only
because powerful social productive forces have become
subordinated to a gang of rich men, whose only concern is to make
profits.Ӡ
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. IV, Book I, pp. 171-72, International Publishers,
New York, 1929.
† Ibid., p, 172.
149
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Under capitalism, production grows spontaneously. Industry proceeds
planlessly, anarchically. The race for profits evokes a tendency towards an
unlimited expansion of production. However, this tendency meets the im-
passable barriers of capitalist relations. These barriers have their roots in the
fact that the consumption capacity of the broad proletarian masses is limited
because of their exploitation by capital.
“In order that an enterprise may make a profit the goods pro-
duced in it must be sold, a purchaser must be found for them. Now
the purchasers of these goods must be the vast mass of the population,
because these enormous enterprises produce enormous quantities of
goods. But nine-tenths of the population of all capitalist countries are
poor; they consist of workers who receive miserable wages and of
peasants who, in the main, live under even worse conditions than the
workers. Now, when, in the period of a boom, the large industrial en-
terprises set out to produce as large a quantity of goods as possible,
they throw on the market such a huge quantity of these goods that the
majority of the people, being poor, are unable to purchase them all.
The number of machines, tools, warehouses, railroads, etc., continues
to grow. From time to time, however, this process of growth is inter-
rupted because the masses of the people for whom, in the last analy-
sis, these improved instruments of production are intended, remain in
poverty, which verges on beggary.”*
Thus, inherent in capitalism, there is the deepest contradiction between
the colossal growth of production possibilities and the relatively reduced
purchasing power of the working masses. The productive forces tend to
grow without limit. In order to obtain more profits, the capitalists expand
production, improve technical processes, exploit the workers more inten-
sively. The development of credit makes it possible for individual capitalists
to expand production far beyond the limits of their own capital. The constant
trend towards a reduction in the rate of profit, peculiar to capitalism, spurs
each entrepreneur on to greater expansion. But this tendency towards an
unlimited expansion of industry inevitably comes into conflict with the lim-
ited powers of consumption of the broad masses of workers. The growth of
exploitation means not only the growth of production. It also means a reduc-
tion in the purchasing power of the masses, a curtailment of the possibility
of selling commodities. The purchasing power of the masses of workers and
peasants remains at a low level. Hence the inevitability of overproduction
crises under capitalism.
* Ibid., p, 173.
150
REPRODUCTION AND CRISES UNDER CAPITALISM
Periodicity of crises
Crises accompany capitalism from its earliest beginnings. From the very
outset of capitalist industry, crises shake capitalism at certain definite inter-
vals. Crises were born together with the capitalist system. Over a period of
one hundred years the capitalist world has been shaken by crises every eight
to twelve years. The first general crisis occurred in 1825. Then there were
recurrent crises in 1836, 1847, 1857, 1873, 1890, 1900, 1907. Beginning
with 1847, crises began to embrace not one country alone but all countries
where capitalism was developed.
As can be seen by this series of crises, they occur at definite intervals
throughout the entire development of capitalism. Capitalist crises are distin-
guished by their periodicity (i.e., they occur at regular intervals of time).
Between one crisis and another, capitalist industry passes through a certain
circle or, as it is called, cycle. In the period before the imperialist war, crises
usually gave place to depression, then this depression passed over into a
moderate revival; the revival in turn gave place to a period of prosperity
when expansion and the race for profits reached their highest point. Then a
crisis came and the cycle was begun anew.
Engels thus describes the process of development of capitalist economy
from crisis to crisis:
“...since 1825, when the first general crisis broke out, the whole
industrial and commercial world, the production and exchange of all
civilized peoples and of their more or less barbarian dependent peo-
ples have been dislocated practically once in every ten years. Trade
comes to a standstill, the markets are glutted, the products lie in
great masses, unsaleable, ready money disappears, credit vanishes,
the factories are idle, the working masses go short of food because
they have produced too much food, bankruptcy follows upon bank-
ruptcy, forced sale upon forced sale. The stagnation lasts for years,
both productive forces and products are squandered and destroyed
on a large scale, until the accumulated masses of commodities are at
last disposed of at a more or less considerable depreciation, until
production and exchange gradually begin to move again. By de-
grees the pace quickens; it becomes a trot; the industrial trot passes
into a gallop, and the gallop in turn passes into the mad onrush of a
complete industrial, commercial, credit and speculative steeple-
chase, only to land again in the end, after the most breakneck jumps
– in the ditch of a crash. And so on again and again....
“In these crises, the contradiction between social production
and capitalist appropriation comes to a violent explosion. The
circulation of commodities is for the moment reduced to nothing;
the means of circulation, money, becomes an obstacle to circulation;
151
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
all the laws of commodity production and commodity circulation
are turned upside down. The economic collision has reached its
culminating point: the mode of production rebels against the mode
of exchange....” *
The causes of the regular appearance of crises are rooted, as we have al-
ready seen, in the fundamental contradiction of capitalism – the contradic-
tion between the social character of labour and the private character of ap-
propriation. Once the crisis has appeared and devastated the economic life of
the country, a certain stimulus is necessary for the transition from depression
to revival. Such a stimulus for the revival of the basic industries producing
means of production is the re-equipment of enterprises. After the crisis
plants and factories need new, improved equipment. They order machinery
and this creates a wave of demand whose vibrations reach the most remote
industries. It can be considered that the equipment of an enterprise serves for
approximately ten years. Thus it is necessary to renew the fixed capital of an
enterprise approximately every ten years. Therefore about every ten years
industry receives the stimulus created by the necessity for renewing the
equipment of enterprises.
This picture changes in the post-war period. Capitalism now lives
through a decline, it decays while it is still alive. Now a crisis shakes its
foundations incomparably more violently than previously. The former cycli-
cal development of industry is shattered.
In many countries there has been no rise in industry at all, in others there
was a slight rise for a short time. On the other hand, the decline during the
present crisis was exceedingly great.
The significance of crises
Crises are of great significance in the entire process of capitalist devel-
opment. In times of crisis the inability of capitalism to cope with the forces
which are called to life by capitalism itself is clearly manifest. The anarchy
and the confusion of capitalist production and reproduction are revealed
with particular clarity. The crisis further reveals the predatory nature of
capitalism, which allows the greatest wealth to perish while even the most
essential needs of the broad masses of the people are left unsatisfied.
“The crisis shows that modern society can produce immeasura-
bly more goods than it does, which could be used to improve the
conditions of life of the whole of the toiling people, if the land, fac-
tories, machines, etc., did not belong to a handful of private owners,
who extract millions of profits out of the poverty of the people.Ӡ
153
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
they first have been converted into capital, into means for the ex-
ploitation of human labour power. The necessity for the means of
production and subsistence to take on the form of capital stands like
a ghost between them and the workers. It alone prevents the coming
together of the material and personal levers of production; it alone
forbids the means of production to function, the workers to work
and to live. Thus, on the one hand, the capitalist mode of production
stands convicted of its own incapacity any longer to control these
productive forces. And, on the other hand, these productive forces
themselves press forward with increasing force to put an end to the
contradiction, to rid themselves of their character as capital, to the
actual recognition of their character as social productive forces.”*
In the Communist Manifesto there is the following clear characterization
of the role of crises in capitalist production:
“Modern bourgeois society with its relations of production, of
exchange and of property, a society that has conjured up such gi-
gantic means of production and exchange, is like the sorcerer who is
no longer able to control the powers of the nether world whom he
has called up by his spells. For many a decade past the history of
industry and commerce is but the history of the revolt of modern
productive forces against modern conditions of production, against
the property relations that are the conditions for the existence of the
bourgeoisie and of its rule. It is enough to mention the commercial
crises that by their periodical return put the existence of the entire
bourgeois society on its trial, each time more threateningly. In these
crises a great part not only of the existing products but also of the
previously created productive forces are periodically destroyed. In
these crises there breaks out an epidemic that, in all earlier epochs,
would have seemed an absurdity – the epidemic of over-production.
Society suddenly finds itself put back into a state of momentary
barbarism; it appears as if a famine, a universal war of devastation
had cut off the supply of every means of subsistence; industry and
commerce seem to be destroyed. And why? Because there is too
much civilization, too much means of subsistence, too much indus-
try, too much commerce. The productive forces at the disposal of
society no longer tend to further the development of the conditions
of bourgeois property; on the contrary, they have become too pow-
erful for these conditions, by which they are fettered, and so soon as
they overcome these fetters, they bring disorder into the whole of
* Ibid., p. 85.
158
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
merged with bank capital); 4) the (economic) partition of the world
among the international cartels has begun. The international cartels
which dominate the whole world market, dividing it ‘amicably’
among themselves – until war brings about a redistribution – al-
ready number over one hundred! The export of capital, a specifi-
cally characteristic phenomenon distinct from export of commodi-
ties under non-monopoly capitalism, is closely bound up with the
economic and territorial political partition of the world; 5) the terri-
torial partition of the world (colonies) is completed.”*
The domination of monopoly
We already know that one of the most important laws of capitalism is
the law of the concentration and centralization of capital. The development
of capitalism leads to the ruin of small-scale production and to the triumph
of the large enterprises. In the process of competition the strong crushes the
weak. In the competitive struggle all the advantages are on the side of the
large enterprises. They take advantage of all the achievements of technical
science, which are beyond the means of their weaker competitors.
The triumph of large-scale production, the concentration and centraliza-
tion of capital inevitably lead, at a definite stage of development, to monop-
oly. Monopoly is an agreement between, or union of, capitalists in whose
hands the overwhelming part of the production of certain commodities is
concentrated. It is easy to see the tremendous advantages of such a combina-
tion for the capitalists. As the entire production (or the overwhelming part)
of a given commodity is in their hands exclusively, they can increase their
profits tremendously by raising the price of this commodity. It is understood
that such a combination is possible only when the greater part of production
is concentrated in the hands of a small number of the biggest capitalists.
Already at the beginning of the twentieth century the concentration of
production in a comparatively small number of large enterprises had gone
very far in most capitalist countries. Of course, in every country there are to
this very day medium and small enterprises which employ a small number of
workers and produce small quantities of products. But the decisive role is
played by the biggest plants and factories which exploit thousands of work-
ers, possess the greater part of the mechanical power and use tremendous
amounts of electrical energy. These gigantic enterprises, putting out an
enormous amount of commodities, occupy dominating positions. Thus in the
U.S.A., for example, at the beginning of the present century almost half of
the entire industrial production was already concentrated in about three
thousand of the largest enterprises. These three thousand giant enterprises
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XIX, “Imperialism and the Split in Socialism,”
p. 301, Russian ed.
159
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
represented numerically only one-hundredth part of the entire number of
industrial enterprises. It is clear that the other ninety-nine hundredths are
represented by petty, scattered enterprises which are entirely unable to con-
tend with the small number of huge enterprises.
The joint stock company form of enterprise greatly helped the trium-
phant progress of big capital. Previously, plants and factories were estab-
lished by individual entrepreneurs. Individual capitalists owned their enter-
prises, managed them and pocketed the profits. However, some enterprises
which needed particularly large expenditures of capital – railroad building,
for instance – proved more than an individual capitalist could manage; for
such purposes joint stock companies were formed. In a stock company the
capital of many owners is joined. Every capitalist gets a definite block of
stock corresponding to the amount of capital he has invested. Formally, the
general meeting of stockholders decides on all fundamental questions, but in
practice a small group of the biggest stockholders is in full control. Since the
number of votes cast at the general meeting depends on the amount of stock
owned, the small shareholders cannot influence the management of the busi-
ness. It is sufficient to own from 30 to 40 per cent of the total stock to be in
control of a stock company. Thus the stock company is a form of organiza-
tion in which big capital subjects to itself and uses for its own ends the ac-
cumulated means of small and medium capitalists and to some extent even
the savings of the upper strata of office employees and workers.
In modern capitalist countries the vast majority of large enterprises are
stock companies. Stock companies stimulate the rapid centralization of capi-
tal and the expansion of enterprises. Stock companies build gigantic enter-
prises such as are beyond the possibility of individual capitalists. Modern
railroads, mines, metallurgical plants, the large automobile plants, steamship
lines – all these would be impossible without stock companies.
Helping to enlarge enterprises, stock companies prepare the ground for
monopoly corporations. Monopoly organizations first arise in the decisive
and basic industries – in heavy industry. In this field the progress of large-
scale production is particularly rapid, and here concentration proceeds apace.
Oil wells, coal mines, iron mines, iron and steel foundries are concentrated
in the hands of a small number of enterprises in every country. Competition
among these giants assumes a particularly fierce character. The free exit of
capital from these fields is exceedingly difficult. Every such undertaking
requires tremendous expenditures of capital on buildings, equipment, huge
machines. The utilization of this capital for the production of other com-
modities at disadvantageous prices is impossible. Crises are felt most keenly
by heavy industry. During crises the demand for machinery, iron and coal
falls faster than the demand for consumers’ goods. Every curtailment of pro-
duction hits heavy industry hard: million dollar plants stand idle for lack of
orders, the cost of production rises tremendously. Heavy industry is the first
160
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
to fall under the power of monopoly. At the same time, having swallowed
heavy industry, monopoly reaches out for the light industries also, subjugat-
ing them one after another.
Cartels, syndicates, trusts
Capitalist associations vary in form. At first there are short term agree-
ments of a fortuitous nature on prices. These only pave the road for longer
term agreements of all kinds.
There are cases when separate undertakings come to an agreement to
maintain prices at a certain level. In this case each enterprise remains abso-
lutely independent. It only undertakes not to lower its prices beyond certain
limits in order not to affect adversely the other enterprises in the same field
through competition. Such associations are called cartels.
