The Non-Performing Loans: Some Bank-Level Evidences
The Non-Performing Loans: Some Bank-Level Evidences
The Non-Performing Loans: Some Bank-Level Evidences
Yixin Hou1
Abstract
This paper looks into the non-performing loan problem in commercial banks. Using the threshold
regression technique, we found some evidences that non-performing loans have non-linear
Key Words: non-performing loan, credit crunch, threshold effect, capital ratio
I. Introduction
A simple definition of non-performing is: A loan that is not earning income and: (1) full payment
of principal and interest is no longer anticipated, (2) principal or interest is 90 days or more
delinquent, or (3) the maturity date has passed and payment in full has not been made.
The issue of non-performing loans (NPLs) has gained increasing attentions in the last few
decades. The immediate consequence of large amount of NPLs in the banking system is bank
failure. Many researches on the cause of bank failures find that asset quality is a statistically
1
Corresponding author Department of Economics, University of Birmingham Edgbaston Birmingham B15 2TT UK
Email address: [email protected]
1
significant predictor of insolvency (e.g. Dermirgue-Kunt 1989, Barr and Siems 1994), and that
failing banking institutions always have high level of non-performing loans prior to failure.
It is argued that the non-performing loans are one of the major causes of the economic stagnation
problems. Each non-performing loan in the financial sector is viewed as an obverse mirror image
of an ailing unprofitable enterprise. From this point of view, the eradiation of non-performing
loans is a necessary condition to improve the economic status. If the non-performing loans are
kept existing and continuously rolled over, the resources are locked up in unprofitable sectors;
thus, hindering the economic growth and impairing the economic efficiency.
the bank level to empirically evaluate how non-performing loans affect commercial banks’ lending
behaviour. The rest of the article is organised as follows. Section 2 provides the definitions of non-
economies. Section 4 explains the methodology for our empirical studies. Section 5 describes the
data. Section 6 gives out the empirical results. And section 7 gives out the conclusion.
There is no global standard to define non-performing loans at the practical level. Variations exist
in terms of the classification system, the scope, and contents. Such problem potentially adds to
disorder and uncertainty in the NPL issues. For example, as described by Se-Hark Park (2003),
during 1990s, there were three different methods of defining non-performing loans in Japan: the
1993 method based on banking laws; the “Bank’s Self-Valuation” in March 1996; and the
“Financial Revival Laws-Based Debt Disclosure” in 1999. These measurements have gradually
broadened the scope and scales of the risk-management method. Similar to the trend in Japan,
more countries, regulators, and banks are moving towards adopting and adapting better and more
consensus practices. For example, in the U.S., federal regulated banks are required to use the five-
tier non-performing loan classification system according to BIS: Pass, Special Mention,
2
Substandard, Doubtful, and Loss. Presently, the five-tier system is the most popular risk
classification method, or, in some cases, a dual system of reporting according to their domestic
policy guidelines as well as the five-tier system. According to BIS, the standard loan
(2) Special Mention: Loans to enterprises which may pose some collection difficulties, for
(3) Substandard: Loans whose interest or principal payments are longer than three months in
arrears of lending conditions are eased. The banks make 10% provision for the unsecured portion
(4) Doubtful: Full liquidation of outstanding debts appears doubtful and the accounts suggest that
there will be a loss, the exact amount of which cannot be determined as yet. Banks make 50%
(5) Virtual Loss and Loss (Unrecoverable): Outstanding debts are regarded as not collectable,
usually loans to firms which applied for legal resolution and protection under bankruptcy laws.
Non-performing loans comprise the loans in the latter three categories, and are further
In addition to the standardised system, efforts have been made to improve the classification of
loans. For example, more countries are shortening the period when unpaid loans become past due,
intending to put loans on lenders’ timetable sooner and require them to address these loans before
losses start to escalate. The International Accounting Standard 39 revised in 2003 focuses on
recognition and measurement of financial instruments and, most importantly, defines and
establishes the measurement and evaluation of impaired loans. As lenders usually make little or no
loss provision for impaired loans, they are at risk to be suddenly forced to reclassify such loans as
a loss and take a full write-down if the borrowers go bankrupt. The initiation of this standard is to
prevent lenders from being caught off-guard. In addition, many global economists, rating
agencies, and organisations such as the World Bank and the Asian Development Bank have begun
2
The details of the loan classifications are collected from various BIS documents.
3
to evaluate the effects of NPLs on GDP growth. They reduce growth estimates to reflect the time
In this paper, we use the standard BIS definition of NPLs, i.e., the last three categories of the BIS
classification. First, the standard definition makes it possible to compare the non-performing loan
problem across countries and banks. Second, the BIS definition is a prudential definition for
NPLs, which includes loans with uncertainty in addition to the virtual loss, thus, it enable banks to
Non-performing loans can lead to efficiency problem for banking sector. It is found by a number
of economists that failing banks tend to be located far from the most-efficient frontier (Berger and
Humphrey (1992), Barr and Siems (1994), DeYoung and Whalen (1994), Wheelock and Wilson
(1994)), because banks don’t optimise their portfolio decisions by lending less than demanded.
What’s more, there are evidences that even among banks that do not fail, there is a negative
relationship between the non-performing loans and performance efficiency (Kwan and Eisenbeis
The phenomena that banks are reluctant to take new risks and commit new loans is described as
the ‘”credit crunch” problem. According to the United States Council of Economic Advisors
(1991), credit crunch is “a situation in which the supply of credit is restricted below the range
usually identified with prevailing market interest rates and the profitability of investment
unwilling to lend, especially when a firm with profitable projects cannot obtain credit in spite of
low interest rates (lower than the expected marginal products). Credit crunch results in excess
demand for credit and hence credit rationing, where loans are allocated via non-price mechanism.
