Payment of Adequate Compensation For Land Acquisit

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 25

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/237125458

Payment of Adequate Compensation for Land Acquisition in Malaysia

Article  in  Pacific Rim Property Research Journal · March 2015


DOI: 10.1080/14445921.2006.11104213

CITATIONS READS

29 14,066

2 authors:

Anuar Alias Mohd Nasir Daud


University of Malaya University of Malaya
57 PUBLICATIONS   359 CITATIONS    8 PUBLICATIONS   63 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Performance of Urban Heritage Trees in World Heritage Site View project

A FRAMEWORK FOR INTEGRATING SUSTAINABILITY INTO THE PROJECT PLANNING PROCESS FOR BUILDINGS: THE CASE OF MALAYSIA View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Anuar Alias on 14 April 2016.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


PAYMENT OF ADEQUATE COMPENSATION FOR
LAND ACQUISITION IN MALAYSIA

ANUAR ALIAS and MD NASIR DAUD


University of Malaya

ABSTRACT
Land acquisition involves the compulsory taking of land, often against the will of the
landowners. The law in Malaysia requires the state to pay compensation adequately;
however, adequate compensation is not defined in the statute. Historically, the courts
seem to have succumbed to the pretense that the adequacy requirement may be achieved
by giving sufficient monetary rewards in exchange. The questions are what monetary
quantum is appropriate to constitute the constitutional mandate of adequate
compensation; what should be the measure of compensation; what makes compensation
adequate, and what are the tests of adequacy? A questionnaire survey was conducted
among practicing valuers to discern their views with regard to the above issues. This
survey revealed the views that compensation attributes under the stipulated laws are not
adequate to fulfill adequate compensation notion under the spirit of Article 13 of Federal
Constitution 1957. There is a need to review the heads of compensation structures by
incorporating other countries practices such as payment of solatium or premium as over
and above total compensation. Most of the valuers believed that land acquisition need not
necessarily present the best alternative for the government to secure land for
development.

Keywords: Land acquisition, adequate compensation, compensation structure.

INTRODUCTION

In Malaysia, federal, state, local governments and public authorities are vested by statute
with the power to acquire land. The law of land acquisition is principally concerned with
the rules governing the procedure to be followed in acquiring the land by compulsory
means and with the awarding of compensation to the dispossessed landowner. Here,
property is acquired by the state against the will of the landowner, but this can be done in
the public interest and not in private interest (Brown, 1991). Eminent domain does not
permit taking property of A and giving it to B to confer benefit on him. It also does not
permit taking away property without just compensation. It is not eminent domain but
expropriation, and this is illegal (Jain & Xavier, 1999).

The land acquisition statutes also provide that a dispossessed landowner shall receive
compensation for the loss of the resumed land. According to Rowan-Robinson and Brand
326 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3
(1995), the purpose of compensation is to compel the owner to sell the right (in monetary
terms) as though the land owner is in the same position as if his land had not been taken.
In other words, the landowner gains the right to receive a monetary payment not less than
the loss imposed on him in the public interest, but, on the other hand, no greater. The
underlying theme in the compensation provisions of the land acquisition statutes is to
ensure that a dispossessed landowner is no worse off and no better off as a result of his
eviction (Brown, 1991). This paper presents a study conducted via questionnaire survey
amongst practising valuers in Malaysia. The survey investigates land acquisition issues
and explores perspective of valuers regarding land acquisition implementations in
Malaysia. The survey emphasised the payment of adequate compensation to dispossessed
landowners.

LAND ACQUISITION IN MALAYSIA

Land is acquired in Malaysia under the Land Acquisition Act 1960. This is a serious
encroachment on the right to property by legislation, although the fact remains that over a
period of time, the law has been liberalized in certain aspects (Brown, 1991; Jain &
Xavier, 1996). Nevertheless, there are still some aspects of the law which need to be
modified (Jain & Xavier, 1996). Land acquisition and compensation matters are therefore
entirely creatures of statute (Xavier, 2001). Historically, the courts have declared that the
requirement may be satisfied by expressing adequate compensation in terms of money.
The problem then is to find out, how much money is required to meet the constitutional
mandate that adequate compensation be paid? To solve this problem, practitioners rely
upon the concept of market value that is also provided under the laws of compulsory
acquisition.

The law requires in any acquisition of land that the State Authority pay adequate
compensation. The term ‘adequate compensation’ is not defined. It is totally abstract; it
has no meaning from a practical standpoint, unless it is related to something which has a
concrete value (Graham, 1984 in Khong, 1996). Market value and adequate compensation
are not defined in acquisition laws, neither has it been contended that adequate
compensation and market value are the same thing. Obviously, in some cases they are not,
rather the idea is that market value is the best method of satisfying the requirement that
adequate compensation is paid. The idea is sound and it works well in practice (Khublal,
1994 in Khong, 1996). Therefore, it is the desire of the state to give adequate
compensation based only on market evidence, and if each party involved in land
acquisition will act in accordance with professional ethics, honesty and integrity, the
objective of arriving at adequate compensation will be achieved based on market value
(Khublal, 1994).

Dundas & Evans (2001) stated that the compensation on the market value basis is
considered to be satisfactory; however, there is a feeling that an additional payment,
probably a percentage of the value, should be paid to all property owners or, perhaps, only
to a restricted category, such as owners/occupiers. Epstein (1998) acknowledges that
Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 327
restrictions on the rights of others often serve as a form of implicit, in-kind compensation.
For example, zoning restrictions in a residential neighbourhood may be justified by the
average reciprocity of advantage received by residential landowners. A study in Aberdeen
(RICS, 1995; Rowan-Robinson et al, 1995) also recommends that a supplement should be
paid. If the compensation were seen to be more generous, it could be possible to present
compulsory purchase positively to the extent that, if it were sufficiently high,
owners/occupiers might welcome compulsory purchase.

