The State in The Post
The State in The Post
The State in The Post
Michael Zürn
Institute for Intercultural and International Studies. University of
Bremen/Centre for Advanced Studies at the Norwegian Academy
of Sciences
The uneasy debate about the declining or reinforced sovereign nation state did not last very long. While hyperglobalists saw the coming global age as one with global
enterprises, global civil society, the dominance of market relations, and no place for sovereign states, globalization sceptics pointed to the rise of trading blocs, economies less
interdependent than 100 years before, and state executives more autonomous than ever. More sophisticated analyses acknowledge significant changes, yet expect them to
lead to a relocation, reconstitution or transformation of sovereignty [1] and the role of the nation state. [2] Most of these efforts are, however, deficient in at least one respect. They
focus exclusively on the nation state, on its activities and attributes, without seeing it as part of a more encompassing, and interconnected set of allocations of authority. This
focus leads to conclusions that, for instance, there are "core aspects of the institution of sovereignty which remain unchanged and there are core aspects of the institution which
have changed dramatically over time" (Sørensen 1999: 591). While it is true that sovereignty and the modern nation state cannot be understood by focusing on only one aspect,
a thorough understanding needs to take into account not only different aspects, but also the relationship between different aspects of statehood. Along this line, I want to put
forward a relational understanding in a changing constellation of statehood. Moreover, debates about appropriate conceptual tools (about assumptions) for understanding the
role of the state in global governance should be geared towards the development of hypotheses on international relations and global politics. In this paper, some expectations
about the impact of changing statehood on governance will be developed against the background of the conceptualization of post-national statehood.
The argument in a nutshell is that statehood consists of three dimensions: recognition, resources, and the realization of governance goals. Statehood in the national
constellation was characterized by a convergence of all these three Rs in one political organization, that is the nation state. This national constellation was bound together by the
congruence of social and political spaces. In a denationalizing world with an increase in cross-border activities and the emergence of new social spaces, the convergence of the
dimensions of statehood in one political organization dissolves and a new architecture of statehood arises. To the extent that we move towards such a post-national
constellation with multi-level statehood, the provision of public goods will change significantly, casting doubts on the capability to manage the problems that we are expected to
face in the new century. I shall proceed in four steps:
In Section 1 I want to develop a multi-dimensional notion of the sovereign state that binds it to the national constellation. I shall thereby demonstrate that it was
only the interplay of a number of dimensions of statehood, all of them converging in the nation state that made the sovereign nation state possible.
With the sharp rise in the number of societal transactions crossing national borders, this national constellation faces a fundamental challenge to which,
however, political actors respond politically rather than merely yielding to external pressures as hyper-globalists would like us to believe. In Section 2 I shall therefore sketch
the challenges of and the political responses to "societal denationalization" (a term I prefer to globalization).
Societal denationalization and political responses to it may eventually lead to a "post-national constellation". Although it is impossible to comprehend this post-
national constellation in detail today – its shape is by no means determined and is more likely to be the outcome of political struggles –, I shall attempt to sketch the
architecture of multi-level statehood by highlighting and extrapolating some empirical trends.
In the final Section 4, I will reflect on the extent to which the realization of governance goals will be possible in the future.
Two notes of caution must be added. First, parts of the argument in this contribution refer to the future and thus cannot easily be tested against observations about the past and
present world. The different steps in the argument follow three different modes of reasoning. The first step is based on an analysis of current trends, in a next step these trends
are extrapolated, and finally hypotheses are developed about the outcomes that this extrapolated world will produce (see figure 1). Needless to say that it therefore contains
elements of (hopefully) informed speculation.
Figure 1: Steps of the Argument
Political -> Responses Postnational -> Constellation of Statehood Postnational Capacity to Govern
Societal -> Denationalization Challenges ->
Second, the focus of this contribution is limited to statehood in the OECD-world. It is this area in the world where the nation state has been fully developed and where
globalization processes are most significant. The notion of a post-national form of statehood in the OECD world therefore does not preclude struggles in other parts of the world
to develop a nation state in the first place. In doing so, they may repeat many of the merits and the sufferingsof nationalization that first took place in Western Europe in the
18th and 19thcenturies. In these especially troubled parts of the world, an understanding of future political developments must take into account both aspirations for nation-
building at the periphery and the impacts of a post-national constellation in the center.
These four challenges to the effectiveness of national policies undermine the nation state capacity to unilaterally attain the goals of governance. The efficacy problem, above all,
reduces the capacity of the nation state to attain unilaterally the governance goal of security; the efficiency challenge concerns mainly legal certainty in the economic sphere; the
input-incongruence casts doubt on the nation state as appropriate level for democratic decision-making; and the race-to-the-bottom problem puts pressure on national welfare
policies. Societal denationalization undermines the congruence of social and political spaces and thus challenges the capacity of the nation state to attain governance goals
unilaterally.
2.2. Responses
These challenges to the effectiveness of national policies in realizing governance goals do not directly translate into a decline of the nation state. The challenges are serious, yet
the outcome is largely determined by political choices. Governments and other political organizations can respond to these challenges in a number of different ways. First, they
may passively await the decline in effectiveness of national policies, partly because they favor the institutional status quo, partly because they can use the pretext of
international pressure to further their own domestic goals like deregulation. Second, regionalist parties may push for decentralization or even secession from nation states in
order to be able to respond as flexibly as possible in the new denationalized environment. The rise of the Lega Nord and the revival of the Scottish National Party as well the
Parti Québécois can be related to economic and cultural denationalization and thus be interpreted as a fragmentative political response. Third, governments and other political
organizations may aim for integrative political responses to denationalization. The incongruence between national political regulations and denationalized areas of social
transactions calls into question the very capacity of the nation state to provide goods that made it the dominant political institution in the first place. In this predicament,
governments and other political may endeavor to regain control by establishing new international and transnational or even supranational regimes, networks and organizations
for the coordination and harmonization of their policies, i.e. to establish governance beyond the nation state. It is this third response to societal denationalization that needs to be
explored more closely for the purpose of this contribution.
In general terms, governance is distinct from anarchy – the unrestricted interplay of actors driven by self-interest – in that social actors recognize the existence of obligations and
feel compelled to honor them by their behavior. Governance refers to the governing of purposive systems of norms and rules. In this sense, "governance is order plus
intentionality", [23] and goals are constitutive for governance. Governance in modernity has best been provided within the nation state by a government that claimed a monopoly
of legitimate force and thus ruled by hierarchical orders. Governance took the form ofgovernance by government.
The form of governance needs, however, to be distinguished from its function, i.e. the realization of goals that are considered worthy and desirable by most people. These
goods can be provided by a government, but also by governance with or without governments. All forms of governance beyond the state lack a central authority or a "world
state" equipped with a legitimate monopoly over the use of force. [24] Thus, governance beyond the nation state cannot take the form of governance by government, but rather it
needs to be a form of governance with governments such as we find in international institutions, or governance without government as in transnational institutions, or
supranational governance. In spite of the absence of governance by government, governance beyond the nation state has developed significantly over the last decades. The
sum of all institutional arrangements beyond the nation state make up regional or global governance systems. The interplay of different forms of governance beyond the nation
state can produce polities of a new quality, that is, representing a new form of statehood, as attested by the European Multi-Level Governance System. [25]
1) Governance with Governments: Governance with governments regulates through intergovernmental agreements state and non-state activities the effects of which extend
beyond national borders. Central to international governance are international regimes, defined as social institutions consisting of agreed-upon and publicly announced
principles, norms, rules, procedures and programs that govern the interactions of actors in specific issue areas. As such, regimes contain specific regulations and give rise to
recognized social practices in international society. [26] Regimes comprise both substantive and procedural rules and are thus distinct from mere intergovernmental
networkswhich frequently only include informal, procedural rules. Such networks meet on a regular basis and may develop coordinated responses to specific situations, but they
do not govern behavior in a certain issue area for a prolonged period of time. [27] Other components of international governance are international organizations that are material
entities and can be the infrastructure for both international regimes and intergovernmental networks. [28] Any of these components of international governance beyond the nation
state can be regional or global in scope.