4
The idea of credit crunch has drawn attention when the traditional view failed to satisfactorily
explain the economy state for those countries that suffered from the South-East Asian financial
crisis in 1997. Under the traditional view, the link between the interest rate change and the real
economic activity occurs through investment and consumer durable expenditure. In response to
the currency crisis in 1997, the interest rate was raised. It was strongly believed by IMF that the
hike would help stabilise the foreign currency market and eventually induce banking reform by
crowding out low-profit projects. However, the persistent fall in economic growth rate and the
lasting economic recession cast doubt on the true benefits of the policy and the effectiveness of the
traditional view of the transmission mechanism. The idea of credit crunch addresses an alternative
During a crisis, in order to restore the credibility among creditors and depositors, failing financial
institutions not only try to expand their equity bases, but also reduce their risky assets or change
the composition of the assets portfolio. As a result of such defensive action, the corporate debtors
Specially, the reluctance of banks to lend can be caused by several reasons, such as the increased
especially small-to-medium enterprises (SMEs); risks of a further fall in collateral value, etc.,
which make the interest rate not to serve as the main determinant by banks in credit approval.
Non-performing loans have been viewed to constitute one of the most important factors causing
reluctance for the banks to provide credit. In a high NPL condition, banks increasingly tend to
carry out internal consolidation to improve the asset quality rather than distributing credit. Also,
the high level of NPLs requires banks to raise provision for loan loss that decreases the banks’
revenue and reduces the funds for new lending. The cutback of loans impairs the corporate sector
as they have difficulties in expanding their working capital, blocking their chances of resuming
normal operation or growing. Unavailability of credit to finance firm’s working capitals and
investments might trigger the second round business failure which in turn exacerbates the quality
of bank loans, resulting in a re-emerging of banking or financial failure. In a worse case, it triggers
5
an endless vicious liquidity spiral: As a result of poor economic condition and the depressed
economic growth, the level of NPLs increases the weaker corporate sector makes banks more
reluctant to provide additional credits with insufficient capital, the production sector is further
weakened, resulting in decreases in aggregate demand again, even worse borrowers’ condition
Krueger and Tornell (1999) support the credit crunch view and attribute the credit crunch in
Mexico after the 1995 crisis partially to the bad loans. They point out that banks were burdened
with credits of negative real value, thereby reducing the capacity of the banks in providing fresh
fund for new projects. Agung et. al. (2001) using the macro and micro panel data analyses to study
the existence of a credit crunch in Indonesia after the crisis. Both the macro and micro evidences
show that there was a credit crunch, characterised by an excess demand for loans, starting to
emerge in August 1997, one month after the contagion effects of the exchange rate turmoil in
Thailand spreading to Indonesia. They investigate the relationship between the loan supply and
real lending capacity, lending rates, real out put, bank’s capital ratio, and non-performing loan.
The results show that the coefficients on NPLs are negative and significant, which indicate that
bank credit supply declines with the worsening of the NPLs problem. Westermann (2003)
compares the cases of Germany after the credit boom of the late 1990s and Japan aftermath the
bubble burst in early 1990s. He argues that even though the German banks were in a better
condition than Japanese banks were, as the path of German’s aggregate credit looks so similar to
that of Japan, it is at least unlikely that the German credit slowdown was entirely driven by
demand, while that of Japan was mostly caused by a lack of supply. There must at least be some
supply side changes that affect the aggregate credit, and differences only exist in the magnitude of
the problem. He further points out that the one of the main reasons in Germany for the credit
crunch is the increased risk of non-performing loans after the credit boom.
6
Empirical Methodology forTesting the Effect of Non-Performing Lonas
One implication from the Credit Crunch view is that increased non-performing loans can cause the
decline in commercial bank credits, as banks with high level of non-performing loans in their
portfolio may become increasingly reluctant to take up new risks and commit new loans.
In this paper, we use panel data from individual bank’s balance sheet to empirical assess whether
non-performing loans will negatively affect bank’s lending behaviour. The empirical model is
specified to capture the credit supply side factors. Normally, the supply of loans is determined by
banks’ lending capacity and factors that influence banks’ willingness to provide credits. In this
paper, non-performing loans are also taken into consideration. Based on Credit Crunch view, the
NPLs should have a negative effect on loans, implying that the higher NPLs in a bank’s portfolio,
the less credit that the bank can and is willing to supply.
For a simple commercial bank balance sheet, assets are mainly composed of commercial loans and
other earning assets; while on the liability side, deposits and capital are the main components.
Thus, we can conjecture that the loan growth is affect by deposit growth, capital growth and other
earning assets growth. In addition, we take the non-performing loan growth into consideration.
LGRi , t =a0 +a1 DGR i, t +a2 CGRi , t +a3 OEAGR i, t +a4 NPLGRi,t−1 (1)
where the index i is the index for individual banks and t is the index for time period.
As financial intermediations, commercial banks’ main function is to receive deposits and make
loans to facilitate the flow of capitals. For most of the commercial banks, deposits are the main
7
funding sources for commercial banks’ assets. And loans take up the biggest proportion in the
asset portfolio. With the expansion of the asset size, banks will expand the volume of the loans to
re-balance the asset portfolio. Under the normal situation, loan growth rate is expected to move in
be positive. But according to the non-performing loan hypothesis, when banks are in poor
condition ridden by high level of NPLs, the willingness for the banks to expand loans is decreased,
which implies that loan growth will not be consistent with the expansion of deposits.
