Modern Law Review, Wiley The Modern Law Review
Modern Law Review, Wiley The Modern Law Review
Modern Law Review, Wiley The Modern Law Review
REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
https://www.jstor.org/stable/1097173?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
Modern Law Review, Wiley are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to The Modern Law Review
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
THE
Judith Freedman*
Introduction
New limited liability forms of business organisation are in vogue. Limited liabilit
is widely regarded as a mechanism that encourages entrepreneurship and makes
major contribution to the law of business organisations.1 Popular and politic
sentiment proclaim: 'the more limited liability the better'.2 In the USA, the Limit
Liability Partnership (LLP) and the Limited Liability Company (LLC) have
emerged over recent years as frequently used and strongly supported new legal
forms of organisation. The UK is following suit, with its own LLP, original
intended for the regulated professions only, but now to be available to all types o
user.3 The Company Law Review Steering Group in the UK is working on th
1 For some examples of this contention see J. Freedman and M. Godwin, 'Incorporating the Micro
Business' in A. Hughes and D.J. Storey (eds), Finance and the Small Firm (London: Routledge, 199
(hereafter Freedman and Godwin (1994)); A. Hicks, 'Corporate Form: Questioning the Unsung Her
[1997] JBL 306.
2 For recent pronouncements and comments to this effect, see ns 17, 38, 132 and text to n 66 belo
3 The Limited Liability Partnerships (LLP) Bill was introduced into the House of Lords in Novembe
1999. See also Department of Trade and Industry (DTI), Limited Liability Partnerships Draf
Regulations: A Consultation Document URN 99/1025 (London: DTI, 1999); Trade and Industr
Committee, Fourth Report Draft Limited Liability Partnership Bill HC 59 (1999) para 38; J
Freedman and V. Finch, 'Limited Liability Partnerships: Have Accountants Sewn up the "Dee
Pockets" Debate?' 422 [1997] JBL 387; A. Griffiths, 'Professional Firms and Limited Liability: A
? The Modem Law Review Limited 2000 (MLR 63:3, May). Published by Blackwell Publishers,
108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 3
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
Analysis of the Proposed Limited Liability Partnership' [1998] CfiLR 157; A. Griffiths, 'Structuring
the Law of Private Limited Companies Through the Next Millennium' in D. Milman (ed), Regulating
Enterprise (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 1999).
4 The Company Law Review Steering Group, Modern Company Law for a Competitive Economy: The
Strategic Framework, (London: DTI, 1999) (hereafter The Strategic Framework) para 5.2.10 and
question 10 and see text to n 66 below.
5 DTI Company Law Review: The Law Applicable to Private Companies URN 94/529 (London: DTI,
1994); J. Freedman 'Small Business and the Corporate Form: Burden or Privilege?' (1994) 57 MLR
555 (hereafter Freedman (1994)); Freedman and Godwin (1994), n 1 above; Andrew Hicks, Robert
Drury and Jeff Smallcombe, Alternative Company Structures for the Small Business (London:
Chartered Association of Certified Accountants, 1995) (hereafter ACCA Report) and contributions
from a number of authors in Barry A. K. Rider and Mads Andenas (eds.), Developments in European
Company Law, Vol 2/1997: The Quest for an Ideal Legal Form for Small Businesses (London: Kluwer
Law International, 1999); The Strategic Framework, ibid.