A first measure for the extent of governance with governments is the number of international governmental organizations (IGOs). Up until the early 1980s this figure grew
continuously to a total of 378, reflecting the permanent growth in the importance of cross-border transactions. In the late 1980s, as the growth of some cross-border transactions
slowed down, the overall number of international organizations declined rapidly to less than three hundred. Only recently has the number of international organizations begun to
increase again. Currently, the number of IGOs is still below the 1980 figure, unless IGO-emanations are included. [29]
The number of international organizations is only a very rough measure for the development of international governance. It is easily conceivable that a relatively constant
number of IGOs has produced a higher regulatory output and thus strengthened international governance. Indeed, the overall number of multilateral treaties deposited at the
United Nations has grown in a linear fashion from less than 150 in 1960 to well over 400 in 1998. The same applies to the annual ratification of multilateral treaties (Hirschi et. al.
1999: 40). This remarkable growth pattern is replicated on the level of different issue areas. The number of new international environmental treaties and agreements has grown
continuously since the beginning of the century. While up until the 1970s, on average every 5 years brought about 5 treaties, this number has grown to about 25 from the 1980s
on (see Beisheim et. al. 1999: 351). A very similar pattern applies to the development of new international economic treaties and agreements (Beisheim et. al. 1999: 353). In the
field of culture and communication, the regulatory output of existing international regimes, such as the ITU-based telecommunication regime, again shows steady growth up until
the 1980s. [30] This pattern only differs slightly in the field of international security. The regulatory output of the non-proliferation regime and the Security Council showed no clear
pattern for a long time and was rather erratic. Since the end of the 1980s however, the output of Security Council resolutions has grown dramatically. This applies also to
conventions and declarations on the protection of human rights (Beisheim et. al. 1999: 343-347).
The rise of international agreements is accompanied by a growing intensity of transgovernmental relations. [31] Different state agencies – regulatory agencies, courts, executives
and increasingly also legislatures – are networking with their counterparts abroad. Learning from counterparts can be considered as the major goal of these transgovernmental
exchanges. Ann-Marie Slaughter (1997: 190), who sees this development as the most significant for understanding the new world order, describes its core very well: "... the
preferred instrument of cooperation is the memorandum of understanding, in which two or more regulatory agencies set forth and initial terms for an ongoing relationship. Such
memorandums are not treaties; they do not engage the executive or the legislature in negotiations, deliberation, or signature. Rather, they are good-faith agreements, affirming
ties between regulators' agencies based on their like-minded commitment to getting results."
At first sight, the quantitative rise of governance with government does not seem to affect the national constellation in qualitative terms. Theconstitutional principles of the
Westphalian system of sovereign states are intergovernmental in that governments mutually acknowledge each other as governments, thus laying the ground for international
society (see Bull 1977). A closer look, however, reveals two anomalies. First, the rise of issue-area specific international regimes has in addition to elements of the recognition
dimension moved parts of the governance dimension to the international level. The international recognition to govern in a given territory, which is constitutive for the
Westphalian system, must not be confused with international governance, which is a much more recent development. Second, it is still true that since the early 19th century –
many see the Congress of Vienna after the Napoleonic Wars as the starting point – international institutions have assisted states in the realization of governance goals. What is
new about more recent developments is not only the sheer amount of governance with governments, but also the types and objects of regulation. Traditional international
institutions regulated the interaction between states, be it in the field of security (for instance alliance, arms treaties etc.) or in the economy (reduction of tariffs). The current rise
of international institutions is mainly to assist states in regulating societal actors. Regarding the governance goal of reducing external and internal threats to the security of
human beings and their environment, most international environmental regimes exemplify this development. The ultimate target of these regulations is society. In addition, new
issues are taken up. In the field of economics, the development of the GATT Regime is a case in point. The early GATT removed government intervention at the borders, that is,
tariffs on manufactured goods. Over time this increased the importance of non-tariff barriers, thus inducing demands for a new type of market-making regulations that focused
on behind-the-border issues. The Tokyo Round of negotiations (1973-1979) began to deal with non-tariff barriers such as anti-dumping, government subsidies, government
procurement, and customs and licensing procedures. The results of the Uruguay Round (1986-1994) are a major step forward in this direction (see Kahler
1995). [32] International institutions have thus changed their character. They aim increasingly to regulate not only the actions of state actors but also those of societal actors. And
they rely increasingly not only on negative regulations (i.e. regulations that prohibit states from taking certain measures), but also on positive regulations (i.e. regulations that
require states to take certain measures). [33] The extent and the objects of international governance no longer match the notion of a sovereign state in a national constellation.
2) Supranational Governance: Supranational governance even more clearly contradicts the notion of a sovereign state in the national constellation. Supranational institutions
develop rules that are considered superior to national law and involve servants that possess autonomy from national governments. [34] The demand for supranational
governance rises to the extent that the density and scope of international governance grows. With international governance covering more and more issue areas, overlapping
and colliding jurisdictions of international regulations with other international or national regulations becomes more likely. Supranational bodies are a logical response to resolve
these collisions. Moreover, the more international regimes address behind-the-border issues, which are especially difficult to monitor and have significant impacts on societal
actors, the more the question of credibility of commitments arises. A logical way to increase the credibility of commitments is to develop supranational bodies that monitor
regulations and resolve conflicts (see Moravcsik 1998: 73-77).
The best known supranational institutions which meet these expectations can be found in the EU: the European Commission and the European Court of Justice. [35] The direct
effect associated with the supremacy of European law over national law and the direct enforcing effect of ECJ case law through the Preliminary-Ruling Procedure of Article 177
EC guarantees European law undoubted validity in all Member states. Hence, Community provisions have to be seen as an inseparable part of the body of law valid for EU
citizens (Weiler 1993). Other elements of the EU polity also contain elements of supra-nationality. In 1996, for instance, in the multi-level system of the European Union, there
were 409 committees active in the implementation of general Council decisions and which in fact enjoy extensive interpretative freedom in their work (see Falke 1996; Wessels
1998). The committee members are mainly experts and representatives of concerned interest groups, as well as national civil servants mainly selected by their governments.
However, the quality and adequacy of these committees' decisions usually meet with approval (see Eichener 1996) and can even be interpreted as an element of "deliberative
supra-nationalism" (Joerges/Neyer 1997). Given that the EU is the most supranational institution, it is quite significant to see that the total number of EU directives, regulations
and decisions increased from 36 in 1961 to 347 in 1970 and 627 in 1980. While the number of EU rules has remained quite constant since then, with a temporary peak of almost
800 in 1986, it is noteworthy that the relative weight of EU legislation has clearly increased in comparison to national legislation in Germany, France and Great Britain. The
yearly national legislative output has remained more or less constant since the 1960s (Beisheim et. al. 1999: 328-330).