Capital is the part of the long-term funds that banks can use with fewer restrictions than other
kinds of funds from outside sources. In addition, capital acts as the safety cushion for bank’s
lending. With a higher capital level, banks will feel more confident and less constrained to extend
loans. In order to maximise profits, which is the primary objective for most of the commercial
banks, banks are supposed to increase lending with the growth of capitals, which implies a
lending and capital is distorted, which suggests the possibility of the negative sign.
substitute for loans for a given amount of total assets. When the banks are heavily ridden by the
non-performing loan problem, they are unwilling to make loans for fear of the generation of new
non-performing loans; instead, they switch for securer assets, such as government bonds or
treasury bills, thus, the substitute effect will be greater. As a result of such greater substitution
effect, the other earning asset growth will have larger negative effects on loan growth. On the
other hand, higher credit risk may impede the growth of other earning asset. With higher credit
risk in portfolio, banks may have to retain more capital rather than investing in other earning
assets to improve the safety position. In addition, higher credit risk will reduce banks’ credit
ranking on the financial markets, which will also reduce their ability to engage in various
investments.
8
Under the non-performing loan hypothesis, the relationship between the loans and non-performing
loan conditions are negative, indicating negative sign associated with non-performing loan growth
rate. In our model, we use the lagged term of the non-performing loan growth. It is because that
the amount of non-performing loans is not normally known until the end of period; however, the
loan decisions are always made at the beginning of the period. Banks make decision according to
their existing non-performing loan situation, which can be roughly represented by the situation of
The Risk-Based Capital Regulation by the Basle Accord II has been playing increasing critical
role in commercial bank decisions. It mandates that banks hold capital in proportion to their
perceived credit risks. The Risk-Based Capital (RBC) is viewed as a regulatory tax that is higher
on assets in categories that are assigned higher risk weights. (Berger and Udell, 1994) As capital is
usually more expensive to raise than other assets, such as insured deposits, therefore, the
implementation of RBC is expected to further magnify the substitution effect, which encourage
banks to switch from the 100 percent risk credit category, such as commercial loans, to assets in 0
Under Basle Accord framework, banks are supposed to perform differently according to their
capital conditions. The reluctance in the supply of credit is expected to be more significant the
greater the proportion of non-performing loans held by the capital-deficient banks. Banks faced
with the requirement to raise their capital ratio to improve their risk position will make efforts to
meet the RBC standards either by raising expensive capital or by reducing risk-weighted assets
through substituting out commercial loans, where the latter enhances the negative effect on loans.
As a result, the capital ratio will affect the lending decision. In addition, it will further influence
According to Basle Accord II, the target ratio of capital to risk weighted assets is set at 8%.
However, the mean capital ratios in our samples that we will show later are all above the required
9
8%, which suggests that banks may have more rigid internal capital ratio requirements. In
response to different characteristics and situations, different samples may have different levels of
effective capital ratio constraints. Thus, in our studies, we need to find out the effective capital
ratios which do play constraining roles for different samples. For each sample, we set
Dummyi ,t =1 if the capital ratio of the examining year t for bank i is equal or higher
than the effective capital ratio we find for that sample, otherwise,
Dummyi ,t =0 . The
adjusted regression equation which including the dummy effect on the constant and the dummy
The variables we use in the regression are potentially endogenous as they are simultaneously
determined through banks’ balance sheet constraints and are correlated with each other. So we
apply the method of two-stage least squares using instrumental variables. Wooldridge (2002)
argues that the two-stage least squares estimator is the most efficient estimator for endogenous
variables. We assume banks’ behaviours are continuous and they re-balance the portfolio at the
each period based on the portfolio of the previous period if nothing abnormal happens. So we use
the first stage to get the estimations for the values of these variables in the current period, and
instrument variables.
10
The Threshold Effect of NPLs
So far, we have emphasised the negative aspects of non-performing loans, i.e., they reduces the
efficiency of resource allocation of the financial system. But in reality, bad loans exist as a natural
consequence of lending behaviour when banks re-balance their portfolio. Banks decide the degree
of risk they will tolerate for a given level of expected return according to their risk preference.
When the level of non-performing loans goes beyond a certain level that banks can accept, the re-
balancing actions will be affected. It implies that the coefficient might change in reference to the
amount of NPLs; and hence, we conjecture that negative effect on lending is non-linear, i.e., there
is a critical threshold level decided by the rate of NPLs to total loans. Banks make lending
decision differently reacting to non-performing loans rate under or above a certain level; when
NPLs increase above the threshold, they start to cause negative effect on lending. The estimation
of the threshold, thus, is the main concern in this study and it will be interesting to compare banks’
Threshold Method
Threshold regression techniques are used to address the question whether regression functions are
identical across all observations in a sample or fall into discrete classes. The threshold models
have a wide variety of applications in economics. Applications include separating and multiple
equilibria, sample split, mixture models, switching models, etc. Hansen (2000) argues that the
The development of threshold regression models can go back to Dagenals (1969). He uses the
durable goods. Hansen (1999) develops the panel threshold regression methods for non-dynamic
panels with individual-specific fixed effects. The basic structural equation for the model is:
where the subscript i indexes the individual and the subscript t indexes time; the scalar
11
y it is the dependent variable, scalar
qit is the threshold variable, and
x it is regressor. In
the model, the observations are divided into two regimes depending on whether the threshold
variable
qit is smaller or larger than the threshold γ . The two regimes are distinguished by
The key issue of threshold method is how to determine the threshold point γ . A simple method
(Berthelemy & Varoudakis 1996) can be carried out as follows: For each possible threshold value,
denote by
σ^ 2j the sum of the squares of the residuals in regressions, which are estimated over
the two sub samples. j=1 and j=2 , which are defined by the breaking point. If
nj is
the size of each sub sample, the quasi log-likelihood of the data for this threshold level is defined
2 2
QL=−∑ j=1 n j ln( σ^ j )
by . The threshold value is chosen as the value which maximises
QL .
In our estimation model, there are two critical thresholds, the non-performing loan rate and capital
{
i,t i,t i, t NPLRi ,t ≥ q
+ a5 Dummy i , t + a6 Dummy i , t NPLGR i , t −1
LGRi , t =
a'1 + a'1 DGR +a'2 CGR +a'3 OEAGR +a '4 NPLGR i ,t −1
i, t' i, t' i ,t ' NPLRi ,t <q
+ a'5 Dummy i , t + a'6 Dummy i , t NPLGR i , t −1
,
(5)
12
where q is the threshold level for the non-performing loan, and
Dummyi ,t =1 if the
capital ratio is greater than the effective capital ratio we find for that sample, and zero otherwise.