6 The term 'closely held firms' is used here to mean firms which are owner managed with few or no
outside investors. Further work is under way on the internal governance issues as part of the Company
Law Review - see The Strategic Framework, ibid.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
Much of the literature discussed below evaluates limited liability on the basis of
economic analysis. This approach measures limited liability in terms of economic
efficiency,' posing three central questions. First, does limited liability allocate risk
to those most capable of bearing it? Secondly, does it result in optimal levels of
risk taking, ensuring that ventures with a net positive value to society, but not
others, are undertaken? Thirdly, does it reduce transaction and monitoring costs? In
this literature, these measures of 'efficiency' operate within an overall framework
of profit maximisation. All forms of satisfaction can be incorporated into this
concept, but they must be given a value in monetary terms. This may lead to many
interests and values being hidden or cancelled out simply in order to produce a
workable model.8 Economic analysis assumes that a society with greater wealth,
measured in terms of profit maximisation, is necessarily better off than a society
with less.9 Self-interest remains the guiding force in this world: all is explained
through this medium.10 In broad terms the test of efficiency used by these analysts
(the Kaldor-Hicks test) is whether the aggregate benefits of the system exceed the
costs to such an extent that the winners could compensate the losers.11
As will be seen below, even accepting the measures and approach of economic
analysis, there are strong arguments in support of the view that limited liability is
not efficient for the smallest firms. In addition, it is argued here that efficiency is
not the only test to be applied. Other values must also be weighed in the balance.12
These other values should be seen as moderating the efficiency test, not simply
contributing to it, although they are sometimes explained away in terms of
efficiency by the economic analysts.13 These underlying considerations, reflecting
society's values, need to be exposed and discussed in order to ensure that legal
policy does properly reflect moral and political criteria. The danger is that they will
be lost under an all subsuming cloak of 'efficiency'. There may come a point at
7 For the different types of efficiency and generally an excellent discussion of the relevance of
economic analysis to company law see S. Deakin and A. Hughes, 'Economics and company law
reform: a fruitful partnership?' (1999) 20 Company Lawyer 212 (hereafter Deakin and Hughes). See
also S. Deakin and A. Hughes, 'Economic Efficiency and the Procedularisation of Company Law'
[1999] CfiLR 169; C.W.Maughan and S.F.Copp, 'Company law reform and economic methodology
revisited' (2000) 21 Company Lawyer 14.
8 G Lawson, 'Efficiency and Individualism' (1992) Duke Law Journal 42:1 53.
9 R. Dworkin A Matter of Principle (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986) 237.
10 R. Posner, Economic Analysis of Law (New York: Aspen Law and Business, 5th ed, 1998) 3.
11 Note that there does not need to be actual compensation. Kaldor-Hicks efficiency is easier to achieve
than Pareto efficiency, which would require someone to be better off and no-one to be worse off: see
Jules L Coleman, Markets, Morals and the Law, (Cambridge: CUP, 1988) chapter 2; Brian R.
Cheffins, Company Law: Theory, Structure, and Operation (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1997) 14-16.
12 Deakin and Hughes, n 7 above, 217.
13 Deakin and Hughes in CfiLR, n 7 above, 171.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
21 Twenty per cent of UK firms are companies, 61 per cent sole proprietorships and 19 per cent
partnerships. Of the 3.7 million businesses in the UK in 1998, over 2.3 million were 'size class zero'
businesses (sole traders or partners without employees). SME Statistics 1999, n 19 above. The US
statistics also seem to show that large numbers of the self-employed act in a 'routinized service
capacity' see Gabaldon, n 16 above, fn 1433.
22 On entrepreneurship see P. Moran 'Personality Characteristics and Growth-orientation of the Small
Business Owner-manager' (1998) 16 (63) International Small Business Journal 17.
23 A number of different models are claimed for the LLC, from the Panamanian limitadas to the German
Gesellschaft mit besechrankter Haftung (GmbH): Richard A. Booth, 'The Limited Liability Company
and the Search for a Bright Line Between Corporations and Partnerships' (1997) 32 Wake Forest Law
Review 79; Ernest A. Seemann, 'The Florida Limited Liability Company: An Update' (1990) 14
Nova Law Review 900; CCH, Guide to Limited Liability Companies (Chicago: CCH, 4th ed, 1997)
(hereafter CCH Guide).
24 William J. Carney, 'Limited Liability Companies: Origins and Antecedents' (1995) 66 University of
Colorado Law Review 855.
25 The Hamilton Brothers Oil Company approached Wyoming to create legislation permitting
vehicle: Carney, ibid 857.
26 The rapid increase in LLCs therefore probably represents conversions from limited partnersh
corporate form as well as from general partnerships and sole tradership: Larry E. Ribstein 'Statu
Forms for Closely Held Firms: Theories and Evidence from LLCs' (1995) 73 WULQ 369 (herea
Ribstein (1995)).
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
37 For example, Larry E. Ribstein 'The Deregulation of Limited Liability and the Death of Partnership'
(1992) 70 WULQ 417 (hereafter Ribstein (1992)); Ribstein (1995), n 26 above; S. J. Orsi, 'The
Limited Liability Company: An Organizational Alternative for Small Business' (1991) 70 Nebraska
Law Review 150; Bernard Black in Ribstein and Sargent, n 35 above, 611.