Closer contact among enterprises is established when they unite in syn-
dicates. Here the enterprises lose their commercial independence: the sale of
finished products and sometimes even the purchase of raw material pass
through the hands of the general office of the syndicate. Every enterprise
carries on its production independently, only now it already has a set quota,
limiting the quantity of commodities it can produce. This quota is set by the
syndicate.
Even closer is the connection in the trust. Here the separate organiza-
tions merge completely. The owners of the individual enterprises become
shareholders in the trust. All the enterprises embraced by the trust have one
general management.
Vertical combinations
The merging of individual enterprises connected in any way in the proc-
ess of production assumes a continually greater role. Thus, for instance, a
metallurgical plant merges with a coal-mining enterprise which furnishes it
with coal and coke. Further, this metallurgical and coal-mining enterprise
often merges with a machine-building enterprise where locomotives or other
machines are built. Such a merger is called a vertical combination.
The development of monopolies spurs many capitalists on to form com-
bined enterprises. Let us assume that the coal-mining companies have
formed a syndicate and raised the price of coal and coke. Metallurgy needs a
great amount of both products. Many owners of metallurgical plants will, in
such a case, try to obtain their own mines and coke ovens. Thus they avoid
high payments to the syndicated coal industry and obtain the opportunity of
making tremendous super-profits.
Corporations
The spread of the stockholding form of enterprise often brings about a
close connection between separate enterprises. A complicated interlocking
of interests of different enterprises is created, by which one enterprise is
161
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
linked up in some way with another, which in its turn is connected with a
third, and so on. The active participation and interference of banks in indus-
try greatly strengthens the spread of such financial connections among
whole groups of enterprises.
It is particularly worth noting those cases in which some powerful group
of capitalists buys up a large share of the stock of some enterprise. We have
already pointed out that it is sufficient to own a third of the stock of a com-
pany to be in complete control of it. Owning such a number of shares (or, as
it is called, the controlling interest), the group of capitalists subjects to its
own influence one stock company after another. This absorption of individ-
ual enterprises into the sphere of influence and action of the kings of big
capital takes place everywhere, and the forms this process takes are most
diversified.
Usually, such forms of closely linking together separate enterprises on
the basis of their financial interdependence is called incorporation, and the
groups thus formed are called corporations.
Monopoly and competition
The substitution of capitalist monopolies for free competition is a fun-
damental attribute of the imperialist epoch. Even in his time Marx pointed
out that free competition inevitably leads to the rise and domination of mo-
nopolies. But monopoly tries to destroy free competition. Monopolists try to
gain control of the entire production of a commodity. The monopolist situa-
tion opens up unwonted opportunities for enrichment to the capitalists, at the
expense of an increased exploitation of the broad masses of workers.
The creation and growth of monopolies does not abolish competition
among capitalists but, on the contrary, makes it even sharper and fiercer. If,
formerly, with free competition many separate capitalists fought with one
another, now, powerful unions of capitalists enter the fight – group against
group. The monopolists wage desperate battle against those enterprises (the
so-called “wild” ones) that do not want to enter into alliance with them. In
the struggle, all manner of underhand methods are used, even to the point of
blowing up rival enterprises. Further, when the monopolists raise the price of
their commodity it arouses fierce resistance in those branches of industry
which are the consumers and purchasers of this commodity. When the coal
syndicate raises the price of coal, this evokes the resistance of all those own-
ers of plants and factories who use coal in their business. Many try to substi-
tute other fuel for coal, for instance peat or oil, or go over to the use of elec-
tric power. The metallurgical industry which uses a, particularly great
amount of coal and coke will attempt to obtain its own coal mines. A strug-
gle to the death develops among whole branches of industry. The more con-
centrated an industry, the greater the role of monopoly in it – the more furi-
ous this struggle.
162
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
A bitter struggle develops within the monopolist association. The com-
petitors and rivals of yesterday, united in a cartel, syndicate or trust, continue
to struggle among themselves by other means. Everyone tries to grab a big-
ger share of the common monopolist gains for himself. The struggle within
the monopoly is most frequently conducted in great secrecy and only in par-
ticularly severe cases does it break out openly.
We thus see that not only does competition give birth to monopoly but
that monopoly, in its turn, gives birth to competition, strengthening and
sharpening it to extreme limits.
“Free competition is the fundamental attribute of capitalism,
and of commodity production generally. Monopoly is exactly the
opposite of free competition; but we have seen the latter being
transformed into monopoly before our very eyes, creating large-
scale industry and eliminating small-scale industry, replacing large-
scale industry by still larger-scale industry, finally leading to such a
concentration of production and capital that monopoly has been and
is the result: cartels, syndicates and trusts, and merging with them a
dozen or so banks manipulating thousands of millions. At the same
time, monopoly, which has grown out of free competition, does not
abolish the latter, but exists alongside it and hovers over it, as it
were, and, as a result, gives rise to a number of very acute antago-
nisms, frictions and conflicts.”*
Imperialism as monopoly capitalism
Lenin time and again emphasized that the replacement of free competi-
tion by the dominance of monopoly, which does not mean the abolition of
competition, but which, on the contrary, is a condition for its extreme sharp-
ening, is the most important attribute of the epoch of imperialism. Lenin
constantly pointed out that imperialism is monopoly capitalism. Monopoly
is, in the words of Lenin, the last word of the latest phase in capitalist devel-
opment. The substitution of monopoly for free competition is a fundamental
economic trait, the essence of imperialism, Lenin says. In his work on impe-
rialism, Lenin, in characterizing imperialism as a special stage of capitalism,
writes:
“If it were necessary to give the briefest possible definition of
imperialism, then we should have to say that imperialism is the mo-
nopoly stage of capitalism. Such a definition would include what is
most important, for, on the one hand, finance capital is bank capital
of the few big monopolist banks, merged with the capital of the mo-
nopolist combines of manufacturers; and, on the other hand, the di-
165
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
resenting a total capital of $74,000,000,000.
Under the blows of the crisis even the most gigantic monopolist con-
cerns crack. It is enough to point out that the Ford plants, which before the
crisis employed 120,000 men, in the autumn of 1932 employed no more than
15,000. Other giants of monopoly capital were in a similar position. A num-
ber of the largest trusts failed altogether, like the Kreuger Match Trust. The
British oil king, Deterding, who is continually trying to instigate intervention
against the U.S.S.R., was faced with great difficulties.
In Germany, before the war the Steel Union had nine-tenths of the entire
steel production under its control; in the coal industry, the Rhenish West-
phalian Coal Syndicate at the time of its organization had control of 87 per
cent (and later 95 per cent) of the coal production in this coal region, which
is the richest in Germany.
In post-war years the Stinnes Corporation in Germany was much talked
about. Stinnes accumulated a tremendous fortune on war supplies during the
war. After the war, taking advantage of the inflation of the mark, he bought
up all kinds of enterprises for almost nothing: coal mines, electrical supplies
factories, telegraph agencies and banks, paper mills and steamship lines,
metallurgical plants and newspapers. As soon as the mark was stabilized this
gigantic concern, employing hundreds of thousands of workers, fell to
pieces.
A new wave of concentration and the creation of tremendous monopoly
associations rose in Germany in post-war years. By the end of 1928 two-
thirds of all the stock companies (according to capital invested) were united
in corporations. At about that time also, the two largest trusts in contempo-
rary Germany, the chemical and steel trusts, were formed by mergers. The
chemical trust commanded a capital of 1,200,000,000 marks. In its hands
were concentrated 80 per cent of the dye works and 75 per cent of the nitro-
gen production. The German steel trust commanded a capital of 800,000,000
marks and employed (up to the time of the crisis) over 150,000 workers,
producing about one-half of all the pig iron and steel in Germany.
The same thing is to be observed in other capitalist countries. In Eng-
land and Japan, France and Italy, even in small countries like Belgium or
Sweden – everywhere, command is in the hands of an exceedingly small
number of tremendous monopolist enterprises, managed by a handful of trust
directors.
In tsarist Russia there were also a number of great monopolist combines
of capitalists. The Produgol Syndicate controlled more than half the coal
produced in the Donets Basin. Another syndicate, Prodamet, controlled up to
95 per cent of all the iron sales on the market. One of the oldest syndicates
was the sugar syndicate.
166
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
Finance capital
The strength and significance of monopolies is vastly increased by the
new role which banks play under imperialism. Banks were at first intermedi-
aries in making payments. As capitalism develops the credit activity of
banks increases. The bank deals in capital. It takes capital from those capi-
talists who cannot for the moment make use of their capital themselves, and
gives capital to those capitalists who need it at the moment. The bank col-
lects all kinds of income and places it at the disposal of the capitalists.
With the development of capitalism, banking establishments, just as in-
dustrial enterprises, unite, their size and turnover continually increase and
they accumulate tremendous amounts of capital. The greater part of this
capital belongs to others, but the bank’s own capital grows apace. The num-
ber of banks becomes less, smaller banks close or are swallowed up by lar-
ger competitors. But the size of banks, the magnitude of their capital, in-
creases. It is sufficient to give the following example. From 1890 to 1912 the
number of banks in England decreased from 104 to 44, but their capital in-
creased from £430,000,000 to £850,000,000. Now a bank can no longer
limit its activity to granting short term loans to industrialists when they need
them. In order to utilize the tremendous accumulations of capital the banks
come into closer contact with industry. The bank now invests a certain part
of its deposits directly in industry by granting long term loans for the expan-
sion of production, etc.
The stockholding company gives the bank the most convenient form for
investing its capital in industry. All the bank must do is to obtain a certain
amount of stock in the enterprise. Having gained control even of only one-
third of the total stock the bank acquires complete control of and unlimited
power over the whole enterprise.
Stockholding companies thus serve as links between the banks and in-
dustry. The banks, in their turn, help the growth of stockholding companies,
taking upon themselves the reorganization (reconstruction on new princi-
ples) of privately owned enterprises into stockholding companies and the
establishment of new stockholding companies. The purchase and sale of
stock takes place more and more through the medium of banks.
The law of concentration and centralization is manifested with particular
force in banking. In the biggest capitalist countries from three to five of the
largest banks control the entire network of banks. The other banks are either
practically subsidiaries of those giants, their independence a mere outward
show, or they play an entirely insignificant role. Those giant banks are
closely welded to the monopolist industrial associations. A merging or fu-
sion of bank and industrial capital is taking place. Bank capital fused to-
gether with industrial capital is called finance capital. The amalgamation of
bank capital with industrial monopolies is one of the distinctive attributes of
imperialism. That is why imperialism is called the epoch of finance capital.
167
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
The growth of monopoly and the growth of finance capital put the entire
fate of the capitalist world in the hands of a small group of the biggest capi-
talists. The merging of bank capital with industrial capital brings about a
situation where the biggest bankers begin to manage industry and the biggest
industrialists are admitted into the bank directorates. The fate of the entire
economic life of every capitalist country lies in the hands of a numerically
insignificant group of bankers and industrial monopolists. And the arbiter of
economic life is the arbiter of the whole country. Whatever the form of gov-
ernment in bourgeois countries in the epoch of imperialism, practically, a
few uncrowned kings of finance capital have full power. The official state is
only the servant of these capitalist magnates. The solution of the vital prob-
lems in all capitalist countries depends on a small group of the biggest capi-
talists. In their own greedy interests these magnates of capital bring about
great conflicts between entire countries, incite wars, suppress the labour
movements and crush uprisings in the colonies.
With the prevalence of monopoly a handful of people control the lives
of the entire people. One of the leaders of capitalist Germany – the director
of the A.E.G. (General Electric Company), Rathenau, once declared openly:
“Three hundred people who know one another are masters of
the economic destinies of the world and they appoint their own suc-
cessors from among their own numbers.”
It has been estimated, for instance, that in France 50-60 big financiers
are the masters of 108 banks, 105 of the biggest enterprises in heavy indus-
try (i.e., coal, iron, etc.), 101 railroad companies and 107 other most impor-
tant enterprises – 421 in all, of which each one involves hundreds of millions
of francs. The concentration of the preponderating part of the entire wealth
in the hands of an insignificantly small group of men is proceeding at a rapid
rate. Thus in England 38 per cent of the entire wealth of the country is in the
hands of 0.12 per cent of private owners, and less than 2 per cent own 64 per
cent of the wealth of the country. In the U.S.A. approximately 1 per cent
owns 59 per cent of all the country’s wealth.
Export of capital
In the epoch of free competition, world trade develops. Tremendous
quantities of commodities are shipped from one country to another. In the
period of monopoly capitalism the export of capital acquires tremendous
significance.
The fact that export of capital is characteristic of imperialism is closely
connected with the reign of monopoly. Monopolies create an enormous
“surplus” of capital in the older capitalist countries which have had a long
period of capitalist development. Monopolies also cause a curtailment of the
opportunities for investing capital in the home countries. The accumulated
168
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
monopolist profits tend to flow out of the country in search of opportunities
for profitable investment. Such opportunities for profitable investment are
found in the more backward countries. Wages there are exceedingly low, the
working day exorbitantly long. The sources of raw material have not yet
been completely plundered by the capitalists. The market possibilities are
big – capitalist products push out the products of the small artisan establish-
ments, condemning millions of petty producers to hunger and starvation. But
the monopolies seize the internal market of the country, and foreign capital-
ists find it continually more difficult to sell their commodities there. The
import of commodities is hampered by high tariffs. At the same time the
organization of monopolies leads to a state where the internal market of the
developed capitalist countries becomes continually less able to meet the re-
quirements of the gigantic enterprises for the sale of their commodities. Mo-
nopolies inflate prices, which leads to a restriction of the internal market.