V. Data
The bank data are collected from BankScope Database by Bureau Van Dijk, which provides in-
depth comprehensive bank statistics from 1998 to 2005. The banks we have included in our study
are commercial banks. Taking deposits and making loans are their most fundamental functions and
they are all oriented to maximise their profits as the primary objective, which are suitable for the
3
No data available for Malaysia.
13
In our samples, the United States has a most developed financial system with sophisticated risk
management and control mechanism. We can use it as a benchmark to compare its results with
other countries and regions. Japan banks have experienced a prolonged stagnancy since the early
1990s, and the non-performing loan problem lies at the heart. By looking at Japanese banks, we
can find out how the extended non-performing loans affect banks lending behaviour. The Asian
Crisis is still remaining fresh in our mind when the financial systems in Southeast Asian countries
collapsed in 1997. The non-performing loans were mainly the results of over-heated lending in the
economic expansion period prior to the outburst of the financial crisis. Banks heavily burdened by
non-performing loans is one of the most important reasons of the crisis. The time period in our
study is from 1998 to 2005, just after the financial crisis, which enables us to study the lending
behaviour of the banks trying to recovering from the crisis. In the West Europe, we have France as
our sample country. Although France is a developed country as the U.S., it has a quite different
banking system. For the U.S., bank holding companies with larger sizes and wider business scopes
are playing main roles; while, in France, the banking system is characterised by many smaller
savings banks and building societies. As these banks generally do business at smaller scales and
scopes, they may have different attitudes towards risks, and hence, non-performing loans; thus the
lending behaviour may differ as well. We also study the banks in the Eastern European countries.
Most of the countries have experienced dramatic changes in political as well as financial system
since 1990s and some countries have joined or are joining the European Union. Economies in
these countries are growing fairly fast and banks are playing increasing important roles in the
economy. By studying these countries, we may find different pattern for these developing
Franc
U.S. Japan Asian Crisis Eastern Europe
e
13.87
0.41 14.01 5.73 37.21
Asset Growth Rate (%) (31.50
(6.30) (27.639) (21.22) (56.16)
)
1.93 4.11
7.68 1.73 4.05
OEA Growth Rate (%) (39.70 (10.18
(49.13) 24.57 (46.11)
) )
Loan Growth Rate (%) 1.12 -1.51 1.58 0.55 7.76
14
(15.33
(4.94) (20.79) (13.33) (30.72)
)
-0.48
Deposit Growth Rate 0.76 1.49 0.53 1.53
(13.74
(%) (5.47) (21.43) (10.90) (15.35)
)
14.86 3.74
9.36 -12.81 1.13
NPL Growth Rate (%) (90.82 (35.82
(88.83) (42.19) (91.21)
) )
2.52 3.45
1.83 3.77 0.57
Equity Growth Rate (%) (23.20 (35.36
(45.35) (48.17) (55.41)
) )
0.83 6.90 12.18 8.75 8.88
NPLs to Loans Rate (%)
(2.38) (3.18) (15.71) (9.48) (10.92)
15.50 9.96
22.30 11.95 19.11
Capital Ratio (%) (14.61 (12.29
(17.83) (8.43) (12.11)
) )
Table - 2 Basic Data Description
Table -2 presents the mean values for the mean value for each of the yearly growth rates for the
convertible stocks and retained earnings. Equity is the main and most stable components of the
capital which banks own and use for long term. Thus, we use equity as a proxy for the capital.
From the basic data description, we can get a general idea of the situations of banks of different
countries and regions. The United States, as a whole, has much lower non-performing loan levels
than the rest: its average NPL rate is only 0.83% compared to the highest 12.18% for Asian crisis
countries, which implies that commercial banks in the U.S. generally have sound risk managing
and controlling mechanism. While, Asian Crisis countries, are severely hit by the non-performing
loans problems and recovering from the financial crisis during the period we are studying. We can
expect different lending behaviours for them. The Eastern European banks have experienced fast
growth for asset and loans; however, the larger standard errors indicate high volatility and
imbalance of the growth in this sample, which is typical for many developing countries. Thus, we
can anticipate that lending behaviour of the developing countries will be different from those of
15
developed countries. Although the NPL rates are quite high for French banks, 8.75%, banks are
experiencing decreases in non-performing loans with the mean rate -12.81%, which suggests that
loan quality is improving in France in the period of study. Again, we may expect different lending
behaviours of banks with improved loan quality against those of the banks with worsening loan
quality.
For the risk-based capital ratio, all the samples have the mean values above the 8% required
capital ratio according to Basle Accord II. On one hand, it indicates that banks have put emphasis
on reserving adequate amount of capital to improve their risk position. Compared with other
countries, the Asian crisis countries have an especially high capital ratio with the mean value of
22.30%. It shows that banks in these countries are improving their asset quality and capital
adequacy since the crisis. However, we can argue that the increased capital ratio is basically the
result of government rescuing actions. In order to save banks from disasters, governments of these
countries have taken various measures, such as re-capitalising banks using public funds,
establishing special vehicles to move problem loans out of banks, etc.. By these administrative
measurements, the capital ratios are improved, while banks themselves have made fewer efforts.
U.S.
