Relationship of Gender Differences in Preferences To Economic Development and Gender Equality
Relationship of Gender Differences in Preferences To Economic Development and Gender Equality
Relationship of Gender Differences in Preferences To Economic Development and Gender Equality
1 Economic Development
.8
.6
.4
Average Gender Difference
.2
in Preferences (Index)
0
6 7 8 9 10
Log GDP p/c
1 Gender Equality
.8
.6
Gender Differences in Preferences .4
.2
Larger Smaller
0
No Data 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Gender Equality Index
Gender differences in preferences across countries and their association with economic development and gender equality. (Left)
World map visualizing a summary index of gender differences in all six preferences (risk-taking, patience, altruism, trust, and positive and
negative reciprocity). (Right) The relationship between the summary index of gender differences in preferences and (top) log GDP per capita
and (bottom) a Gender Equality Index comprising measures of material, social, and political gender equality. The relationships are predicted
from local polynomial regressions. Shaded areas indicate 95% confidence intervals.
F
the corresponding experiment was selected for
undamental preferences such as altruism, nent in explaining the gender preference gap. the international survey. The selected items,
risk-taking, reciprocity, patience, or trust As a consequence, according to the social role described below, comprise a combination of
constitute the foundation of choice theories hypothesis, higher economic development and qualitative self-assessments and quantitative
and govern human behavior. A growing lit- gender equality (and the associated dissolution items that involve economic trade-off decisions.
erature in economics (1, 2) and psychology of traditional gender roles) should lead to a nar- The qualitative items elicit participants’ subjec-
(3) documents important gender differences in rowing of gender differences in preferences. tive assessment of their willingness to act in a
preferences. These differences provide a key ex- In contrast, there is reason to expect that gen- certain way, such as whether participants are
planation for differential choices and outcomes der differences in preferences expand with eco- generally willing to take risks. Complementarily,
between women and men in contexts such as nomic development and gender equality (resource the quantitative items provide revealed prefer-
occupational choice, financial investment, or hypothesis). As suggested by post-materialist ence measures by using participants’ choices in
educational decisions (4, 5), among many others. theory (15, 16), a critical societal precondition for monetary trade-off decisions. As an example,
The origins of gender differences in preferences, self-expression is the fulfillment of basic material the quantitative item for risk-taking provides
and their variability across countries and cultures, needs. In line with this, existing research shows the participants with a sequence of five inter-
are addressed by an extensive literature that dis- that the unrestricted expression of preferences dependent choices between a fixed and a risky
usses biological and evolutionary determinants hinges on the availability of sufficient material payment (lottery). This allows one to progres-
(6, 7) and the role of the social environment (8–10). and social resources (17–20). Therefore, gender sively approach the point of indifference between
differences in preferences should manifest them- the fixed payment and the lottery, which serves
Hypotheses selves only if both women and men obtain suffi- as a revealed preference measure for risk-taking
We contrast two competing hypotheses that make cient access to these resources to independently behavior. The presence of both qualitative and
opposite predictions concerning the cross-country develop and express their intrinsic preferences quantitative items allows for robustness tests
correlational patterns of gender differences in (21). Specifically, greater availability of material with respect to potential culture-specific response
preferences with respect to economic develop- resources eliminates the gender-neutral goal of behavior. So that survey items were comparable
ment and gender equality. Following social role subsistence. This creates scope for attending to across cultures, all items were translated back
theory, one may hypothesize that gender differ- gender-specific ambitions and desires. As a con- and forth by professionals, and monetary values
ences in preferences attenuate in more developed, sequence, economic development may facilitate mentioned in the survey questions were adjusted
gender-egalitarian countries (social role hypoth- the unfolding of differences between women along median household income across countries.
esis). This hypothesis rests on two premises. and men. More developed countries also feature The survey items were pretested in 22 countries
First, economic development is a key determinant higher levels of gender equality in political, social, of varied cultural heritage as part of the Gallup
of societal progression toward gender equality and economic domains (11), which is a critical re- World Poll 2012 pretest, conducted in late 2011,
(11, 12), which is critical for the dissolution of quirement for the acceptance of gender-specific to guarantee cross-cultural validity.