They must continually throw more goods onto the external market. But how
can they sell them there, when these markets are surrounded by high tariff
walls?
Here the export of capital helps. The biggest capitalist enterprises export
part of their capital. They organize their own branches abroad. They build
plants and factories there, thus throwing their commodities onto that coun-
try’s internal market.
However, capital is exported not only for the organization of enterprises.
Capital is also exported in the form of various loans by means of which the
richer countries enslave and subject to themselves the more backward
countries.
Before the war, the foreign investments of the three most important
European countries (England, France and Germany) reached colossal pro-
portions: about 100,000,000,000 francs. The income from this capital
reached about 8-10,000,000,000 francs a year.
The significance which the export of capital bears to the imperialist
states is shown by the following data. In 1925 the export of British com-
modities – products of British industries – amounted to £700,000,000, the
profits from this export amounted to about £100,000,000. In the same year,
1925, Great Britain received £420,000,000 in interest on its foreign invest-
ments. This is more than four times the profits received from the export of
goods.
Capital tends to go primarily to backward countries, where labour power
is cheap, industry weak and the market for goods, therefore, still great. At
the beginning of the World War, for instance, foreign capital invested in
Russian industry amounted to more than 2,000,000,000 rubles. So much
French and Belgian capital was invested in the Russian coal industry that the
main office of Produgol, which disposed of the greatest part of Russian coal
(65 per cent), was permanently located in Paris. The German A.E.G. and
169
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
Siemens Schukert had almost complete control of the Russian electrical and
electrical equipment industries. Tremendous British, American, and Dutch
capital was invested in the oil industry in Russia.
With the export of capital close contact is established between the ex-
porting and importing countries. The country exporting capital is interested
in preserving the existing conditions in the country to which the capital goes.
The French capitalists, for instance, were interested in preserving the tsarist
regime in Russia, which is why they granted the tsar a loan in 1906, thereby
helping materially to crush the first Russian revolution.
With the development of monopoly capitalism the export of capital ac-
quires continually greater proportions and assumes greater significance.
“Under the old type of capitalism when free competition pre-
vailed, the export of goods was the most typical feature. Under
modern capitalism in which monopolies prevail, the export of capi-
tal has become the typical feature.”*
Under imperialism the export of capital comes to the fore. This does not
mean, of course, that the export of goods becomes less or loses its signifi-
cance. The fact of the matter is that the export of capital is closely linked up
with the shipment of tremendous masses of goods. If, for example, Great
Britain exports capital to Argentina, it means that enterprises whose stock is
purchased by British capitalists are organized there. One can be positive that
the greater part of the equipment and machinery for these enterprises will be
imported from England. Or the export of capital may take the following
form. Say Great Britain grants some country a loan, for the money thus ob-
tained the latter country purchases goods in England: material for railroads,
military equipment, etc. Thus we see that the export of capital not only does
not narrow down the export of commodities, but, on the contrary, becomes a
powerful new weapon in the struggle for external markets, in the struggle for
expanding the sale of goods.
Division of the world among unions of capitalists
Syndicates and trusts keep prices up artificially, securing colossal super-
profits for themselves. In order to maintain high prices the monopoly or-
ganizations try to fence their countries off from foreign competition. For this
purpose imperialist governments introduce high tariffs on imported goods.
The tariff frequently amounts to many times more than the value of the
commodity.
Already in 1927 the tariffs amounted, on an average (in percentages of
the value), to 37 per cent in the U.S.A., 20 per cent in Germany, 21 per cent
in France, 15 per cent in Belgium, 29 per cent in Argentina, 41 per cent in
173
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
the badgering of the Soviet Union and had for its purpose the paving of the
ground for new attacks on the part of the imperialists against the first coun-
try in the world to build socialism. The howling to the effect that “Soviet
dumping” was increasing the crisis in capitalist countries is particularly ri-
diculous. As a matter of fact, very little Soviet goods is exported to capitalist
countries. Soviet export has not even reached its pre-war dimensions. The
Soviet Union does not sell its goods abroad at dumping prices. It exports
commodities not in order to capture foreign markets, but in order to pay for
the goods it needs. The advantages of socialist economy make it possible for
the U.S.S.R. to produce a number of commodities more cheaply than the
capitalists. The October Revolution put an end to the parasites – the land-
lords and capitalists – at the same time eliminating the cost of keeping them
– ground rent and capitalist profits. It is thus perfectly obvious that all talk
about Soviet dumping is the invention of the enemies of the U.S.S.R. and is
particularly absurd because Soviet economy, having left the capitalist path,
has as a consequence also freed itself from the methods of struggle bound up
with it.
The law of uneven development under imperialism
In the capitalist system individual enterprises, individual branches of in-
dustry and individual countries develop unevenly and spasmodically. It is
evident that with the anarchy of production prevailing under capitalism and
the frenzied struggle among the capitalists for profits, it cannot be otherwise.
This unevenness of development is manifested with particular acute-
ness in the epoch of imperialism, and becomes a decisive force, a decisive
law.
“Finance capital and the trusts are aggravating instead of dimin-
ishing the differences in the rate of development of the various parts
of world economy.”*
Imperialism is monopoly capitalism. The rule of monopolies increases
the uneven and spasmodic development of individual countries. Monopoly
associations, on the one hand, open up opportunities for the younger coun-
tries to catch up with and outstrip the older capitalist countries, and on the
other, monopolies have, inherent in them, tendencies towards parasitism,
decay and a retardation of technical progress: under certain conditions mo-
nopolies delay the development of some countries and thus create opportuni-
ties for other countries to forge ahead.
“...Under capitalism the development of different undertakings,
trusts, branches of industry or countries cannot be even. Half a cen-
* Ibid., p. 114.
175
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
and sources of raw material, in order to expand, at is necessary to
take such territory from others by force.
“Secondly, the fact that the unprecedented development of
technique and the increasing uniformity of the level of development
in capitalist countries have enabled and assisted some countries
spasmodically to overtake others, have enabled the less powerful
but rapidly developing countries to crowd out the more powerful
ones.
“Thirdly, the fact that the old division of spheres of influence
between individual imperialist groups is continually coming into
conflict with the new relation of forces on the world market, that for
the establishment of ‘equilibrium’ between the old distribution of
spheres of influence and the new relation of forces, periodic redivi-
sions of the world are necessary by means of imperialist wars.”*
Wars of conquest, inevitable under imperialism, bring about tremendous
changes in the relation of forces between the various nations. The imperialist
war of 1914-18 brought about the smashing of Germany, the parcelling out
of Austria-Hungary and the establishment of a number of new states on its
ruins. The unevenness of development of the various countries is manifested
with particular clarity and explicitness in the post-war years. America gained
most by the war. It profited most from the struggle of the others. Formerly, it
was indebted to other countries, especially, England. Now almost the entire
world, including England, is in debt to America. A number of branches of
industry in America almost doubled production after the war.
Less than 7 per cent of the world’s population is concentrated in the
U.S.A. which occupies about 6 per cent of the earth’s surface. At the same
time, up to the present crisis, 40 per cent of the world’s coal mines, 35 per
cent of hydro-electrical energy, 70 per cent of the oil, 60 per cent of the
world’s wheat and cotton, 55 per cent of the timber for construction pur-
poses, approximately 50 per cent of the iron and copper and about 40 per
cent of the lead and phosphates of the world were produced there. Up to the
time of the crisis, the U.S.A. consumed 42 per cent of-the world’s output of
iron, 47 per cent of the copper, 69 per cent of the oil, 56 per cent of the rub-
ber, 53 per cent of the tin, 48 per cent of the coffee, 21 per cent of the sugar,
72 per cent, of the silk and 80 per cent of the automobiles.
On the other hand, England, which had occupied first place in world
economy before the war, declined rapidly. After the war England became a
usurer-land, and a number of the most important branches of industry, par-
ticularly the coal industry, remained at the same level, while rival countries
forged ahead. The present crisis brought about tremendous changes in the
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XVIII, “The United States of Europe Slogan,” p.
232, Russian ed.
177
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
countries, counterposed to the theory of the opportunists his theory of the
proletarian revolution, the teaching of the triumph of socialism in a single
country “even though this country is capitalistically less developed.”
At the same time, the opportunists of all countries try to cover up their be-
trayal of the revolution by asserting that the proletarian revolution must begin
all over the world simultaneously. The traitors of the revolution thus create for
themselves a sort of mutual responsibility. The doctrine of the law of uneven
development is subjected to furious attacks, on the part of those sworn ene-
mies of the proletarian revolution – the Social-Democrats and, primarily,
counter-revolutionary Trotskyism, which is one of the most brazen detach-
ments of social-democracy, the vanguard of the counter-revolutionary bour-
geoisie. Trotsky and his adherents claim that under imperialism the uneven-
ness of development of individual countries does not increase but decreases.
Trotskyism does not see those decisive contradictions which predetermine the
growth of unevenness in the epoch of imperialism. Fighting against the Lenin-
ist law of uneven development, Trotskyism reaches the social-democratic con-
clusion that it is impossible to build socialism in a single country. The Trot-
skyist denial of the possibility of the victory of socialism in the U.S.S.R. is
closely bound up with the Trotskyist “theory of permanent revolution,” with a
lack of faith in the possibility of a firm alliance between the proletariat and the
masses of middle peasants, a lack of faith in the power and creative abilities of
the proletariat in building socialism.
Trotskyism is carrying on a desperate struggle against the Leninist pol-
icy of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union; which is bent on building
socialism in the Soviet Union. A particularly prominent role in exposing the
counter-revolutionary character of Trotskyism was played by Stalin. During
the many years that the C.P.S.U. carried on a struggle against Trotskyism,
Stalin brilliantly exposed the counter-revolutionary, Menshevik essence of
the Trotskyist positions, no matter how “Left” the phrases under which they
were masked.
The complete collapse of the Trotskyist positions is unequivocally
shown up by the universally historic victories of the First Five-Year Plan.
Summing up the results of the First Five-Year Plan, Stalin said:
“The results of the Five-Year Plan have smashed the social-
democratic thesis that it is impossible to build socialism in a single
country taken by itself. The results of the Five-Year Plan have
shown that it is quite possible to build socialist society in a single
country, because the economic foundations of such a society have
already been laid in the U.S.S.R.”*
* Stalin, “The Results of the First Five-Year Plan,” in the symposium: From the
178
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
The theory of ultra-imperialism
In opposition to the Leninist theory of imperialism the Social-Democrats
have formulated the traitorous and false theory of ultra-imperialism, the au-
thor of which is Kautsky, who has enormous experience in the distortion and
falsification of Marxism and who now comes out as one of the most brazen
slanderers of .and agitators for intervention against the Soviet Union.
The substance of Kautsky’s views, against which Lenin fought deter-
minedly, is the following: Kautsky denies that imperialism is a distinct stage,
phase, or new step in the development of capitalism, distinguished primarily
by deep economic peculiarities. According to Kautsky, imperialism is not an
economic system but merely a certain policy of the capitalists of certain
countries. Kautsky’s principal definition, against which Lenin fought deter-
minedly, says:
“ ‘Imperialism is a product of highly developed industrial capi-
talism. It consists in the striving of every industrial capitalist nation
to bring under its control and to annex increasingly big agrarian re-
gions irrespective of what nations inhabit those regions.’ ”*
“This definition is utterly false theoretically,” says Lenin. What
is false about this definition? Lenin exposes Kautsky thus:
“The distinguishing feature of imperialism is not the domina-
tion of industrial capital but that of finance capital, the striving to
annex, not agrarian countries particularly, but all kinds of' countries.
Kautsky separates imperialist politics from imperialist economics,
he separates monopoly in politics from monopoly in economics in
order to pave the way for his vulgar, bourgeois reformism such as
‘disarmament,’ ‘ultra-imperialism’ and similar nonsense. The mean-
ing and the aim of this theoretical falsehood is to gloss over the pro-
found contradictions of imperialism and thus to justify the theory of
‘unity’ with the apologists of imperialism, the frank social-
chauvinists and opportunists.Ӡ
Lenin stresses the fact that Kautsky’s definition is incorrect and non-
Marxian. This definition is the basis of a whole system of views which com-
pletely break away from Marxism both in theory and in practice. Tearing
politics away from economics, depicting imperialism as merely a policy pre-
ferred by some capitalist countries, Kautsky altogether assumes the position
of the bourgeois reformists who think that it is possible to achieve more
* Ibid., p. 90.
181
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
mass” in the form of small producers). Basing herself thus on semi-
Menshevik positions, Luxemburg could not rise to the Leninist conception
of imperialism, to a correct understanding of its fundamental peculiarities
and distinguishing attributes. Luxemburg's mistakes in the conception of
imperialism are closely allied to her erroneous positions on a number of im-
portant political questions: the question of the split in Social-Democracy, the
agrarian and national questions, the role of the Party and spontaneous ele-
ments in the movements, etc. The theory of the automatic collapse of capi-
talism ensuing from Luxemburg’s erroneous theory of reproduction, which
the “Left” Social-Democrats gladly utilize now to hold the working class
back from revolutionary activity by means of supposedly revolutionary
phraseology, in practice disarms the working class, spreads a mood of pas-
sivity and fatalism in its midst, stultifying its will to struggle. It is perfectly
evident that the Kautskyist errors of Luxemburg on the question of imperial-
ism kept her from severing relations with Kautsky and Kautskyism, serving
as a sort of bridge connecting her to the Kautskyist centre even during the
progress of the imperialist war when the absolute treachery of Kautsky and
his complete desertion to the counter-revolutionary camp of imperialism
became perfectly evident.