The meaning of adequate compensation has different interpretations in different countries.


In United States, the market value of the subject property is generally held as just
compensation for the dispossessed owner (Eaton, 1995). In UK, compensation is based on
the principle of value to owner that is made up of market value together with other losses
suffered by the claimant (Denyer-Green, 1994). This principle is broadly followed in most
Commonwealth countries and regions such as Australia (Rost & Collins, 1984) and Hong
Kong (Cruden, 1986). In China, the current compensation laws are far from adequate, due
to the just terms compensation principle not being in place, and has caused great
discontent (Chan, 2003).

Usilappan (1997, 2000) concerned payment of fair, equitable and just compensation to the
affected owners. The Constitution required payment of adequate compensation and the
Act provides for market value and other damages and, though these appear equitable in
law, in practice the landowners still suffer. Various amendments to the Act provide the
landowners lesser compensation such as compensation on planned use, relocation
hardships and business losses. Most jurisdictions have done away with betterment, but in
Malaysia the betterment clause is still in the Act (Buang, 2001; Usilappan, 2000; Xavier,
1999).

Based on the above discussions and the current attributes of compensation under laws of
land acquisition in Malaysia, are compensations adequate? Are the landowners
compensated well? Therefore, the main issue of this research can be concluded as ‘To
what extent the notion of adequate compensation as applied by the existing laws is
concordant with the expectation of the parties involved’.

RESEARCH AIMS AND OBJECTIVES

This research has been carried out in Malaysia with the aim of assessing whether the
existing compensation framework for land acquisition as stipulated in First Schedule of
Land Acquisition Act, 1960 and other related rules, circulars, and guidelines released by
related government agencies, Board of Valuers, Appraisers and Estate Agents, Malaysia,
and valuation practices in Malaysia are effective and adequate in safeguarding the owners’
interest and losses. Specifically, the research assesses the existing (local and foreign
countries) compensation structure, legal instruments and the practice of valuation in
determining adequate compensation for affected land owners.
328 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3
The research firstly reviews all the international guidelines such as acts, charters,
recommendations, and resolutions on compensation as practised by the foreign countries
such as the United Kingdom, USA, India, Australia and Singapore. UK, India, Australia
and Singapore are selected due to the origins of the law is similar to Malaysia. USA is
selected due to comprehensive legal procedures and determination of so-called just
compensation adopted by various states in US is quite substantial. Secondly, the research
studies procedures of the acquisition process in selected countries, with the objective to
consolidate understanding on their significance as well as understanding their approaches
towards compulsory acquisition. Finally, the research assesses the implementation
framework at local level by focussing on whether the practices and guidelines of foreign
countries could be implemented into a local Malaysian context in relation to three aspects:
legal instruments, management/procedural structures and effective valuation approaches
of compensation with the objectives to identify their strengths and weaknesses.

OVERVIEW OF LAND ACQUISITION


Land Acquisition Laws
Freedom of the person and the right to acquire, hold and enjoy property are the two pillars
on which a democratic society rests. These are characteristics as natural rights of the
people. Property is not only an economic asset; it also has emotional and sentimental
value (Jain & Xavier, 1996). The right to property is not absolute. This right has always
been regarded as being subject to eminent domain, an inherent right of the state, an
essential part of the state sovereignty (Ghosh, 1973). Eminent domain is subject to two
essential conditions: private property is to be taken only for public use; and just
compensation must be paid for the property taken (Keith, 1984). Land acquisition,
therefore, is a way of direct control over land development. Land acquisition is also the
government’s tool to assemble land in resolving the land supply problems for
development. Land assembly through land acquisition is a way out to solve problems
with landownership and landowners’ reluctance to offer their land for development (Omar
& Ismail, 2005). The power of compulsory purchase supports the land assembly
negotiations in order to avoid situations where individual landowners can freeze
development by refusing to sell, particularly by trying to hold out for unreasonable
purchase price (Ball, 1996). Under certain circumstances, such as when there are
landownership problems and passive landowners, the government feels that to undertake
land development by compulsory purchase is more complicated, time consuming and
more expensive than to reclaim land from sea for development in certain waterfront areas
(Omar, 1999; Omar & Ismail, 2005).

The government of Malaysia is engaged in a massive programme of construction of


various public works all over the country that involves acquisition of private land on a
large scale. The government intervention over land development is directly exercised

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 329


under the power of land acquisition as stipulated under the Land Acquisition Act (1960),
and provided under Article 13 of the Malaysian Constitution (1957). This article stipulates
that no person may be deprived of property in accordance with law and no law may
provide for compulsory acquisition or for the use of property without adequate
compensation. With reference to the clause of the land acquisition by the Federal
Government, Article 83 set out detailed procedures for land compensation as stipulated by
the Malaysian Constitution (1957). Therefore, using the power contained in the Land
Acquisition Act (1960), the government can acquire land for public purposes with
adequate compensation as determined under Schedule 2 of the Act. Adequate
compensation, therefore, as stated under the provision of Article 13(2) of the Federal
Constitution refers to the amount of compensation which is decided, considering all
principles stated under the First Schedule of the Land Acquisition Act 1960. Even though
the State Authority, under the provision of Land Acquisition Act 1960, has the power to
possess any private land, it does not allow the authority to violate one’s right onto their
private properties (Omar & Ismail, 2005).