traditional gender roles (13, 14). Second, as dis- desires and preferences. In particular, as women After the ex ante experimental validation and
cussed by a large body of literature (8–10), gender- become less exposed and vulnerable to male in- pretests, the international survey was imple-
specific roles instill distinct preferences in women fluence, gender differentiation may be reinforced mented in a total of 76 countries, representing
and men and hence constitute a crucial compo- through women’s greater opportunities for self- about 90% of the global population and global
expression. In sum, greater availability of mate- GDP. To provide geographic representativeness
rial and social resources to both women and men as well as developmental and cultural variation,
1
Department of Economics, University of Bonn, and Behavior may facilitate the independent development and we selected the countries to include all conti-
and Inequality Research Institute (briq), 53113 Bonn, Germany. expression of gender-specific preferences, and nents and a very broad range of economic devel-
2
Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley,
CA 94720, USA.
hence may lead to an expansion of gender differ- opment levels. For each country, the data contain
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected] (A.F.); ences in more developed and gender-egalitarian samples representative of the resident popula-
[email protected] (J.H.) countries. tion aged 15 and older, with a median sample size
A Altruism (+) Trust (+) Pos. Recip. (+) B Correlation: 0.6685 (p<0.0001)
Average Gender Difference (in Standard Deviations)
.25
.25
.25
CAN
1
USA
GBR
SWE
.2
.2
.2
AUS
NLD
AUT
.15
.15
.15
.8
.1
.1
.1
.05
.05
.05
BOL
RUS
UKR DZA ARG LTU JPN
0
0
DEU
POLHUN
.6
−.05
−.05
−.05
ZWE SAU FRA
Poorer Countries Richer Countries Poorer Countries Richer Countries Poorer Countries Richer Countries CHN BWA ISR
MAR PRT ESP
EGY COL
Neg. Recip. (−) Risk taking (−) Patience (−) UGA IND SUR
SRB CHLHRV
NGA GEO GRC ITA
KOR
.25
.25
.4
IDN PER
.25
ROU
RWA PHL CRIVENTUR
HTI JOR
.2
.2
.2
MWI BRA
MDA GTMBIH KAZ ARE
CMR ZAF
.15
.15
.15
VNM MEX
.2
AFG KEN
.1
.1
LKA
.1
.05
.05
KHM
IRN
0
0
0
0
−.05
−.05
−.05
Poorer Countries Richer Countries Poorer Countries Richer Countries Poorer Countries Richer Countries 6 7 8 9 10 11
Log GDP p/c
C Altruism (+) Trust (+) Pos. Recip. (+) D Correlation: 0.5580 (p<0.0001)
CAN
1
Average Gender Difference (in Standard Deviations)
.25
.25
USA
GBR
SWE
.2
.2
.2
AUSNLD
AUT
.15
.15
.15
.8
.1
.1
.1
.05
.05
.05
BOL
RUS LTU
DZA ARG
JPNUKR
−.05 0
−.05 0
−.05 0
DEU
.6 HUN POL
SAU ZWE FRA
Less Gender− More Gender− Less Gender− More Gender− Less Gender− More Gender− BWA CHN ISR ESP
Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries MAR PRT
EGY SUR COL HRV
Neg. Recip. (−) Risk taking (−) Patience (−) IND CHL
UGA SRB
IDN PERKORGRCGEOITA
.4
.25
.25
ROU
.25
.2
.2
.15
.15
MEX VNM
.2
KEN
BGD LKA NIC THA
.1
.1
.1
.05
.05
.05
KHM
IRN
−.05 0
−.05 0
−.05 0
PAK TZA
GHA
0
Less Gender− More Gender− Less Gender− More Gender− Less Gender− More Gender−
Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries Equal Countries 0 .2 .4 .6 .8 1
Gender Equality (Index)
Fig. 1. Analysis of gender differences in preferences in relation to correspond to women exhibiting higher levels of the respective
economic development and gender equality. (A) Mean country-level preference, whereas − indicates that positive differences correspond
gender difference in altruism, trust, positive reciprocity, negative to women exhibiting lower levels of the respective preference.