The Trotskyist position on the theory of imperialism is only one of the
varieties of Kautskyism. During the war Lenin repeatedly established the fact
that Trotsky is a Kautskyist, that he shares Kautsky’s views, defending and
glossing over Kautsky’s distortions of Marxism. In defending the Kautskyist
position, Trotskyism comes out with particular venom against the Leninist
law of uneven development. And this is really not surprising. We have al-
ready seen that the law of uneven development does not leave a single stone
of the whole traitorous and counter-revolutionary Kautskyist structure of
“ultra-imperialism” unturned. Trotskyism builds its counter-revolutionary
theory of the impossibility of building socialism in a single country on the
denial of the Leninist law of uneven development.
The theory of organized capitalism
The traitors to the working class from the Social-Democratic camp de-
pict matters as if the growth of monopoly leads to the replacement of capital-
ist anarchy by a new system – that of organized capitalism.
The Social-Democrats began to spread the legend about organized capi-
talism particularly during the post-war years of partial stabilization. The
most prominent disseminator of this theory is one of the most brazen leaders
of Social-Democracy – Hilferding. The Social-Democrats try to maintain
that with the growth of monopoly there is an end to the blind forces of the
market. Capitalism supposedly organizes itself, competition disappears, an-
archy of production is eliminated, crises become things of the past, planned,
conscious organization predominates. From this the Social-Democrats reach
182
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
the traitorous conclusion that trusts and cartels peacefully grow into planned,
socialist economy; supposedly, one must only help the bankers and trusts
straighten things out for themselves and then capitalism will of itself, unno-
ticed, without any struggle or revolution “grow” into socialism!
It is quite clear that the theory of organized capitalism is a further devel-
opment of Kautsky’s theory of ultra-imperialism. The Social-Democratic
theory of organized capitalism also glosses over and befogs the glaring con-
tradictions of imperialism, just as Kautsky’s theory of ultra-imperialism
does. The traitors to the working class from the Social-Democratic camp try
by every means to gloss over the fact that under imperialism capitalism be-
comes a decaying, parasitic system. Lenin pointed out that Hilferding, even
before the war, in denying the parasitism and decay characteristic of imperi-
alism, stood even lower than some of the bourgeois scientists who, on inves-
tigating imperialism, could not help noting these phenomena which stand out
glaringly.
Denying the decaying, parasitic nature of imperialism, the Social-
Democrats adopt the position of defending the capitalist system by all and
every means. And they really stop at nothing in their attempt to crush the
revolutionary struggle of the working class against imperialism. The theory
of organized, capitalism, promising a peaceful and painless transition to so-
cialism, serves in their hands only as a means of deceiving the more back-
ward elements of the working class, of keeping them away from the revolu-
tionary struggle.
This counter-revolutionary theory is refuted at every step by contempo-
rary capitalist reality. This theory is completely shattered as soon as it is re-
garded in the light of the analysis of imperialism given by Lenin.
We have already seen that imperialism does not eliminate, but, on the
contrary, strengthens and sharpens all the fundamental contradictions of the
capitalist system. Anarchy of production not only does pot disappear, but, on
the contrary, assumes gigantic proportions and gives rise to particularly
devastating consequences. Competition between the monopoly alliances is
much fiercer than it formerly was between individual capitalists. Under im-
perialism crises become keener and more devastating, and their conse-
quences affect the working class even more severely. The crisis of 1907 al-
ready bore witness to this fact, as it struck the country where monopoly had
grown most – the U.S.A. – with particular force. The present world crisis of
capitalism most thoroughly and completely exposes the futility of the legend
about organized capitalism, disseminated by the lackeys of the bourgeoisie.
The fairy tale about organized capitalism serves the Social-Democrats
only to deceive the working class, to detract their attention from the uncom-
promising class struggle, to justify their traitorous tactics of class peace with
the bourgeoisie and struggle against the revolutionary labour movement.
The legend of organized capitalism was caught up by the Right wing
183
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
opportunists in the ranks of the C.P.S.U. and other Parties in the Communist
International. Comrade Bukharin claimed that “the problems of markets,
prices, competition and crises become ever more problems of world econ-
omy, being replaced within the country by problems of organization.”
From this the Right opportunists drew the inference that the inner con-
tradictions in capitalist countries are abating, that capitalism is getting
stronger and that there could be talk about a rise in the revolutionary tide
only after a new imperialist war.
The crude error with regard to the theory of organized capitalism is not
accidental with Comrade Bukharin. This anti-Leninist position is closely
connected with a whole series of errors in the field of the theory of imperial-
ism, which he had committed beginning with the commencement of the war.
Lenin fought Bukharin’s mistakes over a number of years (1915-20).
Against Lenin’s theory, Bukharin counterposed his own theory of so-called
“pure imperialism.” Captured by “Left” phrases and masking themselves
with them, the adherents of this theory, in practice, allied themselves to the
opportunist social-democratic views on questions of imperialism.
The main fault in Bukharin’s theory of “pure” imperialism lies in its ex-
treme simplification and incorrect representation of imperialist reality. The
adherents of this theory gloss over the deepest contradictions inherent in
imperialism. They shut their eyes to the fact that imperialism grows out of
and develops on the basis of the old capitalism, that because of this imperial-
ism does not eliminate the fundamental contradictions of capitalism but, on
the contrary, sharpens them to the extreme.
In his report on the Party program at the Eighth Congress of the Party in
1919, Lenin, touching on his disagreements with Bukharin, pointed out that
“...pure imperialism, without the fundamental base of capital-
ism, never existed, does not exist now and never will exist.”*
In the same speech Lenin said further:
“Bukharin’s concreteness is a bookish description of finance
capitalism. Nowhere in the world does monopoly capitalism exist
without free competition in a number of fields, nor will it exist in
the future.”
And Lenin continued:
“If we had to deal with an integral imperialism which had com-
pletely remade capitalism our problem would be a thousand-fold
easier. We should then have a system where everything was subject
* Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XXIV, “Report on the Party Program,” p. 131,
Russian ed.
184
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
to finance capital only. Then, we should only have to remove this
control and leave the rest to the proletariat. This would be very
agreeable, unfortunately it is not so in reality. In reality the devel-
opment is such that we have to act entirely differently. Imperialism
is a superstructure on capitalism.... We have the old capitalism
which, in a number of fields, has grown up into imperialism.”*
The erroneous theory of “pure” imperialism, defended by Bukharin
when he was one of the leaders of the group of so-called “Left Commu-
nists,” served as the direct basis for the theory of organized capitalism.
The present crisis of capitalism clearly exposed the absolute untenability
of this theory. It is quite evident that this opportunist fiction about organized
capitalism, borrowed from the Social-Democrats, has nothing whatever to do
with Marxism-Leninism. Lenin repeatedly emphasized that monopolies,
growing out of competition, do not eliminate it but exist over and alongside
it, giving rise thereby to a special sharpening of all contradictions, and con-
flicts. Lenin has written:
“Imperialism aggravates and sharpens the contradictions of
capitalism, it intertwines monopoly with free competition, but it
cannot abolish exchange, the market, competition, crises, etc.
“Imperialism is capitalism passing away, not capitalism gone...
dying, not dead. Not pure monopolies, but monopolies, alongside of
competition, exchange, markets and crises – this, generally, is the
most essential feature of imperialism.Ӡ
That is why Lenin emphasized that
“It is this very combination of contradictory principles, of com-
petition and monopoly, that is the essence of imperialism, it is this
that leads to the final crash, the socialist revolution.”‡
The parasitism and decay of capitalism
Imperialism is parasitic or decaying capitalism. Capitalist monopolies
inevitably give rise to a tendency towards stagnation and decay. They tend to
establish monopoly prices and maintain them at a high level. With free com-
petition every capitalist tries to increase his profits by cutting down his out-
lay on production, and in order to cut down his outlay all kinds of technical
improvements are introduced. Monopolies, in-as-much as they can maintain
188
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
Secondly, the antagonisms between the various cliques of financial sharks
and between imperialist powers in their constant struggle to seize new territo-
ries, sources of raw material and markets for sales and for the investment of
capital. This frenzied struggle between the individual imperialist cliques inevi-
tably leads to wars in which the biggest imperialist powers shed oceans of
blood and pile up mountains of corpses in the struggle to redivide the already
divided world, in the struggle to grab new sources of enrichment for a few
billionaires. The struggle of the imperialists inevitably leads to their mutual
weakening, to the weakening of the capitalist positions in general, and thus
brings closer the day of the proletarian revolution, makes this absolutely nec-
essary in order to save society from perishing altogether.
Thirdly, the antagonism between the small number of the so-called
“civilized” nations and the enormous masses of the population of the colo-
nial and dependent countries. Hundreds of millions of people waste away in
the colonial and semi-colonial world under the domination of imperialist
robbers.
“Imperialism means the most shameless exploitation and the
most inhuman oppression of hundreds of millions of the population
of vast colonies and dependent countries.”*
Hunting super-profits, the imperialists build plants and factories in the
colonies and semi-colonial countries, build railroads there, break up the old
order of things, clear the way with fire and sword for new capitalist rela-
tions. The growth of imperialist exploitation leads to the strengthening of the
liberation movement in the colonies and dependent countries, weakening the
capitalist position throughout the world, undermining it at its roots, and lead-
ing to the transformation of these countries, as Stalin points out, “from re-
serves of imperialism into reserves of the proletarian revolution.” The na-
tional liberation movement in the colonies becomes a threat to imperialism,
a support for the revolutionary proletariat.
The extreme sharpening of all the contradictions brings about a situation
in which imperialism becomes the eve of the socialist revolution. Capitalist
contradictions sharpen to such a degree that the further maintenance of capi-
talist relations becomes an unbearable encumbrance to the further develop-
ment of human society. Capitalist relations hinder the further progress of
productive forces; as a result of this, capitalism decays and begins to fall to
pieces while still alive. This tendency to decay does not exclude the devel-
opment of individual countries or individual branches of industry even in a
period of a general capitalist crisis. Tremendous amounts of value are
* The Program and Rules of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union
(Bolsheviks), p. 6, Moscow, 1932.
† Lenin, Collected Works, Vol. XIX, “The Socialist Revolution and the Right «f
190
IMPERIALISM – THE EVE OF THE SOCIALIST REVOLUTION
Elsewhere Lenin says that the epoch of imperialism is the epoch of ripe
and over-ripe capitalism which is on the eve of its collapse, matured to the
extent that it must yield its place to socialism.
The epoch of imperialism is therefore the epoch of the collapse and de-
struction of capitalism, the era of proletarian revolutions.
REVIEW QUESTIONS
1. How does competition lead to the formation of monopolies?
2. Do monopolies eliminate competition?
3. What is the source of the profits of the monopolists?
4. How does the role of the banks change in the epoch of imperialism?
5. What gives rise to the export of capital?
6. What is the function of tariffs?
7. What is the law of uneven development?
8. What is there essentially traitorous in the theory of organized capitalism?
9. How is the theory of organized capitalism connected with the theory of
ultra-imperialism?
10. How does the decay of capitalism manifest itself under imperialism?
11. What are the five fundamental attributes of imperialism?
199
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
gradual advent of partial stabilization in capitalist countries. A certain
amount of “reconstruction,” necessitated by the havoc left by the World
War, took place in the capitalist camp. On the other hand, this period was a
period of the rapid reconstruction of the national economy of the U.S.S.R.,
and of the most vital successes of socialist construction.
Having repelled the attacks of the masses of workers, the bourgeoisie
proceeded to bind up the more gaping wounds left by the World War. Their
method of curing these wounds was by transferring the entire burden of the
heritage of the imperialist slaughter onto the shoulders of the working class.
At the cost of an unbelievable reduction in the standard of living the bour-
geoisie achieved a temporary and partial stabilization of capitalism. In a
number of countries money circulation was re-stabilized after it had been
completely upset by the war and post-war chaos. The bourgeoisie began to
put capitalist rationalization methods into effect. Rationalization under capi-
talism means an enormous increase in the rate of exploitation of the workers.
This is accomplished by the aid of technical innovations introduced by the
rationalizers. Capitalist rationalization reduces the number of workers em-
ployed while increasing their productivity. Part of the workers are thrown
out on the streets without the slightest hope of ever getting employment
again. Those workers who remain are forced to work twice and three times
as intensively, exhausting their entire strength for the benefit of capital.
Partial stabilization of capitalism could only be temporary, tottering, rot-
ten. It could only succeed in deadening the effect of some of the contradic-
tions of contemporary capitalism for a very short time indeed, as it is abso-
lutely unable to solve these contradictions. On the contrary, these contradic-
tions have made themselves felt more and more sharply from year to year.
The process of stabilization was characterized by an increase in the un-
evenness of development of the various countries. Some countries succeeded
in getting on their feet after the ravages of war more or less rapidly, while
others lagged behind in this respect. Currency was relatively stabilized in
various countries at different times. The temporary revival of the production
machinery also began at different times in the various countries. Unevenness
of development in the years of stabilization was one of the sources of those
contradictions which revealed themselves very soon afterwards.
Together with the temporary stabilization of capitalism, the reconstruc-
tion of the economy of the Soviet Union forged ahead with giant strides; the
deep wounds inflicted on the economy of the country by the imperialist war
and the civil war that followed were healed in a comparatively short time,
independently and without recourse to any outside aid. The consolidation
and growth of the power of the Soviet Union deepen the general crisis of
capitalism and render it more acute.