Principles of Compensation
The term compensation is used in a number of other statutes. It has a well understood
meaning in respect of workers’ compensation. It has a different meaning from damages in
the law of contract and tort. When used in the context of deprivation of land it means
recompense or amends. It means the sum of money which the owner would have got had
he sold the land on the open market plus other losses which result from the resumption.
However, the term compensation is not defined in the land acquisition statutes. The term
takes its meaning from the provisions which define what monetary sum must be paid to
the dispossessed owner for the loss of his land (Brown, 1991; Rowan-Robinson & Brand,
1995). The sum payable may represent a sum not only for the land taken, but also other
losses suffered in consequence of the acquisition. The fundamental principle has been to
place the affected landowners in the same position, after the acquisition as he was before,
nor worse, nor better. This also called the principle of equivalence (Cruden, 1986; Brown,
1991, Rowan-Robinson & Brand, 1995; Teo & Khaw, 1995; Jain & Xavier, 1996;
Usilappan, 1997).

Measurement of Adequate Compensation


What should be the measure of compensation? According to Elliott (1977), there is
nothing in any compulsory acquisition laws mentioned on the measure or yardstick to
apply in assessing the compensation. As the result of the unusually open texture of the
legislation, the measure of compensation was left to the arbitrators or juries to determine
(Parish, 1985). Michelman (1980) develops two models of compensation designed to
achieve different objectives, one derived from classical utilitarianism and the other, the
fairness model derived from the justice as fairness approach of John Rawls. Michelman’s
main concern was with the question ‘when to compensate’. However, Bell (1980)

330 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


considers how the objectives of these two models might be reflected in the measure of
compensation. Bell suggests that the objective of the utilitarian approach would be to
maximise social welfare. His research indicates that in view of the time, trouble and
expense being invested in lengthy negotiations with landowners, the greater net benefit
would be likely to be achieved by a measure of compensation which provides claimants
with a small balance of advantages thus encouraging less objections and speedier
settlements. An interesting example of a utilitarian approach to compensation is as quoted
by Cullingworth (1980), who cites the Minister of Transport in a memorandum in 1958 to
the Minister of Housing and Local Government as stating that his department ‘could not
be more strongly in favour’ of a Bill providing for an increase in the measure of
compensation for compulsory acquisition because of the difficulties faced by his
department in time consuming procedures for compulsory acquisition at unattractive rates
of compensation. Bell suggests that this small balance of advantage might be assessed by
reference to the optimum point on a claimant’s satisfaction curve. On the data available,
he estimated that this would point to an addition of some 30 percent to the market value of
a holding.

A Rawlsian approach to compensation would view matters from a different perspective.


Rawls (1958) suggested that the principles of justice for the basic structure of society
should be those principles ‘that free and rational persons concerned to further their own
interests would accept in an initial position of equity as defining the fundamental terms of
their association’. Bell (1980) hypothesised that Rawl’s rationale, which had no idea
whether they would be faced with the prospect of the expropriation of their land, would
select a measure of fairness which would ensure that the worst affected group would end
up marginally better off. He considered that the compensation decisions of the lay juries
prior to 1919 exhibited some of the characteristics of a Rawlsian approach to
compensation and on this basis concluded that such a measure might add at least 10
percent of the market value.

Cane (1988) makes a distinction in the context of compensation for accidents between that
which is intended to provide a financial equivalent for what has been lost and that which
is intended as a substitute or solace for what has been lost. The former is generally taken
to refer to the lump sum required to leave the claimant as well off but no better off than he
or she would be without the change in their expectations. Compensation for compulsory
purchase based on this equivalence might typically reflect the price which the claimant
could have expected to have obtained for the property on a sale in the open market
together with other consequential losses (Rowan-Robinson, 1995). McGregor (1988)
states that compensation which is granted as a substitute or solace for what has been lost
would seem to comprehend rather more intangible loss, something that cannot be
replaced, and something other than patrimonial loss. Such an element in an award of
compensation of compulsory purchase might provide recompense for the individual value
which people commonly ascribe to heritable property in excess of its market value
(McAuslan, 1980; Knetsch, 1983; Farrier & McAuslan, 1988). This is sometimes referred
to as ‘householder’s surplus’ and reflects loss of tie with the area, friendships made, and
Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 331
so on – items which are difficult to value (Rowan-Robinson, 1995). Both the utilitarian
and fairness models of compensation would be likely to make some allowance, although
for different reasons, for the subjective expectations of the claimants (Farrier &
McAuslan, 1988; Rowan-Robinson, 1995).

In Groundwater Recharge Study carried out on Bonriki Island Tarawa, Kiribati during
1996-1997, the monetary compensation did not always compensate for the loss of
relationship to the land, the dignity and identity that it provides. Perhaps the compensation
can be tied in some way to the role of guardianship, which can then be passed on to the
next generation. Although in some respects, traditional attitudes and relationships to land
may work against acquisition and use for public purposes, it may be possible to work with
those values.

Compensation has largely been understood to refer to specific measures intended to make
good the losses suffered by people displaced and/or negatively affected by the acquisition.
Compensation usually takes the form of a one-off payment, either in cash or in kind and is
principally about awards to negatively affected persons. The losses incurred by people
affected by the creation of infrastructure such as project offices and township, canals,
transmission lines and other activities are not usually properly accounted for and so these
losses have not been adequately compensated. Similarly, the impact of the projects (e.g.
dam) on the livelihoods of the downstream population and on people losing lands and
livelihoods due to land acquired for compensatory afforestation has not been properly
assessed and compensated. Compensation is most often awarded only to persons in
possession of undisputed legal title. Tenants, sharecroppers, wage-labourers, artisans and
encroachers are rarely considered eligible for compensation, whereas they are
paradoxically the most vulnerable and in need of support. Community assets and common
resources like grazing grounds and forests, which again may be critical for the livelihood
of the poorest, are not compensated for under the acquisition process.
Compensation on the basis of replacement value still restricts it to individually owned
property; the totalities of rights that are violated are not compensated. The most critical of
these are the customary rights of people to natural resources that are vital to livelihood
and food security; the loss of the common property resources which constitute a valuable
shared productive base of the community. This highlights the need for compensation to be
relocated in a framework of restitution of rights, both community and individual, beyond
even replacement value.