Before estimating the threshold for each sample, we first carry out the Hausman test to make sure
that the sample has specific individual effects so that we can use the Hansen threshold technique.
random effects and the fixed effects is not systematic; in other words, it assumes that
ci is
orthogonal to
x i,t , i.e., the random effects. Thus, if we can reject the
H0 hypothesis, we can
16
use the fixed effects method to determine the threshold. The Hausman test rejects the
H0
hypothesis and shows the evidence of the fixed effects. The major differences are in the other asset
By using the threshold method, we find that the non-performing loan threshold for the U.S. sample
is NPL rate 0.6% and the effective capital ratio is 14.9%, as at such levels that the value of QL
4
5
*** indicates 1% significance, ** indicates 5% significance, and * indicates 10% significance.
17
Overall = 0.2388 Overall = 0.2861
Wald chi2 117.57 235.79
Prob > Chi2 0.0000 0.0000
Table – 4 U.S. sample results
Generally, when banks have non-performing loans less than the threshold, the loan growth rate is
higher as suggested by the constants. Both of the cases have significant constants. When banks
have non-performing loan rate less than 0.6%, the constant is 1.3371; and when banks have non-
performing loan rate greater than 0.6%, the constant is lower at 0.9010. The results indicate that
banks with better risk position (lower non-performing loans) have higher inclination to extend
loans. However, when banks have higher non-performing loans in the portfolio, they may be more
concerned about the risky, and hence, have lower tendency to increase loans.
When we look at the coefficient associated with the non-performing loan growth rates, we find
statistically significant negative coefficient (-0.0089) when banks have non-performing loans more
than the threshold level; on the other hand, when banks have non-performing loans less than the
threshold level, the coefficient is not statistically significant. The results are consistent with our
initial hypothesis that higher non-performing loans than the threshold will hinder banks’ creation
of new loans. By decreasing loans, banks can reduce the possibility of new non-performing loans
generated from new lending. However, when banks’ non-performing loans are below the threshold
level, there is lower tendency for banks to reduce lending as the non-performing loans are under
We find negative coefficients associated with other earning assets growth rates for both cases.
Other earning assets are substitute for loan given a fixed amount of assets for banks to use.
Although making loans are still the most important function for commercial banks; with the
innovation of financial instruments and less activity restriction, banks are expanding their business
scope other than lending in order to obtain higher profitability and larger market power. Especially
when banks have less risk constraints, i.e., less non-performing loans, they have more freedom to
engage in various businesses, which is indicated by a higher degree -0.1494 compared with
-0.1008.
18
When we look into the effect of capital adequacy, we find that higher capital ratios which are
above the effective capital ratio (14.9%) have different effects for the two cases. When banks have
non-performing loan rate below the threshold, the capital adequacy helps to accelerate the creation
of new loans, as the coefficients in front of dm are positive and statistically significant
(1.0660). Capital is the safety cushion for credit risk; as a result, higher capital level gives banks
more desire to increase loans. On the other hand, when the non-performing loan rate is higher than
the threshold level, the capital dummy has a statistically significant negative coefficient -2.8329. It
shows that capital plays a stabilising role to reduce the lending growth rate when banks have more
As a whole, we have found some evidences of our hypothesis that non-performing loans reduce
the incentive to increase lending when banks have non-performing loan rate above the threshold
Japan
The Hausman test shows statistically significant evidence of fixed effects and the great difference
For the sample of Japanese banks, we find the threshold of NPL rate is 6.9%, much higher than
19
that of the U.S., which can be justified by a much higher average NPL rate of the raw data. In
additional, because Japanese banks have been suffering from banking problem for quite a long
period ever since the beginning the early 1990s, their ability to adjust lending objective according
to non-performing loan situations may be impaired. Thus, the threshold for them to change their
lending behaviour is quite high. And the effective capital ratio is 11.4%. The result is as follows:
The constant is negative when banks have non-performing loan rate above the threshold level and
is statistically significant. It is consistent with our expectation that banks with poorer loan quality
There is little evidence that the growth of non-performing loans will cause banks in Japan to
reduce their lending in either cases as neither of the coefficients associated with NPL growth is
statistically significant, which is to the contrary of the hypothesis that non-performing loans have
negative effect on bank’s lending. In fact, the results show that non-performing loan growth rate
20
When we look at the other earning asset growth, we find that there are negative coefficients which
are statistically significant for both cases. The negative signs suggest that there are obvious
substitute effects that with the growth of total assets, banks choose to increase other earning assets
rather than extending loans. However, such substitute effect is much larger when banks have non-
performing loans less than the threshold. It shows that banks have less intention to replace loans
by other earning assets when they have poorer loan quality. It may be explained that with bad asset
quality, banks have less ability to engage in other kind of activity as their credit ranking is not high
enough to support them; and what’s more, poorer asset quality may impose constraints for them to
For banks having non-performing loan rate higher than the threshold level, capital adequacy
increases banks’ incentive to increasing lending. Although the coefficient for Dm⋅NPLGR is
negative (-0.0819), the coefficient for Dm is much larger (2.0530). As a result, the combined
effects shows that banks with more capital has higher tendency to increase lending as they are in a
To summaries, from the result of Japanese banks, we have found mixed result as to the effects of
non-performing loans and capital adequacy on banks’ lending behaviour. Although we haven’t
found direct impact that non-performing loans reduce lending, however, when banks face higher
non-performing loan level and lower capital ratio, they have the least incentive to increase their
lending.
We haven’t found clear evidence that non-performing loans have reduction effect on lending.
Alternatively, according to the view of “debt over-hanging” view, the prolonged distress of
banking problem in Japan is caused by the lack of demand rather than the supply. Banks still
increase their lending despite of their NPL problem; however, with the long-lasing stagnation of
the economy, companies have less capacity and incentive to borrow money as they have less
21
South-Eastern Asian Financial Crisis Countries
The Hausman test shows great difference in all the variables, which strongly suggests that we can
The threshold for Asian Crisis countries is 5.6% and the effective capital ratio is 13.5%. The
results are:
22
Prob > Chi2 0.0000 0.0003
Table – 8 Results for Asian sample
Although this sample has the highest mean value of NPLs to loan rate, the threshold is not
relatively high compared with other samples. Most of the banks in this sample were severely
blown by the financial crisis and have been suffered from a lot of difficulty. As a result, they can
tolerate only low level of risk, and changes in the level of non-performing loans will greatly affect
Different from other samples, the results of the constant terms show quite different patterns. When
banks face non-performing loan rate higher than the threshold, they generally have a larger
constant (4.5449) than the constant (4.2506) when they face non-performing loan rate lower than
the threshold, which suggest that “bad” banks increase lending more aggressively than “good”
banks.