The colonial countries, exploited by the imperialists, rise in a struggle
against their exploiters. The revolution in China, regardless of temporary
200
THE WAR AND THE GENERAL CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
setbacks, does not let the imperialists rest. The revolutionary movement in
India and other colonies of British and French capital continues to grow. The
contradictions between the imperialist countries increase and become
sharper. The transference of the world’s economic centre to America, the
transformation of the U.S.A. into a world exploiter, greatly sharpens the re-
lations between the American and the European, primarily the British, bour-
geoisie. The contradictions between America and Great Britain form the
pivot around which the world imperialist struggles revolve. As capitalist
industry reaches pre-war dimensions again in some countries (1927-28) the
struggle for markets becomes more intensified.
The third period of the post-war general crisis of capitalism arrives.
This period is characterized by the sharpening of the basic contradictions of
contemporary capitalism. In 1927 as compared with 1913, world economy
produced: oil – 300 per cent, iron – 102 per cent, steel – 127 per cent, cotton
– 125 per cent, wheat – 110 per cent, rye – 95 per cent. The following year,
1928, resulted in a further increase in production for many commodities.
Capitalism, about ten years after the war, exceeded its pre-war limits. Simul-
taneously, an exceptional increase in capitalist contradictions resulted both
within individual countries and between them. The third period in the devel-
opment of the general crisis of capitalism is the period of the shattering of
the partial and temporary stabilization of capitalism; under the circumstances
of the world economic crisis that began in 1929 and shook the entire econ-
omy of the capitalist countries to its very foundations, the end of capitalist
stabilization finally arrives, as was pointed out in the resolution of the
Twelfth Plenum of the E.C.C.I., held in the autumn of 1932.
Capitalist rationalization brings with it an unprecedented increase in the
exploitation of the working class by the bourgeoisie. Rationalization sharp-
ens the class contradictions to their extreme limits. Rationalization under
conditions of capitalism results in the shutting down of a number of anti-
quated enterprises and a reduction in the number of workers employed at the
remaining plants and factories. Chronic unemployment sets in. The condition
of the working class becomes worse even in a number of the most highly
developed capitalist countries.
Thus, for instance, in even the wealthiest capitalist country, which the
reformists point to as being almost “heaven on earth” – the U.S.A. – the fol-
lowing changes took place between 1919 and 1925. The number of workers
employed in industry, in agriculture and on the railroads decreased 7 per
cent; production increased 20 per cent; the productivity of labour increased
29 per cent. During these years, the number of workers employed in these
fields fell by almost 2,000,000 people. Part of these found employment in
the sphere of trade and service, but the majority remained unemployed.
In Germany there were no less than three million unemployed at the be-
ginning of 1929. During the later years of capitalist rationalization a constant
201
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
reserve army grew, which even at times of industrial revival never fell below
one to one and half million people in number. Of these, from half a million
to a million people were permanently unemployed and their condition hope-
less. These were real victims of capitalist rationalization, which, had taken
all their strength from them and then thrown them out onto the street.
The total number of unemployed, thrown out of employment by ration-
alization in the foremost capitalist countries, amounted to ten million people.
Precisely the same number as that killed in the World War! Like the victims
of the war, these also are doomed to death by capitalism; the only difference
is that the capitalist victims of “peace” die slowly.
The impoverishment of the working class proceeds apace with the
growth of technical improvement, throwing workers out of employment and
at the same time enormously increasing the quantity of commodities pro-
duced. Together with the tremendous increase in the quantity of commodities
produced, the internal market contracts, as it depends on the well-being of
the broad masses. The increase in production conflicts with the decreased
consumption of the masses. The difficulties of selling increase, and. compel
the capitalists of the various countries to conduct a savage struggle for ex-
ternal markets.
In the third period the contradiction between the development of pro-
ductive forces and the contraction of the markets becomes particularly acute.
The internal as well as the external contradictions grow, rending the capital-
ist countries asunder under the conditions of a general crisis of the capitalist
system. The third period brings with it devastating crises and the ever grow-
ing danger of new imperialist wars.
At the same time, in the U.S.S.R. a transition takes place from the resto-
ration to the reconstruction period. The great Five-Year-Plan of reconstruc-
tion begins to be realized. The reconstruction of national economy, the co-
lossal growth of socialist industry, the radical transformation of agriculture
on the basis of collectivization – all this marks the victorious progress of
socialism on the vast territory which covers one-sixth of the world. The third
period intensifies the struggle between two systems – that of moribund capi-
talism and that of rapidly developing socialism. The absolute hopelessness
of the capitalist system and all the advantages of socialism stand forth with
particular clarity in this period when the enormous growth of socialism in
the U.S.S.R. takes place against the background of a crisis of unprecedented
depth which shook the capitalist countries to their very foundations.
During the years of partial stabilization the bourgeois scribblers and So-
cial-Democratic lackeys of capital made every effort to prove that the capi-
talist system had completely healed the wounds inflicted by the war and had
definitely overcome the post-war crisis. They asserted that capitalism was
full of strength and vitality, that it had a brilliant future before it. The Social-
Democrats, in their slavish catering to the bourgeoisie, asserted that a period
202
THE WAR AND THE GENERAL CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
of capitalist prosperity and well-being had arrived, the millenium of organ-
ized capitalism which knows no shocks, wars or crises.
The opportunists within the Communist Parties repeated these ravings of
the defenders of the bourgeoisie in a more concealed form. The Right oppor-
tunists repeated the Social-Democratic arguments about organized capital-
ism. During the transition from the second to the third period the Right op-
portunists tried to show that the third period is not the end of capitalist stabi-
lization, but a period of its further entrenchment. The Right opportunists
supported the fiction of American prosperity, creating the theory of Ameri-
can “exceptionalism,” asserting that America was unaffected by the general
crisis of capitalism. In the opinion of the Right opportunists, the stabilization
of capitalism was permanent and unshakable. The Trotskyists, rather, at first
tried to deny the significance of capitalist stabilization, disposing of it with a
few “Left” phrases, but soon they joined the chorus of those who sang the
praises of the permanence and steadfastness of capitalist stabilization. The
Right opportunists and the Trotskyists did not want to admit the advent of
the present world crisis even when the majority of the bourgeois politicians
were compelled to admit its existence.
Even at the time of partial stabilization the C.P.S.U. and the Comintern
foresaw the inevitability of the advent of a new crisis. They based them-
selves on the revolutionary, Marxist-Leninist analysis of those inner contra-
dictions which inevitably develop in modern capitalism. In his report to the
Fifteenth Congress of the C.P.S.U. in December 1927, Stalin emphasized
that “from stabilization is born the growing crisis of capitalism.” He said:
“As early as the Fourteenth Congress it was stated in the report
that capitalism may return to pre-war level, may surpass the pre-war
level, may rationalize its production, but that this does not yet mean
– does not mean by far – that because of this the stabilization of
capitalism can become durable, that capitalism can recover its pre-
war stability. On the contrary, out of its very stabilization, out of the
fact that production expands, that commerce develops, that techni-
cal progress and productive capacity increase, while the world mar-
ket, the limits of this market and the spheres of influence of individ-
ual imperialist groups remain more or less stationary – out of this
the deepest and most acute crisis of world capitalism is growing,
pregnant with new wars and threatening the existence of any stabili-
zation. Out of partial stabilization an intensification of the crisis of
capitalism ensues, the growing crisis disrupts stabilization – this is
the dialectics of the development of capitalism in the given histori-
cal period.”
Later developments showed the absolute correctness of this estimate
given by Stalin. Already at the end of 1929 the “deepest and most acute cri-
203
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
sis of world capitalism” had set in. This crisis upset all the fairy tales of the
bourgeois and Social-Democratic apologists of capitalism, all the opportun-
ist theories. This crisis showed the full correctness of the estimate of the
third period which was given by the C.P.S.U. and the Comintern. The pre-
sent crisis, with its development, brought about the advent of the end of the
relative stabilization of capitalism, as was pointed out in the resolution of the
Twelfth Plenum of the E.C.C.I. of September 1932.
Fascism and Social-Democracy
An unwonted sharpening of class contradictions takes place under the
conditions of the general crisis of capitalism. In the new situation the bour-
geoisie, feeling the approach of its downfall, makes use of the severest and
cruellest methods of repression against the working class. In a number of
countries the bourgeoisie, after repelling the first attacks of the working
class in the very first years after the war, established fascist dictatorships
(e.g., Italy and Hungary). In Germany the bourgeoisie established a fascist
dictatorship only after a number of intermediate steps, in February 1933,
when the Hitler government came into power.
The bourgeoisie finds it continually more difficult to maintain itself in
power by means of the more veiled forms of bourgeois dictatorship. It goes
over to open fascist dictatorship. It represses the labour movement by the
bloodiest methods. It passes over to open terror against the working class
and its organizations. All this is clear evidence of the instability of capital-
ism, of the uncertainty of the bourgeoisie concerning what the morrow will
bring.
The fascist form of open dictatorship of the bourgeoisie is extremely
characteristic of capitalism in the epoch of its decay and downfall. Fascism
tries to create a bulwark for the bourgeoisie against the working class. It ap-
peals to the broad masses of the petty bourgeoisie, the peasantry, office em-
ployees and clerks, small businessmen, and the intelligentsia. It penetrates
into the more backward elements of the working class. It widely mobilizes
all the declassed elements. It conducts its frantic defence of capitalism, at
least at first, under the mask of anti-capitalist agitation. The hazy demagogy
against capitalism serves fascism as a decoy to catch adherents from among
the disinherited but politically backward sections of the petty bourgeoisie.
“The principal aim of fascism is to destroy the revolutionary la-
bour vanguard, i.e., the Communist sections and leading units of the
proletariat. The combination of social demagogy, corruption and ac-
tive White terror, in conjunction with extreme imperialist aggres-
sion in the sphere of foreign politics, are the characteristic features
of fascism. In periods of acute crisis for the bourgeoisie, fascism re-
sorts to anti-capitalist phraseology, hut, after it has established itself
at the helm of state, it casts aside its anti-capitalist rattle and dis-
204
THE WAR AND THE GENERAL CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
closes itself as a terrorist dictatorship of big capital.”*
Under conditions of the general crisis of capitalism, Social-Democracy
completes its course of treachery. The roots of opportunist degeneration had
deeply penetrated the parties of the Second International even before the
period of the war. The World War clearly exposed the complete treachery of
international Social-Democracy to the interests of the working class. The
social-patriots and social-chauvinists in each country supported the bour-
geoisie of “their own fatherland” in its annexationist policies. After the war,
Social-Democracy was the force which played the biggest and leading role
in suppressing the workers’ uprisings. In all countries the Social-Democrats
saved their “own” capitalism, not stopping at the vilest means of struggle
against the revolutionary vanguard of the working class. In this situation the
bourgeoisie is continually passing over to fascist methods of dictatorship. To
the Social-Democrats, as to the fascists, the most dangerous enemy is the
revolutionary proletariat. When in power the Social-Democrats employ the
methods characteristic of fascism more and more in their struggle against the
revolutionary forces of the proletariat. At the same time, Social-Democracy
clears the way for the fascist advent to power. This was most clearly seen in
Germany.
“The principal function of Social-Democracy at the present
time is to disrupt the essential militant unity of the proletariat in its
struggle against imperialism. In splitting and disrupting the united
front of the proletarian struggle against capital, Social-Democracy
serves as the mainstay of imperialism in the working class.Ӡ
Anxious to save the bankrupt capitalist system, the bourgeoisie goes
from one method of struggle against the revolutionary proletariat to another.
Now it rules by means of an open fascist dictatorship, now it prefers to back
Social-Democracy which has had such tremendous experience in duping and
betraying the working class.
“Fascism is the militant organization of the bourgeoisie, relying
on the active support of Social-Democracy. Objectively, Social-
Democracy is a moderate wing of fascism. There is no basis for the
supposition that a militant organization of the bourgeoisie could
achieve decisive success in battles or in the administration of the
country without the active support of Social-Democracy. There is
just as little foundation for the idea that Social-Democracy could
achieve decisive successes in battles or in the administration of the
* Stalin, Leninism, Vol. II, “Political Report to the Sixteenth Congress,” p. 254.
207
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
years all the lackeys of the bourgeoisie, all its learned hirelings and toadies
from the Social-Democratic camp glorified American “prosperity” and as-
sured the world that there could be no end or limit to this prosperity. The
crisis unmercifully exposed and refuted these traitorous arguments.
The present crisis came as the first post-war world economic crisis. It
developed unevenly in the various countries: some countries experienced the
crisis sooner, some later. The crisis hit various countries with various de-
grees of force. Nevertheless, it embraced the entire capitalist world and there
is not a single capitalist country which it has spared. Thus, regardless of the
unevenness with which it affected the various countries, the present crisis
caught all the capitalist countries in its iron embrace.
In previous epochs, before capitalism had begun to decline, crises ap-
peared after comparatively long periods of prosperity and a rise and growth
of the national economy of capitalist countries. The present crisis, in this
respect, differs radically from all previous, “usual” crises. The present crisis
was preceded by only temporary flares of revival in various countries.
These “booms” appeared in various countries at various times and were
very short-lived. In Germany the year 1927 was one of revival. But 1928
already showed a decline. In Poland there was a certain revival in 1927-28;
in Japan, in 1928 and the beginning of 1929. On the other hand in such
countries as England, Australia, and Brazil there was no revival whatsoever
before the crisis. In the economy of these countries the pre-crisis period was
one of great stagnation.