METHODOLOGY

A preliminary questionnaire survey was the first stage of the data collection process in this
study. The questionnaire was closed-ended in nature and was designed such that it does
not take long for the respondent to answer. The target population in this study was the
valuers in public and private valuation organisations in Malaysia. Two hundred and fifty
(250) questionnaires were distributed to these organisations based on the following
geographical locations: Klang Valley (N = 100), Northern Region (N = 60), Southern
332 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3
Region (N = 60) and East Coast (N = 30). 90 questionnaires were returned to give the
response rate of 36%, which is considered appropriate based on Ellhag & Boussabaine
(1999) and Idrus & Newman (2002). The data gathered from the survey has been analysed
using descriptive statistical techniques. Generally the weights used in this paper (except
mentioned otherwise) are 1=strongly agree; 2=moderately agree; 3= agree; 4=moderately
disagree; and 5=strongly disagree.

As presented in Table 1, the respondents who took part in the survey are qualified to give
their opinion. This was evident from the fact that 53% of them have experience in
valuation of land acquisition of between 11 to 100 cases. Apart from that, 50% of them
hold managerial posts as manager or assistant manager; 13% are academicians in real
estate management and 4% are holding other posts i.e. as a partner.

Chart 1: Type of Organisation

30
[33%]

54

6
[60%] [7%]

Government Semi-Government Private Firms

Source: Field Survey, 2006

Chart 1 shows the nature of organizations of the participating respondents. Fifty four (54)
or 60% of respondents are from private firms; 33% are from government organisations
and the balance, 7% are from semi-government agencies including universities.

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 333


SURVEY RESULTS AND DISCUSSION OF FINDINGS
Background of the Respondents
Table 1: The Main Characteristics of the Sample
Characteristic Frequency Percentage (%)

Gender
Male 66 73
Female 24 27
Designation
Valuation Officer/Executive 30 33
Deputy - Director/Manager 21 23
Director/District Valuer/Branch Manager 24 27
Academician 12 13
Others 3 4

Highest level of qualification


Bachelor Degree 90 66
Master Degree/PG Diploma 40 29
PhD 6 5

Professional membership
Registered Valuer 54 45
MISM/FISM 54 45
MRICS/FRICS 12 10

Age
21 – 30 years 6 7
31 – 40 years 24 27
41 – 50 years 48 53
51 – 60 years 9 10
> 60 years 3 3

Number of cases valued


< 10 cases 36 40
11 – 50 cases 30 33
51 – 100 cases 18 20
> 100 cases 6 7

Percentage of cases valued and then


referred to court
< 10% 54 60
11 – 25% 24 27
26 – 50% 12 13
51 – 75% 0 0
> 75% 0 0

Location of the organisation


Klang Valley 46 51
Northern Region 20 22
Southern Region 18 20
East Coast 6 7

Source: Field Survey, 2006

334 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


Issues and Perspectives on Payment of Adequate Compensation

Q1: Other Alternatives for Government to Secure Land for Development

Chart 2: Other Alternatives


12
[13%]

78
[87%]
Y es No

Source: Field Survey, 2006

From Chart 2, 87% of the respondents agreed that, apart from compulsory acquisition
under the powers of Land Acquisition Act, 1960, the government does have other ways to
secure land for development. Only 13% believed that compulsory acquisition is the only
means the government can exercise to secure land to carry out public projects.

Q2: Options for government to secure land for development


The weights used in this question are 1=yes; 2=no; and 3=not sure. Table 2 presents
respondents’ views on the options open to the government for securing land for
development. Compulsory acquisition medium was the most popular option, followed by
direct purchase through negotiation and joint venture. An agreement under the threat of
compulsory acquisition is least popular although it remains as one of the options. This
result is concordant with research findings by Omar and Ismail (2005).

Table 2: Options for government to secure land for development


Mean Score
Ranking Option
1 Compulsory acquisition 1.06
2 Direct purchase through negotiation 1.10
3 Joint venture 1.90
4 An agreement under the threat of compulsory acquisition 3.51
Source: Field Survey, 2006

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 335


Q3: Options exercised by the government
For this question, the weights used are 1=most often; 2=often; 3=seldom; and 4=never.
Table 3 shows the general ranking of the regularity of options implemented by the
governments to secure land for development. The result showed that compulsory
acquisition was the most often option exercised by government, followed by joint venture
and direct purchase. Agreement under the threat of compulsory acquisition was revealed
as never have been applied. The researcher is of the opinion that the respondents did not
really understand this option due to its unpopularity in Malaysian scenario as compared to
in Scotland.

Table 3: Options exercised by the government


Mean Score
Ranking Option
1 Compulsory acquisition 1.36
2 Direct purchase through negotiation 2.10
3 Joint ventures 2.74
4 An agreement under the threat of compulsory acquisition 4.51
Source: Field Survey, 2006
Q4: Purpose of Compulsory Acquisition Powers

Table 4: Purpose of compulsory acquisition powers


Mean Score
Ranking Purpose of acquisition
1 Public purposes 1.13
2 Economic development purposes 2.25
3 Residential and industrial purposes 3.46
4 Agriculture 4.26
5 Mining 4.54
Source: Field Survey, 2006

The weights used in this question are 1=all the time; 2=often; 3=sometimes; 4=rarely; and
5=never. Table 4 shows the general ranking of purposes for compulsory acquisition
powers being used in Malaysia. Land acquisition for public purposes was unanimously
agreed by the respondents to be implemented ‘all the time’ by authorities. Keith (1984)
noted that private property is to be taken only for public use, and with the payment of just
compensation. Furthermore, respondents believed that economic development purposes
under section 3(b) of the Act, is ‘often’ implemented under compulsory acquisition.