We haven’t found statistically significant coefficients associated with non-performing loan growth
rate in either case, which means that although asset quality is a serious problem for banks in this
sample, banks’ lending behaviour are not affected greatly by the large amount of non-performing
loans. After the crisis, governments in South-East Asian countries have taken many rescue
activities such as injection of huge amount of government capital into problematic banks, moving
non-performing loans out of banks, and setting up special government organisations to deal with
non-performing loans, etc.. These activities have given banks disincentive to be worried about
their loan qualities as banks are hoping governments to take action to solve their non-performing
loans. Meanwhile, governments encourage banks to lend more to firms in difficulty, hoping that
more funds can help them get out of the difficulty and make profits to pay back loans. However, in
an economic recession as it was after the Asian Crisis, it is quite hard for firms to make profits
even with enough financing because of the decline in aggregate demand. Thus, it would lead to
more non-performing loans and ended up as a vicious circle. This can to some extent explain why
bank recovery is very slow in these countries after the crisis. By the end of 2005, the average non-
performing loan rate for Thailand, Korea, the Philippines and Indonesia were still around 10%.
23
The same reasons can be used to explain that equity growth rate have positive effect on loan
growth rate (0.0593) when banks have non-performing loan above the threshold. With the growth
of capital which is mainly from government injection, banks use these capitals to extend more
One of the main sources of the capital for the banks in this sample during this period is from
government injection, which doesn’t need banks’ own efforts. Thus, banks are not constrained by
the capital requirements. Because of the government intervention, the improved capital adequacy
doesn’t indicate good bank internal risk management; thus, the capital dummy doesn’t show any
The results are not consistent with that of Agung et. al (2001), who support the Credit Crunch
view. But our results support that of Ghosh and Ghosh (1999), who investigate the Credit Crunch
at the aggregate level for Indonesia, Korea and Thailand during 1997 – 98, and find little evidence
of credit crunch. They attribute the decline of credit in these countries mainly to insufficient
France
The Hausman test again shows the difference in deposit growth rate and suggests the fixed effects
model:
24
Table – 9 Hausman Test for French Sample
We have found that threshold for French banks is 5.75% of the NPL rate, and the effective capital
Both as developed countries, for the sample of French banks, we have a threshold much higher
than that of the U.S. sample. Compared with U.S, France is typically composed of smaller banks
such as savings banks and building societies, while U.S. has a large proportion of large banks and
bank holding companies. Bank holding companies and large commercial banks generally have
more alternative ways to invest in other than making loans. These alternatives make it possible for
banks to switch their business when the non-performing loans go up; thus, the lending behaviour
changes at a relatively low threshold. For smaller banks, loan is the main and the most important
asset. It is not very easy for them to change their behaviour of asset composition until a relatively
The non-performing loan growth doesn’t have statistically significant effect on loan growth rate.
25
During the period we are observing, we find that French sample is experiencing high rate of
decreasing in non-performing loan with the mean rate -12.81%, while the other samples have
positive non-performing loan growth rate. Such improvement may be the result of better internal
risk management. With a better portfolio quality, there is less incentive for bank to reduce lending.
Rather than reducing loans, which enables banks to reduce the base for the new generation of non-
performing loans, banks use better risk management to control non-performing loan while keeping
However, we still can detect from our results that banks with higher non-performing loan rate
have less incentive to increase lending than banks with lower non-performing loan rate. When
banks have non-performing loan rate higher than the threshold, facing with deposit growth, banks
reduce the lending, as we have negative coefficient -0.2394, which is statistically significant. The
coefficients suggest that with more funds generating from deposits which are available for banks
to use, banks intend to use the funds in other ways rather than to increase the loans when they
have many non-performing loans in the loan portfolio. Such evidence can also be found from the
coefficients associated with the other earning asset growth rates. We find that the coefficients are
negative and are statistically significant for both of the cases; however, the coefficient is much
higher -0.2623 when banks have non-performing loan rate higher than the threshold, compared
with -0.0086 when banks have non-performing loan rate below the threshold. When banks have
higher non-performing loans, they switch more of their funds to other earning assets; and such
When the non-performing loan rate is less than the threshold, growth in capital gives banks
incentive to increase lending as the coefficient is 0.2077, which is statistically significant. When
banks have less non-performing loans which implies lower credit risk, there is less constraints for
banks to use the capital. Thus, they extend more loans in order to gain more profits. On the other
hand, when banks have higher non-performing loans, banks have to retain capital to achieve the
We don’t find statistically significant evidence whether the capital adequacy helps to increase
26
lending. It suggests that there is less incentive for banks to increase lending with adequate capital.
As French banks are mainly small banks which are more sensitive to risk and have fewer sources
for raising capital, capital adequacy mainly acts as a safety cushion rather than giving banks
incentive to increase loans. Increasing loans will lead to larger risky asset base; as a result, banks
Finally, the Hausman test again confirms the fixed effects model:
The threshold for the Eastern European sample is 4.3% of the NPL rate and the effective capital
27
No. of groups 165 112
R-sq: Within = 0.4105 Within = 0.2022
Between = 0.1871 Between = 0.1036
Overall = 0.3061 Overall = 0.1356
Wald chi2 50.11 51.17
Prob > Chi2 0.0000 0.0000
Table – 12 Results for Eastern European sample
Different from other samples, we find quite different patterns of banks’ lending behaviour for East
European countries.