38 Larry E. Ribstein in Ribstein and Sargent, ibid 638. This is not very far removed from the LLC in any
event. See now in the UK the tentative proposals to limit the liability of bankrupt unincorporated
traders by allowing them to retain up to ?20,000 pound for pound matching their investment in their
business: DTI Press Release, Byers Outlines Details of Bankruptcy Study P/99/575 2 July 1999.
39 Larry E. Ribstein, 'Limited Liability and Theories of the Corporation' (1991) 50 Maryland Law
Review 80 (hereafter Ribstein (1991)); Ribstein (1992), n 37 above, although later writings by the
same author make less firm claims for limited liability in relation to small firms see Ribstein (1995), n
26 above and R. Hillman ' Limited Liability and Externalization of Risk: A Comment on the Death of
Partnership' (1992) 70 WULQ 477; Jonathan R. Macey, 'The Limited Liability Company: Lessons
for Corporate Law' (1995) 73 WULQ 433.
40 Ribstein (1992), n 37 above, 417.
41 To form an LLC, articles of association must be filed with the chosen state but operations are
generally governed by an operating agreement The articles usually include minimal information such
as the name and registered office of the LLC and details about management and date of dissolution.
They do not define the powers of the LLC. If the purposes have to be set out then this is in general
terms only. Annual filing provisions are also minimal and, in particular, do not include the filing of
accounts, although tax returns normally have to be kept by the LLC, available for inspection by
members: CCH Guide, n 23 above, chapter 3.
42 The USA literature also discusses in detail the efficiency of the standard form defaults provided by
the LLC statutes: see especially Ribstein (1995), n 26 above and Dennis S. Karjala, 'Planning
Problems in the Limited Liability Company' (1995) 73 WULQ 455 (hereafter Karjala (1995)). This
question is referred to where relevant but not discussed exhaustively in this article.
43 In the ULLCA 1995 the parties' choice on whether to be member-managed or manager managed
controls questions of authority, fiduciary duties and dissolution characteristics, for example: see
prefatory note to the Act. Most states provide for at-will or fixed term dissolution and for member
management in their LLC statutes. These clauses stem from the original tax requirements that the
entity should not have continuity of life or centralised management and both are now usually subject
to contrary agreement, following the tax changes described above. The ULLCA default allows owners
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
to demand payment of the fair value of their interests at any time in order to exit. If this right is
excluded by agreement, an owner may apply for a judicial dissolution.
44 See n 198 below and text thereto.
45 Saul Levmore, 'Partnership, Limited Liability Companies, and Taxes: A Comment on the Survival o
Organizational Forms' (1992) 70 WULQ 489, 492; Hillman n 39 above; R. Hamilton and L. Ribstein
(a debate) 'Limited Liability and the Real World' (1997) 54 Washington and Lee Law Review 687;
Mark J. Roe, 'Chaos and Evolution in Law and Economics' (1996) 109 Harvard Law Review 641.
On interest group theories see also Macey, n 39 above, W. Bratton and J. McCahery 'An Inquiry into
the Efficiency of the Limited Liability Company: Of Theory of the Firm and Regulatory Competition
[1997] 54 Washington and Lee Law Review 629. For a more general discussion of interest group
theories see R. Baldwin and M. Cave, Understanding Regulation (Oxford: OUP, 1999) chapter 3 an
works cited there.
46 Karjala (1995), n 42 above, argues that similar internal structural freedom could already be achieved
under modern corporation statutes.
47 CCH Guide, n 23 above,18; Ribstein and Sargent, n 35 above 637. A few states spell out the position
in their LLC enabling statute - CCH Guide, n 23 above, 44.
48 See Dennis S. Karjala, 'A Second Look at Special Close Corporation Legislation', (1981) 58 Tex L
Rev. 1207; Ian Ayres 'Judging the Close Corporation in the Age of Statutes' (1992) 70 WULQ 353.
49 CCH Guide, n 23 above 18; Michael Bamberger in Ribstein and Sargent, n 35 above, 626.
50 Karjala (1995), n 42 above; Ribstein and Sargent ibid.
51 Walter D. Schwidetzky in Ribstein and Sargent ibid 617. Schwidetzky ascribes the term 'hyperlexis',
meaning 'pathological condition caused by an over-active law-making gland' to Bayless Manning.