Q5: Stages of Acquisition being opposed


When asked about what stages of land acquisition processes are being opposed, the
respondents indicated that the awarding of compensation stage is ‘all the time’ and ‘often’
being opposed by landowners, which was evident from 74% respondents mentioning it.
This was followed by 26% respondents who indicated that inquiry stage is ‘sometimes’
336 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3
opposed by affected landowners. Rowan-Robinson (1990) commented that ‘compulsory
purchase is one of the harshest impositions by the State upon its citizens’. Studies by
Dundas & Evans (2001) in Scotland revealed that there is evidence of persistent
widespread dissatisfaction with the compulsory purchase process and compensation
extending over long number of years. In many land acquisition cases, people suffer more
than they gain, thus land acquisition needs to be dealt more pragmatically (Usilappan,
2000).

Q6: Reasons for opposing acquisition

Table 5: Reasons for objections in acquisition

Ranking Reason for objection Mean Score


1 Inadequacy of compensation 1.46
2 Purposes not purely public purpose 2.10
3 Emotional attachment to property 2.90
4 Procedures not clear 3.51
Source: Field Survey, 2006

The weights used in this question are 1=most important; 2=moderately important;
3=slightly important; 4=important; 5=slightly unimportant; 6=moderately unimportant
and 7=not important at all. The respondents were asked to score their answers based on
these scales.

Table 5 shows the reasons for people’s objections in land acquisition. Inadequacy of
compensation was the most important reason why land acquisition was opposed by
landowners. This was evident from its mean score of 1.46, while purpose not purely for
public ranked second with the mean score of 2.10. Interestingly, no results showed the
mean score of more than 4.0. This means that the respondents were not in dispute as to the
importance of all the reasons given. However, the collective attitude of society or the
community against compulsory purchase is not mirrored in the attitude of most
individuals whose land is acquired for public purpose who are, in fact, contented with
their deal with the acquiring authorities (Dundas & Evans (2001); Gordon (1989)). No
other reasons were given by respondents for objecting to the compulsory acquisition.

Q7: Advantages of Land Acquisition Powers


As shown in Table 6, the main advantage of compulsory acquisition from the respondents’
point of view was that it was considered as the main government tool to assemble land in
resolving the land supply problems for development. The table also indicates other
advantages, which are: to avoid situation where individual landowners can frustrate
development by refusing to sell; compensation based on market value satisfies adequate
compensation, and; saves time and creates less problems to acquiring body. These are the
advantages that scored higher rating in the survey as compared to holding out land.
Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 337
Table 6: Advantages of land acquisition powers
Mean Score
Ranking Advantage
1 The government’s tool to assemble land in resolving 2.12
the land supply problems for development
2 To avoid situations where individual landowners can 2.46
frustrate development by refusing to sell
3 Compensation based on market value satisfies the 2.48
adequate compensation
4 Save time and creates less problems to acquiring body 2.76
5 To avoid landowners to hold out land for unreasonable 3.43
purchase
Source: Field Survey, 2006

Q8: Disadvantages of Land Acquisition Powers


Table 7 shows the disadvantages of land acquisition powers as identified by the
respondents. The respondents agreed that, the main disadvantages of land acquisition
were; it was complicated, time consuming and expensive to implement and compensation
was not generous. The lowest score on the listed disadvantages was on the factor that land
acquisition was always opposed by landowners. This might not be true if the
compensation is generous and sufficiently high, and the landowners will welcome
compulsory acquisition (Rowan-Robinson, 1995).

Table 7: Disadvantages of land acquisition powers


Mean Score
Ranking Disadvantage
1 Complicated, time consuming and expensive 2.23
2 Compensation was seen as ungenerous and not up to the 2.34
expectation of affected landowners
3 Serious encroachment on the right to property 2.46
4 Not welcome by landowners 2.67
5 Always opposed by the affected landowners 3.85
Source: Field Survey, 2006

338 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


Q9: Whether or not adequate compensations have been given

Chart 3: Adequacy of compensation


12 2
13% 3%

76
84%
Y es No N o t Sur e

Source: Field Survey, 2006

When asked as to whether the existing compensation framework under the First Schedule
of the Land Acquisition Act and other related rules provide for adequate compensation,
84% thought that adequate compensations were not given, while 13% were not sure and
only 3% thought it adequate under the present act and rules. This suggests that adequate
compensation remains as a main issue that needs to be addressed.

Q10: Perceptions on current attributes of compensation

Table 8: Perceptions on current attributes of compensation


Mean Score
Ranking Attributes of Compensation
1 Market Value of Land Taken 3.53
2 Injurious Affection 4.07
3 Severance 4.20
4 Disturbance 4.24
Source: Field Survey, 2006

The weights used in this question are 1=exceedingly generous; 2=generous; 3=adequate;
4=hardly adequate; 5=inadequate. The respondents were asked to score their answers
based on this scale, and the results are tabulated in Table 8.

As shown in Table 8, the majority of respondents agreed that compensation under the
heading of disturbance was hardly adequate. This was evident from the mean score of
4.24 which was the most extreme among the four heads of claims while “market value for
land taken” achieved 3.53 mean score, which can be considered as adequate, others listed
heads of claim achieved mean scores more than 4.0. This means that all heads of claim
under the present Act are hardly adequate. This result is consistent with the findings for
Q9.