Describing the condition of the capitalist world during recent years in
his report to the Seventeenth Congress of the Communist Party of the
U.S.S.R., Comrade Stalin said:
“In the economic sphere these years have been years of continu-
ing world economic crisis. The crisis has affected not only industry,
but also agriculture as a whole. The crisis has not only raged in the
sphere of production and trade, but has also swept into the sphere of
credit and the circulation of money, and has overturned the estab-
lished credit and currency relationships between countries.
“Formerly, there were disputes here and there as to whether
there was a world economic crisis or not, but now nobody argues
about this because the existence of the crisis and its devastating ef-
fects are only too obvious. Now the controversy centres around an-
other question, viz., is there a way out of the crisis or not? And if
there is a way out, where is it to be found?”*
* Stalin, Leninism, Vol. II, “Political Report to the Sixteenth Congress," p. 254.
209
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
employed are deprived of all means of subsistence or, at best, receive a beg-
garly dole. Those who remain at work receive greatly reduced wages. The
earnings of the workers become continually smaller. But this only results in
further lowering the purchasing power of the masses of workers. At the same
time the agricultural crisis cuts down the incomes of the agricultural popula-
tion. The peasant masses are ruined.
The contraction of the internal market compels the capitalists to conduct
a frantic struggle for foreign markets. But foreign markets mean either other
industrial capitalist countries, or colonial and semi-colonial agrarian coun-
tries. The bourgeoisie of every industrial country tries to fence in its own
market from the encroachments of foreign competition. With this end in
view, high tariffs, outright embargoes on the import of certain commodities,
etc., are introduced, and the markets of the colonial and semi-colonial agrar-
ian countries are ruined and drastically contracted because of the devastating
effects of the agrarian crisis and the growth of colonial oppression and ex-
ploitation. All this leads to a catastrophic decline in foreign trade, to an ex-
treme sharpening of the struggle for markets, to an enormous growth of the
contradictions in the capitalist world.
The most profound and protracted of all crises
There have been many crises in the history of capitalism, but never be-
fore has there been a crisis of such depth and acuteness. In scale, force and
prolongation, in the extent to which it has affected all phases of capitalist
economy, the present crisis far exceeds all previous crises.
“The present economic crisis in capitalist countries differs from
all analogous crises, among other things, by the fact that it is the
longest and most protracted crisis, Formerly, crises lasted one or
two years, the present crisis, however, is now in its fifth year and
from year to year has devastated the economy of capitalist countries
and has wasted the fat it accumulated in previous years. It is not
surprising that this crisis is the severest of all crises.”*
All the basic indices evidence of this and characterize the depth and
acuteness of the crisis. According to the basic indices showing the decline of
production, the extent of unemployment and wage reductions, the fall in
prices of commodities, the decline in foreign trade, the drop in stock market
quotations, etc., the present crisis far exceeds all the previous crises that
have taken place in the history of capitalism.
The following table gives the index numbers of the present crisis in
comparison with previous ones, in percentages of decline:
211
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
analysed these causes:
“It is to be explained, first of all, by the fact that the industrial
crisis affected every capitalist country without exception and made
it difficult for some countries to manoeuvre at the expense of others.
“Secondly, it is to be explained by the fact that the industrial
crisis became interwoven with the agrarian crisis which affected all
the agrarian and semi-agrarian countries without exception and this
could not but make the industrial crisis more complicated and pro-
found.
“Thirdly, it is to be explained by the fact that the agrarian crisis
became more acute in this period and affected all branches of agri-
culture including cattle raising, degrading it to the level of passing
from machine labour to hand labour, to the substitution of the horse
for the tractor, to the sharp decline, diminution in the use of and
sometimes to the complete abandonment of artificial fertilizers,
which caused the industrial crisis to become still more protracted.
“Fourthly, it is to be explained by the fact that the monopolist
cartels which dominate industry strive to maintain the high prices of
goods, and this circumstance makes the crisis particularly painful
and hinders the absorption of stocks of commodities.
“Lastly, and what is most important, it is to be explained by the
fact that the industrial crisis broke out amidst the conditions of the
general crisis of capitalism, when capitalism no longer has, nor can
have, either in the home states or in the colonial and dependent
countries the strength and stability it had before the war and the Oc-
tober Revolution, when industry in the capitalist countries is suffer-
ing from the heritage it received from the imperialist war in the
shape of the chronic working of enterprises under capacity, and an
army of unemployed numbering millions from which it is no longer
able to release itself.
“Such are the circumstances which determine the extremely
protracted character of the present industrial crisis.”*
The decline in production
The crisis of overproduction leads to a colossal decline in production in
all fields of economy. Beginning with the autumn of 1929 a stoppage and a
curtailment of production, hitherto unprecedented, has been taking place in
capitalist countries.
While there is a considerable increase of production in the U.S.S.R.
every year, the capitalist world, caught in the iron vice of the crisis, curtails
* Ibid., p. 12;
213
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
From this table it is plain that the industries of England and Germany
are below their pre-war level. The industries of the U.S.A., which in 1929
had reached 170 per cent of its pre-war volume of production, now exceed
the pre-war level by only 10 per cent. At the same time the industries of the
Soviet Union have increased practically fourfold compared with the pre-war
output of the industries of tsarist Russia.
The catastrophic decline of production in capitalist countries signifies an
unprecedented waste of productive forces.
The production apparatus created by the sweat and blood of the toiling
masses is utilized to an extremely small degree. A considerable portion of the
blast furnaces, open hearths, mines, machine-building plants and textile mills
is not utilized. Enterprises equipped according to the last word in engineering
stand idle. Tremendous means invested in these enterprises are wasted; the
plants themselves go to pieces as they are not used or attended to. The over-
whelming majority of enterprises work at only part capacity. The considerable
under-employment of the working capacity of enterprises is one of the clearest
expressions of the general crisis of the capitalist system.
Thus, for instance, in the United States, the chronic utilization of plants
below capacity expressed itself in the fact that even up to the beginning of
the crisis in 1929 coal mines were worked only to 68 per cent of their capac-
ity, oil wells to 67 per cent, oil refineries to 76 per cent, iron smelters to 60-
80 per cent, automobile plants to not more than 50 per cent, machine-
building plants to 55 per cent, textile mills to 72 per cent, and in some
branches even less – as in the polygraphic industry to 50 per cent, in the
flour-milling industry to 40 per cent and in the woollen mills to 36 per cent.
Thus the basic industries, even before the crisis, could not utilize their enor-
mous production capacity in full. The underemployment of the working ca-
pacity of the enterprises increased enormously as a result of the crisis and
the decline in production.
Only 13 per cent of the equipment of steel mills and only 11 per cent of
the machinery used in the manufacture of automobiles were still in operation
in the U.S.A. in October 1932. In Germany the entire industry worked at 36
per cent of capacity in December 1932, in heavy industry the percentage was
even smaller.
In the United States 60 blast furnaces were reduced to scrap in 4 years.
In 1931, 12 open-hearth steel furnaces with a total capacity of 710,000 tons
of steel and 13 rolling mills were torn down. In Germany 23 blast furnaces
and 38 open-hearth furnaces were destroyed.
In bourgeois newspapers one can find dozens of descriptions of tremen-
dous machinery “cemeteries” that have sprung up in all capitalist countries.
Plants and warehouses with boarded up doors, powerful cranes standing in
dusty neglect, abandoned, railroad branch lines overgrown with grass, whole
fleets of freight and passenger steamships, forests of dead factory chimneys
214
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
extend for miles in the industrial regions of the richest capitalist countries.
The decline in the national income and reduction
in the national wealth
The curtailment of production in industry and agriculture and the reduc-
tion in transportation involve a reduction in the total values produced annu-
ally in the capitalist countries. This means that the national income declines
in capitalist countries.
But it is not only the national income which declines in the capitalist
countries under the influence of the crisis. Factories that are standing idle go
to wrack and ruin. Houses that are not repaired become uninhabitable. Fields
that lie uncultivated become over-run with weeds. For lack of use and care
machinery rusts and becomes useless. Tremendous quantities of goods that
cannot be sold are destroyed in various ways. A wanton waste and destruc-
tion of wealth, accumulated by scores of years of persistent toil, take place in
most diverse forms. An extraordinary squandering of productive forces, ac-
cumulated by the toil of many generations, ensues.
The sum total of values in any country – plants, factories, buildings, ma-
chinery, equipment, manufactured goods and raw material – is usually called
the national wealth of that country. It is self-evident that in capitalist coun-
tries this wealth is not at all in the hands of the nation. On the contrary, un-
der capitalism it is concentrated in the hands of a small group of exploiters
and parasites, just as the preponderating part of the national income in capi-
talist countries does not at all go to the nation’s masses but to the minority of
drones.
Here is a table showing the decline in the national wealth and national
income of the most important capitalist countries for the first two years of
the crisis (in billions of dollars):
National Wealth National Income
Country 1929 1931 1929 1931
U.S.A. 400 240 90.0 54.0
England 115 69 19.0 11.4
Germany 80 48 15.5 9.3
France 68 51 9.0 6.7
Italy 30 18 5.0 3.0
These figures show that for two years of the crisis five of the most im-
portant capitalist countries lost almost 40 per cent of their national wealth
($267,000,000,000 out of $693,000,000,000 at the beginning of the crisis).
Their national income also fell from $137,500,000,000 a year to
$84,400,000,000 a year, that is, also, about 40 per cent.
These figures give a universal picture of the unprecedented devastation
wrought by the crisis in the capitalist world. These figures clearly illustrate
215
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
the senselessness, the criminality of the capitalist system which blindly de-
stroys untold wealth while condemning tens and hundreds of millions of
people to hunger and death.
The present crisis has far exceeded previous crises in the extent of the
decline of the national income and the destruction of national wealth. For
comparison it is sufficient to point out that in the 1901 crisis the national
income of Germany fell 6 per cent; the 1907 crisis reduced the national in-
come of Germany 4 per cent, and the national income of England 5 per cent.
Unemployment and the conditions of the working class
The entire weight of the world crisis of capitalism fell on the working
class. The crisis brought about an unprecedented aggravation of the condi-
tions of the working class, an extraordinary increase in the unemployment
and exploitation of the proletariat.
The universal crisis of capitalism which started with the World War
called forth a considerable increase in unemployment. After the war, unem-
ployment in the principal capitalist countries reached enormous proportions.
The industrial reserve army, which formerly disappeared in times of prosper-
ity, has become a permanent army of unemployed since the war. The size of
this army of permanently unemployed was quite large even before the be-
ginning of the present crisis. Thus in England the number of unemployed
since 1920 has never been below a million. Unemployment increased with
the wave of capitalist rationalization that spread in the years from 1925 to
1927. Because of the increase in the intensity of labour the capitalists
achieve “economies” in labour power. Hundreds of thousands of workers
prove “superfluous” for this reason.
In June 1927 the percentage of unemployed in England: amounted to 8.8
per cent and in February 1929 it was already 12.2 per cent; in Germany for
the same period 6.3 per cent and 22.3 per cent or 2,622,000 were unem-
ployed; in the U.S.A. in 1927 there were 2,100,000 unemployed, and at the
end of 1928 and beginning of 1929 there were 3,400,000 unemployed.
The crisis which began in 1929 brought about a colossal increase in un-
employment. The curtailment of production threw millions of workers out of
employment. Under pressure of the crisis a further intensification of labour
was inaugurated and the exploitation of those workers who remained at work
was increased.
In the period of the present crisis unemployment reached proportions
never before experienced in the entire history of capitalism. According to the
most conservative estimates the number of unemployed in the major capital-
ist countries was 45,000,000 people. If we take the families into considera-
tion this constitutes the entire population of a country like the U.S.A. To this
number must be added the tremendous number of workers who are only em-
ployed part time, that is, who work one to two days a week. Finally, these
216
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
figures do not include the vast masses of toilers in the colonial countries
whom the crisis deprived of their last piece of bread. For the period of the
crisis world unemployment increased four to five times, and in a number of
countries even more.
It must be kept in mind that the most important capitalist countries have
no really adequate or reliable statistics on unemployment. Usually the statis-
tical data greatly underestimate.
In a country like the U.S.A. there are no official data on unemployment.
But even bourgeois newspapers cannot hide the fact that at the very lowest
point of the crisis there were approximately 17,000,000 unemployed in the
U.S.A. This amounts to about half the working class in this richest of indus-
trial countries. In England there are some data on the number of unemployed
from the social insurance lists. These lists show about 3,000,000 unem-
ployed. But during the years of the crisis several hundred thousand workers
were removed from the social insurance list. Hundreds of thousands received
no social insurance. In Germany the official data on unemployment very
much underestimate the actual situation, particularly since the Hitler fascist
regime came into power; nevertheless, the number of unemployed there,
even according to official data, is not less than 5,000,000.
At the present time it is rare to find a worker’s family in a capitalist
country in which the head of the family or at least the children or some
member of the family is not unemployed. This means that the meagre wage
of the one who is working must feed a greater number of mouths. It means
that the one who is working cannot be sure of the morrow, cannot be at ease
as to his fate, since the threat of losing his job is always over him.
Capital conducts a desperate onslaught on the miserable dole that is
handed out to the unemployed in capitalist countries. On the pretext of
“economy” in government expenses the aid rendered the unemployed is
greatly reduced. In such countries as France and the U.S.A. there is no social
insurance against unemployment and the unemployed must die of starvation
or apply to private charity. But even in those countries where unemployment
insurance does exist there is a desperate attack on the unemployment dole. In
Germany and England the dole has been cut down considerably. In addition,
part of the unemployed have been deprived of the dole altogether.