Generally speaking, the results show that banks with non-performing loans higher than the
threshold are more aggressive in lending behaviour. The constant term has a large positive value
13.4676, which is statistically significant within 5% level. It suggests that banks with higher non-
performing loans are less risk aversion and increase lending quickly. Again, the results show that
banks increase their lending quickly with increase in capital (0.1033) when banks have non-
performing loan higher than the threshold, and both of the coefficients are statistically significant.
The original data shows that loans are growing much more quickly in this sample. And the mean
non-performing loan to asset rate is second highest and is only lower than that of the South-East
Asian countries sample. In developing countries, banks typically increase their lending
aggressively in order to increase their business and obtain more market power. However, these
banks are always less sophisticated in risk control; as a result, such fast growth in lending will end
up in a vicious cycle that fast growth of non-performing loans is unavoidably accompanied with
high speed of loan growth. For the case of banks having non-performing loan rate less than the
threshold level, the constant is significantly negative (- 31.0899), which suggests that these banks
are much less aggressive in lending. This, in turn, may suggest that the low level of non-
performing loans are the result of prudential lending behaviour, and create a health cycle of
lending behaviour.
In addition, we find that the coefficient associated with other earning asset growth rate is a large
negative figure (-0.3474), which is statistically significant for banks with non-performing loans
higher than the threshold level. It suggests that other earning assets have a large substitute effect
28
on lending. At first glance, it seems to be inconsistent with the speedy growth of lending.
However, when we look at raw data, it shows that the asset growth rate is extraordinary high
40.39% and the loan growth rate only takes a small portion 9.59%. Thus, in this case, rather than
substituting loans out of total assets, other earning assets actually are the complementary for loans.
It indicates that banks are expanding their business widely with the fast development of their
financial markets. With the economic growth and evolution of financial system, banks are trying
to expand their business scope to play more roles in the financial sector rather than just focusing
On the contrary, when banks have non-performing loans lower than the threshold, they are less
regressive in increasing lending as suggested by the estimated coefficients. However, when non-
performing loan rates are under the threshold level, non-performing loans have positive impacts
banks’ lending behaviour with a statistically significant positive coefficient 0.4909. It suggests that
banks may still increase their loans as the generation of non-performing loans is the natural result
The results also suggest that the capital adequacy plays an important role in this sample. Although
this sample have a relatively high average capital ratio (19.11%), the effective capital ratio rate is
fairly low (9.2%), suggesting that that a relative low capital ratio can greatly affect banks’ lending
behaviour. When banks have non-performing loans less than the threshold and have capital
adequacy ratio above the effective value, i.e., the best case in all situations, they have very high
incentive to increase their lending, which is suggested by the very high positive coefficient
39.7979 associated with the capital dummy, and this coefficient is statistically significant.
Comparing the results from the other samples, the coefficient in this sample are of much larger
scale, which implies that banks in Eastern European sample are much more sensitive to capital
adequacy and have great aspiration to increase lending. Banks in expansionary stage are quite
speculative in lending behaviour. Once the capital ratio reaches slightly above the Basle Accord II
required 8% rate, they start to speed their lending. Such phenomenon is different from the other
samples. For developed countries such as the U.S., banks have less incentive to speed expansion
29
and keep the capital adequacy ratio high. Even they have enough capital, they don’t increase the
lending that much. For France and Japan, the capital adequacy doesn’t affect their lending
VII. Conclusion
We have studied how the non-performing loans affect banks’ lending behaviour in different
countries and regions. Our results suggest that non-performing loans have non-linear effects. To
our expectation, we have detected some evidences that higher level of non-performing loans
reduces banks’ aspiration to increase lending. However, countries with different situations have
Evidence is less clear for South-East Asian Crisis countries as a result of distorted financial system
and government intervention. We have found that non-performing loans don’t deter banks’ risky
lending. For Japanese banks, we haven't found the negative influence of non-performing loans on
banks’ lending. The prolonged economic stagnation distorts the generally economic performance.
As a result, the lack of demand for loans may contribute significantly to the extended bank
problem in Japan. For developing countries such as Eastern European countries, banks are
experiencing fast growth, which makes it more difficulty to predict their lending behaviour.
We have also found that the risk-based capital ratio has played a significant role to restrict banks’
risky lending as its initial intention by BIS. Generally speaking, higher capital ratios give more
incentive to increase lending than lower capital ratios when banks have less credit risk in the
portfolio. Theses tendencies are most evident for banks in developed countries such as the U.S., as
it has a well-developed financial systems and sophisticate risk management mechanism. On the
other hand, implementation of risk-based capital requirement can also help to prevent risk-taking
behaviour by calming down over-heated lending behaviour for high risk banks.