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 339


Q11: Opinion on acquisition issues

Table 9: Opinion on acquisition issues


Mean Score
Ranking Issues
1 Other methods of valuation help in adequate 2.13
compensation
2 Could a review of head of claims help the cause of 2.40
adequate compensation
3 Payment of solatium/ premium as over and above the 2.46
total compensation is necessary in Malaysia
4 The decisions by court in land acquisition cases (the 2.66
principles with regards to compensation) contribute to
satisfaction in payment of adequate compensation
5 Over-bearing of comparison method in determining 3.06
market gives impact on adequate compensation
6 Is there a need for the Malaysians to adopt other 3.40
countries’ practices in determining fair compensation
Source: Field Survey, 2006

Based on Table 9, four main issues in land acquisition scored with means of less than 3.0
and were therefore considered important by respondents. These are: the usefulness of
other methods of valuation towards the determination adequate compensation; the need
for a review of head of claims to help the cause of adequate compensation; the necessity
in this country to introduce solatium/premium as payment over and above the total
compensation, and; the contribution of court decisions on land acquisition cases (the
principles with regards to compensation) towards the satisfaction in payment of adequate
compensation. Perhaps the impact of the over-bearing role of comparison method on the
determination of adequate compensation, with the mean score of 3.06, also important to
be explored in land acquisition researches. On the other hand, Malaysia also needs to
adopt other countries’ practices in determining fair compensation, as this issue achieved
mean score of not more than 4.0.

340 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


Q12: Perceptions on the measures of adequate compensation

Table 10: Perceptions on the measures of adequate compensation


Mean
Ranking Measure / Test of adequate compensation Score
1 Component of compensation should include: MV + other 1.60
claims (disturbance, severance, injurious affection) +
solatium
2 Land acquisition power is purely for public purposes 2.06
3 Landowners do not challenge the award 2.13
4 Basis and component of other claims need to be reviewed 2.33
5 Beyond monetary compensation – e.g. resettlement 2.53
6 Negotiation with landowners is mandatory before compulsory 2.60
acquisition
7 Compensation proposal is made available for review and 2.66
consideration by landowners before inquiry
8 Establishment of National Land Management to secure land 2.66
for development
9 Taking into consideration humanity aspects in compensation 2.66
– e.g. hardship, readjustment of life/family/business
Source: Field Survey, 2006

Table 10 itemises the 9 listed measurements of adequate compensation. The respondents


agreed that all measurement factors have scored a mean score more than 3.0. This means
that they were strongly and moderately agreed that all the factors are important to be taken
into consideration in land acquisition researches. Respondents also gave considerably high
marks for suggestion on an establishment of National Land Management to secure land
for development. Usilappan (2000) suggests that an alternative system should be
considered to allow economic development taking place without complete land
acquisition. The government can play the role of a mediator and as a watchdog to
development.

Q13: Ranking of the importance of land acquisition concerns

Based on feedback from the survey, the general ranking of the importance of land
acquisition concerns in Malaysia is as follows:

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 341


Table 11: Ranking of the importance of land acquisition issues

Land acquisition concerns Ranking


Quantum of compensation 1
Determination of the market value and other claims 2
(valuation methods)
Laws of land acquisition 3
Process / procedures of land acquisition 4
Source: Field Survey, 2006

As tabulated in Table 11, the quantum of compensation ranked the highest among the
main concerns on land acquisition with 65% of respondents testifying to that. The concern
on the determinations of market value and other claims came next. Dowdy et al (1998),
Newcombe (1999), Dundas & Evans (2001), Law Commission, UK (2001), Land
Information, New Zealand (2002), Calandrillo (2003) and Omar & Ismail (2005) also
emphasized on various compensation issues in their research.

Q14: General Comments on land acquisition in Malaysia

In addition to the structured questions, the respondents were also encouraged to give their
further comments on any other aspects regarding land acquisition in Malaysia. 17
respondents had given their comments which were summarized as follows:

a) The authorities are discouraged to pre-announce the proposal of acquisition for


projects. This will create speculative purchases among those who have
interests.

b) The independence of assessors appointed by the court need to be ensured.

c) Land should only be acquired when necessary and urgently needed for
development. There were cases where lands acquired were left idle for years.

d) The Land Acquisition Act 1960 is quite clear in determining the compensation
(except for loss of earnings), but each individual interprets them differently.
This gives rise to confusion as to which items can and cannot be claimed. The
Act should be revised and simplified to disseminate all information without
confusion.

e) Land acquisition powers should only be used for public purposes. Economic
development projects that fall under section 3(b) of the Act must be made
compulsory for acquiring body to negotiate with landowners before

342 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


compulsory acquisition. This will make landowners welcome the project
proposals.

f) Justice is done when the landowners are able to appoint lawyer and other
professionals. Thus, the government needs to absorb the cost for those who are
not capable to do so. Now, the cost is limited to valuation fee only.

g) Under the present laws of acquisition in Malaysia, there is no room for


landowners to challenge the validity of acquisition like before. There were
cases where acquisition was done in bad faith.

h) In general, land acquisition in Malaysia is quite fair although the whole


process is long. At least our system has compensated related parties fairly and
provided platform to discuss/negotiate compensation with relevant authorities,
as compared to Singapore.
.

LESSONS FROM OTHER COUNTRIES

A study involving comparisons of the United Kingdom, USA, Hong Kong, China, India,
Australia and New Zealand found six advantages of the systems in those countries as
compared to Malaysia. These factors are perhaps relevant for Malaysian compensation
structure in land acquisition to consider, in moving towards improving its compensation
framework. The advantages are as follows:

i) The recognition of business compensation;

UK, USA, Australia and New Zealand recognise payment for loss of goodwill as an
attribute of compensation. In Malaysia, business losses are allowed under
compensation claims as stipulated in section 2(e) of First Schedule but they do not
cover loss of goodwill and loss of earnings.

ii) Equity of disturbance payments (relocation hardships);

Disturbance payment can include a wide range of items such as professional fees for
acquiring alternative premises; costs of adapting alternative premises, including
carpets, curtains and shelving; removal costs and any other reasonably quantifiable
losses. In Malaysia, a claim under this heading is only for cost of transfer.

iii) Payment of solatium/premium over and above the total compensation;