reciprocity, risk-taking, and patience by development level. Countries (B) Relationship between the aggregate index of gender differences
were sorted into four bins according to their GDP per capita quartile. in all six preferences and log GDP per capita. (C and D) Same
The symbols + and − in the panel titles indicate the sign of the relationships as in (A) and (B) for the Gender Equality Index.
difference for each preference; + indicates that positive differences See supplementary materials for country abbreviation key.
of 1000 participants per country; this made gen- of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. Then, for each and less patient by 0.050 standard deviations (P <
eralizable inferences possible. In total, the data preference, an ordinary least-squares (OLS) re- 0.0001) (26). The observed differences in prefer-
include preference measures for about 80,000 gression was performed on the worldwide sam- ences set the stage for our analysis.
participants. ple, using as the independent variable a gender
After implementation of the worldwide survey, indicator in which male is the reference category, Analysis of gender differences in
the measures for the six preferences were gen- controlling for age, age squared, cognitive skills preferences in relation to economic
erated according to the following procedure. (as proxied by subjective math skills), education development and gender equality
First, each of the survey items was standardized level, household income quintile, and country To test the competing hypotheses, we computed
using the mean and variance of the entire world- fixed effects. Standard errors were clustered at country-level gender differences for each pref-
wide sample. Then, to obtain the preference mea- the country level. The estimated coefficient on the erence. For this purpose, we standardized each
sures, the relevant z-scores were averaged using gender indicator served as the gender difference preference measure at the country level to exhibit
weights developed in the experimental valida- in the respective preference. On the global level, a mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. We
tion. Further details on the data collection and all six preferences featured significant gender then performed for each preference and country
construction of our measures are given below and differences (fig. S1): Women tended to be more a separate OLS regression using as independent
in the supplementary materials. prosocial and less negatively reciprocal than men, variable a gender indicator in which male is the
The data allow assessment of the existence with differences in standard deviations of 0.106 for reference category. We also included several con-
and quantitative relevance of gender differences altruism (P < 0.0001), 0.064 for trust (P < 0.0001), trols to isolate the gender effect from potentially
in preferences at the global level (22). For this 0.055 for positive reciprocity (P < 0.0001), and confounding factors that might differ between
purpose, global gender differences were calcu- 0.129 for negative reciprocity (P < 0.0001). Turning women and men. These controls are age, age
lated as follows: Each preference measure was to nonsocial preferences, women were less risk- squared, subjective math skills, education level,
standardized at the global level to exhibit a mean taking by 0.168 standard deviations (P < 0.0001) and household income quintile. The obtained
coefficient on the gender indicator served as a we conducted a conditional analysis. We con- quantitative items (fig. S7, A and B). A test of
measure of the gender difference in the respec- structed partial regression plots illustrating the the null hypothesis of equality of the correlation
tive preference and country. relationship between the index of gender differ- coefficients failed to reject at conventional sig-
Using the country-level estimates of gender ences in preferences and log GDP per capita con- nificance levels (P = 0.744). Likewise, correla-
differences in preferences, we examined varia- ditional on the Gender Equality Index (Fig. 2A) tions with the Gender Equality Index were 0.480
tion along levels of economic development and and vice versa (Fig. 2B). The dependent and inde- (P < 0.0001) for qualitative items and 0.479 (P <
gender equality. As the measure of economic de- pendent variables were standardized to exhibit a 0.0001) for quantitative items (fig. S7, C and D).
velopment, we used GDP per capita. To assess mean of 0 and a standard deviation of 1. Hence, Testing equality of the coefficients failed to re-
the role of gender equality, we created a Gender the slope coefficients can be interpreted as the ject (P = 0.991), thus providing no support that
Equality Index as a joint measure of four indices standard deviation change in the dependent var- culture-specific response behavior contaminated
of gender equality: (i) the Global Gender Gap iable in response to a change of one standard the results.