30
VIII. Reference
Agung, Juda et.al, “credit Crunch in Indonesia in the Aftermath if the Crisis facts, Causes and
Policy Implications”, directorate of Economic Research and Monetary Policy, Bank of Indonesia,
March 2001
Altman, Edward I. & Anthony Sauders, “An Analysis and Critique of the BIS Proposal on
Capital Adequacy and Ratings”, Journal of Banking and finance, 2001, 25-46
Agenor, P.R., J. Aizenman, A.Hoffmaister, “The Credit Crunch in East Asia: What Can Bank
Excess Liquid Assets Tell Us?”, NBER Working Paper 7915, Ocotber 2000
Arrow, K, “The Theory of Risk Aversion”, In Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing, New York:
Bank of Finland Institute for Economics in Transition, “BOFIT China Review Yearbook
Bank of Japan, “Japan’s Nonperforming Loan Problem”, Quarterly Bulletin November 2002;
Bartel, John & Yiping Huang, “Dealing with the Bad Loans of the Chinese Banks”, Columbia
Berger, Allen N. & Rpbert De Young, “Problem Loans and Cost of efficiency in Commercial
Berger, Allen, & Udell, Grogory F., “Did Risk-Based Capital Allocate Bank Credit and cause A
“Credit Crunch” in the United-Sates?’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol.26, No.3, Part
Batrh, James R., Gerard Caprio Jr., & Ross Levine, “Banking Systems Around the Globe: Do
http://econ.worldbank.org/docs/1079.pdf
Bernanke, Bens, Cara S. Lown & Benjamin M.Friedman, “The Credit Crunch”, Brookings
Berthelemy, J.C. & Varoudakis, A., “Economic Growth, Convergency Clubs, and the Role of
Financial Development”, Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, Vol.48 No.2, 1996, 300-328
31
Besanko, David & George Kanatas, “Regulation of Bank Capital: Do Capital Standards Promote
Borensztein, Eduardo & Jong-wha Lee, ‘Financial Crisis and the Credit Crunch in Korea:
Calem, Paul & Rafeal Rob. “The Impact of Capital-Based Regulation on Bank Risk-Taking”,
Central Bank of Malaysia, “Bank Negara Malaysia Annual Report 2004”, 23 March 2005
Chan-Lau, Jorge A. & Zhao Hui chen, “Financial Crisis and Credit Crunch as a result of
Inefficient Financial Intermediation – with Reference to the Asian Financial Crisis”, 1998;
Hill, 1984
Chen, Johnny P., “Non-performing Loan Securitization in the people’s republic of China’,
Developing and Developed Countries”, IMF Staff Paper 45 (1), 1998, 81-109
Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, Enrica Detragiache, & Poonam Gupta, “Inside the Crisis: An Empirical
Analysis of Banking System in distress”, IMF Working Paper WP/00/56, October 2000
Domic, Ilker & Giovanni Ferri, “The Real Impact of Financial Shocks: Evidence from Korea”,
The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper Series No.2010, October 1998
2004
Furlong, Frederick T. & Keeley, Michael C., “Bank Capital regulation and Asset Risk”,
Economics Review Number 2, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, spring 1987, 20-40
Ghosh, Swati R & Atish R. Ghosh , “East Asia in the Aftermath: Was There a Crunch”’, IMF
32
Hansen, Bruce E., “Threshold Effects in Non-Dynamic Panels: Estimation, Testing, and
Hansen, Bruce E.,”Sample Splitting and Threshold Estimation”, Econometrica, Vol.68, No.3,
2000,575-603
Hancock, Diana & James A Wilcox, “The ‘Credit Crunch’ and the Availability of Credit to Small
Hellmann, Thomas F., Kevin C. Murdock, and Joseph E.Stiglitz, “Liberalization, Moral
Hazard in Banking, and Prudential Regulation: Are Capital Requirements Enough?” The
Hoffmaister, Alexander W. “The Credit Crunch in East Asia: What can Banks Excess Liquid
Assets Tell Us?”, Journal of International Money and Finance 23,2004, 27-47
Jacques, Kevin, & Peter Nigro, “Risk-Based Captial, Portfolio Risk and Bank Capital: A
James, Christopher, “Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans”, Journal of Financial
James, John A., “Portfolio Selection with an Imperfectly Competitive Asset Market”, The
Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol.11, No.5, Dec. 1976, 831-846
Jensen, Michael C., & William H. Meckling, “Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behaviour,
Agency Costs and Ownership Structure”, Journal of financial Economics Vol.3, Issue 4., Oct.,
1976, 305-360
Kim, Daesik & Santomero, Anthony M., “Risk in Banking and Captial Regulation”, The
Kim, dong Wang, Young Soo Lee & Kyung Sung Park, ‘Credit Crunch and Shocks to Firms”
Korean Experience under the Asian Financial Crisis’, Emerging Market Review 3, 2002, 195-210;
Koehn, Michael & Santomero, Anthony M., “Regulation of Bank Capital and Portfolio Risk”,
Finance for Development and Credit Crunch Causes and Cures: Some Evidence from Thailand
Krueger, Anne O., & Aaron Tornell, “The Role of Bank Restructuring in the Recovery from
33
Crises: Mexico 1996 – 98”, NBER Working Paper No. 7042, 1999
Lu, Ding, Shandre M. Thangavelu & Qing Hu, “The Link Between Bank Behavior and Non-
Merton, Robert C., “An Analytic Derivation of the Efficient Portfolio Frontier”, The Journal of
Mitsuru Taniuch, “Recent Development in Japan’s Financial Sector: Bad Loans and Financial
Montgomery, Heather, “The Effect of the Basel Accord on Bank Portfolios in Japan”, Journal of
Park, Se-Hark, ‘Bas Loans and Their Impacts on the Japanese economy: Conceptual and
Practical Issues, and Policy Options’, Discussion Paper series A No. 439, The Institute of
Revankar, Nagesh & Naoyuki Yoshino “An Empirical Analysis of Japanese Banking Behaviour
Santomero, Anthony M., “Modelling the Banking Firm: A Survey”, Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, Vol.16, No.4, Part 2: Bank Market Studies, Nov. 1984, 576-602
Shih, Victor, “Dealing with Non-Performing loans: Political Constraints and Financial Policies in
Stolz, Stephanie, “The Relationship Between Bank Capital, Risk-Taking, and Capital Regulation:
A Review of the Literature”, Kiel Working Paper No.1105, Kiel Institute for World Economics,
Feb., 2002
Suzuki, Kenji, ‘Rethinking Japan’s Bad Loan Management: Implications from a Comparison with
Taggart, Robert A, & Stuart I. Greenbaum, “Bank Capital and Public Regulation”, Journal of
Westermann, Frand, “The credit Crunch: A Comparison of Germany and Japan”, CSEifo Forum
Ye, Yanfei, “The Way of Dealing with Non-performing Loans and Its effects on Maco-statistics in
34