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 343


Solatium is an additional sum in respect of the owner injured feelings or the insult
due to the unilateral action of the acquiring authority in arbitrarily expropriating the
land. A solatium may be awarded as a percentage of the compensation or it may be an
amount calculated without reference to any percentage. This payment has been the
practices in many countries but Malaysia has yet to adopt it.

iv) An element of compulsory negotiation before using compulsory acquisition powers;

In the United States, landowners have the right to negotiate before compulsory
acquisition and this was made mandatory in the land acquisition procedures; indeed,
municipalities are required to prove that negotiations have failed before leave to
proceed through the courts is granted. In Malaysia, negotiation is allowed under
acquisition of Section 3(b) but subject to cooperation in the entire project.

v) Compensation details

In the United States, the compensation proposal which indicates the detailed
valuation of compensation is made available for landowners to review for a period of
one month before an official inquiry. No such procedures is in place in Malaysia.

vi) Alternative compensation

Section 105 of Public Works Act in Australia states that an alternative to monetary
compensation such as ‘land for land’ compensation can be considered where
equivalent crown owned land is readily available. The Law Reform Commission in
Canada (1978) recommended a ‘home for home’ principle whenever a residential
property is expropriated. India also has such clause in her land acquisition act.
However, in Malaysia no laws provided such alternative.

CONCLUSION

The literature review and survey results revealed that the main issue of land acquisition is
the quantum of compensation that is perceived by the respondents as inadequate to fulfill
adequate compensation notion under the spirit of Constitution. There is a need to review
the heads of compensation structure by incorporating other countries, practices. Although
there is a broad acceptance that market value is the appropriate basis for compensation for
land taken, perhaps there is also a general feeling that a solatium or premium should be
paid to compensate the claimant for the compulsory nature of the acquisition. Most of the
valuers perceived that land acquisition need not necessarily present the best alternative for
government to secure land for development. Other alternatives such as direct purchases
through negotiation and joint venture are the alternatives available for government to
exercise rather solely depending on land acquisition powers. According to Usilappan
(2000), land acquisition is a complex process, is sensitive in nature, and needs pragmatic

344 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


approach to deal with. Wherever possible, land developments should be carried through
the process of normal economic supply and demand.

In relation to other countries, evidence from practitioners in every country studied except
UK, indicates that a standard premium is added to the valuation achieved via the statutory
basis of compensation in instances where the owner is prepared to allow the State to
purchase their property by negotiation; indeed, in USA, municipalities are required to
prove that negotiations have failed before leave to proceed through the courts is granted
(Dowdy et al, 1998). The levels of premium have been quoted at 10% - 25% contrasting
strongly with the UK where it is perceived that valuations undertaken by reference to
compulsory purchase legislation produce lower than market value and in relation to blight:
The incidence of blight in the other countries studied tends to be reduced because of the
greater certainty in their land use development plans and in respect of re-expropriation.

Current negotiation and mediation practice suggests that some parties are trying to adopt a
workable approach to compensation. It remains to be seen, however, whether the
principles of valuation by the court in land reference cases are recognized to give space
for compensation that addresses the intrinsic value of land. To secure just terms and
sustainable outcomes, all parties need to be made more aware of the implications attached
to following different statutory pathways for compensation. An impartial interpretation of
the law and a better understanding of the principles and practice of valuation will lead to
an adequate compensation settlement.

At the heart of any call for greater transparency in compensation agreements lies
alternative interpretations of whether the compensation is private (hence there is no
requirement to be open) or public (hence there is a public interest in greater scrutiny
(Altman, 1985, 1998; Levitus, 1999)). Whatever the outcome of that debate, the lack of
transparency contributes to inadequate monitoring of compensation payments, obstructs
independent evaluation of terms and conditions, and limits the development of
benchmarks for how compensation might be better measured, distributed and managed.

Finally, the problems of compensation are more than just a matter of law and valuation; it
is a matter of justice between society and man. “The word compensation would be a
mockery if what was paid was something that did not compensate”.

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 345


REFERENCES

___, (1998), Compulsory Acquisition of Land in Malaysia – Recent Development, Journal


of Valuation and Property Services, Valuation and Property Services Department,
Ministry of Finance Malaysia, Vol. 2 No. 1 1999, p.97.
___, (1998), Compulsory Acquisition of Land in Malaysia, Journal of Valuation and
Property Services, Valuation and Property Services Department, Ministry of Finance
Malaysia, Vol. 1 No. 1 1998, p.71.
___, (2000), Towards an Urban Renaissance, Final Report of the Urban Task Force
chaired by Lord Rogers of Riverside.
___, (2001), Compulsory Purchase and Compensation: Disregarding ‘The Scheme’ – A
Discussion Paper, Law Commission, UK, October 2001.
___, (2002), Assessment of Compensation, Land Information, New Zealand, 1 July 2002.
Aggarawalla Om Prakash, (1981), Compulsory Acquisition of Land in India, 4th Edition,
The University Book Agency, Allahabad.
Altman, J., (1985), Report on the Review of the Aboriginal Benefit Trust Account in the
Northern Territory Land Rights Legislation, AGPS, Canberra.
Altman, J., (1998), Compensation for Native Title: The Land Rights Lessons for an
Effective and Fair Regime, Land Rights, Laws: Issues of Native Title, Issues Paper No.
20, Native Title Research Unit, AIATSIS, Canberra.
Bell, M., (1980), Taking Justice Seriously: Rawls’, Utilitarianism and Compensation, 3
Urban Law and Policy 23.
Brown, D., (1991), Land Acquisition, 3rd Edition, Butterworths: Sydney.
Buang, S.,(1993), Compulsory Land Acquisition, Central Law Book Corporation Bhd.
Kuala Lumpur.
Calandrillo, S.P., (2003), Eminent Domain Economics: Should ‘Just Compensation’ be
Abolished, and Would ‘Taking Insurance’ Work Instead?, Ohio State Law Journal,
Vol.64:451, 2003.
Cane, P., (1988), Atiyah’s Accident, Compensation and Law, Weidenfeld and Nicholson,
London, 5th Ed., Chap. 22.
Chan, N., (2003), Land Acquisition Compensation in China – Problems and Answers,
International Real Estate Review, Vol 6 No. 1: pp 136-152.
Cruden, C.N., (1986), Land Compensation and Valuation Law in Hong Kong,
Butterworths: Singapore.
Cullingworth, J.B., (1980), Environmental Planning, Vol. IV, (HMSO 1980), p. 185.