Index of the World Economic Forum (WEF), (ii) deviation in the independent variable. To further test for the robustness of our re-
the Gender Equality Index of the United Nations There was a quantitatively large and statis- sults, we conducted several additional analyses.
(UN), (iii) the ratio of female to male labor force tically significant association of gender differ- First, because trust reflects a composite trait that
participation rates, and (iv) the number of years ences with log GDP per capita conditional on the captures beliefs about others’ behavior, prosocial
since women’s suffrage. The Gender Equality Gender Equality Index. The estimated slope co- preferences, and preferences for risk-taking, we
Index was constructed as the predicted main efficient was 0.53 (P < 0.0001). Likewise, gender repeated our analysis excluding the trust dimen-
component from a principal components analy- differences were strongly associated with the sion. To do so, we constructed an alternative index
sis of the four indices. Gender Equality Index conditional on log GDP of gender differences in preferences in a proce-
To study the effect of economic development, per capita, with a somewhat smaller slope co- dure parallel to the main index but using only the
we first sorted the 76 countries into four bins efficient of 0.32 (P = 0.0033) (see also table S4, five remaining preferences. Similar to our main
in preferences. These findings may also relate also do not preclude a role for biological or evo- In this regard, our findings point toward the
to other personality traits, such as the Big Five lutionary determinants of gender differences critical role of availability of and equal access
(34, 35) or value priorities (36). Our findings do (37). Our results highlight, however, that theo- to material and social resources for both women
not rule out an influence of gender-specific roles ries not attributing a significant role to the social and men in facilitating the independent forma-
that drive gender differences in preferences. They environment are incomplete (38). tion and expression of gender-specific preferences
2
DZA SAU
Average Gender Difference (Index)
1
NLD DZA CZEUGAAUS SWE
BOL ARG
EST SWE
JOR JPN ARG AUT NLD
RUS
CHN RWA
IND MWI LTU
IND RUS MAR
EGY
ZWE UKR BWA FIN
SURHUN CHE POL
CHN LTUPOL FIN IDN
BWA GEO
IDN COL ARE COL HUN SRBMDA
TUR SUR PHL
0
0
UGA PER CHL ISR SAU JPN PER CMR
GTM VEN DEU KOR
FRA
ESP GRC BGD KEN VNM DEU
SRB HRV JOR
GEO CRI PRT IRN GTM CHL ISR ROU PRT
HRV
MWI CMR ROUBRA ITA CRI
VEN BRA FRA
ESP
KHM
PAK TUR LKA NIC KAZ
PHL
BGD MEX
RWA
MDA KOR
GRC ZAFTZA
−1
−1
KEN LKA PAK THA
GHA
VNM NIC KAZ ZAF ITA
KHM THA MEX
IRN
ARE
TZA GHA Slope Coefficient: 0.5258 (p<0.0001) Slope Coefficient: 0.3192 (p=0.003)
−2
−2 −1 0 1 2 −3 −2 −1 0 1 2
Log GDP p/c Gender Equality (Index)
(Residualized using Gender Equality Index) (Residualized using Log GDP p/c)
2
2
BOL BOL
Average Gender Difference (Index)
Average Gender Difference (Index)
ZWE ZWE
CAN CAN
UKR
USA GBR USA UKR
EST GBR UGA EST
1
1
SRB
0
−2 −1 0 1 2 −1 −.5 0 .5 1 1.5
WEF Global Gender Gap Index UN Gender Equality Index
(Residualized using Log GDP p/c) (Residualized using Log GDP p/c)
BOL BOL
Average Gender Difference (Index)
Average Gender Difference (Index)
ZWE ZWE
CAN CAN
UKR
USA USA UKR
EST
GBR GBR EST
1
1
DZA CZE AUS SWE UGA DZA UGA SWE CZE AUS
NLD
AUTRUS NLD
AUT RUS
ARG CHN RWA
MWI ARG
RWA
CHNIND
MWI
EGY MARIND NGA LTU
FIN
MAR EGY
NGA LTU
FIN
CHE HTI CHE HTI
IDN POL IDN POL GEO
GEO BWA BWA
AFG HUN COL AFG HUN
SUR PHL COL SRB MDA MDA SUR
SRB PHL
0
0
−2 −1 0 1 2 −2 −1 0 1 2
Ratio Female to Male LFP Time since Women’s Suffrage
(Residualized using Log GDP p/c) (Residualized using Log GDP p/c)
Fig. 2. Analysis of gender differences in preferences in relation of gender differences in preferences and five indices of gender equality
to economic development conditional on gender equality, and vice after residualizing all variables with respect to log GDP per capita. Indices
versa. Each panel depicts a partial regression plot. (A) Relationship of gender equality are (B) the Gender Equality Index, (C) WEF Global
between the aggregate index of gender differences in preferences and log Gender Gap Index, (D) UN Gender Equality Index, (E) ratio of female to
GDP per capita after residualizing both variables with respect to the male labor force participation, and (F) years since women’s suffrage.