Under the conditions of the crisis the bourgeoisie conducts an attack
against the standard of living of the working class. In all countries the de-
gree of exploitation of those workers who were still employed increased
enormously. In a number of cases the working day was lengthened. The in-
tensity of labour grew. Those who were partially employed were paid ex-
ceedingly low wages. Working conditions were aggravated in every way.
The bourgeoisie makes use of the crisis conditions for an organized at-
tack on the wages of the workers. During the crisis a reduction in wages was
217
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
effected in all capitalist countries, in every branch of the national economy.
During the years of the crisis the amount of money paid out in wages to
the working class as a whole decreased considerably. In the U.S.A. the
amount paid out in wages in 1932 was only 33 per cent of what it formerly
was. The wages of the working class in Germany fell off 26,000,000,000
marks for three years of the crisis. During this same period the wages fund in
the U.S.S.R., the land of socialism, increased from 8,000,000,000 to
30,000,000,000 rubles.
A certain German economist has investigated how the level of the real
wages of workers in the principal capitalist countries has changed in the past
ten years. On the basis of his investigation he came to the following
conclusion:
“If we compare the level of real wages at present with that of
previous decades we find the following: in Germany and the U.S.A.
the level of real wages is lower than it has ever been for the last half
century; in England real wages are at the same level as they were at
the end of the nineteenth and the beginning of the twentieth
centuries.”
Data from various countries prove this.
Germany. The level of real wages for the latest period has been continu-
ally reduced. Thus, taking 1913-14 as 100, we get the following index num-
bers (in 1928 the level of real wages as a result of slow increases was 100,
but the years following show a continuous decline):
1925 98
1928 100
1930 89
1931 79
1932 64
In 1933 there was a further reduction in the standard of living of the
German working class.
The conditions of the unemployed are even worse. Not to speak of the
great number of unemployed who were altogether deprived of government
aid mainly for political reasons, the fascist administration has reduced the
dole of all others.
England. The average wages of English workers were (taking 1895-
1903 as 100) 98 in 1927, 97 in 1929, 94 in 1932.
In the U.S.A. the wages of the working class as a whole, rising from
1922, reached their highest point in 1929. Taking 1898-1908 as 100, in 1929
they were 125. But at this point a sharp decline began to pull the standard of
living down to the level of years ago. In 1930 the index number fell to 105,
in 1931 to 91, in 1932 to 71.
218
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
Unemployed raking about in garbage cans for something to eat, forming
endless queues at the doors of charity soup kitchens – this is a common pic-
ture in any capitalist city now. Tramping the highways has become common
in the U.S.A. Hordes of people, in entire families, including their children
and their whole miserable household, can often be met on the highways
roaming about in a vain search for work. An investigation conducted by
some charity organization pointed out that in the U.S.A. over a million and a
half unemployed thus wander over the highways.
Hunger drives people to desperation. The number of suicides all over
the capitalist world is continually increasing. In Berlin alone an average of
sixty people daily commit suicide because of starvation.
The so-called help for the unemployed becomes a means of compulsion to
slavery, of forced hard labour. Forced labour for the unemployed is very much
in vogue now in many capitalist countries. At the threat of being deprived of
all assistance, the unemployed are driven to so-called “public works” (these
are mostly either unskilled labour requirements of some big landlords or some
kind of military construction), concentrated in various camps and settlements
where prison discipline prevails. The pay for this work, taken away from in-
dustrial or agricultural workers, is also prison pay. The fascist government of
Germany is hurriedly building such forced labour camps for the unemployed
youth. This example is most tempting to the other capitalist countries which a
few years ago raised such a self-righteous hue and cry about “forced labour”
in the Soviet Union where labour has really became “a matter of honour, a
matter of glory, a matter of valour and heroism.”
The attacks of capital against the vital interests of the workers call forth
resistance on the part of broad sections of the proletariat. A wave of strikes
sweeps over the capitalist countries. Under conditions of the present crisis
these strike struggles are distinguished by a special pertinacity. They help
the workers to understand the real situation. They show up clearly who is
their friend and who their enemy. Under the conditions of the crisis, strikes
soon assume the character of a challenge to the bourgeois order which
criminally condemns millions of people to hopeless misery.
Interweaving of the industrial and agricultural crises
The special acuteness and depth of this crisis are the result of the fact
that both industrial and agrarian countries, both industry and agriculture in
capitalist countries have been affected by it. The present crisis sharpened
and exposed all the fundamental contradictions of the capitalist system, in-
cluding the between industry and agriculture.
“In the course of development of the economic crisis, the indus-
trial crisis in the chief capitalist countries has not simply coincided,
but has become interwoven with the agricultural crisis in the agrar-
219
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
ian countries, aggravating the difficulties and predetermining the in-
evitability of a general decline in economic activity.”*
The industrial crisis leads to an unprecedented growth in unemploy-
ment, to the extreme impoverishment of the toiling masses. The poverty of
the masses means a curtailment in the sales of agricultural products. In addi-
tion to this the curtailment in production also means a curtailment in the de-
mand for agricultural raw material: cotton, wool, etc. In its turn, the agricul-
tural crisis, in ruining the masses of the peasantry, deprives them of the abil-
ity to purchase industrial commodities, thus contracting the sales market for
industry.
The agricultural crisis is a glaring instance of the inability of capitalism
to manage the modern development of productive forces. Modern engineer-
ing makes it possible to use entirely new methods of labour, opens up oppor-
tunities for mechanization which means a colossal increase in productivity.
The limits of capitalism are, however, too narrow for modern technical
achievements. Sharpening the contrast between city and village, capitalism
dooms the village to stagnation and decline. Capitalist relationships are a
stumbling block to the further development of agriculture.
The decline and stagnation of agriculture in capitalist countries is re-
vealed particularly glaringly when compared with the U.S.S.R. While the
area under cultivation in the Soviet Union increased in only the one year of
1931 by about ten million hectares, the area under cultivation for grain in all
capitalist countries has increased in the past twenty years by only thirty mil-
lion hectares. The World War evoked a profound crisis in the agriculture of
capitalist countries. The pauperization of the masses of the peasantry and the
curtailment of production in a number of countries were results of this crisis.
The present crisis, in which the industrial and agricultural crises are inter-
woven, is fatal to the existence of tens of millions of farmers.
Giving rise to an unprecedented impoverishment of the proletariat and
the toiling masses in general, the crisis drastically cuts down the demand for
agricultural products and contracts the sales market for these products to its
smallest possible limits. This extreme contraction of the market results in the
accumulation of tremendous reserves of agricultural products and a catas-
trophic decline in prices. The accumulation of reserves, the decrease in sales
and the decline in prices in their turn bring about a restriction of production
in agriculture.
Warehouses and grain elevators in capitalist countries are filled with re-
serves of agricultural products. The leaders of the bourgeoisie see only one
way of getting rid of this abundance – to burn, allow to rot, throw into the
sea and destroy these reserves, but mainly to reduce the area under cultiva-
* Stalin, Leninism, Vol. II, “Political Report to the Sixteenth Congress,” p. 254.
220
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
tion in order to compel agriculture to produce less. Mountains of wheat and
maize were allowed to rot or were burned, rivers of milk were poured out, in
Germany grain was treated with a special chemical which made it unfit for
human consumption, so that it could be fed only to cattle.
Prices of agricultural commodities have fallen sharply during the crisis.
For instance, the wholesale price of wheat on the world market declined 70 per
cent, cotton, sugar, coffee and wool became half price. It would seem that the
city consumers, the masses of the population, should gain by this. In practice,
however, this is not so. Before the commodity reaches the ultimate consumer
it passes through the hands of dozens of middlemen, wholesalers, who are
united into big monopolies that do not let the retail prices drop. Retail prices in
most capitalist countries did not decline much during the years of the crisis
and in some countries they even rose (Germany, for instance). But the farmer,
the mass of the toiling peasantry, has to deal with the wholesaler and sell his
products at extremely low prices which often do not cover his expenses on
seed and equipment, not to speak of the labour he has expended.
The farmer has to pay taxes to the government, rent to the landlord, in-
terest on bank loans, just as before and even in greater amounts. The pay-
ments in interest on loans and taxes take the lion’s share of what the poor
and middle farmer realize on the market. The farm and all the farmer’s
household goods are sold at auction for debts and taxes. Hundreds and thou-
sands of farms have thus been lost by the poor and middle farmers not only
in Europe but also in the U.S.A., the land to which the capitalists have al-
ways pointed as the paragon of the well-doing and thriving of agriculture
under capitalism. Such unprecedented ruin gives rise to a growing resistance
on the part of the toiling farmers against the pressure of capital, landlord and
bank. The farmers strive to unite, organize against the sale of their goods at
auction, refusing to buy the property. There have been cases in America
where the farmers of a district have gathered in an organized fashion at auc-
tion sales of ruined farmers and kept the bid down to one dollar for the entire
property. In this way, the representatives of the banks were compelled to call
off the auction and prolong the term of debt payments.
Abandoning their farms the ruined peasants swell the armies of beggars
that crowd the highways. The conditions of the hired farm hands in capitalist
countries are even worse. In both Europe and America it has become a
common thing for landlords and rich exploiting farmers who hire farm hands
to refuse to pay in money for the labour power. For a handful of grain, a
peck of half-rotten potatoes they can get an unemployed worker from the
city to do the same work. The bourgeois scribblers shout about returning to
the land. Special societies are formed for the organization of so-called “set-
tlements” for the unemployed. But this only means that there is an increase
in the number of petty farms which without equipment can hardly raise
221
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
enough to feed the workers who spend their hopeless days and nights in
working on them. The crisis of capitalist agriculture clearly shows the hope-
lessness of the situation of small-scale production under capitalism.
The poor and middle farmers suffer most from the blows of the agrarian
crisis. The crisis leads to the impoverishment of the broad masses of farm-
ers. The crisis speeds up the differentiation among the farmers, the transition
of many of them into the ranks of the proletariat. The burdens which the
peasantry have to bear in capitalist countries under the influence of the crisis
are especially unbearable. Taxes, rent, interest on debts and all other charges
– all this presses most heavily on the great masses of the peasantry under
conditions of the crisis.
The agrarian crisis causes a curtailment in the production of agricultural
products. Bourgeois governments in a number of countries frankly advise
curtailment of production declaring that this, in their opinion, is the only
way to alleviate the agrarian crisis. The curtailment of production in agricul-
ture, as in industry, involves a tremendous destruction of productive forces.
Wheat and maize fields stand bare and unsown, cotton, rubber and coffee
plantations remain unattended or are altogether cleared. And this at a time
when millions of people are starving, have no roofs over their heads and lack
even the most necessary clothing.
The agrarian crisis and the ruin of the masses of the peasants brought
about a decline in agriculture. The sale of agricultural machinery and artifi-
cial fertilizers has fallen off catastrophically. In the foremost capitalist coun-
tries the use of tractors, sowers and harvesters has been curtailed. The crisis
brought about the degradation and ruin of agriculture in the capitalist world.
The crisis and monopolies
One of the most important distinguishing characteristics of the contem-
porary crisis is its development on the basis of monopoly capitalism.
“Present-day capitalism, as distinguished from older capitalism,
is monopolistic capitalism, and this inevitably gives rise to the
struggle between the capitalist combines to maintain high monopo-
list prices of commodities in spite of overproduction. Obviously,
this circumstance, which makes the crisis particularly painful and
ruinous for the mass of the people, who are the basic consumers of
commodities; cannot but lead to the dragging out of the crisis, can-
not but retard its dissipation.”*
For many years the lackeys of the bourgeoisie claimed that the growth
of monopolies indicates a transition to organized capitalism. The apologists
of capital told fairy tales about crises being things of the past for monopoly
* Ibid., p. 254.
222
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
capitalism. The present crisis revealed the absolute falsity of these inven-
tions. Actually, the monopolistic nature of modern capitalism has led to an
extreme sharpening of the crisis, to its deepening and protraction.
The lords of monopoly tried, first of all, to shift the entire burden of the
crisis onto the shoulders of the broad masses of consumers, attempting to
maintain inflated prices even under conditions of overproduction. And actu-
ally, irrespective of overproduction, prices on a host of products of monopo-
lized branches of industry fell much more slowly than prices of commodities
produced by other branches.
Germany Austria Poland
(1926 = 100) (1923-31 = 100) (1928 = 100)
Years Cartel Free Cartel Free Cartel Free
Prices Prices Prices Prices Prices Prices
1928 102.1 106.8 – – –
1929 105.0 97.4 99 100 107.7 93.6
1930 103.1 79.7 96 87 108.9 80.9
1931 93.6 60.8 91 76 107.8 63.8
1932 83.9 47.5 93 73 106.1 52.5
1933 83.9 48.3 94 73 94.8 48.8
In a number of cases the pressure of the crisis nevertheless proves
stronger than monopolistic ties and then prices drop precipitately and the
monopoly itself goes to pieces. This is particularly true for the branches en-
gaged in the production of raw material. The sharp decline in the demand for
raw material and the accumulation of tremendous reserves compel the pro-
ducers ultimately to reduce prices considerably. In these fields the monopo-
lists proved unable to maintain prices at a high level.