Beyond Europe, supranational institutions are still rare. However, even here there have been some notable recent developments. First of all, the section of the new WTO on the
manufactured goods trade brought in new monitoring and dispute settlement procedures to deal more effectively with behind-the-border issues. The Dispute Settlement Body
and the Appellate Body seem to develop towards a supranational institution, at least in relation to the "Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures"
(see Victor 1999), and thus to some extent resembles the supranational role of the European Court (Godt 1998). Moreover, the Rome Statute of the International Criminal Court
was established as a permanent institution in 1998 also indicates a move in the direction of supra-nationality. This court "shall have the power to exercise its jurisdiction over
persons for the most serious crimes of international concern (...)." [36] Finally, inasfar as infringements of rights can be brought directly before independent bodies by individuals,
as in the case of the "Civil Covenant", the "Race-Discrimination Convention" and the "Convention against Torture" (see Liese 1998), one may also speak of an element of supra-
nationality. Given these very recent developments and the effects these agreements may have on other issue areas, [37] it is fair to conclude that the extent to which institutions
with supranational elements have emerged in global politics is much more than expected ten years ago.
3) Governance without Government: Although the role of governance without government has increased over the last two decades, it is arguably still less significant than
government with governments. To be sure, the number of transnational organizations has grown significantly over the last decades. [38]However, some of these organizations
are standard-setting associations that work as part of a larger international institution established by intergovernmental agreement, while others are part of an issue-area specific
policy network with national governments still in the position to accept or veto agreements. As Thomas Risse-Kappen (1995: 30) puts it: "The more regulated the inter-state
relationship by cooperative international institutions in the particular issue area, the more are transnational activities expected to flourish." Nevertheless, in some issue areas the
role of transnational regimes, organizations and networks is remarkable. To the extent to which governance without government gains independence and governance with
governments even becomes dependent on transnational relations, the deviation from the notion of state sovereignty in the national constellation becomes evident. These
developments indicate both transnationalization and privatization.
The lex mercatoria is a good example of such a development. [39] It is an established transnational regime for the arbitration of cross-border business disputes with
the aim of by-passing national courts (see e.g. Cutler 1999. Although its roots are pre-modern, the lex mercatoria seems to have grown in importance in recent years. In some
cases, parties to the business transaction deliberately prefer to settle disputes on the basis of the lex mercatoria instead of the nation state-based system of "choice of law"
(Dasser 1991). Moreover, national courts regularly back arbitration panels which use lex mercatoria norms, because the non-acceptor of arbitration awards loses most often in
national courts. There are other important transnational regimes, for instance, the development of some of the technical standards related to the Internet such as the TCP/IP
protocol. The Internet Engineering Task Force (IETF), a sub-organization of the Internet Society (ISOC), developed the TCP/IP protocol. This issue network is open to all
users and being on the mailing list constitutes membership. Decisions are made on the basis of discourses in different fora, which are regulated by a number of procedural
rules. Ballots are held on the basis of strongly qualified majority rules and after the new standard has demonstrated its effectiveness in practice. The decisions are then made
public via the mailing lists (see e.g. Hofmann 1996).
One may further distinguish two types of transnational organizations. Some transnational organizations provide the organizational and infra-structural support for
transnational regimes. The International Chamber of Commerce (ICC) and the Internet Society (ISOC) are examples of about 600 such organizations (Shanks, Jacobsen
and Kaplan 1996: 596). Othertransnational organizations aim at influencing governmental policies by addressing transnational public opinion. Greenpeace and amnesty
international are only the best known of this species. In this way NGOs exert some control on governments from outside the country. [40]
Transnational organizations interact with each other and create networksthat can be seen as the constituents for international and transnational policies. Against
this background it comes as no surprise that in more recent analyses particular attention is paid to these transnational networks. Their role seems to be especially salient
within the field of international environmental politics. After the admission of transnational non-governmental organizations (NGOs) to international negotiations, the latter
received an impetus which distinguished them from conventional intergovernmental negotiations, while at the same time giving so-called epistemic communities a
more prominent status (Adler/Haas 1992, Princen/Finger 1994). It is owing to these epistemic communities that as opposed to simple bargaining, deliberative elements are at
less of a disadvantage than is commonly the case, and that particular interests are balanced by public or diffuse interests (see Gehring 1995). [41] In this sense one may speak
of the emergence of transnational sectoral publics and "sectoral demoi" (Abromeit/Schmidt 1998).
This brief examination of the development of different types of institutions for governance beyond the nation state, be they transnational, international or even supranational,
shows that parallel to the growth of societal denationalization governance beyond the nation state has increased. Especially the shape of more recent inter-, trans-, and supra-
national institutions is hardly compatible with the traditional notion of state sovereignty in the national constellation. Governments and other political organizations do not merely
sit back and watch denationalization and the decline in the effectiveness of unilateral policies. They respond to the challenges by setting up new institutions, and this should not
be neglected in the analysis and understanding of statehood. The national constellation, that is the convergence of resources, recognition and the realization of governance
goals in one political organization – the nation state –, seems to be in a process of transformation into a post-national constellation. The nation state is no longer the only site of
authority and the normativity that accompanies it.
This transformation process itself can be separated in different stages. The first stage can be regarded most plausibly as a more or less unintended, indirect outcome of political
responses following (perceived) functional demands. The permanent deepening of some international regimes so that they now deal with positive interventions into the society
and with behind-the-border issues is part of this first stage. The same seems to be true of the need for credible commitments in designing these more ambitious regimes and the
development of supranational bodies to deal with collisions between different regulations. [42] The second stage of the transformation is much more reflective. When society and
political actors begin to comprehend the change, they begin to include issues of trans-boundary identity and trans-boundary ethics into their considerations. Pressures to
improve the life conditions for people of other nationality and race that live in other countries thousands of miles away, as well as the debate about European identity and
democracy are first signs of this reflective stage in the transformation process.
3. The New Architecture of Statehood
Statehood in the national constellation has been characterized by the coincidence of the dimensions of statehood in one political organization, that is the nation state. The
monopoly of force and the ability to collect taxes, the authority to recognize states as such, and the capability to design policies that show a certain degree of public-interest
orientation could all be found at the level of the nation state. The challenges of and responses to denationalization seem, however, to transform this national constellation.
1) Realization of Governance Goals: Nation states have increasing difficulties in designing unilateral policies that are of use in realizing the governance goals of security, legal
certainty, legitimacy and social welfare. The incongruence of political and social spaces leads systematically to challenges to the effectiveness of national policies (Section 2.1.).