Gender Equality Index. (B to F) Relationship between the aggregate index For corresponding regression evidence, see table S4.
across countries. As suggested by the resource the indifference point between receiving a fixed indicated problems in understanding the word-
hypothesis, greater availability of material re- monetary amount on the day of the survey and ing or the quantitative content of the survey
sources removes the human need of subsistence, a larger amount 12 months later, and (ii) the items. Some respondents suggested rewording,
and hence provides the scope for attending to response to the question “How willing are you which was incorporated through minor adjust-
gender-specific preferences. A more egalitarian to give up something that is beneficial for you ments of some survey items.
distribution of material and social resources en- today in order to benefit more from that in the
ables women and men to independently express future?” Positive reciprocity was elicited by (i) Sampling and selection of respondents
gender-specific preferences. an item asking for the value of a thank-you gift We included the GPS as part of the Gallup World
the respondent is willing to give in return for Poll 2012 through the infrastructure of Gallup
Materials and methods help by a stranger and (ii) the response to the (23). Respondents were sampled to achieve na-
See the supplementary materials for further de- item “When someone does me a favor I am tional representativeness of the resident popu-
tails, including a list of the 76 countries included willing to return it.” Negative reciprocity was lation aged 15 and older. Telephone interviews
in the survey. elicited by responses to the items (i) “If I am were conducted in regions where at least 80%
treated very unjustly, I will take revenge at the of the country’s population is covered by tele-
Experimental selection of survey first occasion, even if there is a cost to do so,” (ii) phone or where it is the customary survey meth-
items and construction of “How willing are you to punish someone who odology. Otherwise, face-to-face interviews were
preference measures treats you unfairly, even if there may be costs for conducted.
Survey items included in the GPS data were you?”, and (iii) “How willing are you to punish The selection of households in countries with
selected in an ex ante experimental validation someone who treats others unfairly, even if there telephone interviews used either a random-digit-
procedure at the Laboratory for Experimental may be costs for you?” Altruism was elicited by (i) dialing method or nationally representative lists
Economics of the University of Bonn in winter the quantitative value in response to the ques- of phone numbers. In countries with face-to-face
19. T. Tanaka, C. F. Camerer, Q. Nguyen, Risk and time preferences: 29. M. Yuki, Intergroup Comparison versus Intragroup 39. D. Cesarini, C. T. Dawes, M. Johannesson, P. Lichtenstein,
Experimental and household survey data from Vietnam. Relationships: A Cross-Cultural Examination of Social Identity B. Wallace, Genetic variation in preferences for giving and risk
Am. Econ. Rev. 100, 557–571 (2010). doi: 10.1257/aer.100.1.557 Theory in North American and East Asian Cultural Contexts. taking. Q. J. Econ. 124, 809–842 (2009). doi: 10.1162/
20. V. McLoyd, Socioeconomic disadvantage and child development. Soc. Psychol. Q. 66, 166–183 (2003). doi: 10.2307/1519846 qjec.2009.124.2.809
Am. Psychol. 53, 185–204 (1998). doi: 10.1037/0003-066X.53.2.185 30. S. Guimond, A. Chatard, D. Martinot, R. J. Crisp, S. Redersdorff, 40. N. Zethraeus et al., A randomized trial of the effect of
21. One may be agnostic about the ultimate determinants of Social comparison, self-stereotyping, and gender differences estrogen and testosteron on economic behavior. Proc. Natl.