346 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


Davies, K., (1984), Law of Compulsory Purchase and Compensation, Fourth Edition,
London: Butterworth.
Denver-Green, B., (1989), Compulsory Purchase and Compensation, Third Edition, The
Estate Gazette Limited
Denver-Green, B., (1994), Compulsory Purchase and Compensation, 4th Edition, The
Estate Gazette Limited
DETR. Inter Departmental Working Group on Blight. Final Report. December 1997.
Dillman, D.A., (1991), Mail and Telephone Surveys: The Total Design Method, 2nd Ed,
New York: Wiley Interscience.
Dowdy, H et al (1998), Suitable Recompense? The operation of the compensation and
compulsory purchase system in the UK – a comparative study, London: RICS.
Dundas, I.H.M & Evans W.M., (2001), Review of Compulsory Purchase and
Compensation, Scottish Executive Central Research Unit.
Eaton, J.D., (1995), Real Estate Valuation in Litigation, 2nd Edition, Appraisal Institute.
Elliot, W.A., (1977), The Scope for General Principle’s Legislation, in Proceeding of the
5th Commonwealth Law Conference, London.
Epstein, R.A., (1985), Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain,
Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Farrier, D., McAuslan, P., (1975), Compensation, Participation and Compulsory
Acquisition of Homes, in Compensation for Compulsory Purchase: A Comparative Study,
Garner J.F. (ed.), United Kingdom National Committee of Comparative Law, London.
Ghosh, A., (1973), The Land Acquisition Act 1894-Law of Compulsory Acquisition and
Compensation, Sixth Edition, Eastern Law House.
Gordon, N.C., (1986), Land Compensation and Valuation Law in Hong Kong, Singapore:
Butterworths.
Graham, L. Fricke (1984), Compulsory Land Acquisition in Australia, Law Book Co.
Limited.
Jain, M.P. & Xavier G., (1996), Compulsory Acquisition in Malaysia, 2 MLJ xxix.
Khublal, N., (1994), Compulsory Land Acquisition- Singapore and Malaysia, 2nd Edition,
Butterworth Asia.
Knetsch, J.L., (1983), Property Rights and Compensation, Butterworth & Co. Ltd,
Canada, Chap. 4.
Levitus, R., (1999), Local Organisations and the Purpose of Money, in J. Altman, F.
Morphy & T Rowse (eds), Land Rights at Risk? Evaluation of the Reeves Report, CAEPR
Research Monograph No. 14 CAEPR, ANU, Canberra.

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 347


McAuslan, P., (1980), Ideologies of Planning Law, Pergamon Press, London, Chap. 4.
McGregor, H., (1988), McGregor on Damages, Sweet & Maxwell, London.
Michaelman, F., (1980), Property Utility and Fairness: Comments on the Ethical
Foundations of Just Compensation’s Law, 80 Harv.Rev.1165
Murray, J.F., (1971), Principles and Practice of Valuation, Commonwealth Institute of
Valuers, 4th Edition.
Newcombe, A.P., (1999), Regulatory Expropriation, Investment Protection and
International Law: When Is Government Regulation Expropriatory and When Should
Compensation Be Paid?, Master of Laws Thesis, Faculty of Law, University of Toronto,
Unpublished.
Omar and Ismail, (2005), Discrepancies in Defining Adequate Compensation in Land
Acquisition: A Case Study in Malaysia, 1st REER Conference and General Meeting, UTM
City Campus, K.Lumpur, 6-7 September 2005.
Parish, H., (1990), Cripps on Compulsory Acquisition of Land, Steven & Sons Ltd,
London, 11th Edition, para. 4-002
Ramachandran, V.G., (1979), Law of Land Acquisition and Compensation 2, 6th Edition,
Eastern Book Co.
Rawls, J., (1958), Justice as Fairness, 67 Phil. Rev. 164.
Rawls, J., (1971), A Theory of Justice, Harvard University Press, p. 22.
Robson, C., (1993), Real World Research, Oxford, Blackwell.
Root, D. & Blimass N., (2003), Increasing Questionnaire Responses From Industry:
Practices Surrounding the Use of Postal Questionnaire, ARCOM, 19th Annual Conference,
September 2003, Volume 2, p.623.
Rowan-Robinson, J. & Lloyd, M.G., (1988), Land Development and Infrastructure
Lottery, T&T Clark, London.
Rowan-Robinson, J., (1990), Compulsory Purchase and Compensation: The Law in
Scotland, W-Green, Edinburgh.
Royal Institution of Chartered Surveyors, (1995), Compensation for Compulsory
Acquisition, RICS, London.
Teo, K.S. & Khaw, L.T., (1995), Land Law in Malaysia – Cases and Commentary, 2nd Ed.
Butterworths.
Usilappan, M., (1997), Land Acquisition Act 1960: The 1997 Amendments, The
Surveyors, 2nd Quarterly 1997.

348 Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3


Usilappan, M., (2000), Issues Affecting Land Acquisition in the Context of National
Development, Valuation and Property Services Department, Ministry of Finance
Malaysia, Unpublished.
Xavier, G., (1995), The Land Acquisition (Amendment) Act 1991, 1 MLJ xxxi.

Pacific Rim Property Research Journal, Vol 12, No 3 349

View publication stats

You might also like