Governments and other political groups react to these unintended consequences of social change that were partially encouraged by national policies. The primary response is
the formation of intergovernmental institutions that help to re-adjust political and social spaces and thus to regain the effectiveness of policies, either by directly regulating cross-
border activities or, more often, by coordinating national decisions to a large extent. Hence, systems of interest mediation that are restricted to the nation state lose importance,
especially since political actors such as national executives, who play at both levels, can use their privileged position for manipulation. A secondary response for more powerful
interest groups therefore is to participate directly at the level of international institutions, which happens increasingly, as indicated by the rise of transnational organizations and
transnational networks. In this sense, the formulation of policies for most of the issue areas affected by the challenges of denationalization has been deferred to levels beyond
the nation state. At these levels state agents are the most important actors, but not the sole ones. Transnationally organized interest groups and non-governmental actors do
play a role in agenda-setting and, to a lesser extent, in actual negotiations. [43]
2) Resources: These developments should, however, by no means be regarded as indications of the end of the nation state, that is, the institution that still provides the
resources. First, the developments described apply only to denationalized issue areas, while others still follow the logic of the national constellation. Second, and more
importantly, it is hard to see how governance goals can be achieved without the nation state. To put it in terms of functional theories: the increasing inability of an institution to
fulfil a function can only be seen as an indicator of its impending extinction if there are rival institutions which promise to fulfil that function more efficiently (Spruyt, 1994). The
elimination of the problems relating to global financial markets, organized crime or global environmental risks is hardly conceivable without nation states. Especially for the
implementation of policies the nation state seems, due to the monopoly of force and the control of resources (based on its capacity to raise taxes), to be indispensable. Even
with respect to this dimension, some notable changes have taken place. The degree of cooperation between governmental agencies and the rise of transgovernmental networks
indicates that many governments see their counterparts less as competitors in a hostile environment, but as allies in the search for effective policy instruments and efficient
administration.
3) Recognition: The most complicated and important changes seem to take place with regard to recognition. Traditionally, external recognition as a sovereign state, once
attained, was, in principle, valid for eternity. Nowadays, the recognition of a state increasingly seems to depend upon its respect of the rights of individual freedom that can be
claimed by individuals before the European Court of Justice and under certain circumstances before the Court of Human Rights. In extreme cases, the violation of human rights
can even be regarded as a justification for intervention – the war in Kosovo may be seen as a case in point. These developments lead Soysal (1994) to reflect upon a notion of
"personhood", which is independent of national citizenship. Moreover, the growing use of international observers at national elections indicates a trend towards making critical
elections into global events (Rosenau 1997: 259), and the concept of "good governance" is now also used for evaluations of national policies through international institutions
like the World Bank (1997). In the light of these developments, it seems that the recognition of a state as such is now seen less as a one-shot constituting act, and increasingly
as the result of a permanent legitimacy control. Thomas M. Franck (1992: 50) already pointed out a few years ago: "We are witnessing a sea change in international law, as a
result of which the legitimacy of each government someday will be measured definitely by international rules and processes" (see also Friedman 1996).
Moreover, the subject carrying out this control function is today not only the international society of states, but increasingly also an emergent transnational society as well as
supra-national bodies. Supra-national bodies judge on the basis of reason whether deviating state behavior is defensible, and thus provide the necessary information. The
transnational society, then, in outrageous or in repetitive cases, may question the legitimacy of a nation state. Along this line, the UN Secretary General also adopted the
perspective that states must serve peoples. "If they fail do so and permit serious human rights abuses", he said, "they open themselves to justified intervention by the
international community in form of the UN itself." [44] Taking this notion further, the authority which assigns sovereignty, that is the right to set the rules of a given territory or the
"Kompetenz-Kompetenz", as it is called in German, seems to change as well as the criterion for this assignment. What has changed in world politics then is both the criteria for
assigning Kompetenz-Kompetenz and the subject, which has "Kompetenz-Kompetenz-Kompetenz". [45]
How is it possible to talk about institutions that assign states rights, as long as states maintain their superiority in resources? Is it not the capacity for the enforcement of norms
and rules that is decisive? This is a challenging objection. Yet speculating further by extrapolating current trends, good reasons can be advanced for the position that the
traditional linkage of governance to a sanction-endowed, super-ordinate central body derives more from our backward-looking nation-state-marked tradition of thought than from
a forward-looking analysis of post-national statehood. To begin with, legitimate regulations and law-like rules have a compliance-pull of their own. It is therefore possible to
envision beyond the nation state a community of law (Rechtsgemeinschaft) without a community of enforcement (Zwangsgemeinschaft), to use this early characterization of
Walter Hallstein for the EU. [46] Moreover, good governance can often increase compliance with regulations without resort to enforcement at all. Only few incidences of non-
compliance by nation states are the result of deliberate cheating. Quite often, compliance can be induced by a number of institutional features short of enforcement (see
Chayes/Chayes 1995). In addition, the stress on the connection between compulsion and the facticity of the norms is almost always combined with a preference for hierarchical
enforcement. It does not usually take into account the possibility of horizontal, reciprocal compulsion deriving from social interdependence. To be sure, considered historically,
the civilizing effect of a monopoly of force cannot be overestimated. In governance beyond the nation state, the decentralized sanctioning bodies, which act in the name of
transnational society and supranational bodies the democratic welfare states , are, however, qualitatively different agents from the force-wielders of medieval society. Nation
states in the OECD world are previously, or internally civilized and do not necessarily require an external leviathan. In the post-national constellation, then, the question arises
whether enforcement necessarily should be hierarchical. The EU experience over the last decade has made it clear that governance with significant rule compliance is, in
certain circumstances, possible even without a force-equipped, hierarchically superior body. In this sense, in a denationalized world it may not only be policy formation that will
be horizontalized, but also its control and enforcement. In other words, the horizontalization of governance might be accompanied by a horizontalization of enforcement
(Zürn/Wolf 1999).
5. Bibliography
Appelbaum, Richard/Felstiner, William/Gessner, Volkmar (eds.) 2000: The Legal Culture of Global Business Transactions, Oxford: Hart Publishers, i.p.
Abromeit, Heidrun/Schmidt, Thomas 1998: Grenzprobleme der Demokratie, in: Kohler-Koch, Beate (ed.) Regieren in entgrenzten Räumen, (PVS-Sonderheft 29/1998), Opladen:
Westdeutscher Verlag, 293-320.
Adler, Emanuel/Haas, Peter M. 1992: Conclusion: Epistemic Communities, World Order, and the Creation of a Reflective Research Program, in: International Organisation 46:1,
367-390.
Albert, Matthias 1996: Fallen der (Welt)-Ordnung. Internationale Beziehungen und ihre Theorien zwischen Moderne und Postmoderne, Opladen: Leske&Budrich.
Alter, Karen J. 1998: Who Are the `Masters of the Treaty'? European Governments and the ECJ, in: International Organization, 52:1, 121-147.
Anderson, Benedict 1991: Imagined Communities. Reflections on the Origin and Spread of Nationalism, London: Verso, 2 nd Edition.
Beck, Ulrich 1997: Was ist Globalisierung?, Frankfurt/M.: Suhrkamp
Beisheim, Marianne/Dreher, Sabine/Walter, Gregor/Zangl, Bernhard/Zürn, Michael 1999: Im Zeitalter der Globalisierung? Thesen und Daten zur gesellschaftlichen und
politischen Denationalisierung, Baden-Baden: Nomos.
Beisheim, Marianne/Zürn, Michael 1999: Transnationale Nicht-Regierungsorganisationen. Eine Antwort auf die Globalisierung?, in: Klein, Ansgar/Legrand, Hans-Josef/Leif,
Thomas (eds.): Neue Soziale Bewegungen – Impulse, Bilanzen und Perspektiven, Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag, 306-319.
Benhabib, Seyla 1996: Toward a Deliberative Model of Democratic Legitimacy, in: Benhabib, Seyla (ed.): Democracy and Difference. Contesting the Boundaries of the Political,
Princeton, NJ: Princeton U.P., 67-94.
Böckenförde, Ernst 1969: Entstehung und Wandel des Rechtsstaatbegriffs, in: Ehmke, Horst: Festschrift für Adolf Arndt, Frankfurt/M.: Europäische Verlagsanstalt, 53-76.
Bogdandy, Armin von 1999: Supranationaler Föderalismus als Wirklichkeit und Idee einer Herrschaftsform. Zur Gestalt der Europäischen Union nach Amsterdam, Baden-
Baden: Nomos.
Braudel, Fernand 1992: The Wheels of Commerce. Vol. 2: Civilization and Capitalism 15th - 18th Century , Berkeley, CA: California U.P.
Brock, Lothar/Albert, Matthias 1995: Entgrenzung der Staatenwelt. Zur Analyse weltgesellschaftlicher Entwicklungstendenzen, in: Zeitschrift für Internationale Beziehungen 2:2,
259-285.
Brock, Lothar 1998: Die Grenzen der Demokratie. Selbstbestimmung im Kontext des globalen Strukturwandels, in: Kohler-Koch, Beate (ed.) Regieren in entgrenzten Räumen,
(PVS-Sonderheft 29/1998), Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Bruder, Wolfgang/Dose, Nicolai 1992: Öffentliche Verwaltung, in: Schmidt, Manfred (ed.): Lexikon der Politik. Vol. 3: Die westlichen Länder, München: Beck, 274-283.
Burley, Anne-Marie/Mattli, Walter 1993: Europe Before the Court: A Political Theory of Legal Integration, in: International Organization 47:1, 41-76.
Cerny, Philip G. 1996: What Next for the State?, in: Kofman, Eleonore/Youngs, Gillian (eds.): Globalization: Theory and Practice, London: Pinter, 123-137.
Chayes, Abram/Chayes, Antonia Handler 1995: The New Sovereignty: Compliance With International Regulatory Agreements, Cambridge, MA: Harvard U.P.
Corbey, Dorette 1995: Dialectical Functionalism: Stagnation as a Booster of European Integration, in: International Organisation 49:2, 253-284.
Cox, Robert W. 1992: Global Prestroika, in: Socialist Register 1992, ed. by Miliband, Ralph/Panitch, Leo, London: Merlin Press, 26-43.
Cutler, Claire A. 1999: Locating "Authority" in the Global Political Economy, in: International Studies Quarterly 43:1, 59-81.
Dasser, Felix 1991: Lex Mercatoria: Werkzeug der Praktiker oder Spielzeug der Lehre?, in: Schweizerische Zeitschrift für internationales und europäisches Recht, 3/91, 299-
323.
De Ly, Filip 2000: Lex Mercatoria: Globalization and International Self-Regulation, in: Appelbaum, Richard/Felstiner, William/Gessner, Volkmar (eds.) 2000: The Legal Culture of
Global Business Transactions, Oxford: Hart Publishers, i.p.
Deutsch, Karl W. 1969: Nationalism and its Alternatives, New York: The Free Press.
Eichener, Volker 1996: Die Rückwirkungen der europäischen Integration auf nationale Politikmuster, in: Jachtenfuchs, Markus/Kohler-Koch, Beate (eds.): Europäische
Integration, Opladen: Leske&Budrich, 249-280.
Elias, Norbert 1976: Über den Prozeß der Zivilisation. Soziogenetische und psychogenetische Untersuchungen, Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp.
Elster, Jon 1992: Arguing and Bargaining in the Federal Convention and the Assemblée Constituante, in: Malnes, Raino/Underdal, Arild (eds.): Rationality and Institutions.
Essays in Honour of Knut Midgaard, Oslo: Universitetsforlaget, 13-50.
Elster, Jon (ed.) 1998: Deliberative Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P.
Falke, Josef 1996: Comitology and Other Committees: A Preliminary Enpirical Assessment, in: Pedler, Robin H./Schaefer, Guenther F. (eds.): Shaping European Law and
Policy: The Role of Committees and Comitology in the Political Process, Maastricht: EIPA, 117-165.
Franck, Thomas M. 1992: The Emerging Right to Democratic Governance, in: American Journal of International Law 86:1, 46-91.
Frieden, Jeffry A./Rogowski, Ronald 1996: The Impact of the International Economy on National Policies: An Analytical Overview, in: Keohane Robert O./Milner, Helen V. (eds.):
Internationalization and Domestic Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P., 25-47.
Friedman, Lawrence 1996: Borders: On the Emerging Sociology of International Law, in: Stanford Journal of International Law 32, 65-90.
Garrett, Geoffrey 1998: Partisan Politics in the Global Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P.
Gehring, Thomas 1995: Regieren im internationalen System. Verhandlungen, Normen und internationale Regime, in: Politische Vierteljahresschrift 36:2, 197-219.
Gellner, Ernest 1991: Nations and Nationalism, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell U.P, 3rd ed.
Genschel, Philipp 1995: Standards in der Informationstechnik. Institutionaller Wandel in der internationalen Standardisierung, Frankfurt/M.: Campus
Giddens, Anthony 1985: The National State and Violence, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Giddens, Anthony 1994: Beyond Left and Right. The Future of Radical Politics, Cambridge: Polity Press.
Godt, Christine 1998: Der Bericht des Appellate Body der WTO zum EG-Einfuhrverbot von Hormonfleisch. Risikoregulierung im Weltmarkt, in: Europäisches Wirtschafts- und
Steuerrecht 9:6, 202-209.
Grimm, Dieter 1994: Staatsaufgaben - eine Bilanz, in: Grimm, Dieter (ed.): Staatsaufgaben, Baden-Baden: Nomos, 771-785.
Habermas, Jürgen 1998: Die postnationale Konstellation. Politische Essays, Frankfurt/M: Suhrkamp.
Held, David 1995: Democracy and the Global Order. From the Modern State to Cosmopolitical Governance, Cambridge: Polity Press.
Held, David/McGrew, Anthony/Goldblatt, David/Perraton, Jonathan 1999: Global Transformations: Politics, Economics and Culture, Cambridge: Polity Press.
Hirsch, Joachim 1995: Der nationale Wettbewerbsstaat. Staat, Demokratie Politik im globalen Kapitalismus, Berlin/Amsterdam: Edition ID-Archiv.
Hirschi, Christian/Serdült, Uwe/ Widmer, Thomas 1999: Schweizerische Außenpolitik im Wandel, in: Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Politikwissenschaft 5:1, 31-56.
Hirst, Paul/Thompson, Grahame 1996: Globalization in Question. The International Economy and the Possibilities of Governance, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P.
Hobsbawm, Eric J. 1992: Nations and Nationalism since 1780. Programm, Myth, Reality, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P., 2nd.
Hofmann, Jeanette 1998: Am Herzen der Dinge - Regierungsmacht im Internet, in: Gellner, Wienand/von Korff, Fritz (Eds.): Internet und Demokratie, Baden-Baden: Nomos, 55-
77.
Holm, Hans-Henrik/Sørensen, Georg (eds.) 1995: Whose World Order? Uneven Globalization and the End of the Cold War, Boulder, Co.: Westview Press.
Horn, Norbert 1996: Einführung in die Rechtswissenschaft und Rechtsphilosophie, Heidelberg: Müller.
Jachtenfuchs, Markus/Kohler-Koch, Beate 1996: Regieren im dynamischen Mehrebenensystem, in: Jachtenfuchs, Markus/Kohler-Koch, Beate (eds.): Europäische Integration,
Opladen: Leske&Budrich, 15-44.
Jackson, Robert H. 1990: Quasi-States : Sovereignity, International Relations, and the Third World, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P.
Jänicke, Martin 1998: Umweltpolitik: Global am Ende oder am Ende global?, in: Ulrich Beck (ed.): Perspektiven der Weltgesellschaft, Frankfurt/M.: Suhrkamp, 322-344.
Joerges, Christian/Neyer, Jürgen 1997: Transforming Strategic Interaction Into Deliberative Problem-Solving: European Comitology in the Foodstuffs Sector, in: Journal of
European Public Policy 4:4, 609-625.
Kahler, Miles 1995: International Institutions and the Political Economy of Integration, Washington D.C: The Brookings Institution.
Kaufmann, Franz-Xaver 1994: Diskurse über Staatsaufgaben, in: Grimm, Dieter (ed.): Staatsaufgaben, Baden-Baden: Nomos, 14-41.
Keohane, Robert O./Nye, Joseph S. jr. (eds.) 1971: Transnational Relations and World Politics, Cambridge, MA: Harvard U.P.
Keohane, Robert 1991: Sovereignity, Interdependence and International Relations (CFIA-Working Paper 1), Cambridge, Ma.
Knieper, Rolf 1991: Nationale Souveränität : Versuch über Ende und Anfang einer Weltordnung, Frankfurt/M: Fischer.
Kohler-Koch, Beate 1993: Die Welt regieren ohne Weltregierung, in: Böhret, Carl/Wewer, Göttrik (eds.): Regieren im 21. Jahrhundert. Zwischen Globalisierung und
Regionalisierung. Festgabe für Hans-Hermann Hartwich zum 65. Geburtstag, Opladen: Leske&Budrich, 109-141.
Kohler-Koch, Beate (ed.) 1998: Regieren in entgrenzten Räumen, (PVS-Sonderheft 29/1998), Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.
Krasner, Stephen D. 1983: Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables, in: Krasner, Stephen D. (ed.): International Regimes, Ithaca/New
York: Cornell University Press, 1-21.
Krasner, Stephen D. 1993: Westphalia and All That, in: Goldstein, Judith/ Keohane, Robert O. (eds.) 1993: Ideas and Foreign Policy. Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell U.P., 235-264.
Krasner, Stephen 1999: Sovereignty. Organized Hypocrisy, Princeton, N.J: Princeton U.P.
Leibfried, Stephan/Pierson, Paul 1995: Semi-Sovereign Welfare States: Social Policy in a Multi-Tiered Europe, in: Leibfried, Stephan/Pierson, Paul (eds.) 1995: European Social
Policy: Between Fragmentation and Integration, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 43-77.
Levy, Marc A./Young, Oran R./Zürn, Michael 1995: The Study of International Regimes, in: European Journal of International Relations 1:3, 267-330.
Liese, Andrea 1998: Menschenrechsschutz durch Nichtregierungsorganisationen, in: Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte B46-47, 36-42.
Lindblom, Charles E. 1977: Politics and Markets: The World's Political-Economic Systems, New York: Basic Books.
Litfin, Karen 1997: Sovereignty in World Ecopolitics, in: Mershon International Studies Review 41:2, 167-204.
Lyons, Gene M./Mastanduno, Michael (eds.) 1995: Beyond Westphalia? State Sovereignty and International Intervention, Baltimore: John Hopkins U.P.
Majone, Giandomenico (ed.) 1996: Regulating Europe, London: Routledge.
Marks, Gary/ Scharpf, Fritz W./Schmitter, Philippe C./Streeck, Wolfgang (eds.) 1996: Governance in the European Union, London: Sage.
Marshall, Thomas H. 1992: Citizenship and Social class, London : Pluto Press.
Mayer, Peter/Rittberger, Volker/Zürn, Michael 1993: Regime Theory. State of the Art and Perspectives, in: Rittberger, Volker with the assistance of Peter Mayer (ed.): Regime
Theory and International Relations, Oxford: Oxford U.P., 391-430.
Mayntz, Renate 1996: Politische Steuerung: Aufstieg, Niedergang und Transformation einer Theorie, in: Beyme, Klaus von/Offe, Claus (eds.): Politische Theorien in der Ära der
Transformation (PVS-Sonderheft 26/1995), Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag, 148-168.
Moravcsik, Andrew 1998: Choice for Europe. Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht, Ithaca, N.Y: Cornell U.P.
Morgenthau, Hans 1967: Politics among Nations. The Struggle for Power and Peace, New York: Alfred Knopf.
Nettl, J.P. 1968: The State as a Conceptual Variable, in: World Politics, 20:4, 559-592.
Neyer, Jürgen 1999: Legitimes Recht oberhalb des demokratischen Rechtsstaates? Supranationalität als Herausforderung für die Politikwissenschaft, in: Politische
Vierteljahresschrift 40:3, 390-414.
North, Douglass C. 1981: Structure and Change in Economic History, New York: Norton.
Offe , Claus 1973: Strukturprobleme des kapitalistischen Staates: Aufsätze zur politischen Soziologie, Frankfurt/M.: Suhrkamp
Offe, Claus 1975: Berufsbildungsreform. Eine Fallstudie über Reformpolitik, Frankfurt/M.: Suhrkamp
Ohmae, Kenichi 1993: The Rise of the Regional State, in: Foreign Affairs 72:2, 78-87.
Princen, Thomas/Finger, Mathias 1994: Environmental NGOs in World Politics. Linking the Local and the Global, London: Routledge.
Reinicke, Wolgang 1998: Global Public Policy. Governing without Government? New York: Brookings Institution.
Reus-Smit, Christian 1997: The Constitutional Structure of International Society and the Nature of Fundamental Institutions, in: International Organisation 51:4, 555-589.
Risse-Kappen, Thomas 1995: Bringing Transnational Relations Back In: Introduction, in: Risse-Kappen, Thomas (ed.): Bringing Transnational Relations Back In: Non-State
Actors, Domestic Structures and International Institutions, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P., 3-33.
Rittberger, Volker with the assistance of Peter Mayer (Ed.) 1993a: Regime Theory and International Relations, Oxford: Oxford U.P
Rittberger, Volker 1993b: Research on International Regimes in Germany: The Adaptive Internalization of an American Social Science Concept, in: Rittberger, Volker with the
assistance of Peter Mayer (Ed.) 1993a: Regime Theory and International Relations, Oxford: Oxford U.P, 3-22.
Rittberger, Volker 1995: The Future of Sovereignty Rethinking a Key Concept of International Relations, Paper prepared for UNU 20 th Anniversary Symposium on the United
Nations System in the 21st century, Tokyo, 21.-22. November 1995.
Rittberger, Volker/Zangl, Bernhard 1995: Internationale Organisationen: Politik und Geschichte, Opladen: Leske&Budrich, 2 nd edition.
Rosenau, James N. 1992: Governance, Order, and Change in World Politics, in: Rosenau, James N./Czempiel, Ernst-Otto (eds.): Governance without Government. Order and
Change in World Politics, Cambridge, Ma: Lexington Press, 1-29.
Rosenau, James N. 1997: Along the Domestic-Foreign Frontier. Exploring Governance in a Turbulent World, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P.
Sassen, Saskia 1998: Globalization and its Discontents, New York: Free Press.
Scharpf, Fritz W. 1996: Politische Optionen im vollendeten Binnenmarkt, in: Jachtenfuchs, Markus/Kohler-Koch, Beate (eds.): Europäische Integration, Opladen:
Leske&Budrich, 109-140.
Schmalz-Bruns, Rainer 1998: Grenzerfahrungen und Grenzüberschreitungen: Demokratie im integrierten Europa, in: Kohler-Koch, Beate (ed.) Regieren in entgrenzten
Räumen, (PVS-Sonderheft 29/1998), Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag, 369-380.
Shanks, Cheryl/Jacobson, Harold K./Kaplan, Jeffrey H. 1996: Inertia and Change in the Constellation of International Governmental Organzations, 1981-1992, in: International
Organisation 50:4, 593-629.
Slaughter, Ann-Marie 1997: The Real New World Order, in: Foreign Affairs, 76:5, 183-197.
Smith, Adam 1776: Inquiry into the Nature and the Causes of the Wealth of Nations, London: W. Strahan & T. Cadell.
Sørensen, Georg 1997: An Analysis of Contemporary Statehood. Consequences for Conflict and Cooperation, in: Review of International Studies 23:3, 253-269.
Sørensen, Georg 1999: Sovereignty at the Millenium – Change and Continuity in a Fundamental Institution, in: Political Studies, 47:3, 590-604.
Soysal, Yasemin Nuhoglu 1994: Limits of Citizenship. Migrants and Postnational Membership in Europe, Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago.
Spruyt, Hendrik 1994: The Sovereign State and its Competitors. The Analysis of Systems Change, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton U.P.
Suchmann, Marc C. 1995: Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches, in: Academy of Management Review 20:3, 571-610.
Thomson, Janice E. 1994: Mercenaries, Pirates, and Sovereigns. State-Building and Extraterritorial Violence in Early Modern Europe, Princeton, N.J.: Princeton U.P.
Thomson, Janice E. 1995: State Sovereignty and International Relations. Bridging the Gap Between Theory and Empirical Research, in: International Studies Quarterly 39: 2,
213-233.
Tilly, Charles 1985: War Making and State Making as Organized Crime, in: Evans, Peter B./Rueschemeyer, Dietrich/Skocpol, Theda (eds.): Bringing the State Back In,
Cambridge: Cambridge U.P, 169-191.
Tilly, Charles 1990: Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990 - 1990, Oxford: Blackwell.
Victor, David G. 1999: Risk Management and the World Trading System: Regulating International Trade Distortions of National Sanitary and Phytosanitary Policies, unpublished
paper, New York.
Vogel, David 1995: Trading up. Consumer and Environmental Regulation in a Global Economy, Cambridge, Ma.: Harvard U.P.
Wallace, Helen 1999: European Policies and Polities, Paper prepared for DGXII workshop on Governance and Citizenship, 8.-9.9. 1999.Weiler, Joseph H. H. 1993: Journey to
an Unknown Destination: A Retrospective and Prospective of the European Court of Justice in the Arena of Political Integration, in: Journal of Common Market Studies 31:4,
417-446.
Wessels, Wolfgang 1998: Comitology: Fusion in Action. Politico-administrative Trends in the EU System, in: Journal of European Public Policy 5:2, 209-234.
Wolf, Klaus Dieter 2000: Die neue Staatsräson Zwischenstaatliche Kooperation als Demokratieproblem in der Weltgesellschaft, Baden-Baden: Nomos, i.p.
World Bank 1997: World Development Report 1997, Washington D.C.
Young, Oran R. 1978: Anarchy and Social Choice. Reflections on the International Polity, in: World Politics 31: 2, 241-263.
Young, Oran R. 1994: International Governance. Protecting the Environment in a Stateless Society, Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell U.P.
Zacher, Mark W. with Brent A. Sutton 1996: Governing Global Networks. International Regimes for Transportation and Communication, Cambridge: Cambridge U.P.
Zangl, Bernhard/Zürn, Michael 1999: The Effects of Denationalisation on Security in the OECD World, in: Global Society, 13:2, 139-161.
Zürn, Michael/Wolf, Dieter 1999: European Law and International Regimes: The Features of Law Beyond the Nation State, in: European Law Journal 5:3, 272-292.
Zürn, Michael 1995: What has Changed in Europe. The Challenge of Globalization and Individualization, in: Holm, Hans-Henrik/Sørensen, Georg (eds.) 1995: Whose World
Order? Uneven Globalization and the End of the Cold War, Boulder, Co.: Westview Press, 137-163.
Zürn, Michael 1998a: Regieren jenseits des Nationalstaates. Denationalisierung und Globalisierung als Chance, Frankfurt/M.: Suhrkamp.
Zürn, Michael 1998b: The Rise of International Environmental Politics: A Review of Current Research, in: World Politics, 50:4, 617-649.
Zürn, Michael 2000: Democracy beyond the Nation State, in: European Journal of International Relations, i.p.
Footnotes
[1]
See for instance contributions to Holm/Sørensen (1995), Krasner (1999), Liftin (1997), contributions to Lyons/Mastanduno (1995), Rosenau (1997), Sørensen (1998), and
Thomson (1995).
[2]
See for instance Sassen (1998), Hirsch (1995), Held et. al. (1999).
[3]
Krasner (1993) is therefore plainly right when he emphasizes that it is a strong over-simplification to see the Peace of Westphalia as a turning point in history. Sovereignty has
been contested for many centuries, before and since 1648, and never prevailed in a pure form. It thus seems premature to conclude from some observations about deviations
from the principle of sovereignty that sovereignty is in decline.
[4]
The distinction between internal and external “recognition" must not be confused with the one between internal and external “sovereignty" (see e.g. Rittberger 1995, Reinicke
1998). Whereas internal/external recognition refers to different “recognizing subjects", the more traditional distinction refers to internal authority vs. independence from external
resources as already implied in Morgenthau's definition.
[5]
See Suchman (1995: 574) for a similar definition relating to organizations in general.
[6]
See Nettl (1968) for a still valuable contribution to the “state as a conceptual variable".
[7]
Resolution 1514 (XV), 14.12.60.
[8]
Jackson (1990) coined the term "quasi-states" for these organizations. See also Knieper (1991) and especially Sørensen (1997) on this issue.
[9]
Historical state theory refers to the "minimum activities of the state", which include warfare, state-building, the protection of individuals and the collection of taxes (Tilly 1990:
chap. 4). Economic theory of the state regards internal and external protection and the provision of public goods as the central "duties of the state" (Smith 1776; cf. also North
1981). Legal theory discusses the "duties (functions) for regulating human co-existence in the relevant state" and identifies peace, liberty, social security, social integration and
co-operation as these duties (Horn 1996: 22-25). Sociological theory established the classic distinction between civil (guaranteed individual liberties), political (participation in
political power) and social (minimum social security) subjective rights – that is, legitimate demands on the state (Marshall 1992). In a more recent contribution, Anthony Giddens
(1994: 246) discusses the reduction of force and violence, the challenging of arbitrary claims to power, the establishment of compensation for environmental damage and the
struggle against poverty as fundamental political orientations. In political theory, Seyla Benhabib (1996: 67) identifies legitimacy, economic welfare and a collective identity as
the "public goods" that must be provided in modern societies. Modern political economy identifies the political regulation of the market, the provision of a public infrastructure
and socio-political adjustments as the "main functions" of the state within the "socio-economic sphere" (cf. Cerny 1996: 124-130 and Majone 1996: 54).
[10]
I use the term "governance goals" for two reasons. First, it should not hastily be concluded that the attainment of these goals depends purely on the existence of a state. If we
are to consider the concept of governance beyond the nation state, then we must analyse the above objectives separately from the state. In this respect terms such as "state
functions", "state aims", "state objectives" etc. are unsatisfactory. Second, it is important to avoid teleological characterizations of the state or of governance (Kaufmann 1994:
17) without falling back on the argument that desirable and necessary state activities are historically and culturally contingent. The term "governance goals" is, I think, a better
expression of the desirable middle position than, say, purpose or function (which sound like a teleological characterization) or activities (which sound completely contingent).
[11]
He puts forward a challenging argument according to which the rise of international institutions can be adequately interpreted as a new form of “Staatsräson" through which
states gain autonomy from society instead of an attempt to achieve societally desirable governance goals (Wolf 2000).
[12]
This aspect is especially emphasized by Moravcsik's conceptualization of the state in explaining European integration (Moravcsik 1998).
[13]
Organization theory emphasizes that purposes are constitutional to organizations. Bogdandy (1999: 23) makes that argument in a similar context.
[14]
This figure counts only the most important coastal provinces of China as "threshold countries", but not the whole of China. If China as a whole were included its share in world
trade would increase marginally but its population ratio would increase by 15 percent. See Reinicke (1998: 39-51) for additional economic indicators showing the OECD focus of
the transnational economy.
[15]
To be sure, the term de-bordering is used in quite different ways. While some use it in the sense of “despatialization", especially Albert/Brock (1995), Albert (1998), Brock
(1998), Kohler-Koch (1998) use it in a way that resembles the notion of denationalization to a large extent.
[16]
See Zürn (1995, 1998a) for an analysis of "uneven denationalization“. See also Habermas (1998), Sassen (1998).
[17]
In a research project funded by the German Research Association we developed 72 indicators to determine the extent of denationalization in different issue areas and
different OECD countries (see Beisheim et al. 1999). For a similar undertaking with similar results see Held et al. (1999).
[18]
To be sure, at least for environmental regulations this fear seems to be unsubstantiated (see Héritier et. al 1996, Vogel 1995, Jänicke 1998). While there indeed seems to be
a parallel drop in corporate taxes in most OECD countries, the question whether there is a downward convergence of national regulations with respect to social policies is most
contested (see e.g. Garrett 1998).
[19]
This specific version of the principle of congruence is discussed in Held (1995: 16).
[20]
The policy that is affected is at the national level, while the policy that is demanded is at the international level.
[21]
It is frequently sufficient to employ a regulative policy at the international level (e.g. minimum social standards) to retain re-distributive policies at the national level. See
Leibfried/Pierson (1995) and Zürn (1998a: 342-344).
[22]
It is a distributive policy in as far as the distribution of participation rights and channels are concerned.
[23]
Rosenau (1992: 5). See also Kohler-Koch (1993); Mayer/Rittberger/Zürn (1993); Young (1994).
[24]
See Young (1978) for arguments why a world state is neither possible nor desirable.
[25]
See Marks et. al. (1996) and Jachtenfuchs/Kohler-Koch (1996).
[26]
See Krasner (1983a: 3). See Rittberger (1993b), and Levy, Young and Zürn (1995), for further elaborations on the definition of international regimes.
[27]
The distinction between international regimes and international networks is similar to the one drawn by Mayntz (1996), between networks for the management of ad-hoc
problems and institutions for the regulation of recurring problems.
[28]
The formal term is International Governmental Organizations (IGOs), as opposed to Transnational Non-Governmental Organizations (NGOs). The latter consist of any kind of
professional association, like the International Political Science Association, and also of profit-seeking NGOs, that is multinational enterprises.
[29]
Emanations include those organizations that have other IGOs' names in their titles, have been created by a provision in another IGO's charter, are a joint or internal IGO
committee or an international center or institute. See Shanks, Jacobson and Kaplan (1996: 597). For a good treatment of the development of international organizations see
Rittberger/Zangl (1995).
[30]
See Zacher with Sutton (1996) and (Beisheim et. al. 1999: 341). In this field it is hard to assess the precise amount of regulatory output in the most recent period, since a de
facto decline of ITU importance relative to other regulating agencies has taken place (see Genschel 1995).
[31]
See Keohane/Nye (1971) for a seminal volume that introduced, among else, the notion of transgovernmental relations. More recently, Robert Cox`s (1992: 30) work has
emphasized the importance of ,,transnational networks that limk policy-making from country to country.“
[32]
See also Hirschi et. al (1999: 43) who demonstrate quantitatively the expansion of issue areas in which Switzerland has signed international treaties and has thus made part
of their foreign policy.
[33]
See Corbey (1995) and Scharpf (1996) for recent contributions using this distinction.
[34]
Moravcsik (1998: 67) distinguishes between “pooled sovereignty", when governments agree to decide future matters by voting procedures other than unanimity, and
“delegated sovereignty", when supranational actors are permitted to take certain autonomous decisions, without an intervening interstate vote or unilateral veto. On the basis of
this distinction between two subtypes of supra-nationality even some intergovernmental institutions contain supranational components.
[35]
See Bogdandy (1999) and Neyer (1999) for a constructive use of the term supranational governance.
[36]
Article 1; see (http://www.un.org/law/icc/index.htm
[37]
Sassen (1998: 20-22), for instance, points out that domestic courts severely restrained policies to control immigration, and thus the right of the nation state to control its
border, since they would violate international agreements.
[38]
See the data of the Union of International Associations (UIA).
[39]
Its character as a generically transnational regime is reflected in the legal debate on the extent to which this law can be regarded as autonomous from state law (see De Ly
2000).
[40]
To be sure, the evidence on the amount and the sources of their influence is not yet definitive. See Beck (1997: 121-128) for an interesting case study of the Brent Spar case.
[41]
The best conceptualization of the arguing bargaining distinction is still Elster (1992, 1998).
[42]
See especially Burley/Mattli (1993) and Alter (1998) for convincing accounts of how the European Court of Justice was not the outcome of intergovernmental design.
[43]
Parts of the literature on transnational NGOs focuses on their role in the formulation and implementation of international policies. See Beisheim/Zürn 1999 and Zürn 1998b:
642-648.
[44]
Financial Times, People first, 22.9.1999: 13.
[45]
The term Kompetenz-Kompetenz-Kompetenz is unusual. The normal use of the concept stops at the second level, the Kompetenz-Kompetenz, and has been used
exclusively for states, since they were the carrier and, in form of the society of states, the assigning instance. Precisely this may be in the process of change.
[46]
See the discussion of these concepts in Bogdandy 1999: 53).
[47]
See Helen Wallace (1999) for a very useful distinction of five modes of policy development in the EU, based on the one hand on the relative importance of major actors and
on the other on the kind of policy in question.
[48]
See Zangl/Zürn (1999) for an argument along these lines and also for further references.
[49]
See Zürn (2000) for an argument along these lines and for further references.
[50]
Note that these hypotheses are based on different grounds than those that are built on the notion of a race-to-the-bottom of regulatory standards. While the latter argue
against the background of a national constellation (competition between sovereign nation states), the hypotheses put forward here are formulated against the background of a
post-national constellation. Whereas the national constellation based explanations have difficulties explaining why it is possible to employ regulatory policies with remarkable
distributional consequences in the environmental field, but not possible when it comes to social policies, an explanation based on the notion of a post-national constellation may
be more successful.