All the contradictions inherent in the nature of monopoly capitalism
greatly increase under the circumstances of the crisis. It is perfectly clear
that the trend of monopolies towards maintaining high price levels leads to
the sharpest kind of conflict between a few monopolies, on the one hand,
and the entire mass of the consumers of their products, on the other. This
conflict becomes more acute between the monopolized branches of industry
and those branches where monopoly is negligible. Further, the conflict be-
tween the monopolies themselves is sharpened tremendously. The contradic-
tions that rend individual monopolies increase sharply, the struggle within
separate monopoly organizations grows keener. A number of monopolies
cannot stand the blows of the crisis and fall to pieces.
The following big monopoly combinations, for example, were dissolved
during the crisis: the International Zinc Cartel, the European Pig Iron Cartel,
the International Tin Cartel. The European Steel Cartel, under continual
powerful pressure, was practically compelled to sanction a return to free
223
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
competition among its members. In Germany the organization of the artifi-
cial silk producers fell apart and the zinc cartel failed; in France the pig iron
syndicate was dissolved, etc.
The governments of capitalist countries give the monopoly associations
powerful support. Monopolies which get into difficulties receive all kinds of
subsidies and other help from the government treasury. Many hundreds of
millions of marks, dollars and francs have thus been transferred from the
lean pockets of the taxpayers to the coffers of private capitalists.
The monopolistic nature of modern capitalism leads to a protraction of
the crisis. In the epoch of free competition, the general reduction of prices,
the failure of the weaker business organizations and the curtailment of pro-
duction led to a gradual dissipation of the crisis and to a renewal of the cy-
clical movement of industry. With the prevalence of monopolies this method
of the natural dissipation of the crisis becomes very much more difficult.
The reign of monopolies leads to a sharpening of the crisis and to its further
deepening.
The decline in foreign trade
The crisis of overproduction and the contraction of markets lead to a de-
cline in foreign trade. The present crisis exceeded all previous crises in the
history of capitalism with respect to the decline in foreign trade.
The following table, showing the decline in foreign trade for 1929-31 as
compared with that of previous crises, bears eloquent witness to this.
DECLINE IN FOREIGN TURNOVER
Crises Percentage
1873-1874 5
1883-1884 4
1900-1901 1
1907-1908 7
1929-1932 65
The decline in world trade weakened the economic ties without which
capitalist economy cannot exist. Industrial countries greatly reduced the
amount of imports of raw material. Agrarian countries reduced the import of
manufactured articles. This led to a still greater curtailment of both produc-
tion and consumption by the broad masses of the workers.
The decline in world trade most forcibly affected the biggest capitalist
countries, which occupy a dominant position in the world market. Here are
the index numbers showing the reduction in export and import of the most
important capitalist countries. (The figures for 1929 are taken as 100.)
224
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
225
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
market. The restriction of production inevitably led to a fall in profits, to
losses and tremendous changes in the distribution of profits among the vari-
ous groups of capitalists.
The crisis led to an unprecedented number of bankruptcies of all kinds
of enterprises.
NUMBER OF BANKRUPTCIES
1929 1930 1931 1932 1933
U.S.A. 22,909 29,355 29,288 31,882 17,732
England 5,900 6,287 6,818 7,321 4,927
Germany 9,846 15,486 19,254 13,966 3,718
France 6,092 6,249 7,220 9,014 8,362
Poland 516 815 738 545 259
The credit crisis has been maturing for a long time. The failures of en-
terprises connected with banks, government budget difficulties, the decline
in profits and the increase in losses, the fall in the prices of stock – all this
prepared the way for an explosion of the credit crisis, which burst forth with
extraordinary force in 1931. Industrial failures caused by the decline in pro-
duction and prices, the impossibility of realizing products, the depreciation
of the stock in hand, etc., inevitably brought about the failure of credit insti-
tutions. Bank failures, in their turn, created difficulties for industry and re-
sulted in new industrial bankruptcies.
The credit crisis first developed in Germany and Austria. As early in the
spring of 1931 the biggest bank in Austria, which had control of 75-80 per
cent of all the industries of the country, crashed. This was followed by a
number of bankruptcies of the largest industrial enterprises in Germany. In
June 1931 the third biggest bank in Germany (the Darmstadt and National
Bank) and another big bank – the Dresden Bank – failed. From Central
Europe the wave of the credit crisis engulfed England, resulting in a credit
crisis in France, America and other capitalist countries.
Under the blows of the crisis a number of the biggest enterprises, consti-
tuting the “pride and glory” of world monopoly capital, failed during the sec-
ond half of 1931 and in 1932. The Swedish Kreuger Match Trust crashed.
Working on American capital, Kreuger wanted to seize the match monopoly
of all countries. He led a frantic campaign against the Soviet Union: the export
of matches from the Soviet Union was an unwelcome obstacle to him.
Kreuger shot himself on the eve of his bankruptcy. After his death it appeared
that in the last years he had held himself afloat by a number of forgeries and
swindles by means of which he delayed the moment of his failure. It was also
revealed that very high state officials of a number of countries had been in his
pay. Many Social-Democratic leaders were supported by him.
One of the biggest American business men – Insull – also proved to be
an outright swindler. In the spring of 1932 the corporation which he headed
226
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
and which owns electric power stations, gas plants and water supplies in
sixty cities, having a capital of half a billion dollars, crashed.
“...the crisis has not been restricted to the sphere of production
and trade, but has also affected the credit system, currency, the
sphere of debt obligations, etc., and this has broken down the tradi-
tionally established relations both between separate countries and
between social groups in the separate countries.
“An important role in this was played by the drop in the prices
of commodities. Notwithstanding the resistance of the monopolist
cartels, the drop in prices increased with elemental force, and the
drop in prices occurred primarily and mostly in regard to the com-
modities of the unorganized commodity owners, viz., peasants, arti-
sans, small capitalists; the drop was gradual and smaller in degree in
regard to the prices of commodities offered by the organized com-
modity owners, viz., the capitalists united in cartels. The drop in
prices made the position of debtors (manufacturers, artisans, peas-
ants, etc.) intolerable while on the other hand it placed the creditors
in an unprecedently privileged position. Such a situation had to lead
and really did lead to the colossal bankruptcy of firms and separate
entrepreneurs. During the past three years tens of thousands of joint
stock companies were ruined in this way in the United States, in
Germany, in England and in France. The bankruptcy of joint stock
companies was followed by the depreciation of the currency, which
to some extent eased the position of the debtors. Depreciation of
currency was followed by the legalized non-payment of debts, both
foreign and internal.”*
The development of the crisis led to the broadest inflation, that is, de-
preciation of currency. The drop in prices results in great difficulties for the
debtor: a debt of the same amount payable when prices have declined costs
him a considerably greater quantity of commodities than when he contracted
the debt. The drop in prices adds additional burdens to the shoulders of
debtor entrepreneurs and makes the positions of entire countries that are
considerably in debt much worse. What is the way out of this difficulty? The
capitalists and their governments seek a way out in two directions: by mora-
toriums, a stoppage of payment on debts, and by inflation. With the devel-
opment of the crisis capitalist countries one after another stopped their debt
payments. But that was not sufficient. They also adopted the course of infla-
tion. At first the weaker countries introduced this measure. Then in the au-
228
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
ties in noble parliaments of Europe and America were shouting until
they were hoarse. I mean the real dumping that is now being prac-
tised by nearly all the ‘civilized’ states, and about which the gallant
and noble deputies maintain a prudent silence.”*
The present depression and its peculiarities
The data on the movement of industrial production in capitalist coun-
tries show that the point of greatest decline was reached in 1932. The fol-
lowing year, 1933, industry in capitalist countries began to show a slight
upward trend. During the course of 1933 there were frequent fluctuations up
and down, nevertheless, industry did not drop to the low point it had reached
in the summer of 1932.
It would be incorrect to explain this phenomenon exclusively by the pol-
icy of inflation and the feverish war preparations which a number of gov-
ernments of capitalist countries have adopted. In some countries, Japan for
instance, colossal orders for the war industries have actually played a great
role. Improvement in the condition of industry is, however, to be observed in
all countries, including those which have a stable currency. It is conse-
quently evident that “side by side with the war-inflation boom the operation
of internal economic forces of capitalism also has effect here.Ӡ
By means of the fierce intensification of the degree of exploitation of
the working class, by means of the ruin of the masses of the farmers, by
means of the robbery of the toiling masses of colonial countries, capitalism
has succeeded in obtaining a slight improvement in the condition of indus-
try. The increased exploitation, the heightened intensity of labour, the reduc-
tion in wages – all this makes it possible for a number of capitalists to con-
tinue production even with a small demand and low prices of commodities.
Prices of raw materials and foodstuffs have declined at the expense of the
peasants and toilers in the colonies; this also means lower costs of produc-
tion for the capitalists. The crisis has destroyed a tremendous part of the
productive forces. The destruction of large quantities of goods has at last so
reduced the reserves that the ratio between supply and demand has in a
number of cases become more favourable. The wiping out of weaker enter-
prises has here and there cleared the market for the surviving stronger ones.
Thus industry in the principal capitalist countries has passed its lowest
point. From this low point industry has entered the phase of depression,
“…not an ordinary depression, but a depression of a special kind which
does not lead to a new boom and flourishing in industry but which, on the
* Ibid., p. 11.
† Ibid., p. 14.
229
POLITICAL ECONOMY – A BEGINNER’S COURSE
other hand, does not force it back to the lowest point of decline.”*
In ordinary times when capitalism had not yet reached its period of de-
cline and fall, crises were replaced by depressions, which were in turn re-
placed by periods of prosperity. But at the present time, capitalism is mori-
bund capitalism. It is undergoing its general crisis, rent by the most profound
contradictions which propel it to its doom. The present economic crisis broke
out amidst the general crisis of capitalism; that is why it is distinguished by
such depth and protractedness, such power of devastation and acuteness. The
new phase of depression has also been entered upon amidst this general crisis;
that is why this depression differs radically from the usual type of depression
and is not the forerunner of a new boom, a new period of prosperity.
“...because all these unfavourable conditions which prevent in-
dustry in the capitalist countries from rising to any serious extent
still continue to operate. I have in mind the continuing general crisis
of capitalism in the midst of which the economic crisis is proceed-
ing, the chronic working of the enterprises under capacity, the
chronic mass unemployment, the interweaving of the industrial cri-
sis with the agricultural crisis, the absence of tendencies towards
any serious renewal of fixed capital which usually heralds the ap-
proach of a boom, etc., etc.Ӡ
The eve of a new round of revolutions and wars
The crisis raging in the whole capitalist world since 1929 has sharpened
to the utmost all the internal and external contradictions of the capitalist sys-
tem. The protracted crisis has brought about an unparalleled aggravation of
the conditions of the toiling masses. Colossal unemployment, ruthless reduc-
tion in wages, the intensification of exploitation – this is the fate of the
working class under the conditions of the present crisis. The crisis has also
subjected the broad masses of farmers to unprecedented ruin. Together with
their impoverishment there is a tremendous upsurge of the resentment of the
toiling masses against the capitalist system.
In the face of the indignation of the masses, the bourgeoisie is more and
more abandoning the old methods by means of which it formerly held the
working class in subjection and is passing over to open terrorist, fascist dic-
tatorship. In Germany the bourgeoisie, with the aid of the Social-Democrats,
set up the bloody dictatorship of Hitler in February 1933. Fascist tendencies
are growing among the bourgeoisie in other countries as well. The estab-
lishment of fascism in Germany bears evidence not only of the traitorous
role of the Social-Democrats who split the ranks of the working class and
* Ibid., p. 15.
Ibid., pp. 14-15.
230
THE CONTEMPORARY WORLD CRISIS OF CAPITALISM
thus weakened its resistance to the bourgeois dictatorship, the accession of
Hitler to power also bears witness to the weakness of the bourgeoisie which
can no longer maintain power in its hands by the old methods of administra-
tion. The bourgeoisie is throwing off its democratic tinsel and is going over
to open, bloody terror against the working class. But this only results in a
further sharpening of the class struggle, threatening to explode the entire
structure of capitalism.
The protracted crisis has extremely sharpened all the existing antago-
nisms between the capitalist powers. Under conditions of the crisis every
country tries to shift its burden onto other countries. The struggle for mar-
kets has grown exceedingly keen. Having recourse to dumping on foreign
markets every country, at the same time, raises barriers around its own mar-
kets against the encroachments of foreign competition. The non-payment of
debts sharpens the antagonisms between creditor and debtor nations. The
crisis has intensified the action of the law of uneven development under im-
perialism. It affected various countries with varying force and thus produced
a shifting in the relation of forces among the imperialist nations. All this has
sharpened the relations between countries to the extreme. The preparations
for a new imperialist war are already proceeding in the most open fashion.
Capitalist countries are arming to the teeth in preparation for a new battle for
the redivision of the world. While all branches of industry restricted produc-
tion as a result of the crisis, one branch of industry – the war industries – did
not contract, but on the contrary, expands from year to year. A number of
years have already passed since Japan first occupied Manchuria with armed
forces and began pushing deeper into Northern China. The Sino-Japanese
war renders the struggle for the Pacific Ocean, where the imperialist inter-
ests of Japan, the United States and Great Britain clash, extremely acute.
In the secret chambers of imperialist staffs the plans for future wars are
already being worked out. Prominent among these plans are projects for
armed intervention against the Soviet Union.
“The tremendous strain of the internal class antagonisms in the
capitalist countries, as well as of the international antagonisms, testify
to the fact that the objective prerequisites for a revolutionary crisis
have matured to such an extent that at the present time the world is
closely approaching a new round of revolutions and wars.”*
The correctness of this estimate of the situation has been confirmed by a
tremendous number of facts. The countries where fascism was “victorious”
are in turmoil. In Germany the Communist Party is conducting an heroic