52 Allan W. Vestal, '"Assume a Rather Large Boat": The Mess We Have Made of Partnership Law'
(1997) 54 Wash & Lee L Rev. 487 (hereafter Vestal) 516.
53 Bratton and McCahery, n 45 above. Note that their discussion is purely in terms of economic
efficiency.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
76 H. Manne, 'Our Two Corporation Systems: Law and Economics' (1967) 53 Va. L. Rev 259; Halpern
et al n 70 above; F. Easterbrook and D. Fischel, 'Limited Liability and the Corporation' (1985) 52
University of Chicago Law Review 89; R. Posner, n 10 above, chapter 14; Cheffins, n 11 above.
77 This, and the summary of the arguments which follows, are taken mainly from Frank H. Easterbrook and
Daniel R. Fischel, The Economic Structure of Corporate Law (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard
University Press, 1991) (hereafter Easterbrook and Fischel), Posner n 10 above and Manne, ibid.
78 R. J. Mofsky and R. Tollinson 'Piercing the Veil of Limited Liability' (1979) 4 Delaware Journal of
Corporate Law 351 also contend that limited liability does not arbitrarily impose unwarranted costs
on involuntary creditors because the cost to consumers will reflect where the tort risk falls.
79 Kevin F. Forbes, 'Limited Liability and the Development of the Business Corporation' (1986) 2
Journal of Law, Economics and Organisation 163; Halpern et al, n 70 above.
80 Easterbrook and Fischel, n 77 above, 45, discussed further below.
81 Hansmann and Kraakman, n 72 above. But see Grundfest, 'The Limited Future of Unlimited Liability:
A Capital Markets Perspective' (1992) 102 Yale L J 387; H. Hansmann and R. Kraakman, 'Do the
Capital Markets Compel Limited Liability? A Response to Professor Grundfest' (1992) 102 Yale LJ
427; D. Leebron, 'Limited Liability, Tort Victims and Creditors' (1991) 91 Colum L Rev 1565.
82 Bratton and McCahery, n 45 above, 640 et seq who show, for example, that this literature questions
the assumption of the 'first generation agency theory' of Jensen and Meckling and others that a single
optimal capital and ownership structure for the firm exists as a theoretical proposition. They cite
Joseph T. Williams, 'Perquisites, Risk and Capital Structure' (1987) 42 J Fin 29; Oliver Hart, Firms,
Contracts and Financial Structure (New York: Clarendon Press, 1995) .
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
83 Bengt Holmstrom, 'Moral Hazard in Teams' (1982) 13 Bell J Econ 324 discussed in Bratton and
McCahery, ibid, 649.
84 On institutional shareholders and corporate governance see Paul L. Davies 'Institutional Investors in
the United Kingdom' in D. Prentice (ed) Contemporary Issues in Corporate Governance (Oxford:
OUP, 1993); Paul L. Davies 'The United Kingdom' in T. Baums and E. Wymeersch (eds)
Shareholder Voting Rights and Practices in Europe and the United States (London: Kluwer Law
International, 1999); V. Finch 'Company Directors: Who Cares about Skill and Care? (1992) 55 MLR
179; Committee on Corporate Governance, The Combined Code June 1998. A Committee of Inquiry
into UK Vote Execution has recommended that 'regular, considered voting should be regarded as a
fiduciary responsibility' for institutional investors: National Association of Pension Funds Press
Release, 5 July 1999.
85 For example see Andrew Winton, 'Limitation of Liability and the Ownership Structure of the Firm'
(1993) 48 J Fin 487. He considers that increased shareholder liability could have productivity benefits
and is interconnected with the efficient choice of ownership structure (discussed in Bratton and
McCahery, n 45 above, 651).
86 Particularly in relation to private, undercapitalised companies and groups: Halpern et al, n 70 above,
discussed further below; Jonathan M. Landers, 'A Unified Approach to Parent, Subsidiary, and
Affiliate Questions in Bankruptcy' (1975) 42 U Chi L Rev 589.
87 Easterbrook and Fischel, n 77 above, 44.
88 Posner, n 10 above, 432.
89 Easterbrook and Fischel, n 77 above, 50.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
97 For example, Manne, n 76 above; Fama and Jensen, n 75 above; Easterbrook and Fischel, n 76 above;
Frank H. Easterbrook and Daniel R. Fischel 'Close Corporations and Agency Costs' (1986) 38 Stan L
Rev 271 (hereafter Easterbrook and Fischel 1986); Halpern et al, n 70 above.
98 These analysts do not purport to be describing the 'real world' but argue that a lack of realism is a
precondition of theory. An attempt to reproduce the complexity of the empirical world would be a
description and not a theory see Posner, n 10 above, 18. The value of the theory may be questionable
if the models are too far removed from reality, however and it may be better to produce a less clear
but also less misleading analysis: - see Deakin and Hughes, n 7 above, 215.
99 Freedman (1994), n 5 above; T. O'Neill, 'Toward a New Theory of the Closely-Held Firm' (1993)
Seton Hall Law Review 603.
100 See Easterbrook and Fischel, n 77 above, 56; Easterbrook and Fischel 1986, n 97 above and Halp
et al, n 70 above for discussions of the arguments summarised here.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
105 Insolvency Act 1986, ss 213 and 214. See Paul L. Davies, G
Law (London: Sweet and Maxwell, 6th ed, 1997), 151-155 a
Farrar's Company Law (London: Butterworths, 4th ed, 1998) 7
case law. Also V. Finch 'Directors' Duties: Insolvency and the
Current Issues in Insolvency Law (London: Stevens, 1991).
106 See S. Wheeler, 'Swelling the Assets for Distribution in Corpo
'Wrongful Trading - Has it been a failure?' (1993) Insolvency Law a
are recovered under sections 213 or 214, it seems they are available
of a charge - see for example Re Oasis Merchandising Services L
(CA) cited by Farrar and Hannigan, ibid in support of this point
Smoke without Fire?' (1995) Palmer's In Company (September
Insolvency' [1998] CfiLR 121 who argues that the attitude shown
provides some cause for optimism that innovative funding mechan
107 Fama and Jensen, n 75 above.
108 In the author's survey 66 per cent gave limited liability as a r
prestige and credibility: Freedman (1994), n 5 above. See also
Business School, Your Business Legal Structure (Manchester:
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
116 Another suggestion which has been made is that directors should not be appointed to limited liability
companies unless they pass an examination or show fitness to run a company in some other way such
as attending a course: see J. Hudson, 'The Limited Liability Company: Success, Failure and Future'
(1989) 161 Royal Bank of Scotland Review 26; Finch, n 84 above; IOD Press Release July 1999, New
Standard for Company Directors (announcing new qualification for directors which would not,
however appear to be suitable for start ups since it requires three years experience). These proposals,
though, do not relate to economic suitability - one may be very aware but still dishonest!
117 Within the European Union only the UK and Ireland do not have a minimum capital requirement for
private companies: the Second Directive on Company Law requires a minimum capital for public
companies. The idea of extending the Second Directive to private companies has been floated but
rejected to date. See Boden de Bandt de Brauw, Jeantet and Uria, Second Directive's Extension to
other Types of Companies (Brussels, 1992); University of Manchester Centre for Law and Business,
Company Law in Europe: Recent Developments, (DTI/University of Manchester, 1999) (hereafter
University of Manchester).
118 Kahn-Freund, n 71 above.
119 See Boden de Bandt de Brauw et al, n 117 above and note the criticisms of the Belgium minimum capital
requirement, for example, as having only an illusory protective role: J. Wouters, 'Towards a European
Private Company? A Belgian Perspective' in H-J De Kluiver and W. Van Gerven (eds) The European
Private Company? (Antwerp: Maklu, 1995) 166. More important, in Belgium, as Wouters notes, is the
requirement that the company's founders must present a business plan to the notary public in which they
justify the amount of capital in the light of the company's projected activities. In addition the founders
are liable in the event of bankruptcy within three years after the formation of the company if the capital
on formation was manifestly insufficient for the normal exercise of the projected activity for a minimum
of two years. Presumably this second provision would be unnecessary if the first was truly effective, but
this does seem to be a significant restriction on limited liability.
120 This decision is, however, the subject of criticism within Sweden. I am grateful to Professors Claes
Norberg and Per Thorell for informing me of this debate. The arguments against the minimum capital
requirement in the Nordic countries appear to be heavily influenced by the law and economics
analysis described here as well as by the practical problems companies are experiencing in doubling
their share capital from 50,000 SEK to 100,000 SEK (?3,750 to ?7,500). The time period for
implementation of the new levels has had to be extended to allow the smallest companies to adapt to
this requirement.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
121 Centros Ltd and Erhvers-og Selskabsstyrelsen Case C-212/97, ECJ. Judgment 9 March 1999 [19
ECR 1-1459.
122 University of Manchester, n 117 above.
123 Company Law Committee Report (chairman Lord Jenkins) Cmnd. 1749 (1962) at para 27.
124 DTI, Company Law Reform White Pape, Cmnd 5391 (1973).
125 The Strategic Framework (1999), n 4 above asks (a)'Is it agreed that it is not desirable to r
access to limited liability? (b) If not, then what constraints should be considered?' (Question 10)
the answers to (a) see text to n 66 above. Where constraints were thought desirable, a min
capital was the most popular approach, supported by the Institute of Chartered Accountan
Scotland, The Association of Chartered Certified Accountants, the Institute of Credit Manag
and the Labour Finance and Industry Group amongst others.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
Mandatory insurance
Another approach found in the general literature on limited liability is that the
adverse effects of risk shifting might be mitigated by mandatory insurance. Again,
though, this could create barriers, particularly for new, small businesses, since the
cost of insurance may be greater where there is no past record.143 Conversely, if
effective monitoring by insurers was not possible, so that insurance was made
available for a risky enterprise at a price not reflecting the full risk, owners might
be encouraged to undertake risky activities which they would not have attempted
without the insurance.144 Such a development would increase moral hazard rather
than decreasing it. Whilst some firms would be encouraged to take risks which
were not beneficial to society, ultimately the existence of insurance for certain
139 As to whether it passes other tests, see part five of this article, below.
140 n 70 above, 149 and see Hansmann and Kraakman, n 72 above.
141 Bratton and McCahery, n 45 above, 639.
142 D. Goddard, 'Corporate Personality Limited Recourse and its Limits' in R. Grantham & C. Rickett
(eds) Corporate Personality in the 20th Century (Oxford: Hart Publishing, 1998).
143 Easterbrook and Fischel, n 77 above, 61.
144 V. Finch, 'Personal Accountability and Corporate Control: The Role of Directors' and Officers'
Liability Insurance' (1994) 57 MLR 880.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
If insurance was always available in the market, there would be less need f
limited liability, but there will be risks which insurance companies will not co
In a perfect world, these would be only the risks that would not benefit society
market failure can occur.146 It will be costly for insurers to gather inform
about large numbers of firms: creditors might be in a better position to eva
risk as they may well deal with fewer firms and have a closer relationship w
them. Halpern et al conclude that, in the type of case where creditors curre
contract out of limited liability - that is, small, high risk firms - insurance w
be unlikely to be available. If insurance were mandatory, the inability of such f
to obtain insurance would indeed have the effect of reducing their access to lim
liability, which is the outcome we seek in some circumstances, but would the
be drawn in the optimal place?
Since a level of insurance cover would have to be fixed upon if the mandat
requirement was to be meaningful,147 the insurance solution has all the difficu
of a minimum capital requirement in terms of fixing this level.148 It would al
difficult to police; possibly more so than a minimum capital requirement, w
could more easily be linked with the registration process. In addition, the argu
for mandatory insurance assumes that insurance will be available w
appropriate and that effective monitoring can and will take place. In essence
mandatory insurance route substitutes the judgement of the insurance mark
(which may be non-specialist and not particularly well positioned to monitor r
for that of the legislator or the creditor about the acceptable level of risk.149
Another modification of the insurance argument is put forward by Leebron
He argues that shareholder/managers in close corporations151 should hav
obligation to provide adequate insurance to meet the claims of foreseeable to
victims. Such an obligation would have the advantage of flexibility. It would b
to the shareholder/managers to decide on adequacy of insurance levels, and t
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modem Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
156 Mitchell, ibid. Mitchell does not seek to explain this odd result b
were similar, n 154 above, 1058, although Ramsay, ibid found a h
Australia than in any other context. The Australian study was of a
157 Adams v Cape Industries plc [1990] Ch 433; Yukong Lines Ltd
Corporation and Ors [1998] BCC 870.
158 Williams and another v Natural Life Health Foods Ltd and another
and C. Rickett, 'Directors' "Tortious" Liability: Contract, Tort or
159 Within the definitions in Insolvency Act 1986, ss 213 and 214
160 See also n 106 above and text thereto.
161 Company Directors Disqualification Act 1986 ss 4 and 6.
162 See ns 105 and 106 above.
163 The deterrent effect of the disqualification provisions has been argued to be weak due to the
number of directors affected and lack of awareness of the provisions: see A. Hicks, Disqualificati
Directors: No Hiding Place for the Unfit? ACCA Research Report 59 (London: Certified Accoun
Educational Trust, London 1998). Professor Sealy has argued, however, that the law on wrongful tr
has had an effect on business, especially as banks may be implicated and so may exert pressu
companies: L. S. Sealy, 'Directors' Personal Liability: English Perspective' in J. Ziegel (ed) Cur
Developments in International and Comparative Insolvency Law (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994) 4
164 Clearly there will be ex ante regulation in individual cases since disqualified directors will not be
to manage new companies for a specified period or may be given leave to act in relation to a spec
company, subject to conditions to protect the public: Re Gibson Davies Ltd. [1995] BCC 11.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
165 See, for example, Harman J in Re Douglas Construction Services Ltd v Anor [1988] 4 BCC 553, 'It is
of vital importance that the court, in operating this very important jurisdiction created by Parliament
for the protection of the public should be careful that it does not so act as to stultify all enterprise. The
purpose and the great value of the invention in 1862 of the limited liability company was to enable
entrepreneurs to take risks without bankrupting themselves'.
166 [1990] BCC 903.
167 See Recommendations of a Joint Institute of Chartered Accountants of Scotland (ICAS) and Institute
of Chartered Accountants in England and Wales (ICAEW) Small Companies Working Party, Getting
Into Shape (London: ICAS/ICAEW, 1999).
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
168 For example, Manne, n 76 above, Posner, n 10 above, 399. See however, Ea
77 above, 237 who argue that the importance of special close corporat
exaggerated since the same result can be achieved by contract.
169 Contrast Hicks n 1 above, who proposes a new unlimited liability regime f
reformed partnership - see Freedman (1999), n 18 above and Freedman (1994),
discussion of internal governance issues.
170 And see Grundfest, n 81 above, 420 who points out the general pressure
Lloyd's names, accountants and lawyers as well as trading firms.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
194 ibid.
195 CCH Guide, n 23 above, 44; Ribstein and Sargent, n 35 above, 645; Karjala (1995), n 42 above, 463
The ULLCA 1995 6303 provides that failure to observe the usual corporate formalities is not a ground
for imposing personal liability. Thompson at n 30 above concludes that liability protection in LLC
will not be markedly different than that under the corporate form, but some uncertainty remains.
196 Macey, n 39 above, 449.
197 Ribstein (1992), n 37 above and Ribstein (1995), n 26 above.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
Conclusion
It has been shown that the arguments for the efficiency of limited liability
widely, although not universally, accepted for public corporations in respect
contractual creditors (though in the case of tort creditors there is som
disagreement). For small, owner-managed or micro-firms, the efficienc
arguments are much less clear. Returning to the economics based questions po
in the first part of this article, first, within very small firms limited liability does
seem to allocate risk to those most capable of bearing it, but rather favo
sophisticated contractual creditors over smaller and involuntary ones. In the lo
run this must weaken the small business sector as well as others, since other sm
businesses frequently lose when one of their number fails.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
May 2000] Limited Liability and Small Firms
207 Often hand in hand with pressure for internal governance reforms, not discussed here.
208 Macey, n 39 above.
C The Modern Law Review Limited 2000 353
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Modern Law Review [Vol. 63
209 The Law Commission recommended to the DTI, in 1994, that education and reform of general
partnership law was the way forward: DTI, Company Law Review: The Law Applicable to Private
Companies, n 5 above. See also Freedman (1994), n 5 above, 583-584. A Law Commission report on
partnership law is now awaited.
210 Vestal, n 72 above.
This content downloaded from 197.232.28.245 on Mon, 20 Apr 2020 11:19:30 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms