Denis O'Hearn - Global Competition
Denis O'Hearn - Global Competition
Denis O'Hearn - Global Competition
Peripherally
DENIS O'HEARN*
University of Wisconsin-Madison
Abstract: This paper challenges the assumption that European integration can reduce core-
periphery inequality within Europe. Global competition will force associated European firms and
states to pursue strategies that impede regional equalisation. Particular attention is given to
regional participation in "leading sectors" during future global expansions and how this will
affect Irish employment. Integration will not significantly increase employment in US sub
sidiaries or indigenous firms, while it will decrease the probability of major investments in
Ireland from the European core. In addition, European transfers used for training, infrastructure
and technology programmes cannot be the basis for Ireland's transformation into a "core"
European economy.
I INTRODUCTION
"This paper was originally prepared for the 1992 Annual Conference of the Sociological
Association of Ireland, Cork, May 1992.1 would like to thank participants in the conference for
their invaluable comments and suggestions. I am also thankful to the anonymous reviewers of
The Economic and Social Review for their helpful criticisms and comments. Funding for the
research was provided by the Graduate School of the University of Wisconsin-Madison. Office
and research facilities in Ireland were graciously provided by the Sociology Department, Univer
sity College Dublin. The Industrial Development Authority of Ireland provided access to data
from their surveys of employment and components of sales of firms operating in Ireland. The
author invites comments and criticisms addressed to him at the Department of Sociology,
University of Wisconsin, Madison, WI 53706.
demand, economic structure, transactions costs and economies of scale. Even
studies which recognise the importance of Irish peripherality tend to pose
"periphery" merely as a geographical concept which increases economic costs
(e.g., Bradley, Fitz Gerald and Kearney, 1992). This paper introduces socio
logical and political power variables to the analyses of European integration
and Irish economic change. I argue that the hierarchical structure of Europe
and the global economy is the major blockage to favourable economic change
i n Ireland.
There are two broad positions about European integration and regional
inequality. One holds that Europe is moving away from the historical colonial
model which promoted, or at least allowed, extreme inequalities between the
"developed" and "less-developed" countries. John Hume of the Social and
Democratic Labour Party, for example, insists that "the imperialists have
learned their lesson". Instead of exploitation, European unity will bring
prosperity to all of its regions, including all of Ireland, from the Bogside to
Ballyhaunis. From this point of view, a stable and prosperous Europe
requires prosperous regions, which will be achieved through the progressive
equalisation of levels of development throughout the community. The term
cohesion was coined to capture this concept. Rather than questioning or
testing the motives of powerful core European actors, this argument assumes
that "social and economic cohesion" really is a major European policy goal —
rather than just a stated goal — and that all European regions have a
"commonality of interests towards ... an external environment" (CEC, 1992,
pp. 10-11).
I explore a second view, which holds that the current transition is not
systemic. I t is another repetition of a form of global crisis and conflict that
has appeared with some regularity since the world capitalist system was
established. As Chase-Dunn (1989) puts i t , the "deep structure" of global
capitalism, whereby capitals from spatially restricted core regions strive to
maximise and dominate global accumulation, has not changed. Emerging
p
strategies i n the United States, Japan and'Eur6pe^are' attempts to compete
successfully within the system. This may require domination of the system,
but not its transformation. I n other words, the global hierarchy of core, semi-
peripheral, and peripheral zones, each with a clearly defined position i n a
global division of labour and a position of relative power or subordination i n
the interstate political economic regime, will remain i n place even while the
major core powers compete (for a review of arguments on the reproduction of
the core-periphery hierarchy, see Chase-Dunn, 1989, pp. 228-255). Only Italy
and Japan have achieved upward mobility into the core i n our time. What is
at stake for countries of the European periphery is whether their association
with the European core i n a political and economic union will hasten their
upward mobility from semi-periphery to core, or whether internal European
political and economic structures will reproduce or even solidify the European
core-periphery hierarchy.
Industrial Investment
For thirty-five years, the attraction of foreign capital has been the central
strategy for Irish prosperity. Despite common agreement that indigenous
sectors should be the main basis of future industrial growth, and despite an
upgrading of policies aimed at indigenous industry following the Telesis and
Culliton Reports (NESC, 1982 and Review Group, 1992), the proportion of
state industrial grants to local industry has hardly risen and indigenous
manufacturing continues to stagnate. During the limited upsurge of
industrial activity between 1988 and 1991, for example, indigenous industry
accounted for only 2,405 of the 12,359 net jobs created in industry, or just
under one-fifth (IDA, 1992). The profitability of Irish firms remains
remarkably low. According to unpublished I D A data, indigenous firms
averaged a profit rate of just 2.99 per cent of total sales during 1983-90. Most
disturbingly, profit rates of indigenous firms i n the leading sectors —
chemicals, metals and miscellaneous manufactures — averaged 0.20 per cent
during the same period. The possibility of achieving a vibrant domestic
presence i n the leading economic sectors remains highly questionable so long
as core regions monopolise key technologies and European peripheral states
are subject to EC restrictions on trade and industrial policies that might
promote indigenous growth (such as Korean-style selective protection,
exchange-rate controls, and sanctions for poor performance).
How will the competitive conflict among the core powers of the global
economy affect the expansion of foreign firms into Ireland? Global crisis and
competition generate two important impulses to the outward expansion of
core investments. First, capitalist crisis is associated w i t h falling rates of
profit, or at least with increasing difficulties i n realising profits on the
expanded level of commodity output which follows a long expansionary phase.
I f firms hope to survive the crisis, they must intensively seek new markets,
cheaper ways of producing, and cheaper materials. Cyclical expansions of
foreign investment thus accompany crises, and are not necessarily indicators
of global prosperity (Gordon, 1988). The other major source of outward expan
sion is the effort by the core firms and states to dominate the new tech
nologies that will lead accumulation during the next upswing. Success
requires the domination of the newest technologies, of markets, and of
sources of raw materials. To the extent that new labour-saving technologies
are generalised throughout core industrial sectors, they may decrease the
attractiveness of cheap peripheral labour for the core. Ireland's attractiveness
may therefore continue to stem from its position as a point of entry into
European markets, and this will be confined to US and Asian rather than
European investments.
The attraction of foreign investments is often considered to be the success
story of the Irish export-led regime. Regardless of the island's overall
economic performance, experts lavished praise on the IDA's ability to attract
inward investment. As early as 1957, Irish experts noted the importance of
the island's position as a gateway for US capital attempting to gain access to
the European market (Carter, 1957). Ironically, Ireland's attractiveness to US
capital was postponed until i t joined the EEC in 1972. A t that time, i t was
under conditions of crisis, rather than expansion, that US capital arrived i n
large quantities.
The pattern of US investments in Ireland appears to be consistent with
Wallerstein's findings about the rise and decline of hegemony — the first
firms to seek new markets under crisis should be i n the consumer goods
sectors that drove the first stage of economic ascent, followed by capital goods
sectors and, finally, services. After a decline of investments i n basic products,
the IDA targeted US electronics firms in the late seventies, and then intro
duced the international services programme during the stagnant years of the
mid-1980s (IDA, 1978). The earliest US investments — concentrated i n basic
manufactures such as metal articles, consumer durables, food, textiles, and
wood — passed their peak by the mid-1970s (see Table 1). Annual new
employment generated i n these sectors between 1975 and 1985, averaged
only about 10 per cent of their 1975 employment level (net new employment
was considerably less, even negative in some sectors). Investments in capital
goods, however, increased into the 1980s. New employment i n US
TransNational Corporations (TNCs) i n machinery and leading high-tech
sectors continued at about 25 per cent of their 1975 employment levels
between 1975 and 1985, peaking i n about 1980-83. Finally, a wave of US
investments i n international services only became significant i n the mid-
1980s, after investments in the other sectors had severely stagnated. The
service sector was the largest source of new employment between 1988 and
1991, when 3,657 new jobs were created i n services compared to 2,542 i n
computers and office machinery. During that time, employment i n services
rose by 2,381 and computers by only 420.
Although other explanations are possible, I would suggest that the severe
investment crisis of the mid-1980s marked the end of a phase of outward
expansion by US TNCs that began during the 1960s, toward the end of the
post-war period of US domination of the global economy. This phase reached
its peak i n Ireland under the conditions of economic (and hegemonic) crisis,
which induced US firms to seek entry into European markets as an adaptive
response. By the mid-1980s, this crisis-induced migration of capital was
practically over and the Irish state could no longer depend on i t as a source of
employment. This helps explain the state's openness to changes proposed by
the Telesis and Culliton reports, which suggested a stronger role for
indigenous firms and a reduction of the programme of capital grants. I t also
explains why influential elites and observers embraced 1992, Maastricht, and
the concept of "cohesion" as Ireland's only hope for the future.
In the event, however, the new competitive forces that were embodied in
the programme for European union led to a revival of US investments in 1988
that was, I would argue, logically distinct from the earlier investments. The
rise i n US investments after 1988 were an innovative response to the per
ceived opportunities of the unified European market, but were also concen-
Metal Cons Leading
Year Food Text. Wood Chem. Arts Mach. Durable Misc. Sectors Serv. Total
1976 213 336 114 196 392 270 331 488 1,230 185 3,758
1977 328 516 109 355 432 288 331 416 1,589 407 4,774 r
1978 186 648 77 214 312 275 330 177 1,934 210 4,379 /—\
1979 513 1,211 126 702 486 318 255 385 1,802 93 5,705 r
1980 55 601 226 302 51 192 264 247 2,226 120 4,299 o
o
1981
1982
1983
77
72
114
455
174
229
187
170
275
246
81
62
209
102
163
163
322
284
446
173
239
460
416
345
1,962
1,957
2,012
116
107
201
4,339
3,574
3,959
H
1984 69 173 247 495 257 338 162 365 1,695 204 4,010 o
1985 50 428 114 47 222 319 322 214 1,168 406 3,279
1986 72 290 79 151 148 175 373 246 1,336 472 3,341 H
1987 52 203 169 57 220 102 287 237 1,148 532 2,996 S
SO
1988 57 608 175 105 236 258 368 330 1,515 750 4,389 o
1989 29 608 214 213 230 349 230 296 1,475 805 4,454
1990 136 560 87 72 147 199 258 194 2,174 915 4,742 %
1991 82 46 73 205 121 163 229 303 2,101 790 4,203 S
1988-
1991 1,304 1,822 549 595 734 969 1,085 1,123 7,265 3,260 17,788 I
<%) 1.7 10.2 3.0 3.3 4.1 5.4 6.1 6.3 40.8 18.3 100.0 w
1976 Employment Levels:
1,764 2,476 1,315 1,133 2,106 1,126 2,667 1,133 7,598 402 21,790
I
*1976-1981 figures are from surveys taken in J a n u a r y of the following year, 1982-1991 surveys were taken i n November of the given year. 3
Source: Unpublished I D A Employment Surveys, 1992.
Note: "food" includes drink and tobacco; "text." is textiles and clothing; "wood" is wooden manufactures, paper and printing, and non-
metallic minerals; "chem." is chemicals; "metal arts" is miscellaneous basic metal manufactures; "mach." is machinery except
machine tools, computers and office machinery; "cons, durable" is automobiles, automobile parts, electrical appliances, a n d
shipbuilding; "misc." is miscellaneous products not i n other categories; "leading sectors" includes pharmaceuticals, machine tools, ^
computers a n d office machinery, electrical engineering, telecommunications equipment, aerospace equipment, instrument 00
1 - 1
engineering, healthcare products, diagnostic medical apparatus, and T V and radio equipment; "serv." is services.
concentrated among firms i n the innovative "leading sectors" that hope to
lead the next expansion of the global economy. These leading sectors —
biotechnologies, robotics, microelectronics and information technologies — are
contained i n the following NACE product groups: pharmaceuticals, machine
tools, computers and office machinery, electronic engineering, telecommuni
cations equipment, television and radio, aerospace equipment, instrument
engineering, healthcare products, and diagnostic medical apparatus. These
product groups also contain "non-leading" products, including some that led
the post-WWII expansion, yet they correspond roughly to what Schumpeter
had i n mind when he spoke of the leading sector and its closely-linked
products which are at the centre of the long expansion. While the "leading
sectors" and services made up only about one-third of new employment i n US
subsidiaries i n the 1970s, they were responsible for six of every ten new jobs
in the US-owned sector during 1988-91 (two-thirds i n 1990-91). The sectoral
dispersion of US investments has thus decreased significantly over time, and
Ireland is increasingly dependent on a few leading sectors as a source of new
foreign investments.
There are several crucial implications of the intensified Irish dependence
on US investments in the leading sectors. First, US subsidiaries i n Ireland
will not necessarily expand further i n response to the unified market. Chemi
cal and electronics subsidiaries i n Ireland, for instance, are significantly
smaller on average than comparable establishments i n core EC countries.
O'Malley (1992, p. 240) interprets this to mean that these subsidiaries do not
need to be as large as EC firms i n order to be competitive i n the unified
market. While this is true, i t is because the stages of production that will
most likely expand as a result of EC liberalisation are located outside of
Ireland. US TNCs do not have to substantially increase their scale of oper
ations i n Ireland i n order to increase the flow of their products into Europe. A
rough indicator of the degree to which firms can increase exports without
substantially increasing their scale of operations is sales per employee.
Unpublished I D A data reveal that US subsidiaries i n the leading sectors
produce about 165,000 dollars of commodities per employee, while other
TNCs produce about 95,000 dollars and Irish firms about 90,000 dollars per
employee. The wave of investments associated with 1992 already appears to
have been a short "bubble", which played itself out much more quickly than
earlier cycles. Employment i n US-owned subsidiaries began to recover i n
1988 and was already falling seriously i n 1991 and 1992 (the net employment
rise fell below 1,000 i n 1991).
Second, even i f TNC subsidiaries i n Ireland expand in order to increase
their supply of commodities to European markets, they are not likely to
increase their use of labour to the same extent, i f at all. US investments are
increasingly i n capital-intensive sectors which provide limited relief to the
island's employment crisis. Although the value of US investments reportedly
reached record levels during 1988-90, the employment generated by these
investments was no higher than levels achieved during the late 1970s and
early 1980s (see Table 1). Capital intensity in these sectors may be expected
to rise even further with the introduction of new production techniques
related to robotics and microprocessing.
Third, i t remains sadly true that the market-oriented investments of US
TNCs create the fewest linkages of any source of investments, and the levels
of linkage are falling as leading sectors such as computers and electronics
increase their share of US investments. As Table 2 shows, during 1983-1990
backward linkages i n US-owned subsidiaries i n the leading sectors (here
defined as pharmaceuticals, computers, and electrical engineering) averaged
about 15 per cent of sales, only half of the average linkages in other TNCs
(about 32 per cent) and a quarter of backward linkages i n indigenous firms
(about 55 per cent). Wages accounted for less than 10 per cent of sales i n the
US subsidiaries, compared to 18 per cent i n other TNCs and 17 per cent i n
Irish firms. US subsidiaries i n the leading sectors created practically no
forward linkages because they exported all of their product, while other TNCs
had average forward linkage rates of about 30 per cent and Irish firms 60 per
cent (of course, the TNC-based model assumes that the compensating advan
tages of exports offset the losses from the absence of forward linkages).
Table 2: Linkages and Profit Rates in US-owned "Leading Sectors", Other TNCs, and
Irish Indigenous Manufacturers, 1983-90 (as % of Sales).
1983 17.24 31.52 60.91 0.95 34.75 61.02 27.85 10.53 0.20
1984 15.86 31.55 56.36 1.36 30.96 59.15 34.73 12.35 2.07
1985 14.55 30.72 56.73 1.14 29.67 62.51 32.43 11.58 1.91
1986 15.13 30.84 56.05 1.33 29.27 59.63 32.32 12.65 2.53
1987 15.44 32.64 56.45 1.29 29.08 62.65 31.81 16.31 3.10
1988 14.00 34.10 54.16 1.58 28.73 62.18 32.58 15.79 4.57
1989 16.80 31.67 54.68 1.51 25.15 62.41 31.14 16.15 4.43
1990 17.74 33.05 54.62 4.37 30.75 64.42 36.82 14.72 3.89
Economic Transfers
Because there is little hope that industrial expansion will reduce regional
inequality, the prevailing core ideology to promote peripheral incorporation is
"cohesion". Cohesion proposes that regional uneven development can be over
come through fiscal transfers from the European core to the periphery. While
positive arguments for Irish accession to the EEC in the 1970s emphasised
the attractiveness of European market access to foreign investors, the
prevailing argument for integration in the 1990s is that i t will bring economic
transfers to Ireland. Even this is often put i n a negative context: that failure
to agree to incorporation will provoke the loss of transfers. The current
argument for peripheral incorporation boils down to the fact that a semi-
peripheral global position — even in permanent dependence on welfare from
the centre of Europe — is better than the poverty and isolation of a peripheral
global position. One cannot help but be struck by the comparison with past
liberal arguments for partition, which claimed that dependence on welfare
from Britain was preferable to the poverty and isolation of an Irish Republic.
How does the recognition of global competition affect our understanding of
the levels and efficacy of transfers? Three principles are paramount here.
First, the levels of transfers will not be allowed to threaten European core
accumulation. Second, certain "core functions" will be kept under core control
and will not be transferred to the European peripheries. Third, there will be
constant core pressures to reformulate the programmes funded by transfers
in ways that will benefit European core accumulation.
Heretofore, core-periphery transfers under the Community Support Frame
work (CSF) have been quite small. The entire community budget amounts
to about 1 per cent of Europe's combined GNP and, even after the planned
rise of CSF funds is completed i n 1993, they will comprise only a quarter of
the EC budget, or one-quarter of 1 per cent of Europe's combined GNP.
Structural and cohesion funds are not likely to rise much further. Germany
and Britain have stated their unwillingness to expand their cohesion contri
butions i f the Maastricht Treaty is approved, suggesting that the core has
effectively h i t a ceiling i n its transfers to the periphery. To complicate
matters, the European periphery is becoming much larger, and no one can
predict the long-term effects of the fall of the Soviet bloc on the shape of
Europe. To the extent that Eastern Europe is incorporated i n the European
sphere of influence, the level of peripheral demands for transfers w i l l
increase, adding further pressure on structural funds. These pressures would
increase i f the European core, i n a drive for global hegemony, adds new
regions of the third world to its zone of influence. A l l of these factors combine
to make peripheral hopes regarding substantial rises in the levels of transfers
seem unrealistic.
I t is one thing to say that core-periphery transfers will remain small. A
more important issue is what effect transfers will have on the core-periphery
hierarchy. The question arises whether transfers, at any level, could sig
nificantly affect core-periphery inequality. This goes to the heart of a dispute
that has exercised critical development theory for some decades: can
exchange-related reforms possibly challenge present patterns of uneven
development without more fundamental changes i n relations of production
and the ownership or control of "core" technologies i n leading sectors? This
question can be answered only by analysing the uses to which transfers will
be put.
According to Bradley, Fitz Gerald and Kearney (1992, p. 56) CSF expen
ditures are distributed i n the following proportions. Forty-two per cent of
expenditures go to human resources, or education and training programmes.
These include specific training programmes for industry and marketing
services, second-level vocational training and apprenticeship schemes, and
various other training schemes. Twenty-seven per cent is spent on improve
ments to physical infrastructure (mainly ports, roads, water and sewerage).
Eighteen per cent goes to farm income supports and agricultural investment
schemes. Fourteen per cent goes to other uses, including grants to industry
(about half) and marketing and R&D.
By far the largest component of CSF (nearly half) funds educational
programmes to enhance the skills of Irish labour. Partly because of a lack of
any other plausible strategies for growth, programmes to "improve human
capital" will probably become even more central to future Irish state policies
(see Review Group, 1992). Such programmes are also important because they
take thousands of workers out of the labour market at any given time,
reducing the official unemployment rate. I t is claimed that training and
educational programmes, by improving the potential productivity of Irish
labour, will change the structure of the economy, making i t more competitive
internationally.
A recent report by the ESRI, for instance, uses the European-designed
HERMES econometric programme to generate a model of the likely effects of
EC-funded "human capital" programmes (Bradley, Fitz Gerald and Kearney,
1992). As with any econometric model, the results are highly dependent on its
assumptions, which can be highly unrealistic. I n this case, the use of struc
tural funds for educational purposes (the enhancement of "human capital") is
assumed to have a 7.5 per cent long-run rate of return, on the basis of one
study of "human capital" programmes i n the United States. The 7.5 per cent
rate of return is also convenient because i t provides a "reasonable margin of
risk over and above the expected medium-term real rate of interest" (p. 82).
Yet there is no realistic basis, apart from wishful thinking, for assuming this
rate of return. The experience of a core economy which participates fully in
the industrial processes of the global economy and, furthermore, has no
problem of emigration of educated labour, cannot be assumed i n a peripheral
region like Ireland.
Indeed, research indicates that Irish "human capital" programmes have
been highly ineffective, particularly with respect to the prospect of finding
jobs for trainees (without which there will be no return to expenditures).
Breen (1991) finds that participation in state programmes by school-leavers
does not affect their probability of being employed one year after they leave
the programme. There is no empirical or logical reason to expect any new
programmes to fare better and, indeed, the likelihood is that such "human
capital" programmes w i l l primarily serve the function of providing excess
skilled labour for the core economies of Europe, as previous Irish emigration
provided vital labour supplies for US and British industrialisation. Clearly,
programmes that increase the skills and education of a population are "good",
and I am not arguing against them, but only against assumptions that
simplify the relationship between skill-formation and economic growth. The
main structural blockage to Irish participation in high-tech production is i n
the control of technologies and markets by core states and firms, and not the
lack of skilled Irish labour.
The second largest component of CSF is designated by the EC as
"measures to offset the effects of peripherality". These funds are spent on
improvements to physical infrastructure, particularly transport and com
munications. This concept of "peripherality" — which is completely defined by
spatial remoteness — is deliberately deceptive. Peripherality is a logical, not
just a spatial, characteristic, which refers to the concentration in certain
regions of particular kinds of production, such as the export-platform, which
ultimately benefit accumulation i n core regions. "Core" economic activities
employ more advanced technologies, are more capital intensive, pay higher
wages, expand more rapidly, and ultimately receive higher returns to labour
expended i n production. Cores have always attempted to improve the
infrastructure of peripheries — bringing them spatially "closer" to the
productive centres — by investing i n roads, ports, railroads, and so on. Rather
than decreasing peripherality, however, these expenditures enable the core to
operate more profitably i n the periphery. Infrastructural expenditures
peripheralise regions i n the world-system, rather than decreasing their
peripherality. Likewise, infrastructural improvements i n Ireland, while
bringing obvious (though mixed) benefits to the local populations, are most
notable for their impact on facilitating the operations of foreign producers on
the island.
One transfer programme, on the surface, might appear to have more
promise of affecting the core-periphery hierarchy. A small proportion of
transfers finances programmes for research and technical development i n the
peripheries. I f a major cause of uneven development is the core monopoly of
profitable technologies, i t would seem that programmes to increase the
technological capabilities of the periphery would reduce long-term regional
inequality. Instead, EC technology programmes are designed to concretise
uneven regional access to technology. First, technological programmes for the
peripheries are puny relative to those i n the core. Second, they are defined i n
such a way as to improve the technological infrastructures necessary to
encourage new external investments, rather than actually enhancing the
abilities of peripheral regions to compete i n core industries. Third, the
European core insists on retaining the largest and most important techno-
logical programmes, while allowing the periphery to participate only i n less
crucial technologies. A n d fourth, the most important technologies which
enable capitalist firms to achieve competitive advantage are privately owned
or controlled, not part of public technology programmes. A t the very least, the
technologies being advanced by EC programmes will require complementary
private capabilities that will remain beyond peripheral firms.
There is a hierarchy of access to technologies, with the core regions and
firms having complete access to the most profitable technologies while
peripheries participate i n smaller and less crucial programmes. A recent
evaluation of the EC Framework Programme, while attempting to paint the
best possible picture on the role of core-periphery transfers of technology,
admits that "some projects ... can only be created once for the whole
Community" and i n these cases "the Less Favoured Regions may not be the
best location for such installations." Peripheral regions, according to the
report, are only satisfactory for inclusion i n "small-scale" technology
programmes where a large number of research facilities can be established
"and thus be located i n a number of regions, including Less Favoured
Regions." The requirements of European global competitiveness clearly
predominates i n the selection process for EC technological projects. Thus,
"there are, of course, other limits to the allocation of substantial resources to
Less Favoured Regions", specifically "the need for resources to be allocated to
the most dynamic partners who are pushing forward the industrial competi
tiveness of Europe" (CEC, 1992, pp. 8-9). I t is clear that the requirements of
global competition will reinforce, rather than reduce, uneven development
among regions of Europe. Peripheral regions like Ireland stand to become
further peripheralised i n technological and economic terms.
IV CONCLUSIONS
Models that assume convergence between European core and peripheral
zones ignore the aspirations of core firms and states to attain or maintain
economic power and the importance of regional inequalities to the acquisition
and retention of power. They especially fail to consider the contradictions
between social goals, such as core-periphery equality and enhanced social
welfare, and economic goals such as the maximisation of the European core's
ability to compete i n the global system.
I have painted a bleak picture for peripheral regions in Europe. Yet, i f the
deep structure of global capitalism has not changed, peripheral and semi-
peripheral regions i n Europe and elsewhere must recognise the implications
of their participation i n a hierarchical structure that provides limited
possibilities for upward mobility. Far from providing an impetus to regional
equalisation, European integration may be expected to reinforce regional
inequalities.
Supposed within-system alternatives like niche-development or "endow
ment based" industrialisation cannot provide solutions, because they
reinforce the-existing productive hierarchy where the core dominates the
most profitable sectors while the periphery is relegated to the "leftovers". This
is the basis of uneven development today. Far from being new, such
"alternatives" were the basis of Irish agrarian-based development since the
seventeenth century. They later became the basis of theories of comparative
advantage, which are among the most important ideological justifications of
the core-periphery hierarchy.
Some people hope that European integration will gain a momentum that
will turn monetary union into fiscal union. This, they argue, would provide
peripheral European citizens with the full range of social welfare benefits
enjoyed i n the core and, thereby, reduce the level of regional income
inequality. While this momentum may exist, one must consider whether the
extension of equal social benefits to the periphery would be such an economic
burden on core resources as to effectively ensure their defeat i n global
economic competition. Furthermore, core-periphery inequality is not pri
marily a continuous stratification of regional income levels, but a productive
hierarchy. While the extension of social welfare to the periphery is a good
thing i f i t reduces poverty and deprivation, i t will not touch the essential
hierarchy of regional uneven development. This can only be effected by
systemic change which allows peripheral regions to fully participate in all
aspects of global production and innovation.
Debate about alternatives must have two components: a strategic debate
and a debate about substance. The strategic debate asks whether the
interstate structures of Europe can be utilised as an arena of struggle for
peripheral interests. Europe, unlike the US, has an immediacy for its
peripheries because many of them participate as member states and
European "citizens". The concept of a "community project", however sham i t
may ultimately be, gives peripheral citizens and states a moral authority to
pursue issues of social justice. But these issues go beyond the European
periphery because the European project also affects peripheral and semi-
peripheral regions throughout the world. I t is, therefore, not enough for semi-
peripheral regions to strive for core status or upward mobility within Europe,
because that would simply turn them into part of the problem — they would
participate i n the subordination of other non-European regions that remain
peripheral.
Beyond the strategic question, however, is the question of structural
alternatives to the present system. While this is not the place to attempt to
articulate such alternatives, they will surely require the removal of the bases
of structural inequality. I have argued that firms and states in the European
core and other cores maintain their position by controlling the technologies
and related markets which are the bases of rapid accumulation. They main
tain these properties because the rules of capitalism confer ownership, and
because the core inter-state system has power to enforce those rules. I n short,
global capitalism is a class-like system, where "class" is based on the
monopoly ownership or non-ownership of specific kinds of property: the most
profitable production processes and technologies. Changing the hierarchy
requires changing the rules of property ownership on which the hierarchy is
based.
Worthwhile alternatives w i l l require new forms of economic decision
making, based on the needs of people and the usefulness of products and
services and not their profitability; the destruction of irrational economic
calculuses that devalue ecological processes such as the reproduction of the
earth's resources; the revaluation of devalued work i n the home, voluntary
work, and "informal" work. Some of these issues require coalition with other
peripheral regions, on the basis of a similarity of their location i n the global
hierarchies of uneven development. Others require solidarity across world-
system hierarchies, because they affect subordinate classes and groups of
people i n all zones of the system.
I f peripheral countries can play a progressive role by being in Europe, and
the efficacy of European membership is still an open question, i t will be
through an adversarial relationship which continually raises issues of uneven
development and irrationality, including the need for all people to participate
in useful labour. Membership would be used to undermine the hierarchical
structures that give rise to these things and to encourage more equal and
rational structures. This, of course, is the opposite of Irish government
strategies i n Europe to date. Semi-peripheral regions like Ireland, which are
in the core but not of the core, have a strategic intermediate position i n the
world system which can make a bridge between peripheral nations and
change-oriented movements i n the core. The first requirement to be effective
in this regard is to t u r n the different peripheral regions' similarities of
economic situation into real political solidarity, on the island of Ireland, i n
the European peripheries, and throughout the peripheral regions of the globe.
REFERENCES