gender-specific preferences. They may be acquired through in self-construals. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 90, 221–242 (2006). Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 106, 6535–6538 (2009). doi: 10.1073/
cross-culturally universal gender roles, or they may be doi: 10.1037/0022-3514.90.2.221 pnas.0812757106
due to biological and evolutionary differences between 31. S. Guimond et al., Culture, Gender, and the Self: Variations and 41. D. Cesarini et al., Heritability of cooperative behavior in the
women and men. Impact of Social Comparison Processes. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. trust game. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 105, 3721–3726
22. A. Falk, A. Becker, T. Dohmen, B. Enke, D. Huffman, U. Sunde, 92, 1118–1134 (2007). doi: 10.1037/0022-3514.92.6.1118 (2008). doi: 10.1073/pnas.0710069105
Global Evidence on Economic Preferences. Q. J. Econ. 133, 32. S. Guimond, Psychological similarities and differences between 42. B. Wallace, D. Cesarini, P. Lichtenstein, M. Johannesson,
1645–1692 (2018). doi: 10.1093/qje/qjy013 women and men across cultures. Soc. Personal. Psychol. Heriability of ultimatum game responder behavior. Proc. Natl.
23. For further details on the Gallup World Poll, see www.gallup. Compass 2, 494–510 (2008). doi: 10.1111/j.1751- Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 104, 15631–15634 (2007). doi: 10.1073/
com/analytics/213704/world-poll.aspx. 9004.2007.00036.x pnas.0706642104
24. We note that trust is not a preference but a composite trait, 33. A specific concern involves cross-cultural differences in 43. D. C. Geary, Evolution and developmental sex differences. Curr.
including beliefs about others’ behavior, prosocial preferences, gender-specific social comparison (29–32): Survey respondents Dir. Psychol. Sci. 8, 115–120 (1999). doi: 10.1111/1467-
and preferences for risk-taking. Given its importance, however, we in less developed, less gender-egalitarian countries may 8721.00027
decided to include it in our analysis. The results remained be inclined to define themselves relative to people of the same
unchanged when excluding trust from the analysis; see gender (intragroup social comparison). In contrast, those in
AC KNOWLED GME NTS
supplementary materials. more developed and gender-egalitarian countries may be likely
25. A. Falk, A. Becker, T. Dohmen, D. Huffman, U. Sunde, “The to compare themselves to both women and men (intergroup We thank P. Andre, E. Avis, S. Fiedler, K. Jensen, M. Kosfeld,
preference survey module: A validated instrument for social comparison). As a consequence, gender differences L. Shiferaw, and J. Tungodden for helpful comments; L. Henkel,
measuring risk, time, and social preferences” (IZA Discussion estimated through self-assessments may be understated in R. Suchy, and S. Walter for outstanding research assistance;
Paper 9674, 2016). less developed countries. M. Antony for his support in collecting and managing the GPS data;
26. The raw gender differences without controls are qualitatively 34. P. T. Costa, A. Terracciano, R. R. McCrae, Gender differences and M. Entner and S. Sauter for administrative support. Funding:
SUPPLEMENTARY http://science.sciencemag.org/content/suppl/2018/10/17/362.6412.eaas9899.DC1
MATERIALS
REFERENCES This article cites 34 articles, 5 of which you can access for free
http://science.sciencemag.org/content/362/6412/eaas9899#BIBL
PERMISSIONS http://www.sciencemag.org/help/reprints-and-permissions
Science (print ISSN 0036-8075; online ISSN 1095-9203) is published by the American Association for the Advancement of
Science, 1200 New York Avenue NW, Washington, DC 20005. 2017 © The Authors, some rights reserved; exclusive
licensee American Association for the Advancement of Science. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. The title
Science is a registered trademark of